1 RESPONSES TO INTERDEPENDENCE. INTERNATIONAL RESTRUCTURING, NATIONAL VULNERA- BILITY AND THE NEW PROTECTIONISM. * By Helge Hveem Institute of Political Science University of Oslo ,. The problem. "Interdependence" is as loose a concept as the international system is complex. One important reason is that the concept has been extensively used for purely political, rhetorical purposes. This has meant that practically all inter-state transactions irrespective of their form, structural characteristics and consequenoes for participants according to this popularised use, fall under the concept. But even the way the concept has been used in theoretical works has contributed to the degradation of it as an analytical tool. In their seminal work - now fast becoming a neo-classical text in its genre - Keohane and Nye recognised the loose character of the concept. It referred according to them, to "situations characterised by reciprocal effects among countries or among actors in different countries". (Keohane and Nye, 1977 p. 8) If one interprets this definition stricto sensu, it may be possible to use the concept for scholarly analytical purposes. Such a definition would reserve the term interdependence INT) (hereafter for those bilateral relationships that offer the two partners concerned equivalent opportunities to affect each other. I believe that the qualification referred to - which the authors did make although not as a main point - has largely been forgotten in the general debate over interdependence. The result is that the concept has become at the same time 2 too normative, too inclusive and hence too imprecise to be of much use for scientific purposes. It needs to be redefined in order to be reactivated for research purposes. I propose that this may be done by on the one hand employing the concept in a more dynamic, more contextual way, and on the other hand by narrowing its scope of application in the direction of the qualification that was made above. I hope to explain in what follows why this apparently contradictory double operation is feasible. It also appears necessary to put more emphasis on the consequences of vulnerability for the parties involved. All this invites a typology of the situations in which INT is relevant and a classification of actors according to how and why they are affected. This is admittedly no easy task. Several authors have done very important contributions to it. My own contribution will be limited to pointing to three ways by which the concept can be used more fruitfully: first, by putting more emphasis on the conflict aspect of the dimension which the INT concept represents; secondly, by emphasising how the workings of an interdependence relationship may change according to changes in the context and in the actors involved; and thirdly, by emphasising that power plays and bargaining are crucial processes to understand when an interdependence relationship is being analysed. My first task will be to look at the vulnerability dimension of the INT concept. Then I shall have a brief look at the concept of "complex interdependence" which I find most unsatisfactory the way Keohane and Nye have employed it. These two points will relate indirectly to the first and the second of the arguments just raised. I shall end up by commenting on the third point, suggesting some working hypotheses for further research. The approach may look like an "old-fashioned positivistic" one. If so that was not intended. The thoughts put forth are preliminary and will be further developed at a later stage. 3 On vulnerability. For Keohane and Nye, the concept "vulnerability interdepend- ence" is distinguished from that of "sensitivity interdependence" . Vulnerability is defined as those costs which an actor must carry as a consequence of contextual change and the actions of other actors, after he has changed his own policies in an attempt to reduce costs. Sensitivity, on the other hand, is a situation where an actor faces costs as a consequence of the actions of other actors with no change in his own policies. (ibid., p. 13) An essential element in the vulnerability dimension is thus alternative costs. Dependence is not a function of the costs that result from attempts to maintain an external relationship but the costs that would result from a collapse of the per relationship or a fundamental change in it. The point is emphasised in various ways by Hirschman Baldwin (1945), Waltz (1970) and (1980). This observation does not, however, make the vulnerability dimension directly applicable when studying the policy or strategy choice of concrete actors, or evaluating their action flexibility. The dimension needs to be defined more precisely still. In the treatments of many US scholars, interpretations, there are differences in levels of abstraction and applications on several important points. Whereas some look upon "sensitivity" as part of the vulnerability dimension (Duvall, 1978 p. 63) , others point out that sensitivity and vulnerability do not necessarily change in the same direction nor to the same degree. (Baldwin, 1980 p. 491) Questions are also asked about the very relevance of the sensitivity dimension, particularly as to whether or not it has any independent explanatory power when explaining different degrees of dependence. (Baldwin, 1979 p. 178 ff) Finally, the relevance of alternative costs when explaining dependence is also questioned by some authors. _ Several of those studies that have attempted to operationalise the vulnerability dimension for measurement purposes also have run into problems. In some works by economists, vulnerability may 4 appear as synonymous with the degree of openness of an economy. (Norman, 1983) This impression is, however, either slightly erroneous as these works may not have been aimed directly at operationalising the dimension. Or, the impression is correct to the extent that the focus of these works is not the strategic or dynamic aspect of vulnerability - the action flexibility of the actor concerned - but rather the static view of vulnerability that disregards alternative costs (and look upon costs in strictly economic