1979 Vol. XVI No.1 1 Helge Hveem: MUltllrlzetlon of Neture: Conflict end Control over Streteglc Re8Ource. end 80me Impllcetlon. for PNce Pollcle. 27 Ekkehert Krlppendorff: Mlnorltle., Violence, end Peece Re· ..erch 41 Steven I. Jeck8On: CepltlIllet Penetretlon: Concept end Mee· .urement 57 Vegerd Bye: Netfonellzetlon of OUln Venauele. Re-deflned Dependence end Legltlmlzetlon of ImperleU.m 79 Wllllem Eckherdt: Globel Compe••lon end Compul.lon 87 Book Note. 91 Booke Received I S S N 0022-3433 Journal o f P e a c e R e s e a r c h , N o . 1 , V o l . X V I , 1979 Militarization of Nature: Conflict and Control over Strategic Resources and Some Implications for Peace Policies* HELGE HVEEM International Peace Research Institute, Oslo Military consumption of natural resources is o n e of the p r o b l e m s which figure p r o m i n e n t l y in the United Nations' action p r o g r a m m e on disarmament and development. Reporting on a s t u d y t h a t w a s i n i t i a t e d i n 1975 a n d w h i c h h a s m e t w i t h c o n s i d e r a b l e p r o b l e m s i n g e t t i n g access t o i n f o r m a t i o n , t h e a u t h o r p r e s e n t s o r i g i n a l d a t a o n m i l i t a r y - r e l a t e d c o n s u m p t i o n o f energy and minerals in t h e U n i t e d States a n d elsewhere. After t h e so-called 'oil crisis', d e c i s i o n - m a k e r s a n d strategists h a v e s h o w n i n c r e a s e d c o n c e r n o v e r e x t e r n a l s u p p l y o f strategic resources a n d h a v e c o m e up with proposals on h o w to deal with vulnerable supply lines. These a n d other options a r e surveyed. It is c o n c l u d e d that t h e m a j o r powers, w h i c h a r e a l s o t h e p r i n c i p a l a r m s p r o d u c e r s a n d e x p o r t e r s , still m a y s e c u r e s u p p l i e s b y m e a s u r e s , including imperialist practices, at t h e international level. At the s a m e time, d e p e n d e n c e on strategic resources domestically n o t available m a y be r e d u c e d by m e a s u r e s internal to t h e importing country. Technological innovations have reduced the relative d e m a n d for m a n y minerals and are increasingly making composite materials available for military purposes. Still, t h e a r m s r a c e c o n t i n u e s t o a b s o r b g r e a t q u a n t i t i e s o f a n u m b e r o f n o n - r e n e w a b l e materials. D u e to t h e close integration of state interests with those of private capital, co-ordination between t h e m is the rule rather t h a n the exception. Purely military-strategic interests m a y sometimes not coincide completely with those of state or private capital, but usually the latter is 'collecting' the necessary foreign resources for the former through the process of i n t e r n a t i o n a l i z a t i o n . T h e s e facts m a k e c o n t r o l o f s u p p l y , f o r t h e p u r p o s e o f r e s t r i c t i n g o r d i v e r t i n g m i l i t a r y c o n s u m p t i o n , difficult — b o t h a t t h e n a t i o n a l a n d t h e i n t e r n a t i o n a l l e v e l . S o m e such measures of control are presented a n d discussed, ranging from imposing taxes through regulating t r a d e to supervising a r m a m e n t s industries in t h e arms-producing countries. 1. Introduction The militarization of the international system and the mobilization of support for a new world order are contending and largely contradicting processes. In this contest, the p r o cess of militarization has been getting the upper hand. One reason is that the interpenetration between the military and the political-economic spheres of the international system is highly advanced. D u e to a strong trend towards internationalization of the process of interpenetration, it now encompasses the whole global setting. Obviously, there are many ways of accounting for interpenetration processes. In the tradition of Leninist imperialism theories, the globalization of the military is a necessary outgrowth of the internationalization of capital. According to this tradition, the military system follows the logic of monopoly capital in its pursuance of profit world-wide, as an integral part of the profit strategy, or perhaps more importantly as its security guarantee. T h e close integration or subordination of the military with the economic sphere is, however, recognized not only in the Leninist tradition. In the words of the Chairman of the US Joint Chiefs of Staff, O u r current (military) c o m m i t m e n t s to fortyo n e foreign countries are entirely consistent with a n d reflect o u r d e p e n d e n c e o n f r e e - f l o w i n g i n t e r national trade, and the forward deployment of our military forces continues to support these imp o r t a n t e c o n o m i c interests. ( B r o w n , 1975) In the Schumpeterian tradition, at the other extreme, the military system per se expands beyond national boundaries into imperialism, waging war as a manifestation of 2 Helge Hveem national aggressiveness, contrary to the interests of capital. Positioned somewhere between those two poles, a more open-ended and less unilinear explanation is found, represented by Hobson and Galtung among others. While accepting a certain inter-penetration of the spheres, this explanation proposes that inter-penetration and internationalization — notably in the form of imperialist behaviour — may originate in any one of the respective spheres. In other words, capitalist accumulation and profit interests do not a priori take pre-eminence over purely military-strategic interests that may follow from the logic of warfare under conditions of modern world-wide military apparata. I believe there is much to be said in favour of the last argument. However, I propose here to view the question of causal explanation in a somewhat different perspective. As pointed out in an earlier contribution (Hveem, 1973) the military has played a decisive role in setting up global dominance relationships over centuries: in some periods and/or in certain geographical areas with seemingly little economic justification, in many others with such justification. To disentangle political-economic justifications for foreign penetration from military-strategic ones would seem less relevant when an overall historical perspective is chosen, a perspective which emphasizes patterns of evolution at the global level and over long periods. It may, however, be relevant in a more limited perspective and for important specific cases. T h e Cold War and the US national security doctrine with respect to many Latin American countries would be cases in point. My assumption is that the causal relationship is complex and that simplistic unilinear reasoning usually is unsatisfactory. It is not my intention to deal with the problem exhaustively in this paper, nor to elaborate on theory. Rather, my purpose is to cover a particular aspect of the complexity discussed: military penetration of the ecological sphere, or more correctly the military's expropriation of non-renewable natural resources, and its economic and political implications. Then I want to discuss what can be done to limit or stop this form of expropriation. 2. On the militarization of the world economy First, a few assumptions and some hypotheses regarding the causation problem. The first assumption follows from the interpenetration thesis: the 'world economic order' and the 'global military order' both must be analyzed as parts of a system of dominance on a global scale. This system is managed through the power of a few units capable of making authoritative decisions for the system. They organize other units according to an imposed value-hierarchy, in a vertical division of labour and unequal sharing of wealth, all structured around world-wide centre-periphery relations. My second assumption is that the inter-penetration of the military system with the economic, cultural, social, and other 'subsystems' takes place at different levels of social organization: at the personal level, at the level of class belongingness through the co-incidence of particular group interests, and through the state and the character it assumes, particularly in the dominant centre(s) of the system. T h e concepts militarization and militarism refer to these twin processes: respectively the tendency for military-strategic interests and military-industrial apparata to grow and to take on an increasing scale and influence, expanding globally; and the tendency for these phenomena to manifest themselves in ideas and value systems throughout society, notably in the political decisionmaking process, and at various levels of social organization. T h e state assumes an important and complex role in this context. Besides its operative and integrative role, it also has a legitimizing function. Whereas the state certainly has no monopoly on the exercise of force, domestically or abroad, it still claims to be 1 Militarization of Nature the one institution vested with a legitimate right to use force. The same goes for those fields of activity that cover production and distribution of the instruments of force. Concretely, this means that international deals in e. g. weaponry normally have to be sanctioned by the state, even if private corporate agents — at least under conditions of capitalism — are the operating force. This has certain policy implications that will be dealt with later. In these capacities, the state seldom acts as a monolithic institution. It may act out as the agent of a class, of corporate interest, of big business as a whole. But it will frequently have to reconcile these with varied other interests such as those of the military leadership, diplomatic considerations, of industrial workers, or even take into account protest movements. Moreover, state bureaucracies are characterized by internal cleavages. This is a function of the orchestrating role of the state in a society of contradicting interests where strict dictatorship or other types of rule by the few is either not possible or insufficient. 