iacomelli, piccinno and villoresi 37 Climate Change, Sustainable Energy, and Caron Finance: The Kyoto Bond Aldo Iacomellia*, Emanuele Piccinno, Daniele Villoresi Rome University “La Sapienza” – CIRPS; REIL abstract The Kyoto Protocol requires a 5.2% reduction of greenhouse gas emissions from developed countries. This is an important starting point both to prevent climate change and to start to implement new Sustainable Energy policy for a Sustainable Economy. At the local level (from regions to cities) lower cost/risk energy portfolios can be developed by adjusting the conventional mix of energy sources and by including low cost Rational Use of Energy and Energy Efficiency tools, greater amounts of fixedcost Renewable Energies and by using the additional financial resources coming from carbon finance. The carbon market can increase investment in renewable energies. This paper proposes a new financial instrument called the Kyoto Bond. Kyoto Bonds would have the following characteristics: ● The capital collected would be invested in local projects that would help reach local energetic policy targets, and allow investors to invest their capital in tangible and controlled operations; ● The performance of Kyoto Bonds has two different natures: ➣ Financial performance: a fixed coupon bond with a lower percentage performance than other over-the-counter instruments; ➣ Non-financial performance: the increase of social and environmental benefits; ● Double parallel accounting showing the real value of non-financial performance that, summed to fixed earning, is higher than market medium performance. ● The implementation of energy policies at the local level is more costeffective and reliable than generalized and unrealistic energy policies. * Corresponding author Tel.: +390654889206; fax: +390586213321, e-mail address: aldo.iacomelli@ uniroma1.it (A. Iacomelli). 38 from debate to design: a report on the work of the reil network 2007-08 Keywords: oil depletion, economy and environment, sustainable development, Kyoto bond, energy commodity. 1. introduction The “Fourth Assessment Report” (FAR) of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) reaffirms that both past and future anthropogenic carbon dioxide (CO2) emissions are a source of danger for the climate system. Figure 1 Global-average radiative forcing (RF) estimates and ranges in 2005 for anthropogenic carbon dioxide (CO2), methane (CH4), nitrous oxide (N2O) and other important agents and mechanisms. (source: IPCC FAR 2007) It is clear that from now onwards the supply of energy will need to be provided by a wider rational use of energy. This includes demand-side management policies, energy efficiency, use of renewable energies, hydrogen technologies, and highly efficient clean technologies. The Rational Use of Energy also needs to include strong policies and measures towards an exit strategy to oil. Policy makers should seriously consider the issues of implementation of Rational Use of Energy, renewable energy targets, and renewable energy portfolio standards. This is necessary both to comply with the Kyoto Protocol and to achieve some level of independence from fossil fuels. In addition, society needs to resist the belief that renewable energy adoption in the energy source mix increases overall generating costs because renewable energy seems to be “more expensive” on a stand alone basis. yale school of forestry & environmental studies iacomelli, piccinno and villoresi Figure 2 Power sector CO2 emissions by country 1990-2030 (Source IEA) At local levels (from regions to cities) lower cost/risk energy portfolios can be developed by adjusting the conventional energy mix and by including low cost Rational Use of Energy and energy efficiency tools, greater amounts of fixed-cost renewables, and using the additionality coming from carbon finance. Adding low cost Rational Use of Energy and energy efficiency tools and fixed-cost generating technologies to a fossil fuel generating portfolio serves to lower overall energy generating costs and risks. Policy makers should consider the additional income and benefits (economical and environmental) of market tools from Tradable Renewable Energy Certificates (TRECs), the “Kyoto Bond” proposed in this paper, or Certified Emission Reductions. 2. the johannesburg milestone: energy for local development The World Summit on Sustainable Development (WSSD) in Johannesburg strongly reaffirmed the commitment to the Rio principles, the full implementation of Agenda 21 and the Programme for the Further Implementation of Agenda 21, and also committed the member nations to achieving the internationally agreed development goals, including those contained in the United Nations Millennium Declaration through the “Plan of implementation.” To this end, concrete actions and measures are needed at all levels along with enhanced international cooperation, all taking into account the principle of common but differentiated responsibilities as set out in Principle 7 of the Rio Declaration on Environment and Development. There are three components to sustainable development. These interdependent and mutually reinforcing pillars of sustainable