Climatic Change DOI 10.1007/s10584-015-1333-2 Allocation of global temperature change to consumers Jonas Karstensen & Glen P. Peters & Robbie M. Andrew Received: 13 August 2014 / Accepted: 13 January 2015 # Springer Science+Business Media Dordrecht 2015 Abstract Climate policy is generally concerned with the mitigation of well-mixed greenhouse gases, allocated to the country where the emissions occur, and with different emissions weighted together with the Global Warming Potential (GWP) using a 100 year time horizon. This perspective is not unique. Recent research has considered the inclusion of Short-Lived Climate Forcers (SCLFs), allocated emissions to the consumption of goods and services, and used alternative emissions metrics. Here, for the first time, we combine these alternative perspectives to explore the potential policy implications of three alternative framings: 1) using the Global Temperature change Potential (GTP) to directly link current emissions to temperature change, 2) including SLCFs that have both warming and cooling effects on climate, and 3) allocating emissions to consuming sectors and regions. Collectively, we use these three aspects to allocate the future temperature response to the consumption of goods and services in a given year. We show, in order of importance, that the method of allocating emissions to economic sectors is the most important, followed by the emission metric (including timehorizon), and then the mix of short-lived and well-mixed climate forcers. The consumption perspective reallocates emissions from electricity and manufacturing to service sectors, which suggests different policy options for demand and supply. The net effect of multiple pollutants and GTP significantly change the importance of the sectors compared to when only considering CO2 or when using the GWP. We argue that a focus on only one accounting system and framing in climate policy can potentially limit consideration of mitigation options to a reduced set of activities, and thereby missing significant opportunities for mitigation in other aspects. 1 Introduction Global climate change mitigation policies are usually framed around the Kyoto Protocol’s core concepts of territorial emissions accounting, mitigation of well-mixed greenhouse gases (WMGHGs), and integrated radiative forcing (via the Global Warming Potential, GWP). However, these three choices are far from unique. First, regional emissions can be accounted on an extraction, territorial, or consumption basis (Andrew et al. 2013; Davis et al. 2011), meaning that they are allocated to where the mining occurred, where the combustion Electronic supplementary material The online version of this article (doi:10.1007/s10584-015-1333-2) contains supplementary material, which is available to authorized users. J. Karstensen (*) : G. P. Peters : R. M. Andrew Center for International Climate and Environmental Research Oslo (CICERO), P.O. Box. 1129 Blindern, N-0318 Oslo, Norway e-mail: jonas.karstensen@cicero.oslo.no Climatic Change happened, or where the products where finally bought, respectively. These accounting schemes can additionally be integrated over time (cumulative) or normalized (e.g., per capita, per unit economic activity). Second, Short-Lived Climate Forcers (SLCFs) also cause both global warming and cooling, and have an important effect on the net temperature change (Stocker et al. 2013). Although recent focus on these gases has gained political momentum, such as in UNEP’s Climate and Clean Air Coalition to Reduce Short-Lived Climate Pollutants, they are often excluded from mitigation studies (e.g., in Life Cycle Assessment; (Peters et al. 2011b)) and are not part of the Kyoto protocol (except for CH4, which we treat as a WMGHGs). Third, there are a number of alternative emissions metrics (Aamaas et al. 2013b; Tanaka et al. 2010), some of which relate more directly to temperature (Shine et al. 2005) and are therefore potentially more consistent with current global negotiations, which have as their main goal keeping the global average temperature increase below 2 °C above pre-industrial levels (Major Economies Forum on Energy and Climate 2009; UNFCCC 2011a, b). We now give a brief background of each of these different framings. Accounting systems are human constructs (Davis and Caldeira 2010), and policy goals will determine which systems are appropriate. Climate policies have traditionally had a territorial accounting focus, built on existing processes to collect energy-consumption statistics and allocating CO2 emissions at the point in space where and time when it enters the atmosphere. Two key alternatives are consumption-based accounting, which allocates emissions to the point where goods and services are finally consumed (Davis and Caldeira 2010), and extraction-based accounting, which allocates emissions to the point where fossil fuels are extracted (Andrew et al. 2013). These three accounting systems are connected via trade, and several studies have demonstrated the increased linkages between global producers and consumers as international trade continues to grow rapidly (Andrew et al. 2013; Karstensen et al. 2013; Moran et al. 2013; Peters et al. 2011d; Wiebe et al. 2012). Under any accounting system, carbon leakage (emission increases in an unregulated region due to activities in a regulated