Speed Couture Gilles Duranton Matthew A. Turner

advertisement
Speed
Victor Couture∗ †
Gilles Duranton∗ ‡
Matthew A. Turner∗ §
University of Toronto
10 June 2012
Abstract: We investigate the determinants of driving speed in large
us cities. We first estimate city level supply functions for travel in an
econometric framework where both the supply and demand for travel
are explicit. These estimations allow us to calculate a city level index
of driving speed and to rank cities by driving speed. Our investigation
of the determinants of speed provide the foundations for a welfare analysis. This analysis suggests that large gains in speed may be possible if
slow cities can emulate fast cities and that the deadweight losses from
congestion are sizeable.
Key words: roads, vehicle-kilometers traveled, public transport, congestion, travel time.
jel classification: l91, r41
∗ We thank Will Strange and Francisco Trebbi for insightful comments. Financial support from the Canadian Social
Science and Humanities Research Council is gratefully acknowledged.
† Department of Economics, University of Toronto, 150 Saint George Street, Toronto, Ontario m5s 3g7, Canada (e-mail:
victor.couture@utoronto.ca).
‡ Department of Economics, University of Toronto, 150 Saint George Street, Toronto, Ontario m5s 3g7, Canada (e-mail:
gilles.duranton@utoronto.ca; website: http://individual.utoronto.ca/gilles/default.html). Also affiliated
with the Centre for Economic Policy Research, and the Spatial Economics Research Centre at the London School of
Economics.
§ Department of Economics, University of Toronto, 150 Saint George Street, Toronto, Ontario m5s 3g7, Canada (e-mail:
mturner@chass.utoronto.ca; website: http://www.economics.utoronto.ca/mturner/index.htm).
1. Introduction
We investigate the determinants of driving speed in a sample of large us cities. We proceed in three
stages. We first estimate the supply of travel faced by drivers in each of our cities. Our econometric
formulation explicitly accounts for the fact that longer trips are faster than shorter trips, and hence
that drivers affect their travel speed with their choice of trip distance. Using the resulting city level
supply of travel functions we calculate a city level index of travel speed. This index is analogous
to a conventional price index and gives the inverse time cost of a standardized bundle of trips.
Our speed index resolves two important problems: it provides a well-defined measure of speed
for each city and it does not depend upon simultaneously determined driver behavior affecting
travel speed.1
Our index allows us to rank cities by speed of travel. This is of intrinsic interest and provides
an alternative to the Texas Transportation Institute’s (tti) widely cited congestion index (Schrank
and Lomax, 2009, Schrank, Lomax, and Turner, 2010). However, unlike the tti index, our index is
grounded in economic theory and hence can be more easily interpreted.
We next investigate the relationship between our speed index and inputs into the transportation
process, aggregate travel time and roads in particular. Since the supply of roads or aggregate travel
time in a city may reflect unobserved determinants of speed, we are careful to account for the
probable endogeneity of inputs in this estimation.
Finally, we investigate the value of higher travel speed using two distinct methodologies. In the
first, we consider hypothetical policy interventions to increase speed. This analysis, which is in the
spirit of standard analyses of factor productivity, suggests that the value of an increase in speed
is measured in the tens or even hundreds of billions of dollars. These results are provocative
and provide some information about the value of hypothetical interventions. However, such
hypothetical changes are unlikely to occur in equilibrium. In our second investigation of the value
of speed, we use our estimates to derive a demand system for travel in our cities. An analysis of
this system indicates that the deadweight loss from congestion is on the order of 80 billion dollars
per year, of the same magnitude as the gains suggested by some hypothetical interventions to
increase speed. To the extent that much of the benefit from the hypothetical supply improvements
1 We
focus solely on travel using privately-owned vehicles. They represent an overwhelming share of all trips in the
us. We do not provide a detailed cost analysis across various transportation modes in the tradition of Meyer, Kain, and
Wohl (1965).
1
are dissipated by increases in equilibrium travel, our results suggest that larger gains are to be had
by managing demand for travel, rather than by improving supply. Our analysis also suggests that
equilibrium driving exceeds optimal driving.
Our results are of interest for several reasons. Two of the principal questions which the literature
on transportation economics addresses are ‘what is travel demand?’ and ‘what does the speed-flow
curve look like?’2 Since the speed-flow curve relates travel time to distance, i.e., time price of
travel to quantity, this second question can be restated differently as ‘what is the supply curve
for travel?’ Extant empirical investigations ask these questions separately. Therefore, while the
study of transportation has a distinguished history in economics, it has almost completely ignored
the fact that observed travel behavior results from an equilibrium that depends upon both supply
and demand conditions. To our knowledge, our paper is the first to implement an econometric
framework which recognizes this problem.3 Our identification strategy exploits the fact that
distance differs across different types of trips.
Related to this, we note that the conventional approach to estimating a speed-flow curve involves measuring the speed and number of cars at a particular point on a road and plotting the
resulting data. This plot arguably reflects both supply, i.e., that traffic slows down when there are
more cars, and demand, i.e., there are fewer cars when traffic is slower. Even if we ignore this issue,
the estimation of speed-flow curves is subject to a second important problem. As observed in their
classic monograph (Beckman, McGuire, and Winsten, 1956), the interpretation of this curve rests on
the assumption that all else is equal. This assumption is problematic. Increasing traffic somewhere
almost surely entails changes elsewhere. In particular, measuring what happens at a particular
point on a road is likely to reflect driving conditions further along on that road. It is difficult to
think of a specific point on a network independently. To avoid this problem, we investigate the
ability of an entire city, rather than a particular road segment, to supply travel.4 This is also novel.
While the productivity of manufacturing and service sectors is extensively studied, in spite of
its size, the transportation sector has received much less attention. Our estimated city level supply
2 Much
of the work on travel demand follows on the pioneering work of McFadden (1973, 1974). See Train (2009)
for a thorough exposition of the state of the art. The first estimation of a speed flow-curve dates back to Greenshields
(1935). Important subsequent work include Keeler and Small (1977) and Dewees (1979). See Small and Verhoef (2007)
for a review of more recent work.
3 In their authoritative book, Small and Verhoef (2007) exposit the supply and demand for travel separately, indeed,
in different chapters. The fact that some variables may affect both supply and demand is recognised but only discussed
in the context of car purchases.
4 Bombardini and Trebbi (2011) apply recent results from graph theory to investigate how distortions to urban
transportation networks affects their efficiency.
2
functions allow us to investigate the cross-sectional determinants of efficiency in transportation.
Consistent with the large extant literature investigating productivity in firms (e.g., Syverson, 2011),
we find that some cities are dramatically more efficient than others. This suggests that there may
be large gains if slow cities can emulate fast cities. Our results also suggest that the supply of
transportation exhibits slight decreasing returns to scale: doubling total driving time and the stock
of roads in a city leads to about a 5% decrease in speed.
Finally, we note that in 2008 the average driver in our sample spent about 72 minutes driving;
the median household devotes 18% of its budget to road travel; in a typical year, the us spends
nearly 200 billion dollars on road construction and maintenance; and the value of capital stock
associated with road transportation in the us tops 5 trillion dollars (us bts, 2007 and 2010). By
providing better estimates of the fundamental relationships that determine the value and costs
of driving, we provide a sounder foundation for the enormous resource allocations affected by
transportation policy. More concretely, by estimating the cost of congestion we facilitate the
calculation of the net benefits of costly policy responses to traffic congestion.
2. Data
Our data describe aggregate travel behavior in a set of large us cities and the individual driving
trips taken by a sample of each city’s residents. Our cities are us (Consolidated) Metropolitan Statistical Areas (msa) drawn to 1999 boundaries. msas are census reporting units and are aggregations
of counties containing a major urban center and its surrounding region. Our analysis relies heavily
on household survey data. To ensure that we observe a sufficiently large number of households
in each msa, in most of our work we consider a sample of the 100 msas that are on average most
populous over our study period.5 When our results are based on smaller samples of nhts surveys,
we sometimes restrict attention to the 50 largest msas.
Data on individual travel behavior comes from the 1995-1996 National Personal Transportation
Survey and the 2001-2002 and 2008-2009 National Household Transportation Surveys. In a slight
abuse of language, we to refer these surveys as the 1995, 2001 and 2008 nhts. Each of the nhts
surveys reports household and individual demographics for a nationally representative sample of
households. More importantly, the ‘travel day file’ of each nhts survey codifies a travel diary kept
by every member of each sampled household. For each adult member of participating households
5 To be consistent with other data, we rank msas by their average population in 1995, 1996, 2001, 2002, 2008, and 2009.
3
we observe the distance, duration, mode, purpose, and start time for each trip taken on a randomly
assigned travel day. See Appendix A for further details. We eliminate trips entered by non-drivers
in order to focus our investigation on the movement of vehicles rather than the movement of
people. In our sample of 100 msas, the nhts describes 418,630 trips, 102,314 drivers and 71,192
households in 2008; 168,765 trips, 40,353 drivers and 27,589 households in 2001; and 152,590 trips,
33,879 drivers and 22,604 households in 1995.
We aggregate to describe travel behavior at the msa level. To estimate msa vehicle kilometers
traveled (vkt) and vehicle time traveled (vtt), we sum the time and distance of each trip over all of
an individual’s trips. Averaging across drivers, we compute the average distance and time driven
by an individual in each msa. We multiply this individual average by msa population (from the
us Census) to obtain total msa vkt and vtt.
Our data on msa road infrastructure are from the 1995, 1996, 2001, 2002, and 2008 Highway
Performance and Monitoring System (hpms) Universe and Sample data. The us federal government administers the hpms through the Federal Highway Administration in the Department of
Transportation. This annual survey, which is used for planning purposes and to apportion federal
highway funding, collects data about the entire interstate highway system (hpms Universe data)
and a large sample of other roads in urbanized areas (hpms Sample data).
The hpms Universe data describe every segment of interstate highway (ih) and allow us to
calculate the number of lane kilometers of ih in each msa for each nhts year. To calculate lane
kilometers of major urban roads (mru) in the urbanized parts of an msa, we sum lane kilometers
for the five classes of roads reported in the hpms Sample data; ‘collector’, ‘minor arterial’, ‘principal
arterial’ and ‘other highway’. We omit a residual class, ‘local roads’, that is not systematically
reported in the hpms. To ensure that the resulting measures of road infrastructure are comparable
to the nhts surveys, which are collected over two years, we average each of the hpms variables
over the two relevant nhts sampling years.
Table 1 contains summary statistics for our main variables in the 100 largest msas. Means and
standard deviations for trip-level variables are reported in Panel a. Trip distance and trip duration
increase from 1995 to 2001, from 12.5 to 13.2 km and from 15.1 to 17.6 minutes. Some of the increase
in average trip duration is accounted for by a decrease in average trip speed (computed across
trips) from 43 to 39 km/h. Average trip duration, distance, and speed are very similar in 2001 and
4
Table 1: Summary Statistics for the 100 largest MSAs
Variable
1995
2001
2008
Panel A. Trip-level data based on the NHTS
Mean trip distance (km)
12.5
(16.2)
Mean trip duration (min)
15.1
(14.2)
Mean trip speed (km/h)
43.1
(23.0)
Mean trip number (per driver)
4.5
(2.6)
Total observed number of trips 152,590
13.2
(17.0)
17.6
(15.3)
39.4
(22.5)
4.2
(2.4)
168,765
12.8
(16.4)
17.4
(15.2)
38.5
(22.2)
4.1
(2.3)
418,630
Panel B. MSA-level data based on the HPMS and Census
Mean daily VKT (’000,000 km)
51.4
59.7
64.2
(74.7) (85.0) (90.9)
Mean daily VTT (’000,000 min)
62.2
79.2
87.3
(91.4) (114.6) (126.2)
Mean lane km (IH, ’000 km)
2.1
2.3
2.4
(2.3)
(2.4)
(2.4)
Mean lane km (MRU, ’000 km)
10.5
11.9
14.4
(13.5) (16.1) (18.1)
Mean MSA population (’000)
1,747
1,943
2,095
(2,673) (2,915) (3,052)
Notes: Authors’ computations using NHTS sampling weights to compute the means of Panel A. Standard
deviations in parentheses. VKT is an estimate of the total vehicle kilometers traveled by privately operated
vehicle in an MSA and VTT is an estimate of the total vehicle time traveled by privately operated vehicles in
an MSA. IH denotes interstate highways for the entire MSA. MRU denotes major roads within the urbanized
area of an MSA.
2008. The average number of trips decreases from 4.5 in 1995 to 4.1 in 2008. We note that 1995 nhts
survey asks respondents to report the time it took to get to their destination, while the 2001 and
2008 surveys ask respondents to report exact departure and arrival times. This slight difference
in wording may partly explain the observed decrease in speed between 1995 and 2001.6 We also
note that driving is sensitive to the business cycle, another reason to be cautious when comparing
across years.
Panel b of table 1 reports means and standard deviations for msa-level aggregates. Average vkt
and vtt grow from 1995 to 2008, by 20% for vkt and by 29% for vtt, with much of the increase in
vkt accounted for by the sample average msa population growth rate of 10%. Lanes of interstate
highway grow by 14% between 1995 and 2008 while lanes of major urban roads grow by 40%.
6 To support this conjecture we note that our results below show that the drop in speed in 2001 is nearly entirely
accounted by a small increase of slightly above 1 minute in the fixed cost of each trip. All comparisons between the 1995
nhts and other years are subject to this caveat.
