Inflation denotes the prevailing annual rate at which prices of goods and services are increasing. Lecture 4: Open Economy Wage-Price Dynamics (Ch 3 of IDM) All prices tend to rise at broadly the same rate, because, when prices of domestic goods are rising, this will generally be true also of wages, and of the price of imported goods. This is because inflation in one sector of the economy permeates rapidly into other sectors. Ragnar Nymoen University of Oslo, Department of Economics The phrase, a ‘high rate of inflation’ therefore usually describes a situation in which the money values of all goods in an economy are rising at a fast rate. September 11, 2007 1 Hyperinflation (> 100% per year or quarter): a crisis in the monetary and political system of a country. Usually both internal and external causes. Not an issue here. Towards the end of last century, the governments of the “Western world” sought to curb moderately high inflation. High European unemployment a big cost. Were there other ways to curb inflation, at a lower cost? Given that inflation has now become a prime target of economic policy, what is the inflation outlook and how can inflation be controlled using the policy instruments that are recognized as legitimate in liberalized economies? Answers to any of these important questions are model dependent: before an answer can be is given, a view has to been formulated of the major determinants of inflation and about which instruments are available for controlling inflation, and so forth. 3 2 Hence our main-focus is this lecture are models of wage and price setting, because those theories represent the modern understanding of inflation (among decisions makers for example). Models of wage-and-price setting also represent the supply side of the macroeconomic models that are in use for policy analysis, and for forecasting the macroeconomy. In Ch 3 of IDM we emphasize two important models that are relevant to the inflation process of small open economies: the bargaining model, Ch 3.2, and the Phillips curve model, Ch 3.3. The main premise of the bargaining model is that firms and their organized workers are engaged in a partly cooperative and partly conflictual sharing of the rents generated by the operation of the firm. In Norway, a system of bargaining based wage setting has been the framework both for analysis and policy decisions for decades. It represents a main element in the socio-economic system. 4 We give a balanced assessment of the wage bargaining approach and the Phillips curve. Wage bargaining and incomplete competition (Ch 3.2 of IDM) We note from the start that there are similarities and differences: The wage bargaining theory can be interpreted as hypotheses of the steady state. Theoretical developments during the last 20 years of the last century developed a supply-side model based on incomplete competition. The Phillips-curve is a short-run model, from the outset. Wages was modelled as determined by bargaining, allowing coordination on both sides of the bargain. Specifically, wages were not assumed to be determined (completely) by decentralized contracts between individual workers and any single firm (as in efficiency wage models, or in older models assuming perfect competition). Hence, the two models “attack” wage-and price setting from different ends of the short-run/long-run spectrum. Nevertheless, we can embed both models in an ECM (equilibrium correction model), which will help us see the real differences and similarities between the models. Specifically, their different implications about the long-run. Prices are set by monopolistically competitive firms (each firm faces “its own” demand schedule). The newest variant of the Phillips curve, the New Keynesian Phillips curve, contain some new traits relative to the old Phillips curve, but some important properties carry over to the New Keynesian Phillips. The whole framework is referred to as the incomplete competition model of wage and price setting. 