terms) . Those empirical works that have attempted to operationalise the INT concept in other ways appear to have departed from the sensitivity dimension. Rosecrance, (Dolan et al s. , 1980; Gosiorowski, 1986; 1980). Few if any have proposed 1977; and Tetreault, to make use of alternative costs as an indicator of dependence. Those analyses that choose the need of an actor for a specific item as a point of departure, are few and appear to be working on a high level of abstraction, difficult. thus making operationalisation (Duvall, 1980 p. 67) In order to assess the alternative costs of a particular relationship for a particular actor, known: 1) question, three aspects ought to be the ability of the actor to do without the item in 2) the ability of the actor to obtain and to make effective use of substitute items to compensate for the loss of the original item, and 3) the ability of the actor to obtain alternative channels for the item. Economic research offers multiplicator coefficients and input-output matrices to cope with the first aspect, and there is an abundant supply of studies on substitution. I offered a survey of some of the literature and some first empirical assessment of substitutability options in a study on one particular sector - strategic minerals. (Hveem, 1979; and Hveem and Malnes, 1980) as input-output tables are concerned, As far their application to particular cases appears to be contingent on such a number of assumptions that their relevance and applicability are certainly limited both in scope and domain. In summary, I believe that there are serious weaknesses in those research efforts that attempt to determine the extent of vulnerability objectively. This appears to underline the relevance 5 of a question that others have raised: is INT a subjective matter only; or can it be defined objectively ? Or, to put the question differently: is INT felt in direct proportion to the degree to which interdependence is factual, i.e. can be determined intersubjectively ? The classical geopolitics literature offers a lot of support for the need to distinguish between the two aspects. Geopoliticians sometimes appear to have exaggerated out of all proportions the vulnerability of "their" country. In retrospect, one may even say that some of the most dramatic accounts of the 1973 OPEC oil price actions were also highly exaggerated, , especially as they transferred what was seen as an OPEC threat to other minerals. In my view, these observations underline the importance of the subjective dimension. In other words: the essence of the concept of vulnerability is assessed by getting to know the perceptions that concrete actors hold on vulnerability - their own and that of others to which they are related. Analysis of vulnerability would therefore have to include analysis of idiosyncratic variables. It also appears reasonable to depart from the assumption of bounded rationality. The vulnerability dimension is, in my view, not primrily an element of theory of interdependence. For one thing, there is no such theory in the strict sense of the word. Moreover, the vulnerability dimension is a perspective that should, in order to become part of a theory (that proposes causality relation- ships, be integrated into several different theories. They would range from bargaining theory via integration theories, theories on internationalisation to theories of economic nationalism and national development strategies. One implication of this view is that there is a need to employ the vulnerability dimension in a contextual way. By that I mean that international structures and change represent a range of important independent or intervening variables. In widening lOne example is the much-cited Bergsten article in Foreign Policy, 1973 and a follow-up in the same journal entitled "The Threat is Real". 6 the focus one ought to be able to relate power structures and their implications better than some existing studies have done. They acknowledge the existence of such structures by including the symmetry vs asymmetry variable. But they do not make it the central issue or the crucial variable it should be. That reduces the chances to construct a working typology of vulnerability situations, discuss strategic options for coping with these situations and to explain why certain strategies are chosen over others in concrete cases. Another implication is that the unitary actor model must be relaxed as an assumption. It is a serious mistake to move, as I believe a great number of researchers now do, in the opposite direction; viz. the increasing number of game theoretical treatises of international relations in particular in US circles. Interdependence's effects are always felt by some particular group or class within countries. If some such group perceives a negative effect, then it will naturally demand protection from it. The normal process of interdependence "activation" therefore is that demand for political handling of its perceived consequences is raised from within a country. Processes of domestic interdependence activation therefore ought to figure prominently in scholarly analysis. They have not done so far. This probably becomes even more of a problem as we turn to the concept "complex interdependence". On "complex interdependence" The notion of complex interdependence (COMINT) was set up in the Keohane-Nye text as a contrast to what they perceived as realist world modelling. COMINT has three characteristics: 1) military power is not dominant in relationships of the complex interdependence type; states, 2) there are multiple channels of contact between organised in a multiplicity of institutions not always closesly co-ordinated one with the others; and 3) policy goals may be subject to trade-offs, they are not arranged in stable orders. If we leave out some very obvious theoretical and conceptual 7 weaknesses 2 one is left with a concept that basically rests on two inter-state processes - that international agendas may be manipulated (subject to bargaining) and that international organisation may modify or regulate the effects of interdependence, including the negotiating agendas. This, I