5
Table 2: Mean trip distance in kilometers, by trip purpose, for the 100 largest MSAs
Trip purpose
Frequency (1995-2008) km 1995 km 2001 km 2008
To/from Work
23.6%
Work-related business
3.3%
Shopping
21.8%
Other family/personal business
24.3%
School/church
4.6%
Medical/dental
2.2%
Vacation
0.3%
Visit friends/relatives
5.7%
Other social/recreational
13.8%
Other
0.5%
18.6
(19.0)
17.6
(21.0)
7.8
(11.3)
9.4
(12.8)
11.5
(13.3)
13.3
(14.9)
35.1
(41.0)
15.7
(20.2)
12.4
(17.1)
13.4
(18.6)
18.8
(18.8)
20.9
(23.4)
8.7
(12.1)
10.1
(14.3)
11.5
(13.6)
12.8
(13.2)
34.5
(40.3)
17.8
(23.0)
12.2
(16.4)
20.3
(25.4)
19.1
(19.1)
18.5
(21.5)
8.2
(11.1)
9.4
(13.6)
12.2
(13.5)
13.0
(13.5)
25.6
(34.6)
17.2
(22.7)
11.1
(15.1)
22.4
(23.9)
Notes: Authors’ computations using NHTS sampling weights and all three years of data (pooled together to
compute frequencies) by averaging across all trips. Standard deviations in parentheses.
While msa boundaries are constant over time, urbanized area boundaries are not, so that some of
the growth in lane kilometers of major urban roads reflects the expansion of urbanized areas.
The nhts data report the purpose of each trip using 10 consistently defined categories such as
‘to/from work’, ‘shopping’, or ‘medical/dental’. Table 2 shows the mean and standard deviation
of distance by trip purpose for the msas in our sample. There is significant and persistent variation
in average trip distance across trip purposes. Shopping trips are shortest at about 8.2 km on
average in 2008. Vacation trips are the longest and average 25.6 km. We note that ‘vacation’ and
‘other’ trips occur infrequently in the data and we sometimes exclude them from our analysis.
Figure 1 plots log distance and log (inverse) speed for two groups of trips in Chicago in
2008. The triangles represent commute trips and the circles represent two other groups of trips:
school/church and medical/dental. It is clear from the figure that for both groups, speed is higher
for longer trips. In fact, this relationship between speed and trip distance is one of the most
important features of our data. Consistent with sample averages reported in table 2, for Chicago
in 2008 commute trips are about twice as long as the other class of trips described in figure 1 (20.3
6
Figure 1: Speed and distance for some Chicago trips in 2008.
4
log inverse speed
3
2
1
0
log distance
-1
-2
-1
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
Commute trips are represented by triangles (mean log distance 2.52, plain line). Church, school, medical, and dental
trips are represented by circles (mean log distance 1.81, dashed line).
km for commutes, 9.0 km for school/church trips, and 12.6 km for medical/dental trips).
In addition to the nhts and hpms, we exploit several other sources of msa level data as explanatory variables or as instrumental variables. Specifically, in our investigation of the determinants
of msa driving speed, we consider a number of geographical characteristics of cities (ruggedness,
elevation range, cooling and heating degree days, and measures of urban form). We also use variables describing historical transportation networks (1947 interstate highway plan, 1898 railroads,
and old exploration routes of the continent dating back to 1528) as instruments for the modern
road network. Details about these variables are available in Appendix A and in Duranton and
Turner (2011).
3. Speed and the supply of travel
Our unit of observation is a trip made by a particular driver in a particular city. In this section,
we treat trips independently and focus only on the ‘intensive margin’ of travel. We turn to the
extensive margin of travel later in the paper when we analyze total vehicle travel time and total
vehicle kilometers travelled. For now, it is enough to understand that by ignoring the extensive
margin of travel, our main identification problem (trip distance and trip speed are determined
simultaneously) might be attenuated (if drivers have a finite time budget for driving) or heightened
(if the overall time budget for driving is very elastic).
7
Let i index the set of cities, j index the set of drivers in each city, and k the set of trips by a
particular driver in a particular city. Let xijk denote distance for trip ijk in kilometers, and cijk the
time cost of the trip in minutes per kilometer. Let τijk ∈ {1,..T } index the possible purposes for trip
τ be an indicator variable that is one for trips of type τ and zero otherwise. Since
ijk. Finally, let χijk
our estimations will rely mainly on within-city variation we often omit the i subscript to increase
legibility.
Drivers incur fixed time costs to begin and end a trip. Drivers must also rely more heavily on
slow local roads for short trips than for the faster freeways and arterial roads that are available for
longer trips. These two facts naturally cause short trips to be slower than short trips. As figure
1 shows, the relationship between speed and distance is an important feature of our data. Given
this, we assume the following speed schedule for trips of different distances in a particular city
−γ
csjk = x jk exp(c + δj + e jk ).
(1)
This inverse supply curve gives the average price in minutes per kilometer, on a particular trip.
The parameter δj measures drivers’ abilities to drive fast on all trips and reflects characteristics
such as the driver’s skillfulness or the proximity of his or her home to a freeway. The parameter
e jk measures drivers’ ability to drive fast on a particular trip and reflects events such as stormy
weather or road construction. The parameter c is the time cost of a one kilometer trip of when
δj = 0 and e jk = 0. Finally, γ is the elasticity of speed with respect to trip distance. Estimating
these supply curves, the parameters c and γ in particular, is the goal of our first empirical exercise.
A driver’s inverse demand for trip distance x and purpose τ is
−β
cdjk = x jk exp(ΣτT=1 Aτ χτjk + η j + µ jk ).
(2)
Because each driver makes their decision regarding trip distance and the time cost of driving , we
take equation (2) to reflect the marginal willingness to pay for distance by drivers. In equation
(2), the ‘slope’ parameter β (> γ) is the demand elasticity of speed with respect to distance. This
parameter determines the rate of decline in a driver’s willingess to pay for an extra kilometer
as trip distance increases. The ‘intercept’ parameter Aτ measures the willingness to pay for a one
kilometer trip of type τ when η j = 0 and µ jk = 0. The parameter η j describes a driver’s willingness
to give up time for distance. It depends on a driver’s innate impatience or value of time. The
parameter µ jk reflects trip-specific factors which affect willingness to give up time for distance, for
example, how busy a day the driver is having.
8
Figure 2: Supply and demand for trip distance.
ln c
c1d (x )
c2d (x )
a
b'
b
MC1 ( x )
MC2 ( x )
ln x
Since drivers recognize that their choice of distance affects the speed of travel, they behave as
ordinary monopsonists and choose trip distance to satisfy
cd = MC ( x ) ≡
d( x cs )
= (1 − γ ) c s .
dx
(3)
That is, the marginal willingness to pay for trip distance equals the marginal cost of trip distance.
Note that drivers are still price takers in the sense that they do not recognize that their driving
behavior may contribute to congestion in the network and thus shift the whole supply curve.
Figure 3 illustrates this equilibrium. This figure depicts two pairs of marginal cost and demand
curves, ( MC1 ( x ), c1d ) and ( MC2 ( x ), c2d ) for two different trips. We observe equilibrium pairs of
speed and trip distance, points a and b. If we estimate our marginal cost curve on the basis of these
points alone, our estimate of the marginal cost curve will look like the thin line connecting these
two points. More specifically, we estimate a slope larger than the slope of the inverse-supply and
marginal cost curves but smaller than the slope of the demand curve. As figure 3 makes clear, the
problem of estimating the marginal cost curve relating trip distance and inverse speed is a textbook
example of a simultaneous equations problem. In order to identify our marginal cost curve, we
require a source of variation in demand which does not affect supply.
After defining χ j to be an indicator variable which is one for trips by person j and zero otherwise, using (2) and (1) in (3), and taking logarithms we arrive at the following system of equations,
−1 τ τ
ln x jk = D j χ j + ΣτT=
1 Ã χ jk + ζ jk
9
(4)
ln c jk = c + δj χ j − γ ln x jk + e jk ,
where D j ≡
−c
β−γ
+
AT
γ− β
+
η j − δj
β−γ ,
Ãτ ≡
A T − Aτ
γ− β ,
τ ∈ {1,..,T − 1}, and ζ jk ≡
(5)
µ jk −e jk
β−γ .
Inspection of equations (5) and (4) shows that Aτ , the willingness to pay for a trip of type τ, χτjk
the dummy for the trip being of type τ, and η j the individual characteristics affecting the demand
for trips of driver j, all appear in the distance equation (4), but not in the speed equation (5). It
follows that variables measuring these quantities are candidate sources of exogenous variation in
demand with which to resolve our simultaneity problem.
In practice, it is hard to think of individual characteristics that affect the demand for trips but
not the ability to produce them. For instance, educational attainment affects a driver’s opportunity
cost of time and hence demand for trip distance. However, education may also affect driving skills
and thus the ability to drive at a high speed. This suggests that individual characteristics are
unlikely to provide good sources of exogenous variation in demand.
Trip type indicators and measures of mean trip distance by trip type are more defensible
sources of variation with which to identify the inverse supply curve described by equation (1).
Denote these instruments Zjk . As made clear by the discussion above, valid instruments for trip
distance must satisfy two conditions. First, they must predict trip distance conditional on the
other controls: cov( Zjk , x jk |.) 6= 0 (relevance). We demonstrate that this condition holds below.
Second, instruments must be uncorrelated with the error term of equation (5): cov( Zjk , e jk |.) = 0
(exogeneity).
The arguments for the validity of trip type dummies and the validity of mean distance by trip
type are different. We begin with trip type dummies. If trip type dummies are orthogonal to e jk
then we are not more (or less) likely to observe trips of type τ when such trips are particulary
fast. In fact, we suspect that some trips (e.g., ‘recreational’ trips, to take an example from the data)
might be taken with greater propensity when traffic conditions are good, i.e., when e jk is high.
To understand why such a correlation might arise, assume there are only two types of trip: to
the gym and to work. Drivers stop going to the gym when there is more than 10 centimeters of
snow on the ground and stop going to work when there is more than 30 centimeters of snow (and
traffic gets even slower). In this case, trips to the gym will be positively correlated with the error
term. This leads to a selection problem which in turn violates the exogeneity condition.
To circumvent this possible problem, we can restrict attention to trips which are not discre-
10
tionary such as trips ‘to and from work’ and ‘medical/dental’ trips.7 We are also concerned that
our instruments are correlated with unobserved determinants of speed, the e jk . Adding controls
reduces the role of unobserved determinants of speed. In our case, we know about trip characteristics like; month, day of week, and time of day. If adding these controls does not cause big
changes in our estimations then this suggests that our concern that our instruments are correlated
with e jk is unfounded.
Turning to the validity of average distances by trip type, we return to the example above. Trips
to the gym may be observed on average under better weather (and traffic) conditions than trips to
work. This is not an issue as long as this differential selection of trips does not affect the distance
of trips to the gym relative to the distance of trips to work. However, suppose that when the
weather is worse drivers go to a closer gym and to a closer workplace. If weather conditions affect
distances equally for all types of trips, then unobserved weather introduces noise but does not lead
to a violation of the exogeneity condition. On the other hand, if more than 10 centimeters of snow
causes drivers to choose a closer gym but does not affect the choice of workplace, then mean trip
distance by type is correlated with the error term in the speed regressions. More generally, average
distances by trip type do not satisfy the exogeneity condition when the unobserved state of traffic
differentially affects the distance of different types of trips depending on mean distance.
Whether the length of shorter trip types should be more (or less) sensitive to traffic conditions
than distance for longer trips types is not obvious. While (on average) distance for short shopping
trips may be sensitive to traffic conditions, that of longer recreational trips might be as well. On the
other hand, distance for short trips to school may be insensitive to traffic conditions and long trips
to work may be similarly insensitive. This said, to avoid a possible correlation between average
trip distance and unobserved traffic conditions, we can again restrict attention to trips with low
discretion. We can also use extensive controls for trip characteristics, as we do when using trip
type dummies as instruments.
To conclude, trip type dummies and mean distance by trip type may fail the exogeneity condition. Unobserved determinants of speed may differentially affect the decision to take particular
types of trips. This would create a sample of trips where different types of trips are observed only
under systematically different unobserved conditions. On the other hand, unobserved conditions
7 Actually, we only need to restrict attention to trips with the same level of discretion. Arguably, trips ‘to and from
work’ and ‘medical/dental’ trips have both a low level of discretion. Whether ‘shopping’ and ‘recreational’ trips have
the same level of ‘high’ discretion is less obvious.
11
may differentially affect the length of different types of trips, which leads mean trip length by type
to be correlated with unobserved determinants of speed. Importantly, if trip type and average trip
distance instruments are not exogenous, they are not exogenous for different reasons. Therefore, if
both types of instruments lead to similar estimates this indicates that they are either both valid or,
improbably, that the selection problem for trip type dummies has the same bias on our estimates
as the hypothetical simultaneity problem for average distance by trip types.
Apart from concerns about the validity of our instruments, we worry that fast drivers sort
into fast cities. As we see in equation (5), the constant term in the speed equation is the sum
of the intercept of the inverse-supply curve c (the coefficient of interest), and driver characteristics
affecting supply δj . Since we only observe drivers driving in one city, c and δj cannot be separately
identified. Our concern is that fast drivers, those with high δ’s, might systematically choose to
locate in fast cities, those with high c’s.