development are: ● economic development; ● social development; and ● environmental protection. yale school of forestry & environmental studies 39 40 from debate to design: a report on the work of the reil network 2007-08 Poverty eradication, changing unsustainable patterns of production and consumption, and protecting and managing the natural resource base of economic and social development are overarching objectives of, and essential requirements for, sustainable development. The main pillar of local development is energy supply and management which promotes economic development. At WSSD in Johannesburg the nations weren’t able to reach an agreement about targets and deadlines for actions needed to prevent climate change and to avoid energy shocks. Nevertheless, one outcome of Johannesburg is to increase the proportion of renewable energy sources in the total global energy supply, recognizing the roles of national and voluntary regional targets and initiatives. In addition, they agreed on the importance developing and utilizing indigenous energy sources and infrastructures and promoting rural community participation, in order to develop and utilize renewable energy technologies while finding simple and local solutions. The local dimension is key to implementing on-the-ground solutions and to facilitating access to energy as a poverty eradication measure. Actions at all levels should include: ● improving access to reliable, affordable, economically viable, socially acceptable and environmentally sound energy services and resources; ● enhancing rural electrification and decentralizing energy systems; ● increasing use of renewables; ● enhancing energy efficiency; ● capacity-building; ● financial and innovative financing mechanisms; ● technological assistance; ● improving access to modern biomass technologies and fuelwood sources and supplies for local community in developing countries; ● developing national energy policies and regulatory frameworks and implementing them at the local level; ● creating the necessary economic, social and institutional conditions in the energy sector to improve access to reliable, affordable, economically viable, socially acceptable and environmentally sound energy services; ● promoting public-private partnerships. Technology transfer must be realized in a mutually agreed upon way between the developed and developing countries. Actions should include: ● developing domestic programmes for energy efficiency; ● providing environmentally sound technology transfer; ● eliminating barriers to the diffusion of environmentally sound technologies; ● developing capacity-building at national and regional levels; yale school of forestry & environmental studies iacomelli, piccinno and villoresi ● developing and disseminating alternative energy technologies with the goal of giving a greater share of the energy mix to renewable energies technologies; ● promoting Best Available Technologies and Best Environmental Practice in the energy sector; ● promoting research programmes for further development in energy technology; ● providing financial assistance to developing countries; ● involving the private sector in the energy field; ● developing policies that improve transparency and information about energy markets and services; ● mobilizing adequate financial instruments and resources. The international community should develop policies and measures to reduce market distortions and promote energy systems compatible with sustainable development. This can be done through the use of improved market signals and by removing market distortions, including restructuring taxation and phasing out harmful subsidies, especially subsidies to fossil fuels, large hydro and nuclear. To this end, action is needed for the inclusion of externalities in energy costs. Externalities that need to be taken into account include the environmental and social impacts and related costs of energy generation and uses. 3. stopping the growth of greenhouse gas emissions with the rational use of energy and new energy services and sources Governments should use several instruments to choose and support preferable energy technologies or innovative energy products such as: ● fiscal measures; ● policies and guidelines; ● information, labelling, voluntary agreements, other programs of assistance and support; ● eesearch and development of new technologies; and ● energy commodity and financial energy related tools such as the Kyoto Bond. Energy policy measures should focus on demand side management tools, maximizing the amount of energy produced by renewable sources and on minimizing the costs of production of energy from renewable sources. One way to support preferable energy technologies and innovative energy products is by using price instruments, for renewable energy sources to try to create a cost competitive supply. For this purpose, a gross remuneration is assured to the producers, with a guaranteed fixed price that is higher than the price of energy from yale school of forestry & environmental studies 41 from debate to design: a report on the work of the reil network 2007-08 conventional sources. Thus, the differential revenue