2.1 Some hypotheses There are several possible explanations of militarization of the periphery at the international level, many of which reflect these tendencies of sectoral and state-capital inter-penetration. These explanatory factors include: a) The exponentially growing arms p r o duction which is increasingly resource-consuming and which continues unabated by the economic crisis. It has to expand in order to sustain the growth and profit rates of the military industry. b) The dominant military apparata (i. e. those of the superpowers), for reasons of their own strategic and other needs, must globalize their lines of operation for both strategic and defensive purposes, through the establishment of bases, communication infrastructure, alliance, patrolling of foreign waters and territory, war-waging assistance, etc. 2 3 c) Partly opposed to this tendency, partly as an alternative to it, there is a trend towards de-centralizing war-waging to become the responsibility of periphery agents, though there is still a basic dependency on the dominant centre through arms trade or aid training and other assistance programmes, subcontracting of weaponry production, etc. This tendency may occur for military-strategic reasons, for instance because of technological, organizational or logistical factors, but is as likely to result from political factors such as mounting opposition to direct centre involvement in periphery wars, opposition which may occur both among allied forces outside the centre as well as domestically (the popular protest or 'Vietnam effect'). Technological changes have reduced the need for globalizing centre-based military apparata — what was referred to under (b) — to be extended to the periphery, making war-waging assistance by these apparata more important. T h e main technological changes behind this new trend are increased speed and the advance of satellite communication and observation systems. d) On the other hand, centre 'interventionism' in the periphery may increase, due to mounting opposition against the dominance relationship from non-allied forces outside the centre. Such opposition is directed not only against the centre actor, but also against its 'bridgehead' agents in the periphery or semi-periphery; it thus responds to calls from such agents for p r o tection against domestic challenges (the master-client or 'Latin America' effect). e) The military becomes a commodity, entering 'normal' exchange relations between nations. This may be due to one or several of the following factors: — t h e n e c e s s i t y f o r e c o n o m i e s of s c a l e in a r m s p r o d u c t i o n d u e t o h i g h initial R & D o u t l a y s a n d o t h e r f a c t o r s , cf. ( a ) , l e a d s t o i n c r e a s i n g p r o d u c tion b e y o n d domestic requirements in the a r m s p r o d u c i n g n a t i o n . T h e excess p r o d u c t i o n h a s t o b e offset a b r o a d , t h o r u g h e x p o r t s o r l i c e n s e d s u b contracting production; — i n c r e a s i n g l y difficult b a l a n c e - o f - p a y m e n t s p r o b - 4 Helge Hveem l e m s w i t h a m o u n t i n g deficit i n t h e t r a d e i n n o n m i l i t a r y g o o d s i n p r a c t i c a l l y all a r m s - p r o d u c i n g countries lead t h e m to maximize use of military goods exports in order to balance their payments position; — in o r d e r to secure vital non-military goods, particularly t h o s e vital for t h e military sector itself, m i l i t a r y g o o d s a r e o f f e r e d f o r w h a t m a y b e b a r t e r d e a l s o r o t h e r tie-in a r r a n g e m e n t s . 3 f) Finally, and related to the factors just mentioned, production and sales of the instruments of force is a highly oligopolistic business, both at the level of countries and at the corporate level, leading to oligopolistic competition at the international level. (Väyrynen, 1977) These are some of the most important push and pull factors in the process of periphery militarization at the international level. This paper deals with one particular aspect of the process — the ways and means whereby dominant centres may gain access to supply or resources vital to their military apparata, and the ways and means of limiting or stopping this tendency as part of arms control and disarmament measures. I will first describe the type and extent of resource consumption by the military. Then I discuss the question of access to supplies of natural resources, problems of dependency, and the nature and extent of integration between state and private capital in securing access. Thirdly I will discuss various possible ways by which present consumption patterns may be changed by the dominant centre actors. Some policy implications will be drawn. Finally, I will suggest possible ways by which military consumption may be controlled internationally or otherwise, for the treble purpose of limiting resource depletion, halting the arms race, and meeting demands for periphery development. 3. Consumption of natural resources by the military 3.1 The data problems There is a considerable problem in getting information on military consumption of natural resources. No systematic data sources are available even approaching those existing for military production and consumption of hardware final products. There are relatively complete and accurate data for the United States and some very few and highly incomplete data for the other major capitalist weapon-producing countries. Attempts by this author to get comparable data for France proved futile. T h e Soviet Union and China PR are also blank spots in the data matrix. Data for dominant centre countries other than the United States may be inferred from various other information such as the size of the national military apparata, arms industry output, aggregate national economic and industrial statistics, and so on. As my observations are not necessarily dependent upon the extent by which global military consumption of resources can be correctly assessed, information on the United States will usually suffice. However, it could be rather important, not least for the purpose of proposing policy, to have such data made available. T h e term 'military consumption' raises some methodological problems. It is not only a matter of consumption by the armed forces and their equipment, or what may be called 'direct military consumption'. Three more categories should be considered: First, that part of the economy directly related to the military system; it would consist of the strategic stockpile, military R & D programmes, that part of industry which is both devoting much of its productive capacity to arms production and which also represents the backbone of the armaments industry in terms of R & D skills, size, and overall capacity. Secondly, that part of the economy which is indirectly related to the military system and which would consist of goods and services daily consumed by the military other than the crucial hardware and infrastructure, of essential transport facilities; it would also consist of the industry which is supplying the military with marginal equipment and which also produces for the military system only marginally. Thirdly, there is the support economy, the rest of the Militarization of Nature economy in terms of goods, services, and production facilities essential to the normal functioning of the nation and vital under conditions of strain. Levine and Yabroff (1975) have suggested a simpler way of classifying consumption of natural resources. They define 'direct military consumption' as 'the material that an industry uses to manufacture the product it sells to D o D ' . * 'Indirect military consumption' covers 'the material consumed by a given industry to manufacture products that are sold to other industries for input to the manufacture of products that are in turn sold to D o D ' . This and several other sources report data on military consumption based on extensive input-output analyses of the US economy. There is a certain error margin in the data, but the margin is assumed to be acceptable. Estimates are also made for E u r o p e and Japan. USSR consumption may be roughly assessed from various other sources, but constitutes a problem. This is even more so for China. According to the US Department of D e fense, current US military consumption of energy, estimated at about 6 % of total US consumption, will treble in the event of major war. (Senate Hearings, FY 1978.) According to the Council on International Economic Priorities (1974), US consumption of critical materials required for military-related production and services is generally regarded as between 10 and 20 % of total US consumption in the event of war, and half of that 'in peacetime'. West European consumption is estimated at between 7 and 15 % and about half of that, respectively. This estimate is arrived at by assuming that military consumption of natural resources corresponds to the ratio of military expenditure to total G N P for these countries. If the same measure is ap- * Refers to D e p a r t m e n t of Defense a n d inc l u d e s all m i l i t a r y sales i n t h e U n i t e d S t a t e s , i n c l u d i n g t h o s e m i l i t a r y g o o d s w h i c h a r e finally e x ported. 