We have two responses to this problem. The first is to consider large areas, the largest us
consolidated statistical metropolitan areas (msas), as our unit of observation. As long as the
problematic sorting of drivers occurs at a smaller scale than our unit of observation, it will not
lead to systematic differences between drivers in one msa and another. Drivers with a desire to
drive fast can always locate close to highways in a less densely populated part of nearly any large
msa in the us. Much the same logic is widely used to identify local peer group effects (e.g., Evans,
Oates, and Schwab, 1992, for an early example). Our second response to the sorting problem is
to parameterize individual effects as a function of observable driver characteristics. In particular,
we expect that extensive controls such as age, income, gender, and education are correlated with
individual unobservables. Since only the residual eijk will be confounded with the intercept, we
use our controls to reduce this residual as much as possible.
The supply of travel and the determination of speed
We now turn to the estimation of travel speed. We start with the estimation of variants of the
following equation,
ln cijk = ci + Yj δ − γi ln x jk + Tjk ξ + eijk .
(6)
This equation differs from equation (5) in two regards. First, it includes a vector of trip attributes,
Tjk , not present in (5). These trip attributes control for variation in traffic conditions by time of day,
12
day of week, and month of year. Second, equation (6) includes an arbitrary vector of individual
control variables Yj . This generalizes equation (5) which restricts attention to individual fixed
effects.
We estimate equation (6) using nhts trips by drivers residing in one of the msas in our sample.
Table 3 reports our results. Panel a report results based on the 2008 nhts for trips by drivers in the
100 largest msas. Panel b replicates panel a but restricts attention to the 50 largest msas. Panels c
and d reproduce panel b but are based on the 2001 and 1995 and nhts. Within each panel and for
each estimation, we report the mean values of the msa intercept ci and the msa slope γi . For both
variables, we report in parentheses the standard deviations of their coefficients within the sample
of msas at hand. We note that the coefficients reported in table 3 are unorthodox. We estimate
equation (6) for each msa. Table 3 reports the mean and variance of the point estimates of ci and γi
across msas.
In column 1, we estimate equation (6) without driver or trip controls. The mean value of ci for
the 100 largest msas in 2008 appears in the first row of panel a. Its value of 1.407 implies just above
4 minutes for a trip of one kilometer.8 This is slightly less than 15 kilometers per hour. The second
row of the same column reports the standard error of the mean of the intercepts across msas. Its
value of 0.092 implies an e0.092 ≈ 10% difference in speed for a trip of one kilometer. The mean of
the standard error within msas is only 0.031. This suggests that the differences in intercepts across
msas reflect mostly true differences in speed, not sampling error.
The third row of panel a reports the average of the coefficients for log distance. In column 1,
its value of 0.428 implies that speed increases by about 20.428 ≈ 35% when trip distance doubles.
Alternatively, our coefficients predict a speed of 29 kilometers per hour for a trip of 5 kilometers
and just less than 15 kilometers per hour for trips of 1 kilometer.9 The fourth row reports the
average standard deviation for these estimates of γ across msas. It equals 0.032. Since this is more
than twice as large as the mean standard error for γ within msas, 0.015, this probably this reflects
again true heterogeneity across msas and not just sampling error.
In column 2, we augment the regression of column 1 with several controls for driver characteristics; household income and its square, driver’s education and its square, age, and dummies
8 Since
this quantity is an exponential of an average of logs from which we omit the errors, strictly speaking, it is not
predicted speed.
9 Of course, we cannot expect this relationship to scale up for extremely long trips. However, 99% of the trips we
observe here are less than 83 kilometers and our elasticity still applies within this region.
13
Table 3: Estimation of inverse-supply curves
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
(8)
(9)
OLS 1
OLS 2
OLS 3
FE
IV 1
IV 2
IV 3
IV 4
IV FE
1.402
(0.102)
0.426
(0.037)
1.281
(0.149)
0.360
(0.075)
1.281
(0.143)
0.359
(0.072)
1.237
(0.138)
0.335
(0.064)
1.214
(0.142)
0.346
(0.074)
1.266
(0.760)
0.357
(0.402)
1.261
(0.098)
0.342
(0.046)
1.251
(0.091)
0.336
(0.042)
1.222
(0.104)
0.320
(0.045)
1.180
(0.087)
0.321
(0.042)
1.258
(0.120)
0.346
(0.054)
1.324
(0.112)
0.348
(0.060)
1.320
(0.122)
0.345
(0.065)
1.298
(0.118)
0.332
(0.065)
1.262
(0.131)
0.342
(0.066)
1.244
(0.240)
0.341
(0.112)
1.121
(0.131)
0.340
(0.070)
1.115
(0.136)
0.338
(0.072)
1.048
(0.119)
0.303
(0.054)
1.070
(0.139)
0.326
(0.075)
1.057
(0.163)
0.310
(0.079)
Panel A. 100 largest MSAs for 2008
Mean c
1.407
(0.092)
Mean γ 0.428
(0.032)
1.338
(0.090)
0.426
(0.032)
1.474
(0.092)
0.425
(0.032)
Panel B. 50 largest MSAs for 2008
Mean c
1.407
(0.065)
Mean γ 0.424
(0.018)
1.342
(0.067)
0.421
(0.017)
1.478
(0.069)
0.420
(0.017)
1.399
(0.070)
0.419
(0.020)
Panel C. 50 largest MSAs for 2001
Mean c
1.383
(0.072)
Mean γ 0.412
(0.022)
1.324
(0.069)
0.407
(0.021)
1.454
(0.071)
0.406
(0.021)
1.350
(0.067)
0.394
(0.022)
Panel D. 50 largest MSAs for 1995
Mean c
1.187
(0.103)
Mean γ 0.380
(0.040)
1.171
(0.081)
0.375
(0.022)
1.199
(0.081)
0.374
(0.023)
1.133
(0.090)
0.351
(0.026)
Notes: Mean of the coefficients across all cities. Standard deviation of city coefficients in parentheses.
OLS estimations in columns 1-4 and IV in columns 5-9.
Controls: No control in column 1. Controls for household income and its square, driver’s education and its
square, age, dummies for males, blacks, and workers, and a quartic for the time of departure in columns 2
and 5-8. 17 dummies for household income, four dummies for education, age, dummies for males, blacks,
hispanics, and workers, 23 dummies for the hour of departure, 11 dummies for the month of departure,
and a dummy for trip taken during the week-end in column 3. Driver fixed effects in columns 5 and 9.
Instruments: Mean trip distance for trips of the same purpose in the same MSAs in column 5. Same
instrument but computed from the four most similar MSA in term of population in columns 6 and 9. Trip
purpose in column 7 (8 categories) and column 8 (2 categories; commutes and other work related trips,
shopping, medical and dental, school and church, and personal business).
14
for males, blacks, and workers. We also include trip controls; a quartic in departure hour, and a
week-end dummy. In column 3, we include more exhaustive driver and trip controls. For drivers
we include 17 dummies for household income, four dummies for education, age, and dummies for
males, blacks, hispanics, and workers. For trips, we include 23 dummies for the hour of departure,
11 dummies for the month of departure, and a dummy for trips taken during the week-end.
We constrain the effect of driver and trip characteristics to be the same for all msas. This increases the efficiency of our estimations, increases the transparency of the speed indices calculated
below, and eases the calculation of these indices. Moreover, since regressions with driver and trip
characteristics give similar results to regressions with driver fixed effects, it seems unlikely that
this simplifying assumption is important to our estimates of the speed distance relationship.10
We cannot compare estimates of ci across columns 1, 2, and 3 because of differences in the
sets of control variables. We can compare estimates of the distance elasticity of speed, γ, across
columns. These estimates are stable.11 The R2 s for the different specifications are also stable. The
R2 associated with column 1 when estimating an intercept (c) and a slope (γ) for each city in a
single regression is 56.6%. Adding driver and trip controls in column 2 raises this R2 slightly, to
57.6%. The more exhaustive controls of column 3 also increase the R2 slightly, this time to 57.8%.
Controls for trip and driver characteristics do not affect our estimation of the distance elasticity.
This does not imply that driver and trip characteristics do not affect speed. They do. While we
do not report these coefficients, several are interesting. Women are about 0.5% slower than men.
Age is more important. A year of age is associated with 0.3% slower speed. Black drivers drive
about 8% slower. Drivers with more education and drivers with higher income are faster, although
in both cases the relationship tapers off after a threshold: drivers with a Bachelor degree are about
7% faster than workers with less than high school; drivers from households with annual income
around $60,000 are about 9% faster than drivers from the poorest households.12 Our findings on
the effect of trip characteristics are unsurprising: week-end trips are about 4% faster than week-day
trips; trips departing during the morning peak are about 4% slower than trips in the middle of the
night; trips departing during the evening peak are about 10% slower than trips in the middle of
10 It would also be of interest to investigate whether the effect of driver and trip characteristics vary across msas, e.g.,
to check if ‘peak’ hours differ in intensity and duration across msas. However, given that our ultimate objective is an
understanding of city level determinants of speed, we leave such an investigation for future research.
11 But this does not imply that the estimated coefficients for the intercept and the distance elasticity are always exactly
the same for all cities. We return to this issue below.
12 This might obviously be related to the state of their vehicles which we do not control for.
15
the night; there are small differences between months, Winter and Fall months are about 1% faster
than Spring and Summer months.
In column 4, we return to the specification of column 1 and introduce driver fixed effects.
The results for this column confirm that driver characteristics do not affect the estimation of
our parameters of interest. With driver fixed effects, the mean of both intercepts and slopes are
unchanged from column 1.
Column 5 replicates the specification of column 2, but, to instrument for trip distance, uses
the mean log distance of other trips with the same purpose in the same msa. We note that this
estimation raises a technical issue. To be consistent with Column 2 we want to estimate a separate
iv regression for each msa.13 At the same time, we want to constrain the effect of driver and trip
characteristics to be the same everywhere. This calls for a two-step approach where the effects
of driver and trip characteristics on speed are estimated first from the cross-section of msas. We
then take these coefficients as given (i.e., treat them as constraints) when estimating a separate tsls
regression for each msa.
If drivers take longer trips when travel is faster, then ols estimates of γ are biased upwards.
Comparing the iv results in column 5 panel a with the corresponding ols results in column 2
we see that, as expected, the iv estimates of γ are smaller than the ols estimates. In column 5,
the mean iv mean elasticity of speed with respect to distance is 0.360. The corresponding ols
value from column 2 is 0.426. This 20% difference between the ols and iv estimates is statistically
significant for a majority of cities. These elasticities imply that after controlling for simultaneity
in the choice of trip distance and speed, speed increases by only about 20.359 ≈ 28% when trip
distance doubles as opposed to the almost 35% increase we observe in equilibrium speed.
We also observe that the estimates of c are higher with iv than ols. By inspection of figure 3,
finding a lower iv than ols estimate of c is the logical counterpart of the smaller iv elasticity since
a lower intercept must be associated with a smaller slope. Consistent with this, the iv of column 5
results imply a speed of nearly 17 kilometers per hour for a trip of one kilometer. This is about two
kilometers per hour faster than is implied by the ols estimate of column 2 (recall that a smaller
value of c implies a lower time cost of travel and hence a higher speed).
In column 6, we replicate the iv estimations of column 5, but instrument for trip distance using
13 So that we instrument trip distance in a city by only the instruments for this city instead of the entire set of
instruments.
16
mean log distance for trips of the same type in the four msas with most nearly the same population.
The results are close to those of column 5. Mean log distance for trips of the same purpose in msas
with similar population is a stronger instrument than mean log distance by trip purpose in the
same msa because the instrument is computed using more observations. In most cases we use
four msas instead of one to calculate the instrument. While weak instruments are an issue for only
a small number of msas in column 5, we prefer the specification of column 6 and we use these
regressions to compute our benchmark speed index.
In column 7, we use seven trip purpose dummies as instruments. Despite the different rationales for the validity of the instruments, this yields mean estimates close to those of columns 5
and 6. In column 8, we only use one trip purpose dummy as an instrument. This dummy is defined
to be one for commutes and work-related trips and zero otherwise. For other trips, we also restrict
our sample to less discretionary trip types; shopping, personal business, school and church, and
medical/dental. The slopes we estimate for the inverse-supply curves are close to those from the
other iv estimates. While we do not report them here, the standard errors associated with our
estimates for each msa increase when using these more demanding methods of estimation.
Finally, in column 9 we return to the same instruments as in column 6 but apply them to the
fixed effect estimation of column 4. This is a very demanding estimation strategy since the effect of
distance on speed is identified within driver from the speed differences between long work trips
and shorter trips. When estimating the slopes and intercepts for the 100 largest msas as we do in
panel a, the coefficients are on average the same as estimates for the 50 largest msas, but exhibit
more dispersion.
Panel b replicates panel a for our sample of the 50 largest msas. For more demanding estimations like column 9, the coefficients of interest are more precisely estimated than when we consider
the 100 largest msas. Even for the specification of column 1, the mean of the standard error on c
and on γ is about twice as large for msas ranked between 51 and 100 in terms of population as for
the largest 50.
Panels c and d replicate panel b for 2001, and 1995, respectively. The results for 2001 are similar
to those for 2008. This is consistent with mean trip distances and speeds being essentially the
same in 2001 and 2008. We note nonetheless that the variances of the city intercepts and distance
elasticities are larger in 2001 than in 2008. This probably reflects the larger sample drawn by the
2008 nhts. For 1995, the estimated distance elasticities of speed are close to but smaller than
17
those for 2001 and 2008. The city intercepts are also smaller. This is consistent with the observed
reduction in mean speed after 1995.