think, boils down to a question of inserting the INT and the COMINT concepts into a theory of bargaining at the international level. In other words and judging from the literature I do not see any prospect that a theory of international interdependence is about to emerge. The best efforts to develop the concept as a theory have so far been those based on Schelling (1963) and been explicitly dealing with bargaining theory. (Oye, 1979; Stein, 1980; Sebenius, 1984; and Baldwin, 1979 and 1980) One interesting branch of contributions has dealt with linkage processes. I shall confine my comments here to one simple point: agenda manipulation or more specifically, under which conditions actors are likely to choose linkaging as a strategy. This boils down to a questioning of another assumption - or maybe it is a hypothesis - in Keohane-Nye that they did not follow up: weak states are more likely than stronger ones to choose linkaging. The more general hypothesis would be that linkaging is more likely under conditions of asymmetrical complex interdependence than under symmetrical ones. The opposite could very well be true. Consider the case of a small country. another, If it felt vulnerability in its relationship with stronger country in one particular sector, well prefer to insulate that sector, it may very not link the INT process to other sectors. This would in particular be true if it is generally weak externally, i.e. has no bargaining power in other sectors with which to influence the international relationship. But even if it had such power, it may choose not to activate it for fear that the stronger state will exert a disproportionate concession. 2 Reference is made inter alia to the fact that the authors treat the concept in a tautological way by assuming that COMINT is characterised by the goals of actors and the type of state policy which they adopt, two criteria that are in fact the defining variables for the concept itself or the very reason why they are selected out in contrast or opposition to the realist mode. 8 Many interdependence authors treat a weak-strong relationship out of context, forgetting about the generalised bargaining power of the strong state that it may activate to counter any sectorial bargaining power that the weak may enjoy. Besides, if a small state happens to be comparatively strong in one particular sector, it normally follows that there are strong interest groups attached to that sector. It is not hard to imagine that such interest groups may very well object to the sector - and hence their interests - being linked to international bargaining that will result in concessions. And if the state had to carry the costs of making the concessions in order to compensate the interest groups for their losses, then the net result may well be negative from the point of view of the state compared to what it would have been if no linkaging had been done. My counter-hypothesis would be that it is especially those stronger states which turn out to be feeling, or perceiving, vulnerability in one particular sector (because of a permanent or ad hoc weakening of its position in that sector) which is also most likely to initiate sector linkaging in international bargaining. (An example would appear to be the United States' attempts to activate its military guarantee to allies faced with a deterioriating cornpetititiveness in manufacturing industries relative to that of Japan and the FRG.) The other issue I wanted to touch concerns whether or not Keohane and Nye are right in hypothesising - or assuming - that COMINT is by definition less likely to produce conflict than is a military type relationship. And that simple interdependence in general creates more conflict than complex interdependence. Intiutively the latter appears correct. But the question is whether what appears to be normally true in micro-economic and in micro-social contexts (market exchanges in the local community or cross-cutting loyalties) is equally true in the international one ? The answer on this occasion is made brief: it is highly questionable, but the criterion for deciding whether it is questionable or not rests on a definitional issue. What may appear as a reductionist argument is nevertheless a serious 9 possibility that few if any INT comments have adressed: The true problem with the non-realist interedependence literature is that it has manipulated the definition of state security to be confined to military security. Economic security is - and has always been - an important aspect of the total concern of foreign policy. It is the context and the dynamics of international systemic change that determine the relative weight of the two (and possible other) aspects of security. But they are both integral, inseparable parts of state policy. That some analysts in the past saw it differently should not keep us from making this very simple but basic assumption. A quick look at some accounts by practitioners in the field ought to convince us of the tenacity of this assumption. 3 State representatives may have clothed their arguments in military security terms in the past, such as did the Nordic Trade ministers when they argued for a special protection clause to be included in the Multi-Fiber Arrangement arguing that a viable national textile industry was a prerequisite for military preparedness. But that argument may have been simply a concession to the international mode or what they at the time perceived of as an issue-hierarchy in the eyes of Secretary Kissinger and his likes. With trade wars on the rise and a stock market crash fresh in our memories, it does not seem to be necessary any longer to plead that economic security be considered a priority goal for state representatives as well as for a number of economic interest groups. A continued defence for the case of COMINT as opposed to realist military security thinking in the present situation look more and more like a heroic fight with windmills. If this perspective on the contemporary international political scene is accepted, then one may also take a fresh look at some of the notions created by the interdependence literature up until the present. Economic vulnerability may still not be perceived as a such a major concern that creates as dangerous threats to 3 I am referring to among others former West German Chancellor Helmut Schmidt, 1979 and to former Secretary of State for Trade, Edmund Dell, 1987. 