is an incentive to open the market, from the supply side, and to the removal of entry barriers. After fixing the unit price and after necessary fluctuations, the quantity produced at that fixed price will be freely defined and stabilized with time by the market. With quantity instruments, on the other hand, it is the amount of energy produced that is fixed, leaving the price floating to set the level of production. Auctions are then used to select producers according to lower costs. The difference between the price instruments and the quantity instruments is the difference between price and costs. In evaluating the two options, it is necessary to distinguish between short term and long term price and costs. In the short term, the auction mechanism will lead to lower production costs for energy from renewable sources and therefore is more efficient. Also, in the short term, the quantity mechanism will lead to an extra price for the community, an extra price that should not be considered different from a public investment in private research: the aim is to recover that investment, achieve a growing technical efficiency and, therefore, minimize costs in the future. In the long term the guaranteed price mechanism may result in the re-investment of the differential revenues, in technology research the results of which can be useful to all producers and which will gradually lead to lower costs. (Figure 3) Figure 3 PV learning curves forecast on global scale 10 Learning factor 20% Learning factor 15% -------- €/Wp 42 1 Year 2002 1330 MWp Year 2010 55000 MWp Year 2020 225000 MWp Year 2030 1250000 MWp 0,1 1 10 00 1 000 GWp cumulative The first phase costs of a new technology tend to remain inflexible or only slightly decreasing. In Italy the PV “feed in tariff ” system is stimulating a rapid growth market. This has already happened in Germany, Spain, and France, with small sized distributed generation plants (from 1 – 20 kW up to 200 kW). This rapid market growth has resulted in larger generation and decreased energy prices. (Figure 4) yale school of forestry & environmental studies iacomelli, piccinno and villoresi Figure 4 PV learning curves forecast in Italy with the new law on “Feed in tariffs” Learning factor 20% 10 € /Wp Learning factor 15% ------ 1 Year 2005 32 MWp (100 MWp authorized with “feed in tariffs”) Year 2010 750 MWp with “feed in tariffs” Year 2020 3.500 MWp with “feed in tariffs” Year 2030 12.500 MWp with market mechanism Year 2040 27.500 MWp with market mechanism 0,1 1 10 1000 GWp cumulative in Italy From the moment of market creation of preferable energy technologies and innovative energy products, prices should be fixed by the pioneer producers at a lower level than the initial actual costs, because these costs are normally so high that they would exclude every approach to the market. For example, in the case of energy efficiency, the market mechanism entails preferences for products with greater efficiency and marginalizes the poorest products. The transformation of energy products markets will lead to the development of better technologies and deeper diffusion of new technologies, if compared with the starting point. New technologies need to be supported with success through the different stages of the innovation process. Public support should be sought throughout the entire process, through all the different phases. At the same time, technologies and techniques already existing today will improve performance and reduce costs. Innovative business strategies could facilitate the transformation of the energy market. In a very simple way, until not long ago, the core business of a utility was selling energy to domestic and industrial clients. The key factor to success was the price of electricity. In fact, within a regulated market, any transformation of the market itself was practically impossible. The deregulation of electricity and gas is increasing market competition. Looking at the most advanced experiences in northern Europe (Nordic pool), the price of electricity at first decreased, almost as if the price itself was the only competitive factor. In general, those companies with the most competitive prices and the lowest costs will prevail in the market. But, without low-cost electricity, how can an energy company survive in the market in the long term? A business does not only sell a product or a technology, but is something that involves the customers and its distribution channels. It is not only a question of new technologies, but a new way of offering products and services. Utilities can benefit the market if they are able to be innovative. Where does the money go in the cycle of energy “value”? The deregulation of the utility business has started. Previously, when production, transmission and yale school of forestry & environmental studies 43 44 from debate to design: a report on the work of the reil network 2007-08 Figure 5 Technology push and market pull through the incentives support. Government Policy Interventions Market Pull Business Academia R&D Demonstration Supported Commercommercial cial Pre-commercial Consumers Product/Technology Push Investments Investors distribution were