As a final robustness check, we experiment with alternative functional forms. Figure 1 suggest
that for Chicago in 2008 the relationship between log speed and log distance is approximately
linear. We see a similar pattern in other cities. To investigate the possibility of non-linearities more
formally, we first re-estimate the specification of column 2 table 3 with a common distance effect.
The R2 of that regression is 0.576. Adding the square and the cube of log distance raises this R2
slightly to 0.589. While the coefficients associated with these two non-linear terms are statistically
significant, they make little economic difference. For a trip of 5 kilometers, the elasticity of speed
with respect to distance is 0.490. For a much longer trip of 30 kilometers(at the 90th percentile of
trip distance) we find a slightly lower elasticity of 0.420.14 We prefer to use the linear specifications
reported in table 3 because they are more precisely estimated.15
In sum, three main findings emerge from table 3. First, there is evidence of the simultaneous
determination of speed and distance. This will affect our estimates of mean speed for all us msas.
As the bias may differ across cities, this can also affect our ranking of cities. Second, different iv
strategies yield similar results. Third, the inclusion of other trip and driver controls makes little
difference to our estimates.
4. Speed index
Our objective is to understand the determinants of driving speed in major us cities. Yet, as our
model and data make clear, ‘the speed of travel in a city’ is not well defined. Cities do not offer a
single speed of travel. They offer a menu of feasible speed and trip distance combinations.16
Therefore, to describe a city’s ability to supply road transportation we rely on a speed index that
is analogous to a standard price index. Loosely, we first calculate the bundle of trips undertaken
by an average us driver. Next, using our city level estimates of equation (6), we calculate the time
14 That the elasticity of speed with respect to distance should eventually decline with trip distance is to be expected
since speed is bounded.
15 We also experimented with non-parametric and semi-parametric specifications. They generally confirm the finding
that a linear specification provides a good first order approximation of the relationship between distance and speed and
that the elasticity of speed with respect to distance falls slowly with distance.
16 This obviously makes comparisons across cities difficult. A city with a high c will be fast for short trips but may
be slow for long trips if its γ is low. The problem is all the more important since we expect c and γ to be positively
correlated, be it only for econometric reasons: c and γ are estimated together so that a positive error in the estimation of
c should also imply a positive error for γ which enters the same estimating equation with opposite sign.
18
required to complete the average daily bundle of trips in the subject city and in an average city.
The ratio of these two times tells us the speed of travel in the subject city in a precise sense: it tells
us the time premium required to complete a standard bundle of trips in the subject city relative to
an average city.
More formally, suppressing msa population weights and year indices, index for city i is
Si =
Σ jk x jk exp (cUS − γUS ln x jk )
.
Σ jk x jk exp (ci − γi ln x jk )
(7)
That is, we compute the the time that it would take to realize all (weighted) us trip distances in
our data at the average estimated us speed relative to how much time it would take to realize the
same trips at the estimated speed of a given msa. Formally, this is the inverse of a Laspeyres time
cost index which we can interpret as a speed index.17
Calculation of speed indices
Table 4 reports our preferred speed index for the largest 50 us msas in 1995, 2001, and 2008. This
index is based on our preferred estimate of equation (3) from column 6 of table 3. In this regression
we instrument for trip distance with mean distance for trips of the same type in the four cities most
nearly the same size.
For 2008, we find that the speed of driving in the slowest msa, Miami, is 28% lower than in the
fastest, Grand Rapids. This gap is slightly larger in 2001 and lower in 1995. More generally, among
the 10 slowest msas, we find the four largest (New York, Los Angeles, Chicago, and Washington),
another from the top 10 (Boston), four large cities with a difficult geography (Miami, Seattle, New
Orleans, and Pittsburgh) and one city with stringent zoning regulations (Portland).18
There are some changes in ranking between 1995 and 2008. The rank correlation between
the 2008 and 2001 ranking is 0.81 while that between the 2008 and 1995 ranking is 0.62. These
correlations are high. Moreover, many of the changes in rank probably reflect changes in city level
fundamentals: in a regression of changes in the speed index from 1995 to 2008 against population
changes over the same period and the 1995 value of the same index, we find a coefficient -0.078
17 We
measure the time cost of travel to estimate supply at the trip level to retain a standard prices vs. quantities
expositional device. When aggregating our results for entire msas we revert to the more usual and intuitive concept of
speed.
18 Obviously, msa boundaries also matter. For instance, the metropolitan area of New York contains much more than
New York City, including many areas where traffic is fast.
19
Table 4: Ranking of the 50 largest MSAs, slowest at the top
Miami-Fort Lauderdale, FL
Chicago-Gary-Kenosha, IL - IN - WI
Seattle-Tacoma-Bremerton, WA
Portland-Salem, OR - WA
Los Angeles-Riverside-Orange County, CA
New York-Northern NJ-Long Isl., NY- NJ - CT- PA
New Orleans, LA
Pittsburgh, PA
Boston-Worcester-Lawrence-Low.-Brock., MA - NH
Washington-Baltimore, DC - MD - VA - WV
San Francisco-Oakland-San Jose, CA
Sacramento-Yolo, CA
Houston-Galveston-Brazoria, TX
Tampa-St. Petersburg-Clearwater, FL
Orlando, FL
Philadelphia-Wilmington-Atl. City, PA - NJ - DE - MD
Norfolk-Virginia Beach-Newport News, VA - NC
Phoenix-Mesa, AZ
Las Vegas, NV- AZ
Cleveland-Akron, OH
Atlanta, GA
Detroit-Ann Arbor-Flint, MI
Austin-San Marcos, TX
San Diego, CA
St. Louis, MO - IL
Dallas-Fort Worth, TX
Denver-Boulder-Greeley, CO
Salt Lake City-Ogden, UT
San Antonio, TX
Indianapolis, IN
Jacksonville, FL
Hartford, CT
Charlotte-Gastonia-Rock Hill, NC - SC
West Palm Beach-Boca Raton, FL
Richmond-Petersburg, VA
Buffalo-Niagara Falls, NY
Memphis, TN - AR - MS
Minneapolis-St. Paul, MN - WI
Columbus, OH
Milwaukee-Racine, WI
Raleigh-Durham-Chapel Hill, NC
Cincinnati-Hamilton, OK - KY- IN
Nashville, TN
Oklahoma City, OK
Rochester, NY
Greenville-Spartanburg-Anderson, SC
Kansas City, MO - KS
Greensboro–Winston-Salem–High Point,NC
Louisville, KY- IN
Grand Rapids-Muskegon-Holland, MI
2008
Index
2008
Rank
2001
Index
2001
Rank
1995
Index
0.88
0.91
0.94
0.94
0.95
0.95
0.95
0.96
0.96
0.96
0.97
0.97
0.98
0.98
0.99
0.99
0.99
1.00
1.01
1.02
1.03
1.03
1.04
1.04
1.04
1.04
1.05
1.05
1.06
1.06
1.07
1.08
1.09
1.09
1.10
1.10
1.10
1.10
1.10
1.10
1.11
1.12
1.13
1.15
1.16
1.16
1.18
1.19
1.20
1.23
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
29
30
31
32
33
34
35
36
37
38
39
40
41
42
43
44
45
46
47
48
49
50
0.88
0.93
0.95
1.04
0.97
0.95
0.98
0.98
0.98
0.98
1.00
1.03
1.06
1.02
1.02
0.96
1.13
1.04
0.94
1.12
1.08
1.08
1.08
1.09
1.09
1.08
0.99
1.08
1.10
1.04
1.14
1.14
1.13
1.12
1.19
1.18
1.25
1.11
1.16
1.08
1.19
1.01
1.09
1.12
1.14
1.17
1.29
1.24
1.09
1.27
1
2
4
19
7
5
9
10
11
8
13
17
21
15
16
6
37
20
3
36
23
24
22
31
28
25
12
26
32
18
40
41
38
35
46
44
48
33
42
27
45
14
29
34
39
43
50
47
30
49
0.91
0.90
0.98
1.09
1.00
0.93
1.02
1.02
0.99
0.97
1.01
1.22
1.10
1.09
1.04
0.97
1.07
1.10
1.16
0.96
1.08
1.06
1.06
1.10
1.21
1.12
0.99
1.07
1.15
1.11
0.98
1.24
1.15
1.05
1.17
1.09
1.13
1.11
1.05
1.06
1.22
1.04
1.24
1.14
1.15
1.46
1.07
1.25
1.29
1.12
1995 Population
Rank
rank
2
1
8
28
11
3
13
14
9
6
12
45
31
26
15
5
24
29
41
4
25
20
21
30
43
34
10
22
38
32
7
47
39
18
42
27
36
33
17
19
44
16
46
37
40
50
23
48
49
35
Notes: Inverse Laspeyres index constructed from the estimations reported in column 6 of table 3.
20
14
3
12
22
2
1
37
21
7
4
5
24
10
20
26
6
31
13
29
16
11
9
35
17
18
8
19
34
28
30
44
40
32
43
49
41
42
15
33
27
38
23
36
45
46
50
25
39
48
47
(significant at 10%) for the 50 largest msas and -0.118 (significant at 5%) for the 100 largest msas.
With this said, some changes in ranking across years are probably due to sampling error.
Robustness checks
To assess the robustness of our preferred ranking, we compare it to alternative rankings based on
the same data but different aggregation methods or different estimation strategies.
First, the exact construction of our index does not matter. Our speed index is an inverse
Laspeyres index. Using a Paasche or a Fisher index instead makes little difference to our ranking of
msas. Using our preferred estimation strategy and our sample of the 50 largest msas, the Spearman
rank correlation between our preferred ranking and its Paasche counterpart is above 0.99 for 1995,
2001, and 2008. If we consider the 100 largest msas the corresponding correlations are all above
0.96. These findings are not specific to our choice of estimation. We find similarly high correlations
for the Paasche and Laspeyres rankings constructed from the output of ols estimation for column
2 of table 3 (i.e., the ols estimation that corresponds to our preferred iv).
Next, we compare our preferred ranking, calculated from column 6 of table 3, with alternative
rankings calculated from other columns of the same table and with average speed calculated
directly from the data. Starting with the latter, the Spearman rank correlation between our
preferred ranking and one obtained based on msa average speed is 0.68 for 50 msas in 2008.
The Spearman rank correlations between our preferred ranking and alternative rankings obtained
from the ols estimates of column 1 to 3 of table 3 are between 0.91 and 0.94 for 50 msas in 2008.
For the fixed-effect estimation of column 4, the correlation is slightly lower at 0.88. For the iv
estimations of columns 5, 7, 8, and 9, the correlations are 0.97, 0.90, 0.95, and 0.72, respectively.
This last correlation is lower because of the more noisy estimates obtained in column 9 (our most
demanding estimation, with driver fixed effects in an iv regression).19
For 1995 and 2001, correlations across rankings are slightly lower. For instance, in our sample
of the 50 largest msas, the Spearman rank correlation between our preferred ranking and the
alternative ranking obtained from the ols estimates of column 2 of table 3 is 0.88 in 2001 and 0.79 in
19 The
variance in average normalized inverse-speed across the 50 largest msas in 2008 is 0.092. The variance of a
speed index based on the simple ols estimation of column 1 of table 3 which controls for trip distance is lower at 0.057.
The variance of our preferred speed index is 0.074. Given our expectation of longer distances when traffic conditions
are better, both controlling for distance and then controlling for its endogeneity should reduce differences in observed
speed across msas. At the same time, more demanding estimation methods introduce greater sampling error. The first
effect dominates when going from the raw data to ols whereas the second dominates when implementing iv instead of
ols estimations.
21
1995 instead of 0.93 in 2008. For the 100 largest msas, the Spearman rank correlation between our
preferred ranking and the same alternative based on ols estimates is 0.85 in 2008. More generally,
correlations drop when we use 100 msas instead 50.
We draw a number of conclusions from these correlations. First, the relatively low correlation between our preferred ranking and raw measures of speed underscores the importance of
controlling for trip distance.20 Second, the high correlations between the indices derived from
our various iv estimations suggest that our preferred ranking is not sensitive to the details of
our instrumentation strategy provided the relationship between speed and distance is precisely
estimated. Third, the relatively high correlations between our preferred ranking and the rankings
derived from ols estimates suggest that controlling econometrically for the simultaneous determination of speed and distance has only a small effect on the final ranking of msas.
Comparison with TTI’s index
The Texas Transportation Institute produces the best known and most widely reported indices of
travel speed. We here investigate the differences between our index and and the 2008 and 2009 tti
indices (Schrank and Lomax, 2009, Schrank et al., 2010).
While tti reports their index annually, their methods changed from 2008 to 2009 (Schrank and
Lomax, 2009, Schrank et al., 2010). The 2008 tti index is based on an estimate of the time cost
of travel constructed from data in the hpms describing road characteristics and traffic levels on
interstate highways and other federally funded roads. The 2009 tti, on the other hand, is based
on directly observed time costs of travel on highways and major arterial roads for a self selected
sample of commercial vehicles and the drivers of privately-owned vehicles. Unlike the tti index,
our index is based on a sample constructed to be broadly representative of all trips in privatelyowned vehicles. In addition, the tti indices do not attempt to control for the simultaneity in the
choice of distance and speed.