region; (Peters 2010)) is a possibility when only a limited number of countries accept emission caps or an effective carbon price (Felder and Rutherford 1993; Peters and Hertwich 2008). Most research on extraction- or consumption-based accounting has focused on regional differences (comparisons of countries), with fewer studies focusing on sector differences (Hertwich and Peters 2009). Since mitigation practically occurs at a much deeper level (sectors, activities, etc.), it is important to elaborate on the differences in accounting at a more detailed level. With a focus on the climate forcing from sectoral emissions (Unger et al. 2010), the significant redistributions of sectoral impacts under a consumption perspective (Peters and Hertwich 2006) become increasingly relevant. Climate policies have almost exclusively focused on WMGHGs such as CO2, CH4, N2O, and synthetic gases as specified in the Kyoto Protocol. While CO2 remains the most important species to mitigate due to its strong radiative forcing, long-lived nature and large emissions (Solomon et al. 2010), complementary mitigation of SLCFs could help reduce near-term warming (Shindell et al. 2012) or delay the peak in temperature increases (Myhre et al. 2011). Some SLCFs have a cooling effect (e.g., SO2) and so their mitigation could lead to a warming (Berntsen and Fuglestvedt 2008; Unger et al. 2010). Recently, there has been increased focus on the climate and health benefits of reductions in pollutants (Chen et al. 2013), particularly for CH4 and black carbon (BC) (Shindell et al. 2012). Careful holistic analysis is required to ensure solving one problem does not exacerbate problems elsewhere. Most proposals for multi-pollutant climate policy require the effects of different climate forcers to be made comparable. This is generally implemented using an emission metric (Aamaas et al. 2013b; Fuglestvedt et al. 2003). The Kyoto Protocol uses the GWP with a 100-year time horizon, the choice of which has recently been labeled ‘inadvertent’ (Shine Climatic Change 2009). Yet, since 2010’s UNFCCC Conference of the Parties in Cancun, the overarching goal of climate negotiations has been framed explicitly in terms of temperature increase (UNFCCC 2011b), and thus a metric based on temperature, such as the Global Temperature change Potential (Shine et al. 2007), may be more suited to the cost-effectiveness framing of climate policy (Tol et al. 2012). In addition, the GWP places more weight on SLCFs (Shine et al. 2007) in the long run as it ‘remembers’ short-lived effects via integration, in contrast to temperature-based metrics, in which the contribution of short-lived pollutants decays over time (Peters et al. 2011a; Solomon et al. 2010). As a consequence, the use of the GTP may lead to alternative mitigation priorities. Here, we combine these three alternative framings of climate policy—consumption-based accounting, including SLCFs along with WMGHGs, and a temperature-based metric—to give consumption-based emission inventories measured in terms of temperature. We quantify how much the results change depending on the different perspectives. We use the framework to illustrate how alternative choices can change mitigation priorities, and to facilitate this we focus on both the region and sector level. We argue that a focus on only one accounting system and framing in global policy (e.g., those presently used under the UNFCCC and the Kyoto Protocol) can potentially limit consideration of mitigation options to a reduced set of activities (e.g., power generation), missing significant opportunities for mitigation in other aspects (e.g., manufactured products, services). 2 Materials and methods We use country- and sector-specific emissions data from the EDGAR database (Emissions Database for Global Atmospheric Research) (Andrew and Peters 2013; European Commission 2011) as the basis of our analysis, with the exception of organic carbon and black carbon (Shindell et al. 2012). The dataset includes CO2, CH4, NOX, SO2, NF3, CO, N2O, NMVOC, NH3, SF6, 8 PFCs and 11 HFCs for the year 2007, aggregated according to UNEP (2012) (see Table S1). We base our analysis on 2007 as that is the most recent year of our economic dataset (discussed below). Organic carbon (OC) and black carbon (BC) data are from the years 2005 and 2010. BC and OC emissions from biomass burning are not included. We estimate 2007 BC and OC emissions by using a weighted average of 2005 and 2010 emissions. We take into account agricultural waste and savanna burning, but we do not include the emissions from deforestation. We exclude deforestation emissions since detailed analysis is required to determine the country-specific sectors that are allocated deforestation (European Commission 2013), and this work is beyond the scope of this current paper. We first converted emissions data to radiative forcing and then to global temperature change potential (GTP) using impulse response functions (IRFs), based on equations from Fuglestvedt et al. (2010) and Aamaas et al. (2013b), and pollutant parameters from Fuglestvedt et al. (2010) and IPCC (2007). GWP calculations use the same pollutant parameters. The temperature IRF includes the heat capacity of the ocean (two layers), and has an equilibrium climate sensitivity (λ) of 0.75 K/Wm−2, based on the latest CMIP5 data (Olivié and Peters 