in the same hands, consumers purchased energy from energy producers. After deregulation of the utility monopoly in Europe, frequently consumers purchase electricity from local distributors. In the future, profits could be realized by selling energy services to consumers using carbon finance tools. This will happen when consumers have the ability to choose between distribution options. Table 1 Estimation of potential employers in energy sector by different source for a TWh of production. Source Oil Oil Off-Shore Natural Gas Coal Nuclear Wood Hydro Mini – hydro Wind PV Ethanol (from biomass) Workers (workers-year) (TWh) 260 265 250 370 75 1000 250 120 918 7.600 4.000 The transition towards sustainable energy for a sustainable economy will be dominated by gas and coal, but, since the transition from one energy system to another takes decades, the foundation of a future system needs to be built now. Therefore, a full application of the Kyoto Protocol and for the European Union set of laws, including the Emission Trading Scheme Directive 87/2003 is imperative, along yale school of forestry & environmental studies iacomelli, piccinno and villoresi with a strong political shove, investments to direct technology innovation, transformation of the energy market, and moves toward rational uses of energy and renewables. These innovations will have the added benefit of employment possibilities, as shown in Table 1. 4. carbon finance at the local level The Kyoto Protocol is a framework for testing programs, rules, measures and market instruments for reaching emission reduction commitments without compromising energy supply security, the competitiveness of industrial systems and economic growth. The Kyoto Protocol offers the opportunity to promote the integration of environmental and energy policies, provided that the flexible elements and market instruments under the Kyoto Protocol are fully taken into account and used. Under the Kyoto Protocol developed countries can achieve their emission reduction targets mainly with domestic measures. In 1997 the Kyoto Protocol developed mandatory targets and International Emission Trading (IET) options. To attract additional financial resources for CO2 emissions reductions, the Kyoto Protocol created joined programmes with economies in transition (Joint Implementation), or with developing countries (Clean Development Mechanism). In doing so, the Kyoto Protocol has integrated environmental objectives and economic requirements in an innovative manner. To reduce global CO2 emissions and the consumption of fossil fuels, IET, Joint Implementation and Clean Development Mechanism projects with high levels of energy efficiency and renewable energy components generate lower marginal costs than projects that the most developed countries would need to implement to reach the same targets on the internal market. The most recent studies estimate the marginal cost for a one-tonne reduction of CO2 at about €10-18 in the European Union, and about €2-4 in developing countries. The European Union Emission Trading System Directive implementation has pushed the price of one tonne of CO2 up to €23 in March 2008 within the EU market and will stimulate the greenhouse gas commodity market worldwide. It has been estimated that the revenue from carbon finance from the years 2008 – 2012 will be 110-150 billion Euros per year of additional capital. The worldwide investment for primary energy will be about six trillion Euros (950 billion in China, 800 billion in North America, 650 billion in the EU) by 2018. Most of projected carbon finance transactions are project-based, and the emissions reduction credits are intended either for Kyoto Protocol or other greenhouse gas reduction schemes (Figure 6). Buyers have various motives in engaging in transactions in the global carbon market: i. immediate compliance in the national markets, where buyers seek to comply with existing legislative obligations and constraints; yale school of forestry & environmental studies 45 46 from debate to design: a report on the work of the reil network 2007-08 ii. Kyoto pre-compliance where buyers expect the project to be registered under either JI or CDM; iii. voluntary compliance where buyers aim to use the emission reductions to meet part of their voluntary targets; iv. retail schemes where buyers wish to be climate-neutral in order to demonstrate their social responsibility or promote particular brand. Other objectives might include: i. learning by doing; ii. experimenting with diverse contract structures; iii. influencing policy; iv. broadening the envelope of flexibility; v. public relations; vi. goodwill. The fragmented nature of the global carbon market generates different prices for emissions reductions. Allowance markets generate high emission reduction prices since the delivery risks are believed to be minimal. Although Joint Implementation and the Clean Development Mechanism are both project-based, the World Bank’s Prototype Carbon Fund pays higher prices for Emission Reduction Units since Joint Implementation is supported by Host Country Agreements and Assigned Amount Units, which reduces buyer’s exposure to risks. In order to achieve global greenhouse gas reductions, it is necessary to implement real projects on the ground. Using tradable certificates such as the proposed Kyoto Bond would foster the use of renewable energy and energy efficiency at the local level. 