Aside from differences in the quality of the underlying data and methodology, the tti indices
are based on a different geography than we use (see Appendix A). While neither geography is
intrinsically preferable, this difference complicates the comparisons of indices. For the 47 cities
reported by tti also in our sample of the 50 largest msas, the Spearman rank correlation of our
20 This
lower correlation of 0.68 is not specific to our preferred estimation. None of the indices built from the
estimations in tables 3 has a correlation with average inverse speed that is above 0.75.
22
preferred speed index is -0.69 for the 2008 tti travel cost index and -0.74 for 2009. For the 71 cities
reported by tti also in our sample of the 100 largest msas, those correlations are -0.61 and -0.63
respectively.21
5. Determinants of speed
To investigate why some cities are faster than others, we regress our speed index on a number of
its determinants, roads and vehicle travel time in particular. That is, we estimate variants of the
following regression,
ln Si = α ln Ri − θ ln vtti + Xi φ + νi .
(8)
In this equation Ri is a measure of the city’s stock of roads, vtti is aggregate vehicle travel time for
the city, Xi is a set of other city characteristics and νi an error term. This regression predicts speed
or, more precisely, the proportional difference in the speed at which a standard bundle of trips is
conducted in a particular msa relative to the sample average speed for the same standard bundle
of trips.
Three comments about this estimation are in order. First, since speed multiplied by vehicle
travel time equals vehicle kilometers traveled (vkt), equation (5) is equivalent to
ln vkti = α ln Ri + (1 − θ ) ln vtti + Xi φ + νi .
(9)
Equation (9), and thus equation (8), is the exact counterpart of a standard production function.
Vehicle kilometers traveled is our measure of output. Roads and vehicle time traveled are factors
of production. α is the share of roads in the production of travel and 1 − θ is the share of vehicle
travel time. It follows that α − θ is also a measure of returns to scale. If α < θ there are decreasing
returns to scale in the production of vkt. The error term νi is total factor productivity, the ability of
a city to move its residents conditional on its stock of roads and aggregate time spent in cars.
Second, an alternative approach to understanding the role of roads and travel time as determinants of speed would be to include Ri and vtt as controls in equation (6). That is, we could
skip the calculation of the speed index altogether and investigate the determinants of speed using
individual data. We prefer the approach based on aggregate data, i.e., equation (9) because we
think the speed index is of intrinsic interest. With this said, our results are robust to this alternative
approach.
21 These
correlations are negative since we use a speed index whereas tti indices measure the time cost of travel.
23
Table 5: The determinants of speed, 100 MSAs in 2008
(0)
Sraw
log lane 0.087c
(0.047)
log VTT -0.10b
(0.045)
2
R
0.11
(1)
SOLS 1
(2)
SOLS 2
(3)
SOLS 3
(4)
SFE
(5)
SIV 1
(6)
SIV 2
(7)
SIV 3
(8)
SIV 4
(9)
SIV FE
0.081a
(0.019)
-0.10a
(0.018)
0.36
0.089a
(0.020)
-0.11a
(0.018)
0.45
0.090a
(0.020)
-0.11a
(0.019)
0.45
0.070a
(0.019)
-0.091a
(0.018)
0.34
0.10a
(0.036)
-0.14a
(0.034)
0.35
0.11a
(0.033)
-0.15a
(0.031)
0.41
0.062b
(0.029)
-0.099a
(0.026)
0.32
0.11a
(0.033)
-0.16a
(0.031)
0.39
0.22
(0.19)
-0.17
(0.18)
0.01
Notes: OLS regressions with a constant in all columns. Robust standard errors in parentheses. a, b, c:
significant at 1%, 5%, 10%. 100 observations per column. In column 0, the dependent variable is average
trip speed. In columns 1-9, the dependent variable is minus the log of the index computed from the results
of the regressions reported in the corresponding column of table 3.
Finally, the econometrics problems with estimating production functions are well-known and
have received considerable attention (e.g., Ackerberg, Benkard, Berry, and Pakes, 2007, Syverson,
2011). Since we observe the true cost of travel, our analysis is not subject to problems associated
with unobserved prices. Second, as in the standard case, both factors of production, roads and
aggregate travel time, may be endogenously determined. To respond to this endogeneity problem we consider a number of instrumental variables estimations and also estimate the dynamic
production functions proposed by Levinsohn and Petrin (2003).
Determinants of speed, empirical results
Table 5 reports ols estimations of equation (8) for our sample of the 100 largest msas. In all
specifications we include a measure of travel speed on the log of msa lane kilometers of interstate
highways and the log of msa vehicle travel time. In column 0, the dependent variable is average
trip speed taken directly from the data. In columns 1 to 9, the dependent variable is the log of the
speed index computed from the results of the regressions reported in the corresponding column(s)
of table 3.
Column 6 reports our preferred regression in table 5. In this regression the dependent variable
is our preferred speed index calculated from the results of column 6 in table 3. This regression
implies an elasticity of travel speed with respect to lane kilometers of road of 0.11. This quantity
also corresponds to the share of roads in the production of travel. The coefficient for log vtt implies
a negative elasticity of speed with respect to aggregate vehicle travel time of −0.15. This quantity,
24
θ = 0.15, also implies that the elasticity of vehicle kilometers travelled with respect to travel time
is 0.85.
The estimated coefficients for the log of lane kilometers and vehicle travel time are very similar
in columns 0-8 of table 5. In all specifications, the coefficient on log lane remains between 0.07 and
0.11 while that on log vehicle travel time remains between −0.09 and −0.16. Column 9 uses a speed
index based on the least precisely estimated speed-distance relationship and yields insignificant
estimates.
Appendix B describes extensive robustness tests for the results reported in table 5. We show that
the coefficients we find on roads, on aggregate travel time, and the existence of modest decreasing
returns are also robust to our choice of sample, year of data, definition of roads, and measure of
aggregate travel time. In this appendix we also tackle the endogeneity of both roads and vtt.
In a first exercise, we instrument roads and/or vtt. In a second exercise, we implement the
methodology developed by Levinsohn and Petrin (2003). Both exercises largely confirm the results
of table 5.
Given the analogy between our estimating equation (8) and a firm level production function, it
is interesting to compare our results about the production of travel with what is known about the
production of other goods.22 We find that the share of roads in the production of travel is about
around 0.10. whereas typical estimates regarding the share of capital in conventional sectors tend
to be around one third. This suggests that the production of travel is an extremely labour (or time)
intensive activity.
We also find evidence of slightly decreasing returns. The literature that estimates the production
function for firms contains a variety of results but micro-data estimates are often suggestive of
constant returns. Slightly decreasing returns in the production of travel might seem surprising
since roads constitute a network and networks are often associated with increasing returns. An
explanation may be that urban roads are often organised as ‘hub-and-spoke’ networks whose hubs
are more congested in larger cities. We return to this issue below.
Finally, consistent with extant research on productivity in firms (Syverson, 2011, Fox and
Smeets, 2011), we find considerable dispersion in productivity across cities. However, there is
much less dispersion in the ability of us cities to produce travel out of roads and vehicle travel
22 We do not know of estimates directly comparable to ours in the literature. Combes and Lafourcade (2005) decompose the decline in generalized transportation costs for trucks in France over 1978-1998 and find that changes in the road
infrastructure only accounts for 8% of this decline.
25
Table 6: The determinants of speed, further explanatory variables
Added:
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
(8)
Emp.
Pop. Job/resid. E pop. log pop. s. manuf. Cooling Heating
central. central. mismatch growth 1920
emp.
deg. days deg. days
0.098a 0.089a
(0.033) (0.032)
log VTT
-0.15a -0.15a
(0.031) (0.030)
Added variable -0.096c -0.14a
(0.051) (0.054)
2
R
0.42
0.43
log lane (total)
0.11a
(0.033)
-0.15a
(0.031)
-35.1c
(20.9)
0.42
0.093a 0.090a
(0.034) (0.033)
-0.13a
-0.15a
(0.033) (0.031)
-0.15a 0.015a
(0.058) (0.0050)
0.43
0.44
0.097a
(0.033)
-0.14a
(0.031)
0.22a
(0.13)
0.43
0.10a
(0.033)
-0.14a
(0.031)
-0.013b
(0.0067)
0.45
0.095a
(0.033)
-0.14a
(0.032)
0.0057b
(0.0026)
0.43
Notes: OLS regressions with a constant in all columns. Robust standard errors in parentheses. a, b, c:
significant at 1%, 5%, 10%. 100 observations per column. Dependent variables is − log SIV 2 in all columns.
time than in the ability of firms to produce output from capital and labour. A city at the 90th
percentile in our preferred estimation (column 6 of table 5) produces around 20% more travel from
the same inputs than a city at the 10th percentile. Firm level data usually imply that a firm at the
90th percentile of productivity produces 100 to 200% more output from the same inputs than a firm
at the 10th percentile.
Other determinants of speed
In table 6 we consider a broader set of determinants of travel speed. In column 1, we introduce
a measure of employment centralization, the share of employment within 20 kilometers of the
employment weighted centroid of the msa in 1992.23 In column 2, we use instead the corresponding measure of centralization for population. The results for both columns indicate that more
centralized cities are slower. These findings should be regarded as suggestive; the coefficient for
employment centralization is only weakly significant, the R2 increases only marginally relative
to the benchmark estimation without these additional variables, and the significance of these
coefficients often disappears when further controls are added. In column 3, we use a measure of
mismatch between employment and residents and find again that a greater mismatch is associated
with slower traffic speeds. We have experimented more broadly with ‘urban form’ variables than
we report here. Consistent with the results reported in table 6, we find that conditional associations
23 We
prefer to use lagged variables to minimize endogeneity problems. These lags typically reduce the significance
of the coefficients.
26
with various measures of density, physical area and employment concentration, occur routinely
in our results. Taken together, these findings are strongly suggestive that more compact and
centralized cities are slower. This is consistent with earlier results in the literature (e.g., Glaeser
and Kahn, 2004).
In column 4 of table 6, we turn to a different type of variable, population growth. We find
a strong association between slow travel speeds and higher expected growth between 1980 and
2000.24 A similar but weaker association is found with actual population growth between 1980
and 2008. That population growth should slow traffic is unsurprising in the light of evidence
that an msa’s roads adjust slowly to population growth (Duranton and Turner, 2012). In column
5, we replace expected population growth with 1920 population. Given that we also condition
for current vehicle time travel which is highly correlated with current population, our negative
coefficient implies that cities that have grown less since 1920 are faster. This confirms the finding
of column 4. In column 6, we turn to the share of manufacturing in employment in 1983 and find
that cities more specialized in manufacturing are much faster. Given that cities with a greater share
of manufacturing employment have grown less in population and tend to be more decentralized
(Glaeser and Kahn, 2001), the positive sign on manufacturing employment is consistent with our
two main findings so far (as well as findings in Duranton, Morrow, and Turner, 2011).
In columns 7 and 8, we introduce two measures of temperature, cooling and heating degree
days, and uncover a weak association between slower traffic and more extreme weather conditions. We also experimented with other geographic characteristics of cities such as their elevation
range or the ruggedness of their terrain but found nothing. We also found no result for a broad
range of socioeconomic characteristics of cities such as their income, education, etc. Finally, we
note that introducing all these supplementary explanatory variables has little effect on the coefficients of our two main regressors, roads and vehicle travel time, both of which remain significant
and nearly constant in all the columns of table 6.
6. The value of speed
In this section we conduct two distinct exercises to estimate the value of speed. The first describes
a series of simple out-of-equilibrium policy experiments. The second conducts a standard partial
24 Again, we use growth predicted by the composition of economic activity of cities in 1980 and the subsequent
changes in employment by sector.
27
equilibrium welfare analysis.
Out-of-equilibrium policy experiments
We consider four different counterfactual experiments. Under the first, we increase the speed of 95
of the 100 largest msas to the level of the msa at the 95th percentile of the distribution of speed and
leave the five fastest msas as they are. Let S95 denote the counterfactual speed index associated
with this policy. In the second experiment, we increase the efficiency with which msas use roads
and travel time. More specifically, we take the 95 msas with the lowest productivity residual in
our preferred estimation of equation (8) and increase their productivity to the level of the msa
at the 95th percentile of the distribution of productivity and leave the five most efficient msas
as they are. Let Stfp95 denote the counterfactual speed index associated with this policy. In the
third experiment, we increase road intensity – the stock of roads per unit of vehicle travel time –
in an analogous manner. Let SRoads95 denote the counterfactual speed index associated with this
policy. In the fourth experiment, we decrease aggregate msa travel time, holding everything else
constant, to the level of the fifth smallest msa. That is, we ask what would happen if we distributed
the drivers in large msa across several smaller msas, holding the relative provision of roads at the
original level. Let SScale95 denote the counterfactual speed index associated with this policy.
More formally, the last three counterfactual experiments involve computing the following three
counterfactual speed indices,
− ln Stfp95 = α̂ ln( Ri /vtti ) + (α̂ − θ̂ ) ln vtti + ν̂i 95
(10)
− ln SRoads95 = α̂ ln( R/vtt)95
i + ( α̂ − θ̂ ) ln vtti + ν̂i
(11)
− ln SScale95 = α̂ ln( Ri /vtti ) + (α̂ − θ̂ ) ln vtt95
i + ν̂i .
(12)
where ν̂95 is the value of the productivity residual, ν̂, at the 95th percentile, ( R/vtt)95 is the road
intensity at the 95th percentile, and vtt95 denotes the analogous counterfactual value of vtt.