10 national security as does the threat of military holocausts. But a proliferation of protectionism, bilateralism and less "hostile" policies of industrial adjustment should be seen as attempts to reduce or even reject interdependence and instead opt for independence. It is in the nature of things that such a process creates conflict and increasing problems of co-operation. Contextual and relational approaches. Our discussion so far has attempted to substantiate the view that the vulnerability dimension is a matter of alternative choice options, has a subjective as well as an objective aspect to it, should be related to several different theoretic- al contributions, should reflect the symmetry vs asymmetry of power relations, and should be broadened. In theory, an actor may solve his vulnerability problem by mobilising alternatives within himself without, (do substitute or reduce his dependence on an i tern) . The self-sufficiency strategy is perhaps more often possible than normative interdependence-promoting models would have it, but may be, and is often, exaggerated as well. Proponents of it often underestimate the trade-offs that can be gained by playing on a vulnerability situation (provided one is good at playing, of course) . In the following I shall therefore concentrate on the relational option for handling vulnerability and not consider the domestic potential as an option. What will be done is to offer some theoretical illustrations of how domestic processes may work to influence the international interdependence relationship. a. The theoretical case. It may be a rational choice for actors not only to produce or reproduce vulnerability in other actors, but to do that for yourself as well. The purposeful creation of others' vulnerability to yourself is a strategy known from many historical and contemporary cases. Literature has perhaps highlighted the extreme cases: Nazi Germany's policy before and during World War 11 II (Hirschman, 1945) and the policy of the apartheid Republic of South Africa vis a vis her neighbouring majority-ruled states during the present time (Hanlon, 1986). There are certainly other and less extreme examples of seeking power over others by making them dependent on you and thus vulnerable to changes in your own behaviour. Big powers' continued dependence on mineral supplies and military bases in a number of Third World countries at a time when they dispose of the means to reduce such dependencies may be a case in point. Lesotho and Swaziland offer the perfect example of absolute vulnerability. They have no alternative but to carry the costs of whatever policy the RSA imposes on them. The Republic for her part retains absolute control over the two landlocked mini-states. She is only theoretically vulnerable to actions that may be considered by (some member of) these states as long as she is in a dominant position when it comes to controlling the military-security situation in the region. (Hveem, 1986) The next logical category to consider is relative vulnerability. This category represents a situation whereby an actor is capable of manoeuvering his vulnerability, but up to a point only. (It should not be confused with comparative vulnerability which is how one actor's vulnerability compares with another's.) Mexico in her relationship with the United States would be a case in point. I shall return to that case in a moment. The general point is the following When we consider the implications of vulnerability, we are considering a relational problem. If two actors confronting each other are both vulnerable to one another, then there is reciprocal vulnerability. If the respective vulnerabilities are (close to) balanced, then there is a symmetrical relationship of vulnerability. This is interdependence strictly speaking. The balance of terror between the superpowers based on the destructive capacity of nuclear weapons is a much observed case of symmetrical vulnerability. Is cooperation the logical or rational choice of an actor that finds himself in a situation of reciprocal vulnerability ? Not only the superpower relationship, but a number of other cases 12 show that it is not. Ideological differences apart, a rational choice may be to initiate conflict, or to choose a mixture of the two. An actor may, in other words, follow a cooperation and conflict strategy at one and the same time. The situation as is and structural elements of the relationship will determine which aspect of the strategy is chosen in a specific case. External pressures or internal processes, or a mixture of the two (a correlation or a causal link) , are such structural elements. Probably more often than not they work with different intensities, or for other reasons do not coincide in two actors that are related. This is one reason why cooperation may be difficult although it may also represent an incentive to cooperate. The Prisoner's Dilemma is one model for analysing choice in such situations; I believe it has some limited applicability Another and probably more fruitful model can be constructed by linking the concepts control and interest. One practical implication of complex interdependence is that an actor's vulnerability in one area may be offset by invulnerability (absolute or comparative) in another. Or, if two actors are vulnerable to one another in two different areas, a linkage strategy or a trade off between the two may be a rational choice. Again, the case of Mexico or the handling of the debt crisis since 1982 may be good examples. b. The first illustration: debt. Absolute vulnerability is the other side of absolute control. In this type of relationship, power is extremely asymmetrically distributed. "Pure imperialism" as is found in many areas, instances and periods of North-South relations is a case in point. The debt crisis of the 1980s is an illustration of a different