5. fostering the use of renewable energies and energy at the local level Government support schemes for renewable energies are not new in the EU, especially at national levels. After the first schemes were developed in Portugal (1988), the Netherlands (1989) and Germany (1990), all member countries implemented support mechanisms. At the European level, the regulatory framework was established in 2003. Under the SAVE program, the European Commission financed setting up regional and local energy management agencies. The role of these agencies is to support the strengthening of renewable energy markets. They have not been able to compete with traditional sources of energy; many of them are short of funds to implement programs in an effective manner. Energy agencies need capital and long term investments to implement programmes and create profits. Citizens often don’t realize how these agencies are the means to reach a greater level of benefits when the programs are well implemented and efficaciously executed. Agencies like the SAVE program cannot reach the entire yale school of forestry & environmental studies CDM CERs New Zealand Switzerland UK JI -E RU s E ha RU ss s r K m ho or YO o u V TO niz ld b ER s e BO w e N ith D Can trade ERUs or AAUs amongst each each other other amongst Annex I countries with a reduction target EU-25 bubble Portugal Italy Spain France Netherlands EU MSs Ireland CDM - CERs Brazil y CERs or VERs Other developing countries Egypt Non-Annex I countries; without a reduction target Syria China Morocco Developing countries – CDM projects CDM CERs Companies and consumer buying KYOTO BOND as CO2 reduction units and support local investment for sustainable development done to the Emitting Energy Agency on behalf of the Municipality E U -E T S 1 4 . 000 p la nts c a n tra d e E U e m is s io n a llo KYOTO BOND Voluntary market among different stakeholders integrated with the Kyoto Protocol Emission Trading and EU ETS. Trading among companies Japan Poland Latvia new EU MSs Norway Ukraine Canada Kyoto Protocol game 2008 – 2012 A us tra lia US A Russia E IT s Figure 6 KYOTO BOND in energy commodity trading systems (Kyoto scheme, EU ETS, Voluntary scheme) Kyoto Protocol game 1 (2008 – 2012 without US and Australia, but after 2012 US and Australia will join the Kyoto game 2 (with China and India with targets). (Source: elaboration from MEDREP IMET report 2006). iacomelli, piccinno and villoresi yale school of forestry & environmental studies 47 48 from debate to design: a report on the work of the reil network 2007-08 population and/or the Kyoto targets because they haven’t enough financial and technical support to generate enough benefits and projects. However, energy agencies could have a more important role if they could collect both public and private capital, operating as a public company with a wide shareholder base. In this way they could operate at the local level, supported by a local population of shareholders who would be the beneficiaries of their energy programs. Figure 7 Energy Agencies Structure Private Investors (Local Population) Public Investors € € € Implementation of energy and environmental policies Trader Energy Agencies Social and environmental benefit Activities E.S.Co. Information and diffusion of RES and EE technologies and best practce A company organized in this manner would result in obtaining social and environmental targets as well as monetary profits. Investments could be oriented to particular policy instruments that will spawn benefits and revenues over time. The strict connection with territory and local population is an important incentive to produce greater results in a more efficient manner. Investors realize two different benefits at the same time: economic, deriving from the return on investments, and social, deriving from the environmental benefits. With greater financial support, and with the necessity of making profits, energy agencies must assume a more important role in the energy market, both with an operating role as an energy savings company, and as a trader for all market based incentive mechanisms adopted to support rational use of energy, energy efficiency and renewable energy. 