2013). The IRF of CO2 is modelled with parameters from Joos et al. (2013), as explained by Olivié and Peters (2013). We use single global estimates for the SLCFs, which is an approximation as the response to emissions of SLCFs often depends on location (Berntsen et al. 2006). We use the absolute GTP (AGTP; in units of global mean temperature change, K) for the temporal change of sectors and the relative metric (GTP; in units of CO2 emissions that will induce equivalent temperature change, CO2-eq) for the remainder of the analysis. Assuming Climatic Change that global emissions will follow high emission scenarios, it is likely that a 2 °C global mean temperature increase will occur before or around 2060 (Joshi et al. 2011; Peters et al. 2013). Because our study is set in the backdrop of international policy aimed at preventing this level being breached, and to be consistent with other recent studies (Aamaas et al. 2013a; Peters et al. 2011b), we use GTP with a 50-year time horizon (GTP50) to illustrate the effects of the emissions (compare with Myhre et al. (2013) who present a range of time-horizons). The most commonly chosen time horizon used with GWP is 100 years, but it has been suggested that this is not based on scientific arguments, and that it may have initially been chosen because it was the middle of the three options first presented (Shine 2009). The appropriate choice of time horizon is determined primarily by the policy context (Myhre et al. 2013). Our intention here is not to advocate 50 years as the optimal time horizon, but we feel it is a choice that we can support based on the literature. We also do not wish to focus on the importance of the time horizon in this article, but use 50 years as a point of departure to analyze the consequences of choices in emission accounting, SLCF, and alternative metrics. Although uncertainties are larger for instantaneous (e.g., GTP) compared to integrated (e.g., GWP) metrics and for SLCFs (Olivié and Peters 2013; Reisinger et al. 2010), we choose to incorporate these aspects to indicate how the results depend on choices for parameters and metric. We do not perform an uncertainty analysis in this article, but refer to ongoing work (Karstensen et al. 2014). The sectoral emissions data were allocated through the global supply chain to consuming regions and economic sectors by using a Multi-Regional Input–Output (MRIO) model based on data from the Global Trade Analysis Project (GTAP), with 129 regions and 57 sectors for the year 2007 (Andrew and Peters 2013; Peters et al. 2011c). While our analysis is performed for all regions and sectors, we allocate the results to nine sectors (see Table S2). The supply chain model is fully explained elsewhere (Andrew and Peters 2013), and references therein point to numerous applications. Territorial accounting of emissions always allocates emissions to the sector where the emitting activity takes place, but when presenting consumption-based emissions there are alternative ways to allocate the consuming region’s consumption emissions to sectors (Peters and Hertwich 2006). First, it is possible to account consumption-based emissions according to the sector in which the emissions occurred, revealing, for the goods and services consumed by a given country, in which sector the emissions occurred (e.g., US consumption might induce emissions in electricity production in China). An alternative is to account the consumptionbased emissions according to the final sector in the supply chain, showing the emissions required to produce the goods and services consumed (e.g., the majority of emissions from agriculture are allocated to food sectors as this is where the purchases are made). Because direct emissions by households do not occur in the production process (they are at the very end of the supply chain), they are not redistributed under a change of accounting system, and are therefore identical under both the territorial and consumption perspective. 3 Results Using GTP50 as the metric, global emissions in 2007 were 35.2 Gt CO2-eq., and of these 24 % were embodied in international trade (Fig. 1). For the purpose of the discussion, we define globally traded emissions as the emissions that, under a consumption perspective, are allocated to a different region than the one in which they occurred as a consequence of a production activity. The traded share varies by pollutant, ranging from 8 % globally for OC (mainly associated with domestic economic activities, such as households) to 69 % globally for NF3 (mainly associated with manufacturing of electronic equipment). International trade is Climatic Change a. Global GTP50 (Gt CO −eq.) 40 2 30 20 10 0 Territorial Exports Imports Consumption b. United States of America 6 2 GTP50 (Gt CO −eq.) 8 4 2 0 Territorial Exports Imports Consumption Imports Consumption Imports Consumption c. China 6 2 GTP50 (Gt CO −eq.) 8 4 2 0 Territorial Exports d. EU27 5 2 GTP50 (Gt CO −eq.) 6 4 3 2 1 0 Territorial EU27 USA China Exports India Brazil South Africa Russian Federation Rest of AnnexB Rest of Non−AnnexB Climatic Change Fig. 1 Regional breakdown of emissions for the year 2007 from territorial and consumption perspectives globally, for USA, China and EU27, using GTP50. First bar shows emissions occurring within the regions’ borders, while the second and third bar