5 plied to China, the Soviet Union and the Warsaw Pact countries, it is reasonable to assume that Soviet consumption of natural resources for military purposes lies somewhat below that of the United States but relatively higher than that of Western E u r o p e . It is also assumed that the consumption of China and the Eastern E u r o pean countries is relatively lower than that of Western Europe. Huisken has estimated that the militaryrelated consumption of natural resources of the United States, in terms of volume, is more than half the total world consumption for military purposes (1975). This obviously relates to the production level, not the level of final demand for military hardware, and included exports. If exports of the final products were deducted, the share in militaryrelated natural resource consumption of arms-importing countries logically would increase. This type of input-output analysis, however, is beyond the scope of the present paper. 4 5 3.2. Energy One source estimates direct energy consumption of the US military system worldwide at 2460 trillion Btus in 1971. In that same year, 'military-related' consumption (that is the energy consumed by those industries which supply the military system with goods and services) was 1870 trillion Btus (Mow & Ives, 1974). This means that between 4 and 7 % of the total US consumption of energy by industry and by utilities producing energy, is consumed by the military sector. By comparison, US direct military consumption of petroleum equalled 2/3 of all of Africa's total consumption in 1974. If private and governmental consumption of energy is included in the total, direct military consumption of energy accounts for some 3 % of total energy consumption in the United States (early 1970s) or 7 % of total consumption of petroleum (Westing, 1977). If 'direct military' and 'military-related' consumption of energy are added, they then would probably 6 Helge Hveem account for some 7-8 % of total energy use in the United States. 3.3. Raw materials Several studies report on US military-related consumption of raw materials, especially non-energy minerals, in great detail. A l though these sources do not always agree (one example is titanium) they give a fairly accurate picture of military consumption by material and end-use (Hughes et al., 1975; Dresch, 1972; Levine & Yabroff, 1975; US Congress, Joint Committee on Defense P r o duction, 1975 and 1976). In fact, most of them base their statistics on US Bureau of Mines data. F o r a number of minerals, consumption by the military in the 1970s turns out to be far in excess of the 5-10 % figure reported as average above. F o r individual years, military consumption accounted for more than 40 % of total US consumption of titanium metal and thallium, more than 30 % of germanium and thorium, and more than 20 % of garnet, cobalt, and copper. T h e Vietnam W a r obviously must have increased consumption, but it seems not to any great extent. Hughes et al. (1975) report time-series data for military consumption of 74 minerals over the period 1963-1972. I selected 32 of these for closer scrutiny. They were the minerals which, relatively speaking, were most demanded by the military system or were highly demanded in absolute, though not as much in relative terms (such as iron), or both. T h e military's share of US consumption is reported in the Appendix, Table 1, along with trend data to show variations in relative demand over time, and finally the most important end-use. Throughout the period, military consumption accounted for more than 20 % of total US consumption of thallium, germanium, garnet, and thorium; and between 15 and 20 % of economically important minerals like cobalt and copper. Military consumption of some important minerals, however, was in relative decline over the period; this is true for copper (from 19.3 % share in 1963-66 to 15.5 % in 1969-72), cobalt (21.8 to 15.5 %, respectively), aluminium (8.3 to 5.8 % ) , thorium and beryllium. Minerals that were increasingly consumed by the military include mica sheet, molybden, mercury, antimony, and germanium. 4. Security of supplies: the strategic imperative Generally speaking, secure access to needed supplies of energy and raw materials is the overriding concern of both private capital and the military. In importance it overshadows the cost concern. This even holds for the petroleum economy, except perhaps for a brief period just after 1973, when a shock wave caught many state and business leaders and made everybody, from President to consumer, look to prices. What most of them seemed to have overlooked was the fact that higher prices can be absorbed by powerful and rich economic units, particularly able to make up for increasing outlays by loading the burden on others, internationally as well as nationally. But as we shall see later, certain parts of the military system were seriously affected and thus rightly concerned by increased oil prices. As far as non-energy minerals are concerned, technological development and the increasing emphasis on ever more sophisticated weaponry have lowered the cost of materials relative to other costs in arms development and production. All the major capitalist military powers are dependent on imports of resources, according to trends of the past few years increasingly so. (For some comparisons, see Appendix, Table 2(2).) The Soviet Union and China are not, or only in small measure. To state leaders and strategists, the fact that the discrepancy in national self-sufficiency follows ideological divisions gives reason for concern. But how serious is the threat really? Militarization of Nature by maintaining imperialist supply lines globally. Let us start with the worst assumption: that of a very high vulnerability. It is estimated that a 5 to 10 % shortage of energy could have 'large effects' on the US economy. (Levine &Yabroff, p. 79.) Energy is the most critical resource in this respect. Material resources shortages are somewhat less dramatic in their impact on the economy, but a 15 to 30 % cut in the supply of a dozen of the 32 materials referred to above could have serious effects on the economy and create stagnation or reduced production. (See Fig. 1.) Those materials most likely to reduce G N P under shortage conditions are, in decreasing order of impact, non-metallic titanium, platinum, cobalt, tin, chromium, aluminium, copper, silver, nickel and tungsten. F o r instance, a 20 % aluminium shortage would mean about 3 % reduction in US G N P . (Levine & Yabroff, p. 9.) 4 . 1 . Vulnerability In order to approach the question, we may adopt a distinction suggested by Keohane & Nye (1977). An economy is sensitive to the extent it is open to costly effects imposed from outside before policies can be introduced to change the situation. One measure of sensitivity would be import dependency, or the percentage of consumption that has to be imported. An economy, on the other hand, is vulnerable to the extent it can suffer costs imposed by external actors even after policies to change the situation have been introduced. Both aspects of dependency are reflected in the Appendix, Tables 2(2) and 3. F o r a realistic appreciation of the problem, however, we need to go much further than the Keohane-Nye concept of 'vulnerability dependency'. They mostly treat the problem in terms of domestic policies, such as substitution, increased recycling, stocking, and increased domestic production. All of these are relevant measures. What is overlooked is the potential for controlling against vulnerability through internationalization and Stockpiling. This would be a dramatic situation if no measures could be taken immediately to cover the shortage presum- 30~_~_~_~_~-.!..1~234~5!..,-~6~7...;8~.?9....!;10,---!1~121;:.2~ / I '/ 28 ~24 I I 2522 Z20 o 18 16 14 0:: 12 fZ 10 el I I I 11 /' ' 1111/ II I I I/ " I I I / b 9_ I, , I , I 1; 2: 3: 4: 5: 6: 7: 8: 9: 10: 'I/ ,',: ,/1,1,'" "'26 g /", I I I I I I I II1II I I I I I / ~ ~ I / / , , i1'1 "', ,'I I :,' / 'I I' / I I I I -?