6. kyoto bond: economic rent, environmental benefits and citizens’ wellness In previous paragraphs, the authors support the importance of a wide shareholder base to develop policies and programs at the local level. In this way energy agencies could operate in energy markets and reach tangible results with environmental and social implications. yale school of forestry & environmental studies iacomelli, piccinno and villoresi 49 Private funding would be limited to investors at the local level who can realize the benefits created by the efficacious implementing of sustainable investments. This strict connection with investors’ wellness also suggests creating different financial instruments that can emphasize the relevance of the environmental and social effects rather than only financial results. These financial instruments would be defined as Kyoto Bonds and would have the following characteristics: ● The capital collected would be invested in local projects that would permit reaching the targets of local energy policies, thus giving investors the ability to invest their capital for tangible and controlled operations; ● The performance of Kyoto Bonds has two different natures: ➣ Financial performance: a fixed coupon bond with a lower percentage performance than other over-the-counter instruments; ➣ Non-financial performance: the increase of social and environmental benefits. ● Double parallel accounting showing the real value of non-financial performance that, summed to fixed earnings, is higher than market medium performance; ● Non-financial performance would be benchmarked with European or national targets of emission reduction derived from the Kyoto agreement. The economic valuation of non-economic goods, such as social wellness and environment, is difficult. It is important to have a transparent instrument that will highlight the non-financial performance of Kyoto Bonds, which will help ensure the success of such innovative financial products. The Environmental Performance Index1 (EPI) is an interesting instrument that would be useful for Kyoto Bond valuation. The index takes into consideration all elements connected with sustainability to point out a value for the environmental Figure 8 Kyoto Bond KYOTO BOND Corporate Bond Financial performance Environmental and social extra profit Kyoto National Emission Reduction Target Performance yale school of forestry & environmental studies 1 “2008 ENVIRONMENTAL PERFORMANCE INDEX” Yale Center for Environmental Law & Policy – Yale University, Center for International Earth Science Information Network (CIESIN) – Columbia University 50 from debate to design: a report on the work of the reil network 2007-08 performance of countries, considering two macro objectives (environmental health and ecosystem vitality) through 25 environmental indicators divided into 8 different policy categories. The relevance of the EPI is that it provides a comparison of the environmental performance of policies in different countries, and provides a ranking which shows the distance of each country from a “perfect sustainability” target chosen by the EPI working group. For Kyoto Bond applications, the climate change policy category is key, in which the following indicator parameters are monitored: ● emissions/capita; ● emissions/electricity generated; ● industrial carbon intensity. Inside the EPI framework, the climate change policy category accounts for 25 percent of the EPI value, and considers aggregated data at national levels for macro categories. The Kyoto Bond valuation would require the disaggregation of data at the local level, creating a Local Environmental Performance Index (LEPI) framework that would consider different categories and data. There is ongoing research to build a LEPI that will emphasize the environmental performance of Kyoto Bond investments in order to give a monetary evaluation of the environmental and social performance of Kyoto Bond investments. 7. conclusion The implementation of energy policies at the local level is more cost-effective and reliable than generalized and unrealistic energy policies. In this paper the authors suggest a different method, one that would increase the efficiency of programs and derive environmental and social benefits: the Kyoto Bond. For success, the Kyoto Bond requires the following: 1. involvement of public local investors; 2. concrete programmes and efficient actuation; 3. environmental and social benefits valued by the local population. The Kyoto Bond would mix public and private investors, focusing the beneficial effects of renewable energy and energy efficiency programs by offering an innovative financial instrument that would give great transparency to the results of environmental and energy policy. yale school of forestry & environmental studies iacomelli, piccinno and villoresi references Achla M., Mozumdera, P., 2004. Gains from an integrated market for tradable renewable energy credits. Ecological Economics. 49, 259–272. Adriaanse et altri (1997), “Resource flows: the material basis of industrial economies,” Wuppertal Institute, The Hague. Alberti M., (1998), “Città, spazio ecologico e sostenibilità,” Equilibri – rivista per lo sviluppo sostenibile, n°1, aprile 1998, Il Mulino/Fondazione ENI Enrico Mattei, Milano. Autorità per l’energia elettrica e il gas, 2004. Annual report on regulatory activities and the state of services. (URL: http://www.autoritaenergia.it). Autorità per l’energia elettrica e il gas, 2005. Annual report on regulatory activities and the state of services. (URL: http://www.autoritaenergia.it). ANPA, 2000, “Serie storiche delle emissioni in atmosfera in Italia.” ANPA, Mario Contaldi, Riccardo De Lauretis, Daniela Romano “Analisi delle emissioni nazionali dei gas serra dal 1980 al 1998.” Awerbuch Shimon, Ph.D., 2004, Towards A Finance-Oriented Valuation of Conventional and Renewable Energy Sources in Ireland, prepared