shows emissions connected to exports from and imports to the regions. Last bar shows emissions from consumption, which subtracts exports from and adds imports to territorial emissions. The “Export” bars are colored according to where emissions embodied in products are exported and finally consumed, while colors in the “Imports” and “Consumption” bars indicate where emissions originally occurred. EU27 imports and export include intra-EU trade dominated by China on the export side (24 % of globally exported emissions), and the US and EU27 on the import side (17 and 33 %, respectively, where the latter includes trade within the EU27). There are larger relative disparities between territorial and consumption emissions for small countries (Davis and Caldeira 2010), but we focus on the world total and the three world regions with the largest absolute disparities (Fig. 1). The US and EU27 are net importers of emissions, with the largest imports coming from China (nearly 500 Mt CO2eq. to the US and about the same amount to the EU27). China, as with many other nonAnnex B countries, is a net exporter of emissions. The inclusion of SLCFs as well as multiple WMGHGs only marginally changes the allocated emissions for the three regions, compared to when only accounting for CO2 (7 % increase of emissions for the US, 4 % for China and 4 % for EU27 in territorial perspective). The differences are, however, more significant on a sectoral basis (Fig. 3), with different time horizons, and with different metrics. Recent studies have highlighted the value in considering emissions, and their climate impacts, from a sectoral perspective (Aamaas et al. 2013b; Shindell et al. 2012; Unger et al. 2010). Figure 2 shows the same regions with emissions allocated to emitting territories on a source basis, consumption by source sector, and consumption by final sector (see Methods). The difference between territorial and consumption is the emissions embodied in exports and imports at the sector level, as in Fig. 1 for regions. While consumption by source shows where the emissions originally occur for a given final consumption of products, consumption by final sector allocates the same emissions to the sectors that sell products to final consumption (household demand, government demand, or capital investments). Figure 2 shows that the same source sectors dominate in the territorial and consumption perspectives: electricity generation, energy-intensive manufacturing, and transport sectors (see SI for sector definitions). The similarity between the source sector figures reflects that electricity and energy-intensive industries are at the core of many production processes, regardless of whether final consumers purchase services or manufactured products. As most final products are processed, the emissions by final sector are reallocated from primary and secondary sectors, to secondary and tertiary sectors. Figure 2a shows the large redistribution of emissions between sectors at the global level. Significant redistributions from territorial to consumption perspective at the global level include: 47 % of emissions associated with energy-intensive manufacturing (EIM) are reallocated to services and 18 % of EIM to non-energy intensive manufacturing (NEIM), 40 % of agriculture to food, 40 % of electricity to services and 18 % of electricity to NEIM, 37 % of transport to services and 11 % of transport to NEIM, 28 % of NEIM to services, 18 % of mining to EIM and 16 % of mining to NEIM, and 16 % of food to services. The service sector is the largest final sector, with 36 % of global emissions, which also includes construction which represents 35 % of final service emissions. The shares of EIM and NEIM change between the two perspectives. EIM is more important in the territorial emissions, while NEIM is more important in consumption by final sectors. All manufacturing combined is allocated 25 and 21 % of the global emissions in territorial and consumption by final sector perspectives, respectively, while it contributes 39 % of traded emission globally. Climatic Change a. Global GTP50 (Gt CO −eq.) 40 2 30 20 10 0 Territorial Exports Imports Consumption Consumption source sector final sector b. United States of America 6 2 GTP50 (Gt CO −eq.) 8 4 2 0 Territorial Exports Imports Consumption Consumption source sector final sector c. China 6 2 GTP50 (Gt CO −eq.) 8 4 2 0 Territorial Exports Imports Consumption Consumption source sector final sector d. EU27 5 2 GTP50 (Gt CO −eq.) 6 4 3 2 1 0 Territorial Exports Agriculture Mining Food Imports Consumption Consumption source sector final sector E−intensive manu. NE−intensive manu. Transport Services Electricity Households Climatic Change Fig. 2 Sectoral breakdown of emissions for the year 2007 from territorial and consumption perspectives, including imports and exports globally, for USA, China, and EU27, using GTP50. The territorial emissions occur within regions’ borders, while consumption by source and final sector include imports and exclude exports. Consumption by source sector allocates emissions to the sectors that originally emitted the emissions, while the final sectors represent the sectors consumers purchase from. Bars are colored according to sector attributions The transport sector is allocated 12 % of global territorial emissions, and as a significant part of the