~/J:/) OIL--L_:................_ .......;;:;;;;;._?---._...,,:::::.......,_--J o 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 PERCENT SHORTAGE Fig.I: Effect! of Energy and Materi_l Sbortages on (U.S.) GNP. Source: Levine & Y_broff. 45 Gas Petroleum Coal Non-metallic titanium Platinum Cobalt Aluminium Nickel Zinc castings Tungsten 11: Lead 12: Metallic titanium I I I AI' 11/ , 11//1 8 I I "I I I I 7 50 8 Helge Hveem ably resulting from an embargo on supplies by exporting countries. A look at the US government stockpile balance, however, shows that there is such 'instant defence' against vulnerability. Stockpiles cover months and years of national consumption. Only in the case of cobalt and possibly nickel does there seem to be reason for concern. A n d if government and industry stocks are collapsed, the reason for concern is even further reduced. Import dependency is practically 100 % for such vital minerals as manganese, tin, chromium, and tungsten, but stockpiles may sustain consumption of up to several years under conditions of no major war, and may be around one or oneand-a half years under conditions of a major war. (Cf. App., Table 2(2)) T h e situation is probably considerably less favourable for other key N A T O countries and Japan. (Japan Economic Council, 1970). Thus, policies of stockpiling materials have been stressed in several countries and may in fact have resulted in decreased vulnerability. But vulnerability for the whole N A T O area still is considerable on this score and is reason for concern in military circles (Broekmeijer, 1963; Zeiner-Gundersen, 1978). In a study of N A T O dependency on strategic raw materials, commissioned by the US A r m y Command, Kevitz proposes a N A T O stockpile of such materials (1975). He recommenels either a common stockpile run by N A T O centrally, or nationallyheld stocks according to quantities and time for fulfilment to be jointly decided upon. T h e second option, which because it is more realistic also seems to be the favoured one, would be to create institutions similar to the International Energy Agency (IEA) for non-oil minerals and other raw materials. T h e N A T O Charter provides, in its A r ticle 3, for collective measures to secure supplies of strategic materials for military but not for overall economic purposes. This limitation seems to have been put aside in the newly created Committee on the Challenges of Modern Society (CCMS). T h e committee is sponsoring efforts for joint programmes in energy and raw materials. T h e situation in the Warsaw Pact in this regard is not known, but as the Soviet Union guarantees supplies of natural resources within the Pact, it can be assumed that she keeps these supplies under strict control. 4.2. Imperial (external) measures Stocking is the most readily available defence against vulnerability. As regards the external, international setting, there are basically four possible main lines of action: (a) to rely on internationalization, through operations of transnational corporations, to provide sufficient quantities of and acceptable prices for raw materials; (b) unilateral or multilateral action by the centre economy state, through diplomacy, aid or trade policies etc. with the aim of securing supplies from abroad; (c) to establish and maintain protectorates abroad by taking direct or indirect control over supply areas and sea routes so that supplies can be safely counted upon; (d) establish international regimes whereby regular supply of materials is guaranteed by mutual agreement or through international law. Multilateral regimes are insufficient. Option (d) is the Havana Charter and the G A T T model which is, in a somewhat new structure, also what U N C T A D negotiations are about. T h e G A T T regime, according to Article X I , prohibits imposition of export control except in cases where there is an international agreement, where national security interests are at stake, where the purpose is to assist domestic price-control programmes, or to prevent a critical shortage of foodstuffs or other products essential to the exporting country. The Atlantic Charter is the basis for the post-war 'free trade' regime in stating, in its Title IV, that a major goals is 'access on equal terms to the trade and the raw materials of the world' for all countries. T h e main intention of the United States and other centre economies was to open up Militarization of Nature markets. After 1973, there has been an increasing emphasis on open access to supplies of resources. Thus, the US Congress introduced an amendment to the trade bill that resulted in the T r a d e Reform Act of 1974. The act instructs the US government to enter into agreements with foreign countries to assure supplies of essential articles at reasonable prices and to include rules against denial of equitable access to supplies of materials. T h e President is also given wide authority to retaliate in case agreements are violated. (Hultman, 1976) The US government thus has introduced a system of sanctions unilaterally. On military-business relations. From a strategic-military point of view, a regime such as G A T T is not a sufficient guarantee of access to supplies. A guarantee can be obtained only through options (b) or (c); but for practical organizational purposes, either option would have to be combined with one of the others. Again, from a strategic-military point of view, option (a) is the preferred one among these, but (d) could be tolerated in the event that option (a) might no longer be sufficient or realistic — e. g. because of nationalizations of corporate interests in the periphery supply area. It should be kept in mind that the statemilitary establishment for some time after 1973 was making complaints about the oil companies concerning what they considered unfair pricing of products which the military required. (US Congress, 1975.) T h e administration vs companies quarrel over company compliance with A r a b governments also indicates that the state-business relationship is not always an eye-to-eye matter when it comes to foreign policy. Still, state and military interests generally coordinate with private capital and let the corporations collect the required resources with their support. The case of energy illustrates this well. Three-fourths of US military consumption falls on petroleum. F o r the Navy, which accounts for 1/3 of all US military energy 9 consumption, reliance on petroleum is 86 %. In 1976, the Navy procured close to 40 % of all its petroleum from foreign sources; in the Pacific and in E u r o p e almost all from foreign sources. US oil companies handled these procurements. (US Congress, 1977.) T h e same holds for the Air Force and the Army. If procurement of jet fuel is a valid indicator for energy supplies to the military and in general, there is a high degree of concentration. Exxon alone supplies 30 % of all U S A F jet fuel consumption, with Socal (12 % ) , Mobil (10.5 %) and Phillips (8.6 %) following next. Seven companies supply 80.5 % of all the jet fuel consumed by U S A F . (US Congress, 1975 II) 6 The 'protectorate' strategy: the need for being tough. Option (c) is both a more permanent and tougher measure than option (b). T h e former is exemplified by French relations to a number of African neocolonies such as Gabon, Niger, and the Central African Republic (N'Dongo, 1972) all of which are rich in some strategic mineral. And it is exemplified by Soviet policy t o wards Eastern E u r o p e (Stehr, 1977, and Galtung, 1976) and US policy towards a great number of countries. In these relations, there is a range of ties that link the periphery to the centre in subordination. These links may be intercepted by third parties, but there is little probability that they will be broken by the periphery part, or be allowed to be broken by the centre. One obvious form of interference is direct military intervention in the territory concerned; another form is interference with land or sea routes over which mineral supplies travel. T h e former is still a possibility, but may seem less likely in the form of direct, open intervention. There may, however, have been elements of this in the French operation, M a y 1978, in Shaba, so vital for copper and cobalt supplies to Western Europe. M o r e likely now is indirect great power support through providing experts and arms and by other forms of behind-the-scene support. Or by using a bellicus vicarius: the military forces of a client 10 Helge Hveem country. T h e Soviet-Cuban and the proposed NATO-protectorate African military force are cases in point. Interference with extended sea routes