relationship. Since the IMF, the big creditor banks and the US government rushed to refinance the Mexican debt in 1982, a simple model of the new North-South relationship could be described as follows: The creditor front controls the access of debitor countries to new credits and the renegotiation of old loans; although some would claim that the interest rate is determined by the market, 13 the creditors (or US authorities) also exercise discretionary control over that factor as well. The debitors on their side control the repayment of old loans and the payment of interest. As the Mexican Rescue proved, the creditors felt vulnerable to the threat of a financial collapse resulting from failure by Mexican authorities to comply with their repayment obligations. And as we realize when looking at the background for the huge loan transfers of the 1970s, the moving force behind it was not purely financial motives: banks had cash, wanted borrowers. Even motives of industrial policy and general foreign policy played a role: newly industrialising countries pursued aggressive export industrialisation policies and needed to import inputs which the industrialised countries of the OECD were only too happy to supply them. By doing that, they would reduce the pressure mounting on their own industries due to the overcapacity that had been built up and the stagflation that they were living through. Also, the huge loan transfers were one way of softening the perceived danger of a Third World front demanding international economic reform and redistribution. Loan financing was also a way around the new economic nationalism that threatened to cut into the interests of TNCs by nationalising their affiliates in the Third World. Then suddenly came dramatic increases in world that is US interest rates and a reversal of world price trends into a deflationary trend. Both changed the rationality of financing economic development by loan finance and a consequent accumulation of foreign debt. After holding the debt operation for several years, creditors started (1987) to write off "bad debt" . As one approaches the 1990s, the situation appears to be one of long-term complex interdependence. Industrial firms in the North were the first beneficiaries of the debt financing of the 1970s; commercial banks took the burden of carrying the debt. The debtors can only manage their commitments if they are able to earn, and preferably to increase, export incomes. Such a goal may partly coincide with the interests of manufacturers in the North (high technology such interests And banks, firms) , partly collide with (competing processing and cost sensitive firms) . the multilateral credit institutions and the govern- 14 ments (Finance Ministries) all have their stake, partly coinciding or overlapping, partly at odds with the interests of the manufacturing sector. In the debtor countries, different and partly contradictory interests are also at work. There are natural temptations to evade the debt sector and refuse to repay or set limits (cf. Peruvian case) . Such the tempations are tempered by the pressures of foreign policy, by long-term interests in the relationship and fear that they may be negatively affected by a rupture of repayment, and by domestic interest groups profitting from the conditionality imposed by the debt position. The implications for theory are quite obvious. First, the working of the relationship is contingent upon the evolution and the relative power of domestic interest groups, just as it depends on the development of the bilateral relationship itself and contextual, systemic developments. Secondly, power can be exercised, or the power of others modified, even though an actor is weak on power resources. What may be referred to as the power of the weak is an underestimated option. Thirdly, we may speculate on another "unexpected consequence": the lack of power of the not-so-indebted. Do the heavily indebted have more leverage on the creditors than do the latter ? Are the latter in fact relatively worse off after the debt crisis than before because the threat to the stability of the system and the fear of bankruptcy in debtor countries and in heavily exposed banks require that priority is given to the heavily indebted ? Do greater caution in creditor circles further add to the problems of access to loan finance for the not-so-indebted ? c. The second illustration: bilateralism in trade. During the last decade, bilateralism has come to the forefront in international trade. There has been a proliferation of Voluntary Export Restraint Aareements and Orderly Marketing Arrangements (VERAs and OMAs) . More important, however, has been a surge of countertrade arrangements that go a long way beyond simple barter, and that involve a good number of countries. Estimates of the magnitude of the countertrade phenomenon vary 15 greatly. The variation, however, appears in large part to be due to differences in definition. If a fairly broad definition of the phenomenon is chosen, expert estimates hold that some 25-30 percent of international trade (mid-1980s)is covered by some form of countertrade arrangement, whether offset, buy-back, counterpurchase, compensation or other. The backbone of this new wave of an old trade form is no longer East-West relations, but SouthNorth and some North-North as well as many South-South relationships. More than 100 countries and 300 transnational corporations are believed to be involved in the trade. (Walsh, 1985) What may explain this surge - a huge leap away from the market mechanism into some form of organized trade (or "managed free trade" as the most stubborn free-traders prefer to call it) 7 In another context I have suggested and discussed several possible hypotheses. (1987) . One is the decline of hegemony thesis, or to put the hypothesis more generally: the decline of multilateral trade regimes. GATT is about dead; up come bilateral agreements in its place. Bilateralism in this version would then be a substitute for the order created by multilateral trade regimes. Without discussing the issue here, (1984) I agree with Strange that hegemonial power has not