transport sector involves delivery of products, only 66 % of the territorial emissions remain allocated to transport in the consumption view. The rest (34 %) is embodied in the transported products in the consumption by final sector perspective. The proportion of emissions accounted to agriculture varies significantly by region, due to factors such as geography, climate and production methods, but it is allocated 13 % of global territorial emissions, which reduces by about half when allocated to final sectors, with the other half allocated to other sectors such as food. The food sector has low production emissions, but is allocated 9 % of global emissions from consumption by final sector due to supply-chain contributions from agriculture and transport. Emissions from households include activities causing direct emissions (personal transport, usage of gas, etc.). This sector is equal in all perspectives, by definition (see Materials and Methods), with 13 % of global emissions. In the US (Fig. 2b), the electricity sector dominates with 34 % of territorial emissions. The majority of electricity generation is used by other productive sectors of the economy, and only 37 % of direct emissions are retained by electricity when using the final-sector perspective. Manufacturing accounts for 18 % of territorial emissions, which grow to 23 % at consumption by final sector. Transport is also an important emitter in the US, with 19 % of emissions, but this drops to 6 % in the final sector view. Table 1 Changes in CO2-eq. emissions when changing perspectives for selected regions and sectors. As the Global row shows, the first two perspectives change the global emissions, while the third column only allocates the same emissions differently. Colored bars are normalised to ±50 %. Small global emitting sectors (such as Food sectors) that are allocated large emissions in a consumption perspective lead to large changes a using production emissions and all pollutants b using production emissions and GTP50 c using all pollutants and GTP50 d from production GWP100 emissions to consumption-based GTP50 emissions using all pollutants Climatic Change CO 14 2 SO 2 N O 10 CO BC NO 2 Territorial Consumption X HFCs NH3 8 OC NMVOC SF6 2 GTP50 (Gt CO −eq.) CH4 12 6 PFCs NF3 4 2 0 −2 Agr Mining Food EIM NEIM Trans Services EL Households Fig. 3 Global emissions for the year 2007 by species and sector using GTP50, where the first bar in each sector is territorial emissions and the second bar shows emissions reallocated to final sectors. The black circles represent the net effect of each sector In China (Fig. 2c), the domestic manufacturing sector is the largest emitter (39 % of territorial emissions), of which 33 % is exported, while the electricity sector is close behind with 32 % of territorial emissions. By final sector, however, the shares only amount to 20 % and 7 %, respectively. As China exports more emissions than it imports, the emissions allocated to Chinese consumption are less than its territorial emissions. The transport sector in China has a relatively small overall contribution to territorial emissions, due both to relatively low emissions, and similar contributions from warming species such as CO2 and cooling species such as NOX and SO2, resulting in a net effect closer to zero than the other regions. The service sector increases from 7 % under the territorial perspective to 51 % under the final-sector perspective, due mainly to that sector’s consumption of the output of electricity, EIM, NEIM and transport. In EU27 (Fig. 2d), the largest sector by territorial emissions was electricity (27 % of emissions), while only 7 % is allocated in the final sector consumption perspective. Manufacturing is allocated 23 % of territorial emissions, and, at 25 %, is about the same at consumption by final sector. As with the US, transport has substantial emissions, accounting for 19 and 12 % of the emissions in the two perspectives. With respect to trade, 42 % of US imports are from manufacturing, while the same sector is allocated 39 % of EU27’s imports. Chinese emissions exports are dominated by electricity (35 %) and manufacturing (48 %), and of the total Chinese export, 25 % goes to the US and 25 % to EU27. Figures 1 and 2 show a Bsnapshot^ of the temperature response after 50 years, and therefore do not capture the different temporal effects of the pollutants, such as the trade-off between WMGHGs and SLCFs. As the pollutants’ lifetimes and effects in the atmosphere differ, the ordering of the largest sectors may change depending on the chosen time horizon. Fig. S1 shows the distribution of sectors for the three regions over time. Uniquely, we show the results from a consumption by final sector perspective, which is significantly different to a territorial Climatic Change by source distribution (Andrew et al. 2013; Davis and Caldeira 2010). All regions show emissions starting with a net-negative effect, and peaks in net effect occur within 3 decades of the pulse emission. The figure illustrates the consequence of choosing different time horizons for the metric, with the effect on temperature changing significantly over 100 years. Three examples serve to demonstrate how the allocation of emissions to sectors, using AGTP and a territorial basis, can change markedly depending on the time horizon chosen: when