Table 7 describes the value of these alternative policies for our sample of the 100 largest msas.
Each of the first four columns of the table describes one of the four policies. Each of the three
panels describes the effect of our policies in a different year. In the first row of each panel we
calculate the change in person weighted travel speed associated with each policy. In the second,
we calculate the number of people affected by each experiment. Finally, in the third row of each
28
Table 7: Valuing policy experiments for the 100 largest MSAs in 2008
S95
STFP95 SRoads95 SScale95
S
1995
Mean Speed (km/h)
63.6 60.0
People affected(millions)
172
171
Aggregate ∆ VTT (millions of hours) 6,927 5,046
53.6
171
1,260
57.1 49.9
173
3,386
2001
Mean Speed (km/h)
57.6 52.9
People affected(millions)
190
189
Aggregate ∆ VTT (millions of hours) 9,113 5,658
48.4
191
1,748
52.3 48.8
192
5,184
2008
Mean Speed (kph)
57.3 52.3
People affected(millions)
207
205
Aggregate ∆ VTT (millions of hours) 9,579 5,332
50.1
207
3,281
51.3 46.5
206
4,411
Notes: Authors’ computations, using the 100 largest MSAs and regression results from column 6 in Table 5
for 2008, and the equivalent regressions for 2001 and 1995. We report the population of the 95 MSAs below
the 95th percentile of each distribution in parentheses.
panel, we calculate the change in aggregate travel time resulting from each experiment, holding
distance traveled constant. All calculations in table 7 are based on the estimation of equation (8)
reported in table 5, column 6. Finally, column 5 of table 7 reports mean speed across the 100 largest
msas where speed in each msa is computed from our preferred speed index.
Table 7 suggests a number of conclusions. First, the value of increasing speed is large. Increasing
speed to the 95th percentile of the distribution would save about 9.6 billion hours of travel in 2008.
Common practice in the transportation economics literature is to value these hours at half the
average wage of 23 dollars per hour and consider an average of 0.25 passengers in each car.25
This implies a gain of slightly less than 140 billion dollars.26 The second policy experiment, which
involves raising the productivity of cities below the 95th percentile, would imply gains of 77 billion
dollars. This suggests that, if slow msas can emulate fast ones in their ability to produce travel out
of roads and vehicle time, large gains would also occur. Put differently, if we can understand
the factors that affect the efficiency with which roads and time are employed, then large savings
should be possible. Since using roads and travel time more efficiently is likely to be a lot less
25 Existing
estimates of value of time traveled for commuters generally center around 50% of an individual’s hourly
wage (Small and Verhoef, 2007). We note that the Texas Transportation Institute uses a much higher number of nearly
24 dollars per hour per person (Schrank et al., 2010).
26 The Texas Transportation Institute (Schrank and Lomax, 2009, Schrank et al., 2010) conducts an exercise in the same
spirit as this one. Despite its much higher valuation of delay and a broader geographical coverage, it finds smaller
numbers; 87 and 115 billion dollars for 2008 and 2009, respectively. The main reason for this difference is that they focus
on major roads that measure only a small fraction of travel.
29
costly than building new roads, this suggests that research into the efficiency of transportation
networks is important. Finally, increasing road intensity and decreasing aggregate travel time by
redistributing drivers to smaller msas in the third and fourth experiment would imply gains of 47
and 63 billion dollars, respectively.
A simple variance analysis confirms the results of these counterfactual experiments. After
rewriting the determinants of speed into road intensity, scale, and productivity as in equations
(10) to (12), the variance of ln S is equal to the sum of the variance of the road intensity term,
α̂ ln( R/vtt), the variance of the scale term, (α̂ − θ̂ ) ln vtt, the variance of the productivity residual,
ν̂i , and twice the covariance between road intensity and scale. Consistent with the counterfactual
experiments above, we find that the productivity term accounts for 59% of the variance in log
speed whereas the contribution of scale is smaller at 20%. The contribution of road intensity is
smaller still at 9%. The remaining 12% are accounted for by the covariance term for scale and road
intensity which reflects the fact that larger msas have a lower road intensity.
Welfare analysis
We now conduct an alternative analysis of the value of speed in which we explicitly account for
the fact that our speed index is the result of an equilibrium process. This analysis is in the spirit
of the approach initially proposed by Beckman et al. (1956) and Vickrey (1963). To keep matters
simple we work directly from aggregate data using the speed index computed above.27 We begin
with equation (8) and make the substitution − ln Ωi ≡ αi ln Ri + Xi φi + νi . Rearranging, and
suppressing the i subscript for legibility, we have
C ≡ 1/S = Ω vttθ .
(13)
Note that the left hand side of this expression is the time cost of travel which is the inverse of speed
computed from our preferred speed index. We revert to the time cost of travel instead of speed to
facilitate the application of a conventional supply and demand framework below.
In an equilibrium where road access is unpriced all users will face the same unit cost of travel.
Our index measures this for a standardized bundle of trips. Thus, equation (13) gives the average
cost of a kilometer of travel as a function of msa aggregate travel time. Since vehicle kilometers
27 A
full analysis would require solving for the choice of distance for every trip (as we do above) and the choice of the
number and types of trips. Our speed index corrects for the endogeneity of the choice of trip distance. The measure of
vkt we compute below also accounts for this but does not account for the choice of number and types of trip since we
take vehicle travel time as given.
30
traveled (the quantity of travel) is equal to vehicle time traveled times speed, i.e., vkt ≡ vtt × S,
we can write vtt = C × vkt.28 Substituting in equation and solving for S, we have the following
supply equation for vkt:
1
θ
C = AC (vkt) = Ω 1−θ vkt 1−θ .
(14)
This equation is an aggregate supply curve for automobile travel in msa i.
Starting from the average cost curve given in equation (14), simple calculations then imply that
the marginal time cost of travel is
MC (vkt) =
C
.
1−θ
(15)
The marginal cost for travel reflects both the private value of a marginal kilometer of travel, and
also the extent to which this marginal kilometer slows down other drivers. Thus, this marginal
cost curve reflects the social cost of time lost to congestion.
In order to complete a partial equilibrium model of travel and speed, it remains only to specify
the demand for travel. Write the demand for vkt as vkt = ΓC −σ , where Γ is a constant and σ is
the demand elasticity of vkt with respect to the time cost of travel. For our purposes, it is more
useful to rearrange this and write it as an inverse demand curve,
1
1
C = Γ σ vkt− σ .
(16)
Equating average cost, equation (14), and demand, equation (16), we can solve for equilibrium
vkt,
eq
vkt = Γ
1− θ
Ω
−σ
1
1− θ (1− σ )
(17)
Optimal vkt results from equilibrating demand and marginal cost
σ (1− θ )
vktopt = (1 − θ ) 1−θ (1−σ) vkteq .
(18)
Since drivers base their decisions on average rather than marginal cost, equilibrium driving
exceeds the optimal. The deadweight loss from this excessive driving is given by,
Z vkteq vktopt
1
θ
1
1
− σ1
1
−
θ
1
−
θ
σ
Ω vkt − Γ vkt
dvkt .
1−θ
(19)
28 We keep in mind that we are using a speed index that corrects for the endogeneity of the choice of trip distance. The
measure of vkt we compute here also accounts for this.
31
Using equations (16) and (14) to write Ω and Γ in terms of vtteq = C eq × vkteq this expression
evaluates to
vtt
eq
1 − (1 − θ )
σ
1− θ (1− σ )
σ−1
−
σ
1 − (1 − θ )
(σ−1)(1−θ )
1− θ (1− σ )
.
(20)
.
(21)
Normalizing by total travel time we arrive at
∆=
1 − (1 − θ )
σ
1− θ (1− σ )
σ−1
−
σ
1 − (1 − θ )
(σ−1)(1−θ )
1− θ (1− σ )
This expression gives the deadweight loss from congestion in a particular city as a proportion of
the total travel time. It depends on just two parameters, the supply and demand elasticity, θ and
σ.
In our preferred regression in column 6 of table 5, we estimate the average supply elasticity θ̂
to be 0.15. We do not estimate the elasticity of the demand for vkt here. However, Duranton and
Turner (2011) suggests that the demand for vkt is highly elastic and provides a point estimate of
16.29
Using these values of θ = 0.15 and σ = 16, ∆ in equation (21) is about 0.105. That is, the value
of deadweight loss from congestion is equal to about 11% of total travel time. Taking aggregate
travel time for 2008 from panel b of table 1, converting from minutes per day to hours per year,
and adjusting upwards by 1.25 persons to car, we find 71 million hours per year of loss due to
congestion in an average msa in our sample. This works out to about 34 hours per person per year.
If we value this time at 11.5 dollars per hour this is 391 dollars per person per year. In total, for our
whole sample of 100 msas, the loss is about 7.1 billion hours per year or, again valuing time at 11.5
dollars per hour, 82 billion dollars per year.
The general magnitude of these estimates does not appear to be particularly sensitive to our
choice of σ, the demand elasticity. For example, if, contrary to the findings in Duranton and Turner
(2011) of σ = 16, we take σ = 1 so that demand for travel is much less sensitive to its price in
time, the deadweight loss from congestion increases from about 71 million hours per year in an
average msa to about 98. If we double the demand elasticity to 32, this quantity decreases to about
57 million hours per year. On the other hand, our findings are more sensitive to θ, a quantity that
we estimate and which measures how congestible the road network is. Keeping σ at our preferred
value of 16 and decreasing θ to 0.075 decreases the deadweight loss in an average msa to about
29 The working paper version of that work (table 6, columns 4 and 8 in Duranton and Turner, 2009) contains an explicit
estimation of the demand for vkt which yields σ ≈ 16.
32
46 million hour per year. Increasing θ to 0.225 we have a loss of 95 million hours per year. These
values of θ are respectively more than two standard errors smaller and larger that our preferred
estimate from column 6 table 5.
We can also use our analysis, equation (18) in particular, to calculate the extent to which
equilibrium driving exceeds optimal driving. At our preferred values of θ and σ, this calculation
indicates that the optimal level of vkt is only about half the equilibrium value. For values of σ
close to one, the gap between equilibrium and optimal vkt decreases dramatically to about 15%.
The amount of ‘overdrive’ is less sensitive to other changes in the parameters.
These calculations call for several comments. The first is of course one of caution. Although
robust to reasonable variations in our two key parameters, our estimated deadweight loss of about
82 billion dollars annually is conservative in many respects. We only consider the time cost of
travel and ignore fuel costs and other car usage costs, e.g., maintenance, pollution and collisions
for which estimates are reviewed in Parry, Walls, and Harrington (2007). We also consider only
travel by residents and ignore commercial traffic for which the time and fuel costs of congestion
are arguably higher.30 Finally, our estimates are based only on the population of the 100 largest
msas. However, these msas account for about two thirds of the us population, and presumably,
most of the traffic congestion. With this said, to the extent that congestion occurs outside of these
100 msas, our estimates are too low.
Discussion
Figure 3 illustrates our partial equilibrium model of speed and travel. In the figure, the demand
curve corresponds to the demand curve given by equation (16), the average cost curve, AC1 , corresponds to the supply curve given in equation (14), and the marginal cost curve, MC1 , corresponds
eq
to equation (15). In this figure, equilibrium speed and vkt1 are determined by the intersection of
supply curve, AC1 , and the demand curve. Socially optimal speed and vktopt are determined by
the intersection of demand and the marginal cost curve, MC1 .
30 To fix ideas, according to Duranton and Turner (2011), the share of trucks traffic for interstate highways in 228 large
us msas was 13% in 2003. In the calculations of the Texas Transportation Institute the cost of truck congestion represents
slightly more than a quarter of the total cost of congestion. As for fuel losses, they represent only a fraction of the time
cost of congestion. To see this, consider an hour lost to drive 10 kilometers. With a car consuming 15 liters per 100
kilometers, this is only 1.5 liters of fuel or about 1.5 dollars at one dollar per liter. This is small relative to a time cost of
11.5 dollars per hour.
33
Figure 3: Equilibrium speed and distance.
1/ S = C
MC1
B
A
F
AC1
C
D
E
I
H
G
AC2
Demand
VKT
VKT1opt
VKT1eq
VKT2eq
The counterfactual experiments performed earlier in this section involve increasing the speed
of travel, decreasing minutes per kilometer, holding travel constant at its equilibrium level. In this
figure, the value of such an experiment is given by the hatched rectangle whose corners are the
points FCGI. If we interpret this experiment as shifting down the supply curve in such a way that
eq
the cost to provide vkt1 is lower by the appropriate amount, then our counterfactual experiment
requires an alternative supply curve such as the curve AC2 in the figure. For every level of vkt,
travel is faster along this hypothetical supply curve than along the actual supply curve, AC1 .
It is obvious from the figure, that the area of the rectangle is likely to overstate the benefits
realized from our hypothetical improvement to supply. If we were to improve an msa’s ability
to provide travel so that the supply curve dropped from AC1 to AC2 , then the new equilibrium
eq
level of travel would be vkt2 . The increase in surplus associated with this improvement is not
the rectangular region FCGI, but rather the region whose corners are FCDE. Therefore, much
of the benefit associated with hypothetical improvements in an msa’s ability to supply travel are
dissipated by increased equilibrium demand: we should not expect dramatic shifts in the speed of
urban interstate highways at 4 pm to persist in equilibrium.