5 6 A bargaining theory of the steady-state wage Since price formation plays a role for how wages are bargained, we have to start by a stating our assumptions about price setting. Two sectors: the exposed (e) and sheltered (s) sector. e-sector firms are price takers. In the s-sector there is monopolistic competition among firms. Qe and Qs denote the producer prices in the two sectors. We assume that the consumer price index P is a weighted average of the two prices: (1−φ) P = Qφ s Qe 0<φ<1 (1) where φ is a coefficient that reflects the weight of non-traded goods in private consumption. Assuming a stationary environment, profit maximizing behaviour among firms in the s-sector gives: Ws . >1 (2) Qs = As Ws is the hourly wage cost. As is the average labour productivity, As = Ys/Ls where Ys denotes output (measured as value added) in the sheltered sector, and Ls denotes labour input. The mark-up coefficient is determined by the elasticity of demand facing each firm. Reference: next slide. 7 8 The wage level in the sheltered sector is determined by the following equation: Memo: s-sector price setting Ws = We (3) saying that the sheltered sector wage is proportional to the wage in the exposed sector of the economy. Assume common technology Fs(Lsi). Firm i maximizes: Πi = QsiDi(Qsi/Qs) − WsFs−1(Di(Qsi/Qs) The hourly wage level We is determined by bargaining between labour unions and organizations representing firms. We define real profits, π, as with respect to own price Qsi given demand function Di(Qsi/Qs). 1 oc: Qsi(1 + 1/ElQsi D) = Ws/Fs0 = (1 + 1/ElQsi D)−1 and Fs0 = As in a symmetric equilibrium with Setting Qsi = Qs gives (2). We We 1 Le = (1 − )Ye. Qe Qe Ae For simplicity, we assume that Ye is a non-increasing function of real unit labour costs: We/Qe Ye = Ye( ), Ye0 ≤ 0. (4) Ae π = Ye − 9 10 The core of the theory is that We is settled in accordance with the principle of maximizing the Nash-product denoted N : Using the specifications of the profit and the utility functions, the Nash-product can be expressed as N =(ν − ν0)fπ 1−f ( (5) where ν denotes union utility and ν0 denotes the fall-back utility or reference utility. We specify union utility as We , U, Zν ) P 0 > 0 and ν 0 ≤ 0. Z represents other factors in union preferences. The νW ν U fall-back or reference utility: ν( W̄ , U) P where W̄ is the average level of nominal wages. Assume in following that 0 − ν 0 < 0. νU 0U )f ( or ⎧ ⎨ ⎫f ½ ⎬ W̄ N = ν( P , U, Zν ) − ν0( , U) ⎩ ⎭ P Q Wq e (1 − Wq )1−f ¾1−f 1 )Ye Ae where Wq = We/Qe denotes the producer real wage. We assume that (1), (2) and (3) are taken into account during the bargaining. Note that P can be written in terms of Wq : ν0 = ν0( 11 We 1 (1 − )Ye Qe Ae We W̄ N = ν( , U, Zν ) − ν0( , U) P P P = à We Qe !φ Qe µ ¶ µ ¶φ 1 φ = WqφQe , As As (6) and that the two relative prices P/Qe and W̄ /P are also functions of the real 12 wage Wq : µ P = Wqφ Qe As (7) We Wq 1−φ Qe ´φ = ³ ´φ ³ ´φ = ³ ´φ We e As Qe As As W̄ We = ³ ´φ ³ We P Q Qe ¶φ (8) Using (6)-(4), the N becomes: ⎧ ⎛ ⎞ ⎛ ⎞⎫ ¶ µ ¶¾ 1−φ φ 1−φ φ ⎬f ½µ ⎨ Wq W A W A Wq 1−f q s q s ⎠ ⎝ ⎠ N = ν⎝ , U, Z − ν 1 − Y ν e 0 ⎩ ⎭ εφ εφ Ae Ae (9) The 1st oc condition for a maximum is given by NWq = 0 which defines the bargained real wage Wqb implicitly as Wqb = F (Ae, As, f, U, Zν ), In a wider interpretation, union bargaining power f is negatively related to U , meaning that the total derivative of Web with respect to U is negative even though the partial derivative might be positive. By choosing a log-linear functional form for the G-function in (11), we can write web = me0 + ae + qe + γe1u, γe1 ≤ 0 (12) where web = ln(Web), and ae, qe and u likewise denote the logs of the corresponding variables in (11). For simplicity, we regard As, and Zv as constants, (10) and they are therefore subsumed in me0. (11) Equation (12) represents the hypothesized long-run or steady-state relationship for e-sector wages. Equivalently, for the bargained nominal wage Web: Web = AeQe G(As, f, U, Zν ). The expected non-negative sign of the partial derivative of the G function with respect to U can be shown to depend on the specification of the utility functions. 14 13 Wage bargaining and dynamics For completeness we also express the relationships (1), (2) and (3) in logarithmic form: p = φqs + (1 − φ)qe, 0 < φ < 1, (13) ws = web, (14) qs = ln( ) + ws − as. (15) The long-run model therefor consists of (12)-(15). The four static(!) equations determine web,ws, qs and p. The exogenous variables are ae, qe and u. Assume that wet is determined by the dynamic model wet = β0 + β11mct + β12mct−1 + β21ut + β22ut−1 + αwet−1 + εt. (16) with mct = aet + qet, for simplicity. mct and ut are exogenous in (16). The next question to ask is whether this steady state is dynamically stable. As we have explained in lecture 3, the answer to this question depends on whether the wage level in period t, wet, approaches web in the case where the initial situation is characterized by disequilibrium: we0 6= wb. 15 The exogeneity of ut is assumed because we first want to see which stabilizing mechanisms in wage formation are at work even at a constant and exogenous rate of unemployment. This is a contrast to “natural rate models” of wage dynamics which dominates the macroeconomic policy debate, and which takes it as a given thing that unemployment has to adjust in order to bring about constant wage growth and, eventually, stable inflation. 