shifting between the often-chosen time horizons of 20 and 100 years, net warming from emissions of the electricity sector in China increases from 22 to 36 % of China’s contribution to global warming, US agriculture declines from 8 to 3 %, and EU27’s transport increases from 13 to 21 % of EU27’s contribution to global warming. Comparisons between global emissions of GWP100 and GTP50 reveal that the latter has higher magnitude since it places less weight on SLCFs with cooling effects (mainly SO2, OC, and NH3). In a sectoral view, the differences between allocation methods are usually much larger than the differences between metric values (Fig. S3), although some sectors show substantial differences in metric values: agriculture is 25 % lower using GTP50 than with GWP100 (due mainly to CH4), while the electricity sector is 56 % higher (due mainly to SO2). A change in perspective will have very different sectoral and regional impacts (Table 1). Globally, the net GTP50 values are 9 % higher than GWP100 when including all pollutants, but while China has a 22 % increase in emissions when using GTP50, Brazil’s emissions decrease by 12 %. At the global sector level, agriculture, mining, services and household sectors have decreased emissions when using GTP50, while the other sectors have an increase. The inclusion of all pollutants, instead of including only the Kyoto Protocol gases, decreases the global net emissions by 11 % and a similar result follows in most countries. Allocating emissions to consumption instead of production often changes the emissions substantially, especially in sectors as e.g. secondary and tertiary sectors (such as food and service sectors) with small production emissions may be allocated relatively large emissions in a consumption perspective (Table 1). One further breakdown is instructive: contrasting the differences between sectors by the species of pollutant, from territorial and consumption perspectives using GTP50. Figure 3 shows that CO2, CH4, and N2O are the largest contributors to temperature increase, while SO2 and NOX are the largest cooling components, though these change strongly with different time horizons (Fig. S2). Globally, the temperature-weighted magnitude of cooling species relative to warming species decline from 20 % at 20 years to only 8 % at 100 years. Mitigation by sectors with high emissions of cooling pollutants (e.g. SO2 and NOX) may lead to increased global warming in the short term (Matthews and Zickfeld 2012). At 100 years, all sectors’ emissions profiles are dominated by CO2, except agriculture, where N2O still has the largest effect. Shifting from territorial emissions to consumption also shifts the relative importance of pollutants within sectors. Figure 3 shows that a change of perspective reallocates more than half of the emissions to other sectors. 4 Discussion and conclusion Our analysis gives an alternative perspective on climate policy in three key areas. First, there is significant added value in considering mitigation from a temperature perspective. The climate policy community is working to keep the global average temperature increase below 2 °C relative to pre-industrial levels, and analyses of the largest drivers of temperature change are needed. The widely used GWP does not relate directly to temperature (Shine et al. 2005). A temperature-based metric, like the GTP, leads to different weighting of emissions at the sector level, particularly for sectors with a large share of SLCFs like BC and SO2. While the global manufacturing sector is the Climatic Change largest emitter using the GWP, the GTP suggests the electricity sector is largest. Thus the use of the GWP may lead to different mitigation priorities compared to using a GTP (c.f. Fig. S3). Second, including SLCFs in addition to WMGHGs reveals the overall net climate effect of economic activities (Unger et al. 2010). By adding the non-Kyoto SLCFs and WMGHGs to the Kyoto basket of pollutants (in a territorial view), the global emissions allocated to each sector can change substantially, from -11 % for transport, -14 % for NEIM and -19 % for electricity (due to cooling effects of NOX and SO2) to +3 % for household emissions (due to warming effects of BC and CO). Third, and as argued by others (Barrett et al. 2013; Wiedmann 2009), a consumption perspective can be complementary to the established territorial perspective to emission allocation. More than 75 % of global emissions in 2007 occurred in electricity generation, energy-intensive manufacturing, transport and agriculture, and only 10 % of the global emissions are allocated to services (including construction), non energy-intensive manufacturing and food in the territorial perspective. Using the consumption perspective, however, nearly 60 % are allocated to services, NEIM and food, while electricity generation, EIM, transport and agriculture only accounts for 29 %. This change of allocation is due to a large redistribution of emissions from the producing sectors to the sectors consuming goods and services, and may lead to different mitigation priorities (Barrett et al. 2013; Hertwich and Peters 2009). At the global sector level, a change in emissions accounting proposes significant changes, often larger than the inclusion of additional gases outside of the Kyoto Protocol and changes in metrics (Table 