has been pointed out as a major concern in military and political circles. Supplies to Western E u r o p e and Japan are considered particularly vulnerable. (Wu, 1975) Here, the global strategy of US and Soviet military systems, in particular the deployment of important naval units in the Pacific, the Atlantic, the Indian Ocean, and the Mediterranean, has a geo-political reason. Option (b) is to be regarded as a softer line of action with respect to the means employed to secure supplies. Economic aid has been used extensively for the purpose, as has food aid under PL 480 (Wallensteen, 1976). T h e link to trade policies is close. Over the years, delivery of food has been linked to supply of some mineral(s) or other goods in return. T h e link to trade packages, however, may have gone much further. Thus, big deals between major arms-exporting and resource-exporting countries over the last few years have probably reduced considerably whatever element of vulnerability there might have been in those inter-state relationships concerned. Particularly noticable are the French-Saudi and the West German-Brazilian trade agreements involving nuclear reactors, plutonium technology, jet fighters for oil and other minerals. Include South Africa and Iran, and the big dealers of the periphery have been mentioned. These are the semi-peripheries, the aspiring sub-emperors or regional hegemonial powers in the periphery. In some cases, there are several countries involved in these tie-in arrangements, directly or indirectly. As an example, Iran and South Africa both import nuclear technology from France and West Germany, supply in return oil and uranium, respectively, but the two sub-emperors also exchange these minerals between themselves. In most cases, such tying-in seems to be more indirect and informal than direct. Also, there are strong elements of competi- tion. T h e strong resource position of a country like Saudi Arabia sometimes gives an image of the world turned upside down: A country of the periphery, previously subordinated to the feudalism of the global centre-periphery system where peripheries compete for a market in the centre which in turn plays split-and-rule tactics against the periphery, suddenly finds itself in a position to play on fierce competition between centre actors over its resources. A new 'First World'? This scenario, however, should not be carried too far. The sub-emperors are still dependent and can be controlled. Also, the centres or the emperors are still able to control their competition from escalating into a conflict reaching unmanageable levels. The fragility of the old hegemonial order and the need for coping with mutations have, however, led to strategic rethinking in some important circles. In N A T O circles, there seems to be increasing pressure to engage N A T O forces militarily and permanently in vital supply areas, notably the Persian Gulf - Atlantic and the Indian Ocean routes. (Zeiner-Gundersen, 1978.) The argument is that increasing Soviet naval presence in these waters represents a threat to N A T O supplies of vital materials and energy. This w o u l d — d e facto if not formally — mean a joint military venture with South Africa, eventually even Saudi Arabia. A second option that has been put forth is a retreat to a continental 'Fortress America'. It would be based on the rich resources both in the North and the South, including the continental shelf, and be defended by US military power (Ott, 1975). This proposal, put forth in National Defense, breaks with the belief in an inter-continental imperial necessity advocated by state and military leaders (cf above), but only partially since it falls back on a deepening of the M o n r o e Doctrine. T h e main argument is that a continental supply area is easier to defend than supply lines involving extra-continental areas. Militarization A third proposal is more in line with both the official doctrine and the imperial-subimperial system described above. It advocates the formation of a new 'First World' grouping which would consist of the strong industrial power-houses of the old First World (United States and West Germany plus Japan), nations that combine some industrial power with natural resource abundance (Canada, Australia, Brazil, South Africa), and finally resource-rich but nonindustrialized countries that will be vital for filling the energy equation (Saudi Arabi and Iran) (Harrigan, 1976). Its formation would require building-up strong global military systems 'capable of assuring the flow of strategic materials and preventing Communist intimidation of resource areas.' (ibid.) As the resource problem develops, the primary task of the military apparatus 'after physical defense of the homeland will be to support access to needed resources against constraints, interruptions, or denials, whether imposed by military force, by governmental actions, or by economic effects' (Lee, 1974). Evidence as to whether such a new First World is developing is as yet unsystematic. There has been a remarkable increase in the relative share of arms purchases from centre suppliers by especially Iran and Saudi Arabia, and a noticeable increase in the size and number of trade arrangements related to arms transfers. (SIPRI Yearbook, 1978) Most new investments by centre corporations and state bureaus in mineral exploration and exploitation take place within the New First World, particularly in Australia, Canada, Brazil and South Africa or South Africa-dominated regions (Namibia and Botswana). Saudi Arabia's new role as a world bankier has led it into the inner circles of the monetary system. And Iran's industrial potential has given that country a special treatment by centre corporations, viz the shares in the Krupp concern, in E u r o dif, and in North Sea explorations. The political upheavals in Iran do not seem to have broken this pattern, but they may o b - of Nature 11 viously change the picture as far as that country is concerned. These scenarios and policy proposals reflect widespread thinking in US industrial and military circles. Yet they may be too much coloured by over-reactions on the 1973 'oil crisis' in these same circles. T h e question therefore is whether developments actually indicate that one or the other of the new 'vertical ordering' of the world is underway. If so, it would run contrary to attempts to create a New International E c o nomic Order. It would also eventually mean increased conflict and possibly the breakdown of old orders like the N A T O alliance. Both the proposals mentioned are aimed at securing unrestricted supply of vital resources in 'outreach' control schemes under US hegemony. T h e second option, however, is clearly the most outreaching one; it is also most in line with current trends in international diplomatic relations and with the process of internationalization. South Africa's natural resources give the country a strong protective shield against the demand on Western great powers for economic and military sanctions against the apartheid regime. As yet, there is little evidence that this protection is becoming inefficient. On the contrary, it is more likely that the Shaba incidences, the mounting African pressure on the apartheid regimes, and the failure of the counter-revolutionary campaign against M P L A in Angola make not only South Africa, but the whole of Southern Africa, more vital to Western interests. We pointed out above that platinum, cobalt, and chromium were among the most critical materials because they represent the highest level of vulnerability. These are also materials which the Western economies get primarily from Southern Africa. F o r cobalt, chromium, manganese, platinum, copper, and, in a different way, for gold, uranium, and diamonds, these economies are vulnerable to drastic changes in the political regime in Southern Africa. T h e vulnerability of Western countries is 12 Helge Hveem even better reflected when one realizes that the major alternate supplier to the West of platinum, chromium, titanium, industrial diamonds, and a few other strategic minerals is the Soviet Union. O n e fourth of chromium and titanium and almost half the platinum consumption of the United States was in 1972 covered by imports from the Soviet Union. T h e same more or less holds for Western Europe. (Council on International Economic Policy, 1974) A revised 'vulnerability' concept. Geopolitics is important, but should not be overestimated. T h e percentage of consumption imported is but one indicator of externally-caused vulnerability. Another is the reliability of the supply sources. This reliability is a function of geography, of political-ideological factors, and of the probability that the supply area may be taken over by antagonists. Conflict over sources of strategic minerals is a matter not only of Soviet-US confrontations, but of fierce competition within the capitalist camp as well. (Marshall, 1973; North & Choucri, 1974) A revised typology of vulnerability