16 If we apply the same error-correction transformation as in lecture 3, we obtain: ∆wet = β0 + β11∆mct + β21∆ut (17) + (β11 + β12)mct−1 + (β21 + β22)ut−1 + (α − 1)wet−1 + εt For the bargaining theory to be a realistic model of long term wage behaviour, it is necessary that (16) has a stable solution. Since wages usually show a rather smooth evolution through time we state the stability condition as 0 < α < 1, saying that the elasticity of wb with respect to the rate of unemployment is identical to the long—run multiplier of the actual wage wet with respect to ut, and then impose the following restriction on the coefficient of mct−1: β11 + β12 = (1 − α) (20) since (12) implies that the long-run multiplier with respect to mc is unity. Then (19) becomes (18) Subject to the stability condition in (18), equation (17) can be written as ∆wet = β0 + β11∆mct + β21∆ut (19) ½ ¾ β11 + β12 β21 + β22 − (1 − α) wet−1 − mct−1 − ut−1 + εt. 1−α 1−α To reconcile this with the steady-state relationship (12), we define β + β22 γe,1 = 21 , 1−α ∆wet = β0 + β11∆mct + β21∆ut (21) − (1 − α) {wet−1 − mct−1 − γe1ut−1} + εt which is an example of the homogenous ECM (with respect to one explanatory variable, mct). The short-run multiplier with respect to mct is β11, which can be considerably smaller than unity without violating the long-run relationship (12). 18 17 (21) can be re-expressed as 0 Wage bargaining and inflation ∆wet = β0 + β11∆mct + β21∆ut n − (1 − α) we − web or o t−1 (22) + εt To sketch the theory’s implication for inflation, we need to reconsider the three equations (13)-(15). Equation (13) is a definition equation that holds not only in the long run, but also in each time period. Hence, we have 0 ∆wet = β0 + β11∆mct + β21∆ut − (1 − α) {we − mct−1 − γe1ut−1 − me0} + εt, (23) we only need to keep in mind that β00 = β0 − (1 − α)me0 as explained. pt = φqst + (1 − φ)qet Subject to the condition 0 < α < 1 stated above, wage growth is seen to bring the wage level in the direction of the bargained wage web. For example, assume that the sum of price and productivity growth is constant so that ∆mct = gmc, and that the rate of unemployment isnconstant,o ∆ut = 0 . If there is disequilibrium in period t − 1, for example we − web > 0, wage growth n t−1o n o from t − 1 to t will be reduced, and this leads to we − web < we − web t t−1 in the next period. 19 or in terms of growth rates: ∆pt = φ∆qst + (1 − φ)∆qet. (24) The two equations (14), for the s-sector wage, and (15), for the s-sector price level, have different interpretations. They are hypotheses about the steady state. Realistically speaking,e there is no reason why adjustment lags and friction should not be important for wage and price adjustments in the sheltered 20 sector. Hence, it is only in order to simplify the model as much as possible that we write the equations for ∆wst and ∆qst as ∆wst = ∆wet, and ∆qst = ∆wet − ∆aet. (25) (26) showing that the bargaining model implies the following explanation of inflation in a small-open economy: 1. Autonomous inflation: φβ00 , Equation (23) for e-sector wage growth and (24)-(26) are 4 equations which determine the endogenous variables wet, wst, qst and pt as functions of initial conditions and given values for exogenous variables mct, ut and εt. The exogenous and pre-determined variables are wet−1, mct−1 and ut−1. The model is a recursive system of equations: The wage growth rate in the exposed sector is determined first, from (23) and then the other growth rates follow recursively 3. Shock to unemployment: φβ21∆ut Specifically, the reduced form equation for the rate of inflation, ∆pt, is found to be: 4. Productivity growth: φβ11∆aet − φ∆ast, ∆pt = φβ00 + (φβ11 + (1 − φ))∆qe,t + φβ21∆ut + φβ11∆aet − φ∆ast − φ(1 − α) {wet−1 − mct−1 − γe1ut−1 − me0} + φεt 2. “Imported inflation”: (φβ11 + (1 − φ))∆qet (27) 5. e-sector equilibrium correction: −φ(1−α) {we.t−1 − mct−1 − γe1ut−1 − me0} 