SØK460/ECON460 Finance Theory, Diderik Lund, 2 September 2002 The “mean-variance” approach Much of elementary finance theory assumes: Each individual only cares about the expected value (“the mean”) and the variance of wealth. • Very convenient for making more precise theories. • Little doubt that expected value is important. • Variance is one (but only one) measure of uncertainty. • Restrictive: Quite possible that actual people care about other characteristics of random variables. • Three ways to underpin the assumption, two based on vN-M. • Mean-variance preferences always combined with risk aversion. Mean-variance versus vN-M expected utility • In general those who maximize E[U (W̃ )] care about the whole distribution of W̃ . • Will care about only mean and variance if those two characterize the whole distribution. • Will alternatively care about only mean and variance if U () is a quadratic function. The third way to underpin mean-var assumption • Perhaps things are so complicated that people resort to just considering mean and variance. (Whether they are vN-M people or not.) 1 SØK460/ECON460 Finance Theory, Diderik Lund, 2 September 2002 Mean-var preferences due to distribution • Assume that choices are always between random variables with one particular type (“class”) of probability distribution. • Could be, e.g., choice only between binomially distributed variables. (There are different binomial distributions, summarized in three parameters which uniquely define each one of them.) • Or, e.g., only between variables with a chi-square distribution. Or variables with normal distribution. Or variables with a lognormal distribution. • Some of these distributions, such as the normal distribution and the lognormal distribution, are characterized completely by two parameters, the mean and the variance. • If all possible choices belong to the same class, then the choice can be made on the basis of the parameters for each of the distributions. • Example: Would you prefer a normally distributed wealth with mean 1000 and variance 40000 or another normally distributed wealth with mean 500 and variance 10000? 2 SØK460/ECON460 Finance Theory, Diderik Lund, 2 September 2002 • If mean and variance characterize each alternative completely, then all one cares about is mean and variance. • Most convenient: Normal distribution, since sums of normally distributed variables are also normal. Most opportunity sets consist of a lot of alternative sums of variables. • Problem: Positive probability for negative outcomes. Share prices are never negative. 3 SØK460/ECON460 Finance Theory, Diderik Lund, 2 September 2002 Mean-var preferences due to quadratic U Assume U (w) ≡ −aw2 + bw + c where a > 0, b > 0, c are constants. With this U function: E[U (W̃ )] = −aE(W̃ 2) + bE(W̃ ) + c = −a{E(W̃ 2) − [E(W̃ )]2} − a[E(W̃ )]2 + bE(W̃ ) + c = −a var(W̃ ) − a[E(W̃ )]2 + bE(W̃ ) + c, which is a function only of mean and variance of W̃ . Problem: U function is decreasing for large values of W . Must choose a and b such that those large values have zero probability. Another problem: Increasing (absolute) risk aversion. 4 SØK460/ECON460 Finance Theory, Diderik Lund, 2 September 2002 Indifference curves in mean-stddev diagrams • If mean and √ variance are sufficient to determine choices, then mean and variance are also sufficient. • More practical to work with mean (µ) and standard deviation (σ) diagrams. • Common to put standard deviation on horizontal axis. • Will show that indifference curves are increasing and convex in (σ, µ) diagrams. • Consider normal distribution and quadratic U separately. • Indifference curves are contour curves of E[U (W̃ )]. • Total differentiation: 0 = dE[U (W̃ )] = ∂E[U (W̃ )] ∂E[U (W̃ )] dσ + dµ. ∂σ ∂µ 5 SØK460/ECON460 Finance Theory, Diderik Lund, 2 September 2002 Indifference curves from quadratic U Assume W < b/(2a) with certainty in order to have U 0(W ) > 0. E[U (W̃ )] = −aσ 2 − aµ2 + bµ + c. First-order derivatives: ∂E[U (W̃ )] ∂E[U (W̃ )] = −2aσ < 0, = −2aµ + b > 0, ∂σ ∂µ Thus the slope of the indifference curves, ∂E[U (W̃ )] dµ 2aσ = − ∂E[U∂σ(W̃ )] = , dσ −2aµ + b ∂µ is positive, and approaches 0 as σ → 0+. Second-order: ∂ 2E[U (W̃ )] ∂ 2E[U (W̃ )] ∂ 2E[U (W̃ )] = −2a < 0, = −2a < 0, = 0. ∂σ 2 ∂µ2 ∂µ∂σ The function is concave, thus it is also quasi-concave. 