dependence may thus be introduced: ( 1 ) Highly vulnerable supplies a r e t h o s e w h i c h either come from a strong cartel controlling a decisive share of e c o n o m i c a n d available resources a n d w h i c h i s less l i k e l y t o g i v e i n t o p r e s s u r e , threats of retaliation etc.; or w h i c h a r e t r a n s p o r t e d over long sea routes susceptible of being interfered with by antagonists, against which retaliation is n o t automatically feasible; or both. T h e O P E C e m b a r g o is a case in point. ( 2 ) Relatively vulnerable supplies are resources w h i c h a r e less s u b j e c t t o t h e s e a n d s i m i l a r f a c t o r s , a n d for which there are better options for avoiding rupture of supplies. S h a b a copper a n d cobalt are examples. ( 3 ) Relatively secure supplies w o u l d be t h o s e c o m i n g typically from sources which are politically close, b u t at s o m e geographical distance f r o m t h e i m p o r t i n g u n i t a n d less l i k e l y t o b e e x posed to threats of third party intervention. Examples would be Australian bauxite to North America. ( 4 ) Secure supplies w o u l d b e t h o s e i m p o r t e d from politically a n d geographically close areas, e x a m p l i f i e d by C a n a d a vis a vis t h e U n i t e d S t a t e s . I have made a rough estimate of what may be termed 'critical import dependency' again mainly using US data for the period 1973-75. In doing so, categories (1) and (2), (3) and (4) were collapsed, respectively, into two broad categories. In most cases, 'critical' imports are imports from the Third World and from Socialist countries. This is clearly an over-simplification of the distinction between critical and non-critical imports: many Third World countries presently are well-guarded protectorates. The right term would rather be potentially critical imports. T h e results are presented in the Appendix, Table 2(2). Particularly 'critical' minerals — bearing in mind the qualifications just made — are in order of import dependency and for the United States: mica sheet (97 % from potentially critical areas), graphite, tin, columbium, bauxitealumina, fluorine, chromium, and cobalt. Increasing nationalism in the Third World, increasing exposure of sea transports of vital materials to third party presence — and I repeat that the two factors are not a priori related — would tend to move the supply situation from category (4) towards category (1). T h e internationalization process no longer guarantees supplies in these cases. Some Caribbean countries (bauxite), certain O P E C countries and Southern Africa are areas where decreasing centre reliance on secure supplies is the dominant trend. Here, various measures such as reduced production (bauxite in Jamaica), the tying-in strategy (OPEC), and political and para-military intervention (Southern Africa) are being adopted and/or considered. Also, geographical diversification from less to more secure supply areas is actively being sought by corporations and governments (Hveem, 1977). It also should be kept in mind that some of the minerals concerned are highly monopolized. This is true for nickel (INCO), platinum (Rustenburg), diamonds (de Beers), zirconium (Wah Chang), and aluminium (the cartel of Six). If the production and first-level transformation are nationalized, Militarization of Nature monopolistic control over the market outlets still may make the difference and eventually make aggressive nationalizers bow after some time. (Hveem, 1977; Helleiner, 1978.) An indication that monopolistic internationalization still is a means to power is the fact that the Soviet Union sells much of its diamonds through a sales affiliate of de Beers, South Africa. (Business Week, 9 May, 1977) 4.3. Domestic measures A country with a strong reserve base in crucial minerals may be faced with three obstacles to supply security: time, technology, and commercial viability of production. As noted above, time and technology may be more important than costs. Ecological considerations may represent another obstacle, because these make it difficult to expand domestic production where important ecological interests with considerable popular support are threatened. Increased domestic production nevertheless is a goal. Time and technology are obviously linked. The potential for manipulating with these factors lies chiefly in substitution, recycling, and reduced absolute consumption through saving. Stockpiling as a measure against vulnerability dependency has already been mentioned. All the other measures mentioned are also being re-emphasized, not least by military-strategic planners. Let us therefore deal with each of them, assessing the potential for reduced vulnerability which they represent. Also, the inter-relationship of these factors must be kept in mind. Often, increased domestic production lies in substitutability at the level of industrial processes and products. Substitution. This combined strategy of substitution and increased domestic production to attain greater self-sufficiency comes out both in the field of energy and in that of materials. In energy, military-sponsored research on alternative energy sources is now being intensified. T h e goal is to cut petroleum consumption by developing synthetic fuel that will become commercial be- 13 fore 1985, first based on shale oil, later on coal and tar sands. Compared to the Soviet Union, the United States is extremely well endowed with these energy sources. (US Congress, 1977) Successful experiments have already taken place. Thus, the US destroyer USS Johnston was operated for 24 hours on coal liquids in November, 1973. Successful coast-tocoast jet flights have also been carried through on synthetic fuel. (Ibid.) T h e goal is to reduce military consumption of energy by 40-50 % by 1985 through savings of various forms. (Aviation Week & Space Technology, 8 Sept. 1975, p. 23) As indicated above, energy costs have been worrying military and state leaders as fuels for the military services quadrupled in price from 1974 to 1976. (AW & ST, 26 Jan. 1976) In materials, much the same pattern is seen. However, material consumption as a share of total financial outlays, globally and per unit, may be on the decline due to technological innovation, an increased relative share of electronical equipment, etc. T h e US Air Force is emphasizing the use of composite materials as a substitute for traditional single-metal materials, saving weight and costs by about 25 %. (AW & ST, 26 Jan. 1976) The A r m y is emphasizing use of the more abundant metals such as silicon, magnesium, aluminium; while the new materials from the viewpoint of aircraft corporations are boron and graphite, also among the most aboundant materials in the earth's crust. Graphite-epoxy, developed by Alcoa in cooperation with the major aircraft producers, is said to be the material of the 1980s. It is weight-saving and will make structures last longer. It has the further strategic advantage of not reflecting as much under radar surveillance as aluminium and steel alloys do. On the negative side is the fact that the United States is highly dependent on imports of graphite. T h e US could, however, improve self-sufficiency and/or get relatively secure supplies from neighbouring Mexico. Composite structures are being tested or already being flown in the General Dy- 14 Helge Hveem namics F-16, McDonnell/Northrop F-18, Rockwell's B - l bomber, and other aircraft. Metals will continue to play a major role, in that the composite aircraft will contain 30 % or more metal by weight because of temperature and curvature limitations of composites. T h e search is no longer for new alloys, as in the past, but for improving the properties of existing alloys. (Ibid., pp. 4 4 45.) To the extent this prediction also is valid for the Army and the Navy, where metals seem b o u n d to play a larger role compared to non-metal materials, and compared to the Air Force, we may conclude that strategic minerals have a somewhat reduced but secure future position in the armaments industry. Substitutability of materials is referred to as an important trump card for corporations that handle the technology and have access to many materials and sources. This is often an exaggeration. Modern industrial processes are rigid, because much capital has been invested in them. They are technically complicated, and considerable time and capital is needed if changes are to be made. Nickel is used in more than 300 alloys; manganese still is absolutely necessary for steel fabrication; and cobalt, wolfram, and a number of other materials are not readily substitutable even in the medium-term perspective. A N A T O study has estimated the percentage of the most strategic materials which cannot be readily substituted (and which therefore are indispensable both for the civilian and the military sector) at between 30 and 40 % on the average. ( N A T O , 1976) In another study by US researchers, the