for Sustainable Energy Ireland, Perspective from Abroad Series, Tyndall Centre Visiting Fellow SPRU – University of Sussex, UK, June. Awerbuch Shimon, Ph.D., 2000, Investing in Photovoltaic: Risk, Accounting and the Value of New Technology, in Energy Policy, Special Issue, Vol. 28, No. 14, November. Awerbuch Shimon, Ph.D., 2000a, Getting It Right: The Real Cost Impacts of a Renewables Portfolio Standard, in Public Utilities Fortnightly, Interstate Renewable Council, 15 February. Awerbuch Shimon, Ph.D., Martin Berger, (2003) Energy Security and Diversity in the EU: A Mean-Variance Portfolio Approach, IEA Report Number EET/2003/03, Paris: February, in: http://library.iea.org/dbtw-wpd/textbase/papers/2003/port.pdf. Bode, S., 2006. Multi-period emissions trading in the electricity sector winners and losers. Energy Policy. 34, 680-691. Barcelona Diputaciò – Area di Medio Ambiente (Xarxa) (1999), “Proposta de 50 indicadors de sostenibilitad,” Barcelona. Chaureya, A., Ranganathana, M., Mohantyb, P., 2004. Electricity access for geographically disadvantaged rural communities – technology and policy insights. Energy Policy 32, Elsevier. yale school of forestry & environmental studies 51 52 from debate to design: a report on the work of the reil network 2007-08 Commisssion of the European Communities (1998), “Sustainable Urban development in the European Union: a framework for action” DGXI, Brussels. D’Angelo E., Perrella G., 1999, “Energy efficiency in Italy” (1970-1996). Final Report of ‘Cross country comparison on energy efficiency indicators’ – Phase IV, 1999 Paris ADEME. Drennen, T.E., Erickson J.D., Chapman D., 1996. Solar power and climate change policy in developing countries. Energy Policy 24, Elsevier. European Environmental Agency (EEA) (1997), “Feasibility study on the production of an yearly EEA Indicator report (2 draft, 13/10/1997),” Copenhagen. EEA (1996), “Guidelines for data collection for Dobris,” Copenhagen. Eurostat (1997), “Indicateurs de developpment durable,” Luxemburg. Eurostat (1999) “Towards environmental pressure indicators for EU.” Official publications for the EC, Benelux. European Sustainable Cities and Towns campaign, DGXI EU, WHO, Health Cities Network, (1997), “City planning for health and sustainable development,” Copenhagen. Geller, H., Harrington, P., Rosenfeld, A., 2006. Policies for increasing energy efficiency: Thirty years of experience in OECD countries. Energy Policy. 34, 556-573. IEA Energy Outlook 2002. International Energy Agency, Paris, 2002. IEA Energy and Poverty 2002. Special Publication for Johannesburg Summit International Energy Agency, Paris, 2002. IEA Energy Balances of non-OECD Countries 2001. International Energy Agency, 2002. IEA Energy Balances of OECD Countries 2001. International Energy Agency, 2002. IEA, Beyond Kyoto: Next Steps, IEA/GB(2003)5. IEA, Issues for Discussion at the IEA Meeting of the Governing Board at Ministerial Level, Background Papers, 28-29 April 2003, Paris, France. IEA Workshop, Toward Hydrogen, Paris, 3 March 2003. IEA (2002), Cool Appliances: Appliance Strategies for Energy Efficient Homes, Paris, France. IEA (2002), Energy Policies of IEA Countries: 2002 Review, Paris, France. yale school of forestry & environmental studies iacomelli, piccinno and villoresi IEA/Standing Group on Long-Term Co-operation, Longer Term Energy and Environment Scenarios: Three Exploratory Scenarios to 2050, Note by the Secretariat, 4-5 December, 2002. IEA, Technology Options: CO2 Capture and Storage Technologies, Note by the Secretariat, 22 October 2002, IEA/GB(2002)34. IEA (2002), Towards Solutions: Sustainable Development in the Energy Sector, Paris, France. IEA Working Party on Fossil Fuels, Solutions for the 21st Century: Zero Emissions Technologies for Fossil Fuels, Technology Status Report, May 2002. IEA (2002), World Energy Outlook 2002, Paris, France. IEA (2001), International Emission Trading: from Concept to Reality, Paris, France. IEA (2001), World Energy Outlook 2001: Assessing Today’s Supplies to Fuel Tomorrow’s Growth, Paris, France. IEA (2000), World Energy Outlook 2000, Paris, France. Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change-WGIII (2000), Special Report on Emission Scenarios, Cambridge University Press. Nijkamp, P., Patuellia, R., Pelsb, E., 2005. Environmental tax reform and the double dividend: A meta-analytical performance assessment. Ecological Economics. 55, 564–583. Pearce, D., Moran, D., 1994. The Economic Value of Biodiversity. Earthscan Publications Ltd. Ringel, M., 2006. Fostering the use of renewable energies in the European Union: the race between feed-in tariffs and green certificates. Renewable Energy. 31, 1–17. Rousse, O., 2008. Environmental and economic benefits resulting from citizens’ participation in CO2 emissions trading: An efficient alternative solution to the voluntary compensation of CO2 emissions. Energy Policy 36, Elsevier. Yale Center for Environmental Law & Policy - Yale University, Center for International Earth Science Information Network (CIESIN) - Columbia University. 2008. 2008 Environmental Performance Index. http://epi.yale.edu/Home. yale school of forestry & environmental studies 53