6. random shocks: φεt 21 22 Set the share of non-traded goods in consumption to 0.4. Then φ = 0.67, and setting β11 = 0.5 gives a coefficient of ∆qet of 0.66. Foreign inflation in the range of 1% − 5% is of course not uncommon, and our model implies that a 3% inflation abroad imputes 2% “imported inflation”. Equilibrium correction in the exposed sector represents a numerically significant factor in this model. With the chosen parameter values, and setting α = 0.7 in the wage equation, the coefficient of {we.t−1 − mct−1 − γe1ut−1 − me0} in equation (27) becomes 0.2. The interpretation is that a 1 percentage point deviation from the the steady-state wage in period t − 1 leads to a reduction of the period t inflation rate of 0.2 percentage points, ceteris paribus. Size of effects The coefficient of ∆aet is 0.33, and for ∆ast we obtain −0.67. The net-effect of productivity growth rates at around 2% may therefore be rather small. Note the implication that increased productivity in the exposed sector of the economy increases inflation. It occurs because e-sector productivity growth increases the bargained wage in that sector, which inflicts price increases in the sheltered sector via the assumption of relative wage stabilization. 23 Practical use of the framework needs to represent ∆wst and ∆qst by separate ECM equations, to avoid the imposition of instantaneous adjustment. Many of the properties of (27) will continue to hold true. For example the strong role of imported inflation, the sign reversal of the two productivity terms, and the role of equilibrium-correction in exposed sector wage setting. 24 Wage-price spiral In real world wage setting, compensation for increases in cost-of-living is always a main issue. Hence, to increase the degree of realism of the model can include ∆pt in the dynamic equation of exposed sector wages setting, with a positive coefficient. Clearly, with this generalization of the model, the inflation model is no longer a recursive system, since instead of (23), we have: ∆wet = β00 + β11∆mct + β21∆ut + β31∆pt (28) where the coefficient with an e are the original coefficients of (28) divided by (1 − β31φ), and β41 = −β31φ/(1 − β31φ), β51 = β31(1 − φ)/(1 − β31φ). By using (29) instead of (28) in the system-of-equations, the recursive solution method of the original model is re-installed. − (1 − α) {wet−1 − mct−1 − γe1ut−1 − me0} + εt. However, since inflation can be expressed as: ∆pt = φ∆wet − φ∆ast + (1 − φ)∆qet we can derive the following semi-reduced form for ∆wet: ∆wet = β̃00 + β̃11∆mct + β̃21∆ut + β41∆ast + β51∆qet − (1^ − α) {wet−1 − mct−1 − γe1ut−1 − me0} + ε̃t. (29) 25 26 The Norwegian model of inflation The Norwegian model of inflation has a longer history in economics than both Nash bargaining theory and error correction models. Already in the 1960s, Odd Aukrust fomulated the main-course model of inflation, or the Norwegian Model of Inflation. The first hypothesis, about wage formation in the e-sector, is in many ways the defining characteristic of the whole framework. It takes the place of Nashbargaining in the model set out above. Central to the model is the distinction between an exposed sector where firms are price takers, and a non-tradables and sheltered sector where firms set prices as mark-ups on wage costs. The wage share of value added is The model’s long-run propositions are, 1. that e-sector wage growth will follow a long run tendency defined by the exogenous price and productivity trends in that sector. 2. If relative wages are to be constant in the long-run, the wage level of the s-sector needs to follow the same tendency. WeLe We Ye = , where average labour productivity is given as Ae = QeYe QeAe Le By definition, the rate of e-sector profits is QeYe − WeLe We =1− . QeYe QeAe If there is there is a long-run rate of profit which is needed to sustain investment and employment in the e-sector, there is also a long-run sustainable wage-share. The development of the domestic price level will also be influenced by trend growth in international prices and the productivity trend. 