materials' substitutability is evaluated from the point of view of civilian economic usage. (Hughes et al.) T h e two studies differ considerably in their assessment of substitution possibilities, cf. Fig. 2 and Appendix, Table 3. There is agreement, however, that platinum, cobalt, and copper — to a lesser degree silver — are quite indispensable materials. This further stresses the geopolitical importance of Southern Africa. Recycling. Recycling requires a political will to promote it and economic incentives to invest in it. These motives are not always present. Thus, there has been a stagnation or decrease in the share of recycled material in national consumption over the last decade, according to information on the United States (Mighdoll & Weisse, 1976). Yet, the potential is there. Data on actual recycling rates are available for some materials for the United States, France, and West Germany. Three different data sources show considerable discrepancies in their estimates of actual and potential recycling. Hence, it is not possible to draw a clear picture of the situation and the potential. T h e information presented is only indicative. In a N A T O study, theoretical recycling levels of indispensible materials have been estimated, cf. Fig. 2. The study stresses that these are rough estimates that cover great variations among N A T O countries and are made with considerable uncertainty. Comparison with figures given in App. Table 3 and with those presented in another study (Hveem, 1977) underlines this. F o r several alloy metals, recycling is dependent on recycling of steel. One military source believes that there is great potential for steel recycling, especially in the military sector. In practice, however, recycling does not seem a major weapon for import-dependent economies. Becoming one would probably require considerable state intervention. Private capital would have important vested interests in the present structure which gives primacy to raw materials processing, and would thus not be inclined to escalate recycling. Saving through conservation and changed design. Around 7/10 of the metals mined each year are lost. At this rate, less than 0.001 % remains after ten use cycles. At present growth rates of metal consumption, recycling at current levels extends the life of the resources by less than 10 years. If recycling became twice as effective as at present, this would extend the life of resources by another 10 years. If, however, growth of consumption were reduced to Militarization of Nature 100 % ~ 80 % .--- 60 $I 40 % 20 % .---- e- ff- r- l.- - I.- I.- - f-- o% f- r- f-- f- Ag Cd Co Cu Hg Pb PI Sb So \V Zo E ~ u > " ~ ~ ;; .D u 0. 0. ~ "uu ~ '" •0 ~ " •.~ ,5 '".:l 0:: ~ ~ ~~0 N•u E '"'" a 8 8 ::!1 Essential (indispensable) ~ Fig. 2. and theoretical rates of recycling total consumption (NATO area) use of materials as percentage of Shaded area = fraction recyclable. The results are subject to much uncertainty and argument. Not only is there considerable variation between counrties but also the criteria for essential use are open to dispute depending on vested interests. Furthermore, substituting for one metal may throw an added burden on another. Nevertheless they indicate the broad scale of possible improvements. Source: Rational Use of potentially scare Report of a N A T O Science C o m m i t t e e Group, Brussels, 1976, p. 30. metals. Study 0.5 % per year, the life of the resource base — given present recycling rates -— would be extended by over 100 years. ( N A T O , 1976) This shows the crucial impact that saving on absolute consumption would have. A similar impact could be obtained in energy, where waste through losses is another major problem besides high absolute demand. R e duced weight, changed design, and more efficient use of a given volume of a mineral are all theoretically possible. T h e official goal of the Pentagon as regards energy was formulated recently. Primary conservation measures would be to (a) develop and implement operational 15 practices that will eliminate losses now incurred without losing effectiveness; and (b) develop new propulsion and auxiliary machinery technology with higher basic efficiency expectations than the present system. (US Congress, 1977) Considerably increased funds are now being made available for R & D efforts in these fields. T h e same holds for non-energy minerals. According to a N A T O study, chances for materials conservation should be better for state and military applications than for private consumer ones, because the former puts more emphasis on performance and prestige, less on costs, thus facilitating conservation through improved design. This assumption does not seem totally convincing. But it may be true, as the study assumes, that designers and engineers hold the key to the problem of resource conservation, because they make the first and thus vital decision on products. Military R & D institutions may play a marginally positive role in this respect to the extent their innovations offer civilian spin-offs. However, great leaps forward cannot be expected. Moreover, a continued arms race with ever shorter life-cycles for new weaponry — even if it stresses quality over quantity of arms — will mean continued growth of absolute consumption that may make up for any savings per unit. 4.4. Summary and conclusions In this paper I have illustrated and analyzed military appropriation of natural resources as an important part of the process of world militarization. This appropriation follows the logic of the internationalization of capital, which is both the main instrument by which resources are made available and at the same time a force necessitating and demanding the support of the state through its military apparatus. Although there are clearly elements of conflict in the relationship between state and private capital — with the military even at times acting as a pressure group on its own — the relationship is basically one of co-ordination and 16 Helge Hveem integration. I assume that this is particularly true in times and areas of crisis or perceived threat against targets of common interests. Access to and control over energy and raw materials is such a target. Various propositions on possible reasons for the increasing militarization of global centre-periphery relations are set forth. Only a few of these are explored here. In particular, the link between the internationalization of capital and various forms of trade, aid and interventionist policies by the state has been pointed out. Conflict over resources is assumed to be on the increase along nation-state divisions. However, Cold War type interpretations of e. g. conflicts in Southern Africa are much exaggerated. International regimes based on multilateral agreements between governments are insufficient as a guarantee of access, particularly from the viewpoint of the military. Tougher measures by the state, bilaterally or multilaterally through alliance formations, are necessary; these may supplement, not rule out, international regimes. Here, certain measures seem favoured over others, like advanced military patrolling of extended sea routes and overseas areas, packaging of strategic minerals to delivery of other goods and services, military goods and services assuming a more and more important role. Such trends go counter to efforts for a N I E O . Insofar as the 'New First World' consisting of the dominant centre economies and resource-rich periphery 'subemperors' is becoming a reality, the N I E O is undermined. To the same extent, new dimensions of conflict arise; other periphery countries follow a policy of resource nationalism, and they bargain with the centre — two of the main elements in the claim for a N I E O . These are not new trends: periphery disunity is as old as imperialism and its divide-andrule tactics. But the realization of subsystems of secure resource supplies involving important parts of the periphery will inevitably weaken the potential bargaining power of periphery raw material exporters working together in producer associations. Such a potential is there for bauxite, which by US military research institutions is ranked as the single most vulnerable strategic mineral for the United States. To a lesser extent the potential also exists for tin, iron ore, copper and some of the economically less important but industrially vital minerals. (Hveem, 1977.) Weighing external vs domestic measures to reduce vulnerability against each other, the best solution would be self-sufficiency. This is largely unrealistic. An optimal solution would be to strengthen the imperial grip on foreign resources while preparing better against potential counter-action by taking domestic measures. This would gain time and would maintain the interests of capital abroad, while making it possible to maintain global military interests in the name of the 'freedom of the seas', the 'free flow of goods', etc. A less than optimal strategy would be to rely even more on imperial supplies: this might be politically possible because of a break-down of periphery unity and because there will be periphery regimes willing to play the centre's game. Indeed, it may be politically and economically necessary because increased selfsufficiency may prove ecologically unfeasible and economically too costly, at least from the viewpoint of private capital. This picture may vary from one mineral to another and from one country or region to another. But the closer co-ordination of state and business interests in dealing with foreign economic policy proposed here makes the sub-optimal solution realistic, at least as an option for the 1980s. A major shift to relying on domestic measures could be possible only after a series of state interventions and technological breakthroughs. These are possible but seem less likely in that period. 