1). An important remaining question regards the uncertainty in our analysis. While previous work has investigated the uncertainty of individual components of the analysis we have performed (Aamaas et al. 2013b; Lenzen et al. 2010; Olivié and Peters 2013; Peters et al. 2012; Reisinger et al. 2010; UNEP 2012; Wilting 2012), the quantification of overall uncertainty of this chained system remains an open research question. In parallel work we are using Monte Carlo techniques to address this research gap (Karstensen et al. 2014). The parametric uncertainty in consumption-based temperature allocations to global sectors is in the range from ±9 to ±27 % using GTP50, although structural uncertainties might increase these values. As in other work, higher uncertainties are found at the regional and sectoral levels. Our analysis clearly demonstrates the dependency of results on allocation methods, metric, time horizon of metric, and whether the territorial or consumption perspective is used. Emission mitigation strategies should consider these alternative approaches carefully, as priorities can change depending on the choices that are made. Allocating emissions to consumption by final sector suggests the secondary and tertiary sectors are the largest drivers of emissions and temperature change. Recognizing these underlying drivers from multiple perspectives can help in developing alternative mitigation strategies, where a significant reduction in emissions from one sector can have significant impacts throughout the supply chain, which in turn can help keep global warming below 2 °C. Acknowledgments The authors acknowledge funding from the Norwegian Research Council project BQuantifying the global socio-economic and policy drivers for Brazil’s contribution to global warming^ (Project Number: 196090). References Aamaas B, Borken-Kleefeld J, Peters GP (2013a) The climate impact of travel behavior: a German case study with illustrative mitigation options. Environ Sci Policy 33:273–282 Aamaas B, Peters GP, Fuglestvedt JS (2013b) Simple emission metrics for climate impacts. Earth Syst Dyn 4:145–170 Climatic Change Andrew RM, Peters GP (2013) A multi-region input–output table based on the global trade analysis project database (Gtap-Mrio). Econ Syst Res 25:99–121 Andrew RM, Davis SJ, Peters GP (2013) Climate policy and dependence on traded carbon. Environ Res Lett 8:034011 Barrett J, Peters G, Wiedmann T, Scott K, Lenzen M, Roelich K, le Quéré C (2013) Consumption-based GHG emission accounting: a UK case study. Clim Pol 13:451–470 Berntsen T, Fuglestvedt J (2008) Global temperature responses to current emissions from the transport sectors. Proc Natl Acad Sci 105:19154–19159 Berntsen T, Fuglestvedt J, Myhre G, Stordal F, Berglen TF (2006) Abatement of greenhouse gases: does location matter? Clim Chang 74:377–411 Chen Y, Ebenstein A, Greenstone M, Li H (2013) Evidence on the impact of sustained exposure to air pollution on life expectancy from China’s Huai River policy. Proc Natl Acad Sci 110:12936–12941 Major Economies Forum on Energy and Climate (2009) Declaration of the leaders the major economies forum on energy and climate Davis SJ, Caldeira K (2010) Consumption-based accounting of CO2 emissions. Proc Natl Acad Sci 107:5687–5692 Davis SJ, Peters GP, Caldeira K (2011) The supply chain of CO2 emissions. Proc Natl Acad Sci 108:18554–18559 European Commission (2011) Emission Database for Global Atmospheric Research (EDGAR), release version 4.2. Joint Research Centre (JRC) and Netherlands Environmental Assessment Agency (PBL) European Commission (2013) The impact of EU consumption on deforestation: Comprehensive analysis of the impact of EU consumption on deforestation Felder S, Rutherford TF (1993) Unilateral CO2 reductions and carbon leakage: the consequences of international trade in oil and basic materials. J Environ Econ Manag 25:162–176 Fuglestvedt JS, Berntsen T, Godal O, Sausen R, Shine KP, Skodvin T (2003) Metrics of climate change: assessing radiative forcing and emission indices. Clim Chang 58:267–331 Fuglestvedt JS, Shine KP, Berntsen T, Cook J, Lee DS, Stenke A, Skeie RB, Velders GJM, Waitz IA (2010) Transport impacts on atmosphere and climate: metrics. Atmos Environ 44:4648–4677 Hertwich EG, Peters GP (2009) Carbon footprint of nations: a global, trade-linked analysis. Environ Sci Technol 43:6414–6420 IPCC (2007) Climate change 2007: the physical science basis. Contribution of working group I to the fourth assessment report of the intergovernmental panel on climate change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge Joos F, Roth R, Fuglestvedt J, Peters G, Enting I, Bloh WV, Brovkin V, Burke E, Eby M, Edwards N (2013) Carbon dioxide and climate impulse response functions for the computation of greenhouse gas metrics: a multi-model analysis. Atmos Chem Phys 13:2793–2825 Joshi M, Hawkins E, Sutton R, Lowe J, Frame D (2011) Projections of when temperature change will exceed 2°C above pre-industrial levels. Nat Clim Chang 1:407–412 Karstensen J, Peters GP, Andrew RM (2013) Attribution of CO2 emissions from Brazilian deforestation to consumers between 1990 and 2010. Environ Res Lett 8:024005 Karstensen J, Peters GP, Andrew RM (2014) Uncertainty in temperature response of current consumption-based emissions estimates. Earth Syst Dyn Discuss 5:1013–1073 Lenzen M, Wood R, Wiedmann T (2010) Uncertainty analysis for multi-region input–output models–a case study of the UK’s carbon footprint. Econ Syst Res 22:43–63 Matthews HD, Zickfeld K (2012) Climate response to zeroed emissions of greenhouse gases and aerosols. Nat Clim Chang 2:338–341 Moran DD, Lenzen M, Kanemoto K, Geschke A (2013) Does ecologically unequal exchange occur? Ecol Econ 89:177–186 Myhre G, Fuglestvedt JS, Berntsen TK, Lund MT (2011) Mitigation of short-lived heating components may lead to unwanted long-term consequences. Atmos Environ 45:6103–6106 Myhre G, D. Shindell, F.