6 SØK460/ECON460 Finance Theory, Diderik Lund, 2 September 2002 Indifference curves from normally distributed W̃ √ 2 Let f (ε) ≡ (1/ 2π)e−ε /2, the std. normal density function. Let W = µ + σε, so that W̃ is N (µ, σ 2). Define expected utility as a function E[U (W̃ )] = V (µ, σ) = Z ∞ −∞ U (µ + σε)f (ε)dε. Slope of indifference curves: ∂V ∂σ − ∂V ∂µ = 0 −∞ U (µ + σε)εf (ε)dε . R∞ 0 (µ + σε)f (ε)dε U −∞ − R∞ Denominator always positive. Will show that integral in numerator is negative, so minus sign makes the whole fraction positive. Integration by parts: Observe f 0(ε) = −εf (ε). Thus: Z U 0(µ + σε)εf (ε)dε = −U 0(µ + σε)f (ε) + U 00(µ + σε)σf (ε)dε. Z First term on RHS vanishes in limit when ε → ±∞, so that Z ∞ U 0(µ + σε)εf (ε)dε = −∞ Z ∞ −∞ U 00(µ + σε)σf (ε)dε < 0. Another important observation: ∞ εf (ε)dε dµ −U 0(µ) −∞ = = 0. lim+ R∞ σ→0 dσ U 0(µ) −∞ f (ε)dε R 7 SØK460/ECON460 Finance Theory, Diderik Lund, 2 September 2002 To show concavity of V (): λV (µ1, σ1) + (1 − λ)V (µ2, σ2) = < Z ∞ −∞ Z ∞ −∞ [λU (µ1 + σ1ε) + (1 − λ)U (µ2 + σ2ε)]f (ε)dε U (λµ1 + λσ1ε + (1 − λ)µ2 + (1 − λ)σ2ε)f (ε)dε = V (λµ1 + (1 − λ)µ2, λσ1 + (1 − λ)σ2). The function is concave, thus it is also quasi-concave. 8 SØK460/ECON460 Finance Theory, Diderik Lund, 2 September 2002 Mean-variance portfolio choice • One individual, mean-var preferences. • Has a given wealth W0 to invest at t = 0. • Regards probability distribution of future (t = 1) values of securities as exogenous. (Values at t = 1 include payouts like dividends, interest.) • Today also: Regards security prices at t = 0 as exogenous. • Later: Include this individual in equilibrium model of competitive security market at t = 0. Notation: Investment of W0 in n securities: W0 = n X j=1 pj0Xj = n X j=1 Wj0. Value of this one period later: W̃ = n X j=1 = n X j=1 p̃j1Xj = n X j=1 W̃j = pj0(1 + r̃j )Xj = n X j=1 n X j=1 pj0 p̃j1 Xj pj0 Wj0(1 + r̃j ) n Wj0 X = W0 (1 + r̃j ) = W0 wj (1 + r̃j ) = W0(1 + r̃p). j=1 W0 j=1 (D&D (e.g., p. 93) use R for return on portfolio, here: rp.) Stochastic variables have a tilde, thus no subscript for state s. n X 9 SØK460/ECON460 Finance Theory, Diderik Lund, 2 September 2002 Mean-var preferences for rates of return W̃ = W0 n X j=1 1 + wj (1 + r̃j ) = W0 n X j=1 = W0 (1 + r̃p ). wj r̃j • r̃p is rate of return for investor’s portfolio. • This and next week: Each investor’s W0 fixed. • Then preferences well defined over r̃p, may forget about W0 for now. • Let µp ≡ E(r̃p) and σp ≡ var(r̃p). Then E(W̃ ) = W0(1 + E(r̃p)) = W0(1 + µp), var W̃ = W02 var(r̃p), r r var(W̃ ) = W0 var(r̃p) = W0σp. r Increasing, convex indifference curves in ( var(W̃ ), E(W̃ )) diagram imply increasing, convex indifference curves in (σp, µp) diagram. But: A change in W0 will in general change the shape of the latter kind of curves (“wealth effect”). 10 SØK460/ECON460 Finance Theory, Diderik Lund, 2 September 2002 Mean-var opportunity set, two risky assets Investor may construct (any) portfolio of (only) two risky assets. What is opportunity set in (σp, µp) diagram? W0 = W10 + W20 W10 W20 (1 + r̃1) + (1 + r̃2) W̃ = W10(1+ r̃1)+W20(1+ r̃2) = W0 W0 W0 = W0[a(1 + r̃1) + (1 − a)(1 + r̃2)] ≡ W0(1 + r̃p). For j = 1, 2, let µj ≡ E(r̃j ), σj2 ≡ var(r̃j ), and let σij ≡ cov(r̃1, r̃2). Then: µ − µ p 2 , µp = aµ1 + (1 − a)µ2 ⇒ a = µ1 − µ2 σp2 = a2σ12 + (1 − a)2σ22 + 2a(1 − a)σ12. Taken together: r σp = Aµ2p + Bµp + C, where σ12 + σ22 − 2σ12 A≡ , (µ1 − µ2)2 −2µ2σ12 − 2µ1σ22 + 2σ12(µ1 + µ2) B≡ , (µ1 − µ2)2 µ22σ12 + µ21σ22 − 2µ1µ2σ12 C≡ . (µ1 − µ2)2 11 SØK460/ECON460 Finance Theory, Diderik Lund, 2 September 2002 Opportunity set, two risky assets, contd. √ The function σ(µ) = Aµ2 + Bµ + C is called an hyperbola, the square root of a parabola. Both have minimum points at µ = −B 2A . 12 SØK460/ECON460 Finance Theory, Diderik Lund, 2 September 2002 Opportunity set, two risky assets, contd. r σ(µ) = Aµ2 + Bµ + C Asymptotes for hyperbola: √ B Aµ + √ , 2 A √ B µ → −∞ ⇒ σ → − Aµ − √ . 2 A Proof (of first part only): √ √ √ (σ(µ) − Aµ)(σ(µ) + Aµ) √ lim [σ(µ) − Aµ] = µ→∞ lim µ→∞ σ(µ) + Aµ µ→∞⇒σ→ Bµ + C (σ(µ))2 − Aµ2 √ √ = µ→∞ lim √ 2 = µ→∞ lim σ(µ) + Aµ Aµ + Bµ + C + Aµ = µ→∞ lim s B + Cµ A + Bµ + µC2 + and the result follows. 13 √ B = √ , A 2 A SØK460/ECON460 Finance Theory, Diderik Lund, 2 September 2002 Opportunity set, two risky assets, contd. • When a varies, the hyperbola is traced out. • a = 1 gives the point (σ1, µ1). • a = 0 gives the point (σ2, µ2). • Value of a at minimum point, f.o.c.: 0= dσ = 2aσ12 − 2(1 − a)σ22 + (2 − 4a)σ12 da gives σ22 − σ12 a= 2 ≡ amin. σ1 + σ22 − 2σ12 14