This means that these counterfactual experiments should be understood as informing us about
the sensitivity of the supply of travel to policy interventions to increase network capacity and
speed. More specifically, the counterfactual experiments above hint at a number of solutions to
34
improve traffic speed: increase the productivity of cities in their production of travel, increase
road intensity, and reduce scale. This last solution involves population dispersion and is thus not
feasible. The second solution, road construction, is often proposed in policy discussions. Using
data from Duranton and Turner (2012) based on estimates of road construction costs by Ng and
Small (2008) and maintenance costs from the us Bureau of Transportation Statistics 2007, increasing
the supply of interstate highways by 1% in all of the 100 largest msas has an annual cost of 1.45
billion dollars. Even with a low elasticity of the demand for vkt with respect to speed of one, the
annual gains are only 874 million dollars. Taking a higher elasticity of 16 as Duranton and Turner
(2009) makes these gain lower still at 269 million dollars.31 While such numbers should obviously
be taken with caution, they are indicative of low returns to ‘across-the-board’ road construction
at the margin (a conclusion we share with Winston and Langer, 2006). The last, and perhaps,
more promising solution suggested by our counterfactual experiments above is an improvement
of the management of the road network from ramp metering systems for highway access to the
management of intersections, etc. While a detailed analysis of these solutions goes well beyond
the scope of our paper, our findings are suggestive of large gains for slow msas if they can emulate
fast msas.
Figure 3 also illustrates our partial equilibrium welfare calculation. In fact, the value of the
deadweight loss from excessive driving given by equation (19) is equal to the area of the shaded
region ABC. The substance of our empirical results is that this area is large, on the order of 80
billion dollars per year. This is slightly lower than our estimates of the gains associated with
raising the speed in msas to the level of the fastest ones as represented by the hatched rectangle
FCGI.
While the counterfactual experiment performed above suggest some supply responses to congestion, the welfare calculation points to another direction: the management of demand. The large
deadweight loss estimated above arises because of a wedge between what drivers pay to access
the road (the average cost of driving) and the social cost they cause (the marginal cost of driving).
Reducing this wedge and the associated excess driving would yield large social gains without the
31 The welfare gain associated with road construction is equal to the reduction in speed caused by road construction
times initial vtt plus the triangle associated with the increase in vtt. Using (8), (13), and the demand for travel time
vtt = ΓC1−σ , we find that the elasticity of (inverse) speed with respect to roads is equal to −α × 1/θ1/θ
+σ−1 and the
elasticity of vtt with respect to roads is −α × 1−σ σ . Since we consider an increase in interstate highways, we take a value
of α of 0.067 which corresponds to the coefficient for this class of roads estimated in column 8 of table 8. For θ, we retain
our preferred value of 0.15 as above.
35
cost of constructing new roads.
Interestingly, figure 3 also points out that we can use our estimations to calculate an optimal
congestion tax. This tax is given by the height of the segment AH. With a uniform tax of | AH | per
eq
kilometer, we shift up the average cost curve AC1 so that the intersection of AC1 (vkt1 ) + | AH | is
eq
equal to the demand at vkt1 . To calculate this tax, we evaluate the difference between supply and
marginal cost at equilibrium vkt. Letting τ ∗ denote this optimal tax, we have
τ∗ =
h
i1/(1−θ (1−σ))
1
Ω1/(1−θ ) Γ1−θ Ω−σ
1−θ
(22)
Using equation (14) and (16) we can write Ω and Γ in terms of observed equilibrium vkt and C.
This gives,
−σ 1/(1−θ (1−σ))
1 eq 1−θ eq θ 1/(1−θ )
eq σ eq 1−θ
eq 1−θ eq θ
τ =
C
V
C V
C
V
1−θ
∗
(23)
Evaluating this tax at equilibrium quantities with θ = 0.15 and σ = 16 gives a tax of about 0.2
minutes per kilometer of travel. If we continue to value time at 11.5$/hour, this works out to a tax
of about four cents per kilometer.
That is, our empirical results indicate that travel in our sample of 100 msas is sufficiently
congested that even a small constant congestion tax applied to all roads would lead to welfare
gains on the order of 100 billion dollars per year. However, we note that our estimations are of
course too coarse to provide detailed guidance about congestion taxes but, as just shown, they are
useful to establish some magnitudes.32
7. Conclusion
Road transportation accounts for nearly one fifth of the budget for an average us household
and about 1.2 hours per day for an average us driver in 2008. In a typical year, the us spends
about 200 billion dollars on road construction and maintenance. Congestion naturally arises in
the course of turning these resources into travel. Despite a distinguished history of research in
transportation economics, the extant literature has struggled to measure the value of investments
in road transportation or the social cost of road congestion.
32 Importantly, we consider an average θ of 0.15 but this average is unlikely to be effective for peak hour travel where
most of the congestion occurs. With θ = 0.6, optimal ‘peak hour tax’ is much larger at around a dollar per kilometre.
However having a θ = 0.6 for a quarter of travel and θ = 0 the rest of the time yields a total revenue that is not very
different from having an average θ = 0.15 that applies all the time.
36
We make three advances in this agenda. First, we develop an econometric methodology and
data to identify city level supply curves for trip travel. With these supply curves, we construct
an index of travel speed for each of the largest us cities. This index number, for the first time,
provides a theoretically founded measure of the efficiency with which different locations produce
transportation.
Our investigation of the determinants of our speed index suggests that the production of transportation at the city level is subject to slight decreasing returns to scale. This finding provides an
empirical basis for the positive relationship between city size and congestion costs that is axiomatic
in nearly all extant theoretical models of city size. It also reveals the role of roads, travel time, and
unobserved productivity. The presence of economically important variation in the unobserved
productivity of cities at producing transportation suggests the possibility of large gains in efficiency if slow cities are able to emulate fast cities. We conduct a rudimentary investigation of city
characteristics associated with efficiency. Our findings are unsurprising: dense centralized cities
are less efficient. Refining this investigation is an important topic for further research and may
provide an empirical basis for the design of cities where travel is provided more efficiently.
Our investigation of the efficiency of travel amounts to the comparison of equilibrium speed
with counterfactual, out-of-equilibrium scenarios. In this, it resembles the widely known travel
cost indices published by tti. Fundamentally, these counterfactual cases do not evaluate an
economically meaningful definition of congestion. Such a measure of congestion is intrinsically
subtle, and requires the calculation of the deadweight loss incurred at equilibrium levels of travel
as opposed to optimum. Our estimates allow us a rough, and highly aggregated calculation of the
deadweight loss from congestion. This calculation indicates that the losses from congestion are
probably even larger than those suggested by counterfactual supply improvements. Since equilibrium responses dissipate much of the benefit from supply improvements, our results suggest that
the largest gains in transportation policy are probably to be had by managing demand.
37
References
Ackerberg, Daniel, C. Lanier Benkard, Steven Berry, and Ariel Pakes. 2007. Econometric tools for
analyzing market outcomes. In James J. Heckman and Edward E. Leamer (eds.) Handbook of
Econometrics, volume 6A. Amsterdam: North-Holland, 4271–4276.
Bartik, Timothy. 1991. Who Benefits from State and Local Economic Development Policies? Kalamazoo
(mi): W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research.
Baum-Snow, Nathaniel. 2007. Did highways cause suburbanization? Quarterly Journal of Economics
122(2):775–805.
Beckman, Martin, C. B. McGuire, and Christopher B. Winsten. 1956. Studies in the Economics of
Transportation. New Haven, ct: Yale University Press for the Cowles Commission for Research
in Economics.
Bombardini, Matilde and Francesco Trebbi. 2011. Gains from distortions in congested city networks. Processed, University of British Columbia.
Burchfield, Marcy, Henry G. Overman, Diego Puga, and Matthew A. Turner. 2006. Causes of
sprawl: A portrait from space. Quarterly Journal of Economics 121(2):587–633.
Combes, Pierre-Philippe and Miren Lafourcade. 2005. Transport costs: Measures, determinants,
and regional policy implications for France. Journal of Economic Geography 5(3):319–349.
Dewees, Donald N. 1979.
47(6):1499–1512.
Estimating the time costs of highway congestion.
Econometrica
Duranton, Gilles, Peter M. Morrow, and Matthew A. Turner. 2011. Roads and trade: Evidence from
the us. Processed, University of Toronto.
Duranton, Gilles and Matthew A. Turner. 2009. The fundamental law of road congestion: Evidence
from us cities. nber Working Paper 15376.
Duranton, Gilles and Matthew A. Turner. 2011. The fundamental law of road congestion: Evidence
from us cities. American Economic Review 101(6):2616–2652.
Duranton, Gilles and Matthew A. Turner. 2012. Urban growth and transportation. Forthcoming,
Review of Economic Studies.
Evans, William N., Wallace E. Oates, and Robert M. Schwab. 1992. Measuring peer group effects:
A study of teenage behavior. Journal of Political Economy 100(5):966–991.
Fox, Jeremy T. and Valérie Smeets. 2011. Does input quality drive measured differences in firm
productivity? International Economic Review 52(4):961–989.
Glaeser, Edward L. and Matthew Kahn. 2001. Decentralized employment and the transformation
of the American city. Brookings-Wharton Papers on Urban Affairs :1–47.
Glaeser, Edward L. and Matthew E. Kahn. 2004. Sprawl and urban growth. In Vernon Henderson
and Jacques-François Thisse (eds.) Handbook of Regional and Urban Economics, volume 4. Amsterdam: North-Holland, 2481–2527.
Greenshields, Bruce D. 1935. A study of traffic capacity. Highway Research Board Proceedings
14(0):448–477.
38
Keeler, Theodore E. and Kenneth A. Small. 1977. Optimal peak-load pricing, investment, and
service level on urban expressways. Journal of Political Economy 85(1):1–25.
Levinsohn, James and Amil Petrin. 2003. Estimating production functions using inputs to control
for unobservables. Review of Economic Studies 70(2):317–342.
McFadden, Daniel. 1973. Conditional logit analysis of qualitative choice behavior. In Paul Zarembka (ed.) Frontiers in econometrics. New York and London: Academic Press, 105–142.
McFadden, Daniel. 1974. The measurement of urban travel demand. Journal of Public Economics
3(4):303–328.
Meyer, John R., John F. Kain, and Martin Wohl. 1965. The urban transportation problem. Cambridge
(ma): Harvard University Press.
Michaels, Guy. 2008. The effect of trade on the demand for skill - Evidence from the Interstate
Highway System. Review of Economics and Statistics 90(4):683–701.
Ng, Chen Feng and Kenneth A. Small. 2008. Tradeoffs among free-flow speed, capcity, cost, and
environmental footprint in highway designs. Processed, University of California at Irvine.
Parry, Ian W.H., Margaret Walls, and Winston Harrington. 2007. Automobile externalities and
policies. Journal of Economic Literature 45(2):1335–1353.
Schrank, David and Tim Lomax. 2009. Urban mobility report 2009. Technical report, Texas
Transportation Institute.
Schrank, David, Tim Lomax, and Shawn Turner. 2010. Urban mobility report 2010. Technical
report, Texas Transportation Institute.
Small, Kenneth A. and Erik T. Verhoef. 2007. The Economics of Urban Transportation. New York (ny):
Routledge.
Syverson, Chad. 2011. What determines productivity. Journal of Economic Literature 49(2):326–365.
Train, Kenneth. 2009. Discrete Choice Methods with Simulation. Second edition. Cambridge (ma):
Cambridge University Press.
United States Bureau of Transportation Statistics. 2007. Transportation Statistics Annual Report 2007.
Washington, dc: us Government printing office.
United States Bureau of Transportation Statistics. 2010. Transportation Statistics Annual Report 2010.
Washington, dc: us Government printing office.
United States Department of Transportation, Federal Highway Administration. 2003a. Archive
Highway Performance Monitoring System (HPMS) Data Item Descriptions 1993 - 1998. Washington,
dc.
United States Department of Transportation, Federal Highway Administration. 2003b. Archive
Highway Performance Monitoring System (HPMS) Data Item Descriptions 1982-1987. Washington,
dc.
United States Department of Transportation, Federal Highway Administration. 2005. hpms Field
Manual. Washington, dc.
Vickrey, William S. 1963. Pricing in urban and suburban transport. American Economic Review
(Papers and Proceedings) 53(2):452–465.
39
Winston, Clifford and Ashley Langer. 2006. The effect of government highway spending on road
users’ congestion costs. Journal of Urban Economics 60(3):463–483.
Appendix A. Data
Consistent msa definition: msas are defined as aggregations of counties. We use the 1999 definition.
The nhts data contain either a county identifier or an msa identifier consistent with our msa
definition. Our variables either come from county level data or from maps that we overlay with a
map of 1999 counties.
nhts data (trip-level data): Our trip-level data are from the 1995-1996 National Personal Transportation Survey (npts) and its successors, the 2001-2002 and 2008-2009 National Household
Transportation Surveys (nhts). The surveys are sponsored by various agencies at the us Department of Transportation. Detailed documentation on the nhts sample design and data content
is available on the nhts website (http://nhts.ornl.gov/). The data are intended for use by
transportation planners in governmental agencies and aim at providing reliable, representative
and comprehensive micro-data about the daily travel of Americans.
nhts aggregate data: As explained in the text, the general idea behind our method for computing
msa totals like vkt and vtt from trip level data is to multiply sample averages by population
estimates. With the sample that we use however, this simple multiplication would lead to biased
estimates, because of the way in which we removed outliers.
The sample of trips we use consists of all trips by privately owned vehicle entered by a driver.