-M. Bréon, W. Collins, J. Fuglestvedt, J. Huang, D. Koch, J.-F. Lamarque, D. Lee BM, T. Nakajima, A. Robock, G. Stephens, T. Takemura, Zhang H (2013) Anthropogenic and Natural Radiative Forcing. In: Climate Change 2013: The Physical Science Basis. Contribution of Working Group I to the Fifth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change [Stocker, T.F., D. Qin, G.-K. Plattner, M. Tignor, S.K. Allen, J. Boschung, A. Nauels, Y. Xia, V. Bex and P.M. Midgley (eds.)]. Cambridge, United Kingdom and New York, NY, USA Olivié D, Peters G (2013) Variation in emission metrics due to variation in CO2 and temperature impulse response functions. Earth Syst Dyn 4:267–286 Peters GP (2010) Policy update: managing carbon leakage. Carbon Manag 1:35–37 Peters GP, Hertwich EG (2006) Structural analysis of international trade: environmental impacts of Norway. Econ Syst Res 18:155–181 Peters GP, Hertwich EG (2008) CO2 embodied in international trade with implications for global climate policy. Environ Sci Technol 42:1401–1407 Climatic Change Peters GP, Aamaas B, Berntsen T, Fuglestvedt JS (2011a) The integrated global temperature change potential (iGTP) and relationships between emission metrics. Environ Res Lett 6:044021 Peters GP, Aamaas BT, Lund M, Solli C, Fuglestvedt JS (2011b) Alternative BGlobal Warming^ metrics in life cycle assessment: a case study with existing transportation data. Environ Sci Technol 45:8633–8641 Peters GP, Andrew R, Lennox J (2011c) Constructing an environmentally-extended multi-regional input–output table using the gtap database. Econ Syst Res 23:131–152 Peters GP, Minx JC, Weber CL, Edenhofer O (2011d) Growth in emission transfers via international trade from 1990 to 2008. Proc Natl Acad Sci 108:8903–8908 Peters GP, Davis SJ, Andrew R (2012) A synthesis of carbon in international trade. Biogeosciences 9:3247–3276 Peters GP, Andrew RM, Boden T, Canadell JG, Ciais P, le Quere C, Marland G, Raupach MR, Wilson C (2013) The challenge to keep global warming below 2°C. Nat Clim Chang 3:4–6 Reisinger A, Meinshausen M, Manning M, Bodeker G (2010) Uncertainties of global warming metrics: CO2 and CH4. Geophys Res Lett 37, L14707 Shindell D, Kuylenstierna JC, Vignati E, van Dingenen R, Amann M, Klimont Z, Anenberg SC, Muller N, Janssens-Maenhout G, Raes F (2012) Simultaneously mitigating near-term climate change and improving human health and food security. Science 335:183–189 Shine KP (2009) The global warming potential - the need for an interdisciplinary retrail. Clim Chang 96:467–472 Shine KP, Fuglestvedt JS, Hailemariam K, Stuber N (2005) Alternatives to the global warming potential for comparing climate impacts of emissions of greenhouse gases. Clim Chang 68:281–302 Shine KP, Berntsen TK, Fuglestvedt JS, Skeie RB, Stuber N (2007) Comparing the climate effect of emissions of short-and long-lived climate agents. Philos Trans R Soc A Math Phys Eng Sci 365:1903–1914 Solomon S, Daniel JS, Sanford TJ, Murphy DM, Plattner G-K, Knutti R, Friedlingstein P (2010) Persistence of climate changes due to a range of greenhouse gases. Proc Natl Acad Sci 107:18354–18359 Stocker T, Qin D, Plattner G, Tignor M, Allen S, Boschung J, Nauels A, Xia Y, Bex V, Midgley P (2013) IPCC, 2013: climate change 2013: the physical science basis. contribution of working group I to the fifth assessment report of the intergovernmental panel on climate change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge Tanaka K, Peters GP, Fuglestvedt JS (2010) Policy update: multicomponent climate policy: why do emission metrics matter? Carbon Manag 1:191–197 Tol RS, Berntsen TK, O’Neill BC, Fuglestvedt JS, Shine KP (2012) A unifying framework for metrics for aggregating the climate effect of different emissions. Environ Res Lett 7:044006 UNEP (2012) The Emissions Gap Report 2012. Nairobi UNFCCC (2011a) Establishment of an Ad Hoc Working Group on the Durban Platform for Enhanced Action. Draft decision -/CP.17 UNFCCC (2011b) Report of the Conference of the Parties on its sixteenth session, held in Cancun from 29 November to 10 December 2010. http://unfccc.int/resource/docs/2010/cop16/eng/07a01.pdf Unger N, Bond TC, Wang JS, Koch DM, Menon S, Shindell DT, Bauer S (2010) Attribution of climate forcing to economic sectors. Proc Natl Acad Sci 107:3382–3387 Wiebe KS, Bruckner M, Giljum S, Lutz C (2012) Calculating energy-related CO2 emissions embodied in international trade using a global input–output model. Econ Syst Res 24:113–139 Wiedmann T (2009) A review of recent multi-region input–output models used for consumption-based emission and resource accounting. Ecol Econ 69:211–222 Wilting HC (2012) Sensitivity and uncertainty analysis in mrio modelling; some empirical results with regard to the dutch carbon footprint. Econ Syst Res 24:141–171