really declined, at least not to the extent claimed by hegemonial stability theories. Multilateralism has, however, been much weakened since the breakdown of the system of stable currency exchange rates. A second hypothesis is found in the serious imbalances in the balance of trade and payments position of a great number of countries. This is partly related to the debt crisis: lack of foreign currency has forced many countries in the South to seek financing of imports by paying not in cash, but in goods. But even several industrialised countries have engaged in bilateralism for about the same reason. This holds not only for the number of offsets in military-related deals, States and others, but even for the United like France, which have experienced serious deterioriation of their foreign accounts balances. The EC and the United States have been the most active parties seeking VERAs and OMAs in their relations with Japan and the South East Asian NICs. This may be referred to not simply as old-fashioned protecti- 16 onism but bilateral protectionism. The effect of the deal is, intended or not, quite often to exclude third parties from a market. Bargaining strength becomes a greater asset than quali- ty or other comparative advantages. Vulnerability of one country in its relationship with some other, more efficient country is controlled by a bilateral arrangement that transfers the vulnerability to third parties. This is not always the case; there are cases where a VERA has opened up a market for third parties while blocking the party whose trade is regulated by the arrangement. There is one final hypothesis, however, that seems to be of increasing validity: the industrial restructuring hypothesis. This is particularly related to the wave of countertrade and has both an offensive and a defensive motive attached to it. The offensive motive is that of the NICs. Their export industri- alisation strategy has required that in order to be able to finance huge industrial projects and secure their functioning for some time in the future, industrial co-production projects have been set up. These projects imply that the TNC delivering the technology supplies a range of assistance and, as partial or full payment, take back some part of the resulting production. Estimates are that this type of countertrade, industrial counter- trade, has grown in importance relative to the more traditional, commercial countertrade. Over the recent years, starting 1986, a third form, financial countertrade, has been initiated. It means that debt positions are swapped with goods with capital as equity or other investment (debt-for-goods) or (debt-far-equity) . The defensive motive is found first of all in the practice of poor and weak countries in the South and the Southern European belt in particular to compensate for lack of currency and competitive ability by asking for countertrade arrangements to maintain their market shares. They would normally ask for commercial deals, in other words: they operate in a declining sector of the world economy. But the defensive motive is also detectible in the actions of the United States towards Japan. With a growing deficit in the trade balance, protectionism has grown correspondingly and resulted in demands for reciprocity in transactions of goods and 17 services between the two economies. Some political factions in the United States have even demanded sector-by-sector balancing of exchanges. Such a measure would amount to fargoing regulation of trade that would be a complete negation of the free trade ideology. Also, there have been attempts to play on mutual vulnerabilities, in e.g. a US embargo of soybean exports to Japan. Japanese vulnerability in essential goods (and security) were to be used as a bargaining chip to obtain reduced US vulnerability when it comes to maintaining foreign markets for US manufacturing industry. All these forms are in some way or other, and to some degree, attempts to control against increased vulnerability at the national and/or corporate level. One may thus say that the general motive is to attempt to control the effects of international restructuring, either by simple unilateral protectionism or, a more preferred option as it seems, by bilateralism. Some implications for theorv. I shall leave the concrete case and end by a few remarks on possible implications for theory. These remarks and the concrete suggestions which I make, are preliminary. 4 Vulnerability is lack of control over something that is of interest to you. Let us assume that it is possible to adapt our model to the conditions imposed by complex interdependence. Now, it is quite obvious that some part of that lack of control derives from systemic, impersonal factors related to any one actor) and that it may vary over time (not (the dynamism of vulnerability) . Both these aspects will have to be taken into account when attempts are made to construct a model of vulnerability. The model, in other words, needs to be both contextual and relational, Having said this, both situational and dynamic. and with the critical comments on game are indebted to Bachrach and Lawler, 1984 and to Aslak H e m e s , 1975 as well as to work done by an assistant, Brun during 1986-87. They will be developed further in a research project on comparative foreign economic policies that was initiated in 1987. 18 theory's simplications, we may still draw some benefits from adapting a simple two-actor model. The idea behind the model is that it is possible to manipulate either the interest or the control variable, or both. It may even be claimed that the following model can be applied to multiple-issue and multipleactor relationships. Examples of an element of interest are: a vital resource, a commodity, access to technology or a market share, and a collective or an individual good (to confine our examples and the reasoning that follows to political economy) . Control is effective power. When the two are combined, we have the following classification of strategic options: 1 • The actor may reduce others' control over that which he himself is interested in. 2. The actor may reduce his interest in that which is controlled by others. 