27 28 Assume that both Qe and Ae are exogenous variables with a trend-like growth. We can then formulate what we might call the main-course proposition: We∗ = MeQeAe, (30) where We∗ denotes the long-run equilibrium wage level consistent with the twin assumptions of exogenous price and productivity trends and a constant normal wage share, denoted Me in (30). Using logs, the long-run wage equation for the e-sector becomes: H1mc: It is easy to prove (by citation) that Aukrust meant equation H1mc as a long-run relationship between the e-sector wage level and the main-course: we∗ = qe + ae + me, where an asterisk,∗ denotes a long-run equilibrium value, and we∗ = ln(We∗) etc. The marker H1mc indicates that this is the first hypothesis of the theory. The normal situation is that both qe (foreign price adjustments) and ae (technical progress) increase over time. According to H1mc we∗ is also trending upwards along a path determined by the so called main-course variable: mc = ae + qe (31) The relationship between the “profitability of E industries” and the “wage level of E industries” that the model postulates, therefore, is certainly not a relation that holds on a year-to-year basis. At best it is valid as a long-term tendency and even so only with considerable slack. It is equally obvious, however, that the wage level in the E industries is not completely free to assume any value irrespective of what happens to profits in these industries. Indeed, if the actual profits in the E industries deviate much from normal profits, it must be expected that sooner or later forces will be set in motion that will close the gap. (Aukrust, 1977, p 114-115). Therefore, the graphical representation of the main-course theory shows the actual time series of the wage level,we,t, fluctuating around a growing maincourse, but always inside a wage corridor . 29 30 log wage level "Upper boundary" Main course There is nothing in Aukrust’s theory which rules out that the long-run wage level can change as a result of shocks to the economy. Hence, me is a function of the rate of unemployment, a plausible generalization of H1mc is represented by H1gmc we∗ = me,0 + mc + γe,1u, where u is the rate of unemployment (or its log). We use H1gmc in the following. "Lower boundary" 0 time Figure 1: The ‘Wage Corridor’ in the Norwegian model of inflation. 31 Clearly H1mc has the same interpretation as the “bargained wage” in the incomplete competition model: If wet follows a stable dynamic process, then its steady-state is given by we∗. As noted there are two other long-run propositions which complete Aukrust’s theory: a constant relative wage between the sectors (denoted mes ) and the existence of a normal sustainable wage share also in the s-sector: H2mc we∗ − ws∗ = mes, H3mc ws∗ − qs∗ − as = ms 32 as is the exogenous productivity trend in the sheltered sector. Re-arranging H3mc, gives qs∗ = ws∗ − as + ms 2.25 which is similar to the ‘price equation’ in the incomplete competition model above! 2.20 extended main-course upper-boundary 2.15 A simulation model of wage dynamics solution for we,t 2.10 2.05 We can use computer simulation to confirm our conclusions about the dynamic behaviour of the main-course model. The following three equations make up a representative main-course model of wage-setting in the exposed sector: lower-boundary 2.00 1.95 2003 we,t = 0.1mct + 0.3mct−1 − 0.06 ln Ut−1 + 0.6we,t−1 + εw,t, mct = 0.03 + mct−1 + εmc,t Ut = 0.005 + 0.005 · S1989t + 0.8Ut−1 + εU,t (32) (33) (34) 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 Figure 2: Simulation of calibrated model 33 34 Change in ln U t to a regime shift in 1989, that raises the equilibrium rate. -3.0 Empirical performance of ECM wage equation -3.2 Norwegian manufacturing 1970—2004 data. OLS estimation results -3.4 -3.6 1990 1.9 1995 2000 Solution of we,t ∆wt = + 0.25 ∆qt − (4.2) 0.31 (w − w∗)t−1 (10.3) + 0.43 ∆pt − 0.04 IPt − 0.79 ∆ht (3.9) (4.1) (4.4) Without regime shift in U t 1.8 With regime shift in U t 1.7 1990 1995 2000 IP , is an incomes-policy indicator. ht is the length of the working day. The (modified) main-course variable wt∗ is: w∗ = mct − 0.1ut + me Figure 3: Unemployment and wage resonse to a regime shift in the equilibrium rate of unemployment in 1989. Simulation of the calibrated model 35 36 The main-course model and the Scandinavian model of inflation 0.175 Δwt Fitted The “Scandinavian model” specifies the same three underlying assumptions as the main-course model: H1mc (we do not need the extended version of the hypothesis for the point we wish to make here), H2mc and H3mc. 0.150 0.125 But the distinction between long-run and dynamics is blurred in the Scandinavian model. Hence, for example, the dynamic equation for e-sector wages in the Scandinavian model is usually written as: 0.100 0.075 ∆we,t = β0 + ∆mct, (without a disturbance term for simplicity) which is seen to place the restriction of α = 1 on the ECM for e-sector wage dynamics. 