For distance, duration, and speed, we identify the 0.5% of trips with the lowest value and the 0.5%
of trips with the largest value and we eliminate all trips by an individual who entered any of these
trips. We remove individuals instead of trips because we want to match population totals using
sample averages at the individual level. Including individuals with an incomplete trip schedule
would bias our estimated averages downwards. However, before removing the individuals who
entered a trip with an extreme value, we compute the share of individuals driving at least one trip
by privately owned vehicle. We then multiply this share by msa population to obtain an estimate
of the total number of people, in each msa, who drive at least one trips by privately owned vehicle.
To obtain an estimate of vtt and vkt, we just take the average duration and distance traveled from
40
the clean sample of privately owned vehicle drivers and scale it up by a factor such that the sample
size matches our estimate of the population driving at least one trip by privately owned vehicle.
As an example, suppose that in a given msa, the nhts contains 5 individuals driving at least one
trip by privately owned vehicle, out of 10 individuals in our sample for that msa. If msa population
is 100, then our estimate of the number of individuals driving at least one trip by privately owned
vehicle in this msa is (5/10) × 100 = 50. If, for the individuals who remain in the sample after
cleaning, the average distance driven (distance driven for an individual is the sum of the distance
of each trip by privately owned vehicle for which they are the driver) is 20 kilometers, then our
estimate of vkt in this msa is 50 × 20 = 1000 vehicle kilometers traveled.
hpms data (road infrastructure): To estimate our travel production function, we rely on the
Highway Performance Monitoring System (hpms) data for 1995, 1996, 2001, 2002, and 2008. These
data are collected and maintained by the us Federal Highway Administration in cooperation with
many sub-national government agencies. Documentation is available in several reports from the
Federal Highway Adminstration (dot, 2003a, 2003b, and 2005). See also Duranton and Turner
(2011).
For the interstate highway system, the hpms records number of lanes, length, average annual
daily traffic (aadt), and county. By construction, road segments do not cross county borders.
For segments in urbanized areas, the hpms also provides an urbanized area code. Since msas are
county based units, these data allow us to calculate vkt for the urbanized and non urbanized area
interstate systems by msa.
Population and employment data: Population data for 1995-1996, 2001-2002, and 2008-2009 is
obtained from annual population estimates provided by the us census for these years. These
estimates are themselves based on interpolations and extrapolations of population counts made
by the us census. In some regressions we also use population data dating back to 1920, the first
census year which allows us to retain our samples of msas. We also use employment data from
the County Business Patterns to build two variables for our exploration of the determinants of
speed. The first is that of manufacturing employment. The second is an exogenous measure of
msa employment growth which interacts the sectoral composition of economic activity in an msa
in 1980 with the national growth of these sectors between 1980 and 2000.
41
Climate: We use two measures of temperature in us msas taken from the data used by Burchfield,
Overman, Puga, and Turner (2006).
Urban form: We have available the data underlying Burchfield et al. (2006). These data provide
fine scale employment data from 1994 zipcode business patterns and from 1990 tract level census
data: for every 990 meter × 990 meter cell in a regular grid covering the whole of the continental us,
these data report imputed 1990 population and 1994 employment. These data allow us to calculate
the measures of urban form used in the first three columns of table 6; employment centrality,
population centrality, and employment-residence mismatch.
The population centrality measure reports the largest share of population that occurs in any
ring of radius 20 kilometers whose center lies in the msa. The employment centrality measure is
identical, but is based on employment rather than population.
The mismatch variable provides an aggregate measure of the extent to which people do not
live where jobs are (though not of the extent to which people do not live where their jobs are).
Specifically, let ei be employment in cell i and pi be population. Our mismatch measure is
∑i∈msaj | pi − αei |
∑i∈msaj pi
,
where α is the inverse share of employment in total population α ∑i∈msaj ei ≡ ∑i∈msaj pi . Since
we are normalizing by population, this is a per capita measure of mismatch.
Instruments for contemporary interstate highways: Our measures of the 1947 interstate highway
plan and the 1898 railroad network are taken from Duranton and Turner (2011) and are documented there. Further discussion of the 1947 highway plan is available in Baum-Snow (2007),
Michaels (2008), and Duranton and Turner (2012).
Texas Transportation Institute travel time indices: Until 2009 (using 2008 data), the annual tti
travel time indices were constructed using counts of vehicles on interstate highways and major
urban roads from the average annual daily traffic (aadt) item measured in the hmps ‘Sample’ data.
More specifically, the tti methodology subjected the aadt variable to a series of transformations
using external information and turned it into a measure of speed. This measure of speed was
then ‘operationally’ adjusted for several factors (e.g., the existence of a ramp metering system to
access interstate highways) to obtain a final measure of speed by city. These quantities were then
42
compared to a measure of free flow traffic to infer a travel cost index by city and their travel cost
index for the us.
In 2010 (to exploit 2009 data), the tti paired with inrix, a leading provider of traffic information,
directions, and driver services. Real speed data is now measured using information provided by
location devices from vehicles operated by various fleet operators and by the smart phones of
voluntary individuals for a subsample of segments of roads covered by the hpms ‘Sample’ data.
Importantly, the tti data cover only urbanized areas. This implies that areas for which the tti
computes its index are smaller than the msas that we use. This said, the ‘urbanized’ part of msas
will host the vast majority of their residents and jobs. In order to compare our msa based index
with tti, we merged several tti urbanized areas to approximate msas more closely. To do this,
we weighted urbanized areas by their population. The full list of merged tti urbanized areas
is: Washington dc and Baltimore, San Francisco-Oakland and San Jose, Cleveland and Akron,
Los Angeles and Riverside-San Bernardino, Denver and Boulder, Greensboro and Winston-Salem,
Boston and Worcester. Finally, for Fort Myer-Cape Corral msa, the only tti data point is for Cape
Corral and for Norfolk-Virginia Beach-Newport News msa, the only tti data point is for Virginia
Beach. Overall we can match 47 of the 50 largest msas and 71 of the 100 largest using data for the
90 urban areas for which the tti reports an index for 2008.
Appendix B. Robustness tests for determinants of speed
Table 8 confirms our findings using different samples of msas, years of data, and variables. In
column 1 we duplicate our preferred estimation of column 6 of table 5 using only the 50 largest
msas to find virtually the same results (but a higher R2 given the greater precision of our index
in larger msas). In columns 2 and 3, we also duplicate our preferred regression from table 5 but
use 100 msas for 2001 and 1995, respectively. While the results for 2001 are virtually the same
as those for 2008, the coefficient on lanes for 1995 is insignificant and the R2 is much lower. In
columns 4 and 5, we use a log speed index computed from the 2008 and 2009 tti travel cost indices,
respectively, as dependent variables. The results for the 2008 tti index are close to those of our
preferred estimation. With the 2009 tti index, the coefficient on lanes is small and insignificant.
Column 6 substitutes population for vtt finds results similar to the other specifications. In column
7, we use log interstate highway lane kilometers as a measure of roads. Excluding smaller roads
43
Table 8: The determinants of speed, alternative years, samples, and variables
log lane (total)
(1)
SIV 2
2008
(2)
SIV 2
2001
0.11a
0.098a
(3)
SIV 2
1995
(4)
(5)
TTI 2008 TTI 2009
2008
2008
(6)
SIV 2
2008
0.052
0.029 0.085a
(0.039) (0.031) (0.044) (0.022) (0.023) (0.032)
0.067a 0.066a
(0.014) (0.014)
0.052c
(0.029)
a
-0.11 -0.15a
(0.013) (0.032)
log lane (major urban roads)
-0.16a -0.15a -0.096b -0.18a -0.075a
(0.033) (0.030) (0.042) (0.019) (0.019)
log population
Observations
R2
(8)
SIV 2
2008
0.12a
log lane (interstate highways)
log VTT
(7)
SIV 2
2008
50
0.54
100
0.40
100
0.23
71
0.71
78
0.64
-0.13a
(0.031)
100
0.36
99
0.47
99
0.49
Notes: OLS regressions with a constant in all columns. Robust standard errors in parentheses. a, b, c:
significant at 1%, 5%, 10%.
leads to a smaller coefficient. Finally in column 8 we contol separately for log lane kilometers
of interstate highways and major urban roads. We find a slightly higher coefficient for interstate
highways than for major urban roads. Importantly, the sum of these two coefficients is very close
to the coefficient for both types of roads considered jointly in our preferred regression.
Table 9 further confirms our findings using alternative estimation techniques. As argued above,
vehicle travel time is expected to be determined simultaneously with travel speed. To deal with
this problem, in column 1 we instrument for vtt using population. As might be expected, population is a strong predictor of vtt. The estimated coefficient on vtt is −0.14, only marginally
higher than (and statistically undistinguishable from) its ols counterpart. One may worry that the
exclusion restriction associated with this regression is not satisfied since population in 2008 may
be correlated with traffic speed through variables other than roads and vtt. This worry may not
be as important as it seems. First, Duranton and Turner (2012) document that interstate highways
have only a modest effect on urban growth. Second, to explore this question further, in column 2
we duplicate the regression of column 1 but also control for population growth between 1980 and
2008. The results remain the same. To confirm this finding, in column 3 we use a more exogenous
proxy for urban growth, namely expected population growth between 1980 and 2000. This proxy is
44
Table 9: The determinants of speed, 100 MSAs in 2008 IV regressions
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
(8)
TSLS
TSLS
TSLS
TSLS
TSLS
TSLS
TSLS
TSLS
(9)
(10)
TSLS LEVPET
log lane
0.093a 0.085a 0.078b
(0.032) (0.032) (0.034)
log lane (IH)
0.083a 0.087a 0.086a 0.078a 0.082a 0.079a
(0.020) (0.020) (0.021) (0.020) (0.019) (0.020)
0.056c 0.049
0.042 0.033
(0.029) (0.030)
(0.029) (0.031)
-0.14a -0.13a -0.12a -0.12a -0.17a -0.16a -0.11a -0.15a -0.13a -0.11a
(0.030) (0.030) (0.032) (0.018) (0.035) (0.038) (0.017) (0.033) (0.037) (0.028)
log lane (MRU)
log VTT
Intrumented
log VTT
log lane (IH)
Instruments
log pop. 2008
log highways 1947
log railroads 1898
X
X
Controls
∆ 1980−2008 log pop.
E∆ 1980−2000 log pop.
log pop. 1950
log pop. 1920
Observations
100
Overid. p-value
First-stage stat.
345
X
X
0.10b
(0.046)
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
95
0.37
31.2
X
X
X
95
0.45
23.7
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
95
0.33
20.0
X
X
X
95
0.48
15.7
X
X
100
315
100
269
95
0.26
31.1
95
0.26
20.4
300
-
Notes: Regressions with a constant in all columns. Robust standard errors in parentheses. a, b, c: significant
at 1%, 5%, 10%. Dependent variables is − log SIV 2 in all columns.
computed by interacting the sectoral composition of employment in msas in 1980 and employment
growth for these sectors between 1980 and 2000.33 The results are still very close to the previous
estimates.34
In column 4, we turn to the simultaneous determination of roads and travel speed. Unfortunately, we do not know of any good exogenous predictor of lane kilometers of both interstate
highways and major urban roads. However, we can follow Duranton and Turner (2011, 2012) and
use the 1947 plan of interstate highways and a map of 1898 railroads to predict contemporaneous
33 This
variable is inspired by Bartik (1991) and further details about its construction can be found in Duranton and
Turner (2011).
34 Overall the finding of a slightly less negative effect of travel time on speed in tsls relative to ols after controlling
for population growth is consistent with higher travel speed having a modest positive effect on population.
45
lane kilometers of interstate highways in us msas. Appendix A provides further details about the
construction of these two instruments. As can be seen from the results, these two instruments
are good predictors of contemporaneous lane kilometers of interstate highways and pass the
appropriate overindentification test. The coefficient on lane kilometers of interstate highways
is 0.082. This is slightly above its corresponding ols estimate of 0.067 in column 7 of table 8.
In column 5, we estimate the same regression but add lane kilometers of major urban roads as
control. The sum of the two lane coefficients is 0.14, slightly above the sum of the corresponding
ols estimates of 0.12 (in column 8 of table 8). Again, our instruments could be correlated with
travel speed through the error term. Cities that received more railroads during the 19th century
or cities that were allocated more roads in 1947 may be different in systematic ways. In particular,
they were bigger at the time and thus may be spatially organised in a different way and may have
a different transportation network relative to more recent cities. In turn, that might affect travel
speed. To preclude these correlations, in column 6 we introduce 1920 population (the closest year
to 1898 for which we can get population estimates), 1950 population, and expected population
growth between 1980 and 2000 as before. Introducing these controls in column 6 changes close to
nothing to the estimates of column 6. The marginally significant coefficient on major urban roads
is now marginally insignificant.
In columns 7 to 9, we repeat the same strategy as in columns 4 to 6 but now instrument for
both lane kilometers of highways and vehicle travel time. The results remain the same as before.
Finally in column 10, we use a completely different instrumenting approach which makes use
of all three cross-sections of data (and changes in the roadway prior to 1995) and implement the
estimation technique for productivity suggested by Levinsohn and Petrin (2003). It is true that,
unlike firms, cities do not invest in roads in response to positive demand shocks to maximize profit
(be it only because roads are funded mainly by the federal government). Nonetheless we expect
road provision to respond to changes in travel conditions. While suggestive, our Levinsohn-Petrin
results are very close to our ols and tsls estimates.
46
Download