3. The actor may increase his own control over that which is of interest to others. 4. The actor may increase others' interest in that which he controls himself. This classification is valid both for symmetrical (typi- cally bargaining) (domination) situations and for asymmetrical relationships. But how realistic is it ? The first hypothesis. The debt case discussed above already shows that the first of these propositions may be invalid. In that case, in question (Mexico) the actor could benefit from the fact that others controlled its financial situation through debt. The Mexican Rescue apperars to have been decided upon and implemented within a few hours. That is the kind of instant operation that you expect from people who know that the threat comes from a person sitting on a fire bomb: if it explodes, all of them will go. In the case of trade bilateralism, there appears to be an important element of cooperative strategy through shared control of respective vulnerabilities. For those actors who 19 become parties to such bilateral deals, it may be an efficient substitute for multilateral rules. The national or corporate interest would then take precedence over the collective. all actors had access to bilateralism, If then the outcome would be about the same as under the MFN clause or other nondiscrimination rules in GATT. That is most certainly not the case: some of the rationale for bilateralism is its selective character, its character as an individual or dual good. To those parties involved, bilateralism may offer more pre- dictability, and hence less vulnerability, than does no deal at all. In times of rapid restructuring and change, only the monopolist and those who are sure of their competitive edge are willing to risk the vote of the market indefinitely. This is the logic behind the fact that more countries and corporations are fleeing the market than during any period since the 1930s. Returning to the first hypothesis and its counter-hypothesis, there is reason to doubt that the latter is more valid. Loan financing has become more difficult for all but the most indebted and the biggest debtors. The latter are big enough to represent a real difference, a threat to the stability of the world financial system. Besides, they are important economic and political partners. For the rest, no such "special treatment" like that accorded to Mexico and a few others is possible. On the contrary, indications are that they have become more, not less vulnerable to the decisions of the core North than they were some years ago. The second hypothesis. Several studies highlight the power of the big importer. (Hir- schman, 1945; Aggarwal, 1985) He may threaten the export- er with closing down his imports. By doing that he will threaten third parties with having to take over the diverted exports; this makes domestic market producers more vulnerable. Assuming in this case that the importer is big in terms of share of international trade in the product, he may use this position - dependence on something of interest that others control - in bargaining with exporters (and third parties) stance, in order, for in- to obtain concessions in some other field (linkage polit- 20 ics) . The third hypothesis. Turning to the third of the four hypotheses that were presented above, the counter-hypothesis would be that an actor may reduce his vulnerability the more he reduces his control over some element of interest to others. Think of the vulnerable position of a small Third World country attempting to exercise national control over its own resources, which might be some strategic mineral and which might also be under the control of a big power or corporation (or both) . This is definitely not to say that the country concerned had bette give up exercising such control (something that many a country has had to do) . It only emphasises that economic nationalism and national vulnerability may have to live side by side. Some Central American countries have probably had experiences with such a situation. The more obvious example to which the counter-hypothesis may apply is, again, the debt crisis. For several of the huge debtors, includind Mexico, it may be said that they did not control that element which was in the interest of the creditors: that loan commitments were being met. And this lack of control was indirectly working as a bargaining chip because the countries concerned were believed by creditors when they told them they were out of control. Creditors simply, in their own interest, had to come to the rescue. Now, there is obviously an appendix to this conditionality. The price tag attached to extending new loans to finance repayment of old ones is a matter for discussion in some other context. Suffice it to say that it may represent a greater - or a real - vulnerability at some future time if or when it turns out that the fuit en avant that both parties make in handling the crisis or in postponing it, is no longer possible. Again the write-offs of debt that started in 1986-87 are proof that parties have begun to realise this. The fourth hypothesis. The fourth and final hypothesis says that you reduces your own vulnerability by increasing the interest of others in something that you control yourself. But as Bachrach and Lawler show, your 21 partner in such a process may get a stronger urge to pressure or to work on you in other ways in order to extract concessions from you (op.cit. p. 64) The interest dimension in this case clearly has a double edge. A low level of interest in you from others may be an advantage if you are without the power to icnfluence them. In this case, self-sufficiency would seem to be an optimal choice. This seems especially true if you are yourself strongly interested in the item concerned. A small producer of a strategic mineral might be wise to process it before export, or better, using it as a base for the purpose of manufacturing goods to be consumed at home. In some cases an item that is small per se in terms of its interest to others, may have a large interest in a wider, systemic perspective. Again the Peruvian debt