0.050 0.025 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 This implies unstable dynamics. If the wage path is ever pushed off the main course, it never returns. 2005 Figure 4: Actual wage growth, and fitted according to main-course ECM. In terms of the Typology of Lecture 2, the Scandinavian model is a Differenced data model. 37 38 Wage and price curves The standard exposition sets we = we∗ and p = p∗ in each time period. The implication is that actual wages and prices are determined by a static model! Models that feature mark-up behaviour in price and wage setting are not uncommon in textbooks. They are presented as equations for a wage-curve and a price curve. In our framework these equations take the form: we∗ = me0 + qe + ae + γe1u, and (35) p∗ = φ(mse − ms) + φ(we∗ − as) + (1 − φ)qe (36) This procedure also raises an issue about which variables are determined by the wage-curve and the price curve. To look into this issue a little further, we simplify the notation by setting as = ae = a, and mse = 0, so that we∗ = ws∗ = w∗. In the case of w = w∗ and p = p∗ (35) and (36) can then be re-expressed as: w − qe − a = me0 + γe1u, 1 w − qe − a = ms + (p − qe) φ (37) (38) where we have utilized the s-sector wage and price setting to derive (36) for the desired price p∗ as a mark-up on bargained unit-labour costs (we∗ − as). Due to the openness of the economy, p∗ depends on foreign prices, qe. where (38) is simply (36) in the (e-sector) wage share on the left hand side of the equation. 39 40 Equation (37) can be represented graphically as downward sloping line in a graph with w−qe−a along the vertical axis and u along the horizontal axis. This is the wage-curve. Equation (38) defines a horizontal line in the same graph. This is the price-curve. The intersection point between the curves is often viewed as the determination of the wage-curve natural rate of unemployment (or NAIRU). However there are logical problems with this approach: The price-curve depends on the relative price p − qe, so an unique intersection point does not exist unless we can fix p − qe at a certain value. Put differently: (37) and (38) are two equation in three unknown variables, and it is not clear why it is that u should be regarded as endogenous, and not p − qe. Most commonly: The requirement that the trade balance (or the current account) is balanced in the long term. However, the properties of the dynamic wage and price setting system imply that if a steady state exists for the wage share wt − qet − at, a unique steadystate also exists for pt − qet. Hence, there is an internal inconsistency in the approach which determines the long-run or steady state value of the rate of unemployment from static wage and price curves. The argument is that p − qe can be regarded as determined from outside the system of wage and price setting equations. 42 41 ∗ denotes the (log of) foreign prices in foreign currency, and E is the where qet t nominal exchange rate (kroner/euro). Role of exchange rate regime Later in the course, a main focus will be the choice of exchange rate regime, and how that choice conditions macrodynamics. So far we have implicitly assumed that the rate of foreign exchange is exogenous, corresponding to a fixed exchange rate regime. In order to make this explicit, we need to expand the notation a little. For example, the sum of the logs of productivity and foreign price The reason why we have suppressed the nominal exchange rate Et from the model so far, is that in a fixed exchange rate regime, the Et has no separate influence on wage growth. Clearly if We and E are endogenous, as in the case of a floating exchange rate regime, the main-course model is incomplete: we need more theory to be able to explain E. mct = ∆aet + ∆qet + mct−1, (39) Ch 3.2.8 in IDM shows that if there is perfect capital mobility and depreciation expectations are perfect, then the main-course becomes modified by the (exogenous) difference between the domestic and foreign interest rate, but the dynamic wage equation is still stable. ∗ + ∆ ln E + mc mct = ∆aet + ∆qet t t−1. (40) Hence, what we have learnt about stability of wages, for a given level of unemployment may hold for a floating exchange rate regime as well. mct = aet + qet which can be written as or 43 44