policy after 1985 is a case in point. For the creditors, Peru's accumulated debt as well as the annual repayments due on it had little impact on their own financial position. The weight of the Peruvian debt was and is a function of the perceived impact on the other debtor countries of the Peruvian policy of restricting repayment. The fear of a debtor cartel may be exaggerated. The fear of some sort of a domino effect may be much more real. Conclusions. The purpose of the paper was a multiple one. First, the epiBtemology of interdependence, I discussed selecting the vulnerability dimension as both the more relevant and the more interesting one. I made a strong point about the role of power and its implications for vulnerability analysis. In that connection, I made a special point about the possibility that weak or inferior party in a relationship of asymmetrical power distribution, in fact may exercise power. Potential power is not necessarily effective power. On the other hand, impotence in a structural relation of power asymmetry may turn out to be potent at the end. Then I made a point of opposing four hypotheses with their counter-hypotheses. That exercise showed that the four strategies for reducing vulnerability were only partially resistant to changes in environmental conditions. From that, one may conclude that more case studies are necessary if theory is to be developed further. Moreover, there 22 is a need to differentiate better between various aspects of power on the one hand and the relationship between power (potential) and structure of a given relationship on the other hand. Finally, we need to posit the discussion of interdependence and vulnerability in a context of systemic causes and effects. The vulnerability position of actors is not only conditioned by changes of a general systemic nature races, (stagflation, restructuring etc) . Strategies to cope with vulnerabilities also affect systemic variables. In some cases, paradoxically, systemic effects may make it easier to remain vulnerable. Or several vulnerability-affected actors may find it opportune to seek collective solutions to their problem. Bilateralism in world trade is partly explained by this factor. One may also find examples of collective or cooperative solutions involving several actors at the same time. Interdependence is a loose concept, but it may be made both more precise and quite fruitful if it is developed. If it is not, it will finally end up as a phrase for the rhetorics of international politics and of foreign policy. *) I am indebted to Olav Schram Stokke, Aslak Brun, Dag Harald Claes and to participant at the Groningen conference, November 1986 for comments on the draft. The final result is however all my own responsibility. REFERENCES VINOD AGGARWAL, Liberal Protectionism: The International Politics of Organized Textile Trade Berkeley, (University of California Press, 1985) PETER BACHARACH and MORTON LAWLER, Outcomes DAVID A. BALDWIN Bargaining: Power, Tactics and 1984) 'Power analysis and world politics: new trends versus old techniques', in World Politics, no. 2, 1979 DAVID A. BALDWIN, 'Interdependence and power: a conceptual 23 analysis', in International Organization, no. 4, vol. 34, 1980 C. FRED BERGSTEN, 'The Threat from the Third World' , Foreign Policy, no. 11, Summer 1973; and 'The Threat is real' , in no. 14, Spring 1974. EDMUND DELL, The Politics of International Economic Interdepend- (Macmillan, London 1987) M. B. DOLAN ET ALS, 'Foreign Policies of African States in ence. Asymmetric Dyads' , in International Studies Quarterly, vol. 24, no. 3, 1980 RAYMOND DUVALL, M. J. GOSIOROWSKI, 'Economic Interdependence and International Conflict: Some Cross-National Evidence' , in International Stud- ies Quarterly, no. 30, 1986 JOSEPH HANLON, Apartheid's Second Front. GUDMUND HERNES, (Penguin, London 1986) Makt og avmakt (Power and Powerlessness) (Univer- sitetsforlaget, Oslo 1975) ALBERT 0. Trade. HIRSCHMAN, National Power and the Structure of Foreign (University of California Press, Berkeley 1945) 'Militarization of Nature: Conflict and Control over Natural Resources and some Implications for Peace Policies' , in HELGE HVEEM, Journal of Peace Research, no. 1, vol. 16, 1979 HELGE HVEEM AND RAINO MALNES, Military Use of Natural Resources. (The International Peace Research Institute, Oslo 1980) 'Mini-NIEO and the Dependency Issue. Structural and Political Aspects of National Vulnerabilities' . Paper presented HELGE HVEEM, at the Conference on Preferential Arrangements between Developed and Developing Countries, November IDS/WIDER, Helsinki 1986 HELGE HVEEM, 'Export Organisation and contractual Relationships in International Trade. The Emergence of Bilateral Protectionism' . Oslo, Institute of Political Science, PETER KATZENSTEIN, versity Press, 1987 Small States in World Markets, (mimeo) (Cornell Uni- Ithaca 1984) ROBERT 0. KEOHANE AND JOSEPH N. NYE, Power and Interdependence. (Little and Brown, Boston 1977) VICTOR NORMAN, En liten åpen økonomi (A small open economy), (Un- 24 iversitetsforlaget, Oslo 1983) KENNETH A. OYE, in K. A. Oye, Donald Rotchild, and Lieber, Robert J. Eagle Entangled: US Foreign Policy in a Complex World. (Longman, New York 1979) Introduction. RICHARD ROSECRANCE ET ALS, 'Whither Interdependence?'. in Inter- national Organization, no. 3, vol. 30, 1977 THOMAS SCHELLING, The Strategy of Conflict. (Harvard University Press, Cambridge 1960) 'The struggle for the world product' , HELMUT SCHMIDT, Affairs, no. Foreign 1979 JAMES SEBENIUS, Negotiating the Law of the Sea (Harvard Universi- ty Press, Cambridge 1984) 'The Politics of Linkage' , in World Politics, ARTHUR A. STEIN, no. 33, October 1980 SUSAN STRANGE, ed. Paths to International Political Economy, (Longman, London 1982) M. A. TETREAULT, 'Measuring Interdependence', in International Organization, no. 3, vol. 34, 1980 JAMES WALSH, 'The role of countertrade in international trade' , Paper delivered at a seminar at FLACSO, Costa Rica, November 1985. KENNETH WALTZ, 'The Myth of International Interdependence' • in Charles P. Kindleberger, ed. The International Corporation, (The MIT Press, Cambridge 1970)