5. Implications for peace policies: diversion and disarmament I have emphasized the strong current tendency to protect privileged access to natural Militarization of Nature resources under the assumption of unlimited growth of the military apparatus and its international spread. In major capitalist countries, the relative autharky of the Soviet Union and China is in fact used as an argument in favour of such a tendency. The arms race thus has a direct impact on the depletion rate of the world's resources, particularly resources located in Third World areas. This assumes particular importance as it become clear that the consumption of natural resources for military purposes is even more concentrated in the main military powers than is resource consumption generally. From the above conclusions it follows that policies aiming to increase chances for peace must work from two angles. They must reduce or restrict ecologically and economically unjust appropriation of natural resources and redress unequal o p portunities for growth and development in the present global dominance system. They must also improve chances for disarmament and arms control, thereby diverting resources, in a wide sense, to more justified political and social aims. Although these two goals are aspects of the same problem, they may be attacked independently, in various ways, and at various levels of social organization. In fact, successful implementation of military resource conservation programmes like those described above would help achieve the first-mentioned goal: but its explicit purpose would be to preserve the military system and the arms race, rather than halt it. Military systems are abnormal institutions. Ideally, their purpose is to guarantee personal security through national and/or international defence arrangements. T h e organization and scale of the modern military apparata are far out of proportion to this purpose: they threaten, not guarantee, personal and collective security. There is thus a great need for a thorough discussion of how much is enough: how much resource utilization is necessary, at the basic level, for guaranteeing security. This question 17 would not only necessitate a discussion of the security concept. It would change perspectives radically and provide a priority ranking of resource utilization: first comes basic needs satisfaction; then the social and physical organization necessary to provide such satisfatcion, including if necessary military defence institutions; finally and lastly comes additional (luxury) needs satisfaction. At the extreme end of the continuum is resource utilization which is socially and ecologically destructive in character and consequence. Quantitative restrictions on and political and economic costs of resource utilization should be progressively increased according to such a continuum of end-uses, from basic needs satisfaction, to use for destructive purposes. One might also discriminate between various military end uses. T h e main point 'however' is diversion from military to civilian purposes according to a priority ranking which starts from the necessity of development with the fulfilment of basic needs and other human rights. T h e world as it is is a system with a tremendous over-capacity for self-destruction. Do moderate restriction schemes make sense in such a situation? Does it really make any difference? T h e huge stockpiles of arms and strategic materials to be used for arms production call for radical measures not marginal ones. Yet, it may be feasible to start with the first steps. What follow are some initial suggestions in that spirit. 5.1. International measures The principle of equal access set down in the Atlantic Charter was non-interference with the self-determination of nations. It was implied that equality of access was not valid in the case of aggressors (prohibiting the rearmament of the Axis powers) or, in general, arms build-up beyond that necessary for legitimate defence purposes. O b viously, these principles have been flagrantly violated. Nor were the 'mineral sanctions' advocated by the League of Nations and others ever carried out. (Eckel, Lathe, 18 Helge Hveem & Cook, 1935.) Mineral sanctions that have really worked are those enforced unilaterally by great powers, such as the sanctions imposed by the United States against the Soviet bloc during the Cold War. T h e O P E C embargo was rather ineffective in comparison, as were also the Rhodesia sanctions. Concrete questions which arise include: — Since the arms race or the overall relationship between the superpowers is the force moteur of the spiralling military consumption of natural resources, does a balanced arms reduction scheme also require special guarantees to the US and N A T O for access to materials in which they are less self-sufficient or deficient? Whether the US gets its deficit covered by imperialist or voluntarist means, or is deliberately playing on continued imports to spare own available resources, it can argue from an status quo position. — What are the implications of such an access guarantee for N I E O demands like the quest for national self-determination over resources? Disregarding the possibility that they can be reconciled bilaterally — which would be contrary to the purpose of an international agreement — is reconciliation of the two possible? — In a highly integrated and internationalized system such as the present international system and the military-industrial network within the major powers, which control measures are feasible and at the same time effective? — Considering the increasing role of technological innovations in weaponry and their implications for material usage, can international measures be devised which control for rapid changes in military demand for materials, due to substitution and other domestically developed and controlled measures? Periphery 'opecizatiori"? Political decolonization and later the claim for selfdetermination over national resources of decolonized areas have to be in contradiction to the strategic need of major military powers to control these resources as closely as possible. (I am here referring to real selfdetermination, not more or less neo-colonial forms of 'economic nationalism'.) That this is a sensitive area is clear from the fact that 'cartellization' of uranium by Third World countries exporting this highly strategic resource has been characterized as politically 'too aggressive' by one Third World representative who otherwise greately favoured such action in other raw materials. 7 There are strong political barriers and disincentives to 'opecization' of periphery resources. However, chances in bauxite and a few other minerals (cf. above) do exist. This does not necessarily mean that the periphery will for economic reasons be disinclined to participate in measures aimed at restricting military consumption of natural resources, although there may be some reasons to believe so (Leitenberg, 1976). Reduced demand due to restrictive measures can be compensated for partly by increased civilian consumption made possible by diversion of funds from military to civilian production (UN, 1972), and partly by higher prices. What this means, however, is that under present conditions the Third World will see few incentives in policing a restriction scheme on and by its own, nor will the major powers be willing to tolerate such policing. With present highly uneven distribution of power internationally, the sole chance seems to lie in some multilaterally agreed upon and directed control scheme. Multilateral schemes. In their classical study of the problem of resource control, Leith, Furness, and Lewis developed a radical approach in the form of an ambitious control scheme (1943). Their premises were inter alia that — t h e s c h e m e m u s t be e s t a b l i s h e d in a d v a n c e of a r m e d conflict; — it m u s t i n c l u d e all or m o s t of t h e w o r l d ' s r e source areas; — it w o u l d h a v e to i n c l u d e a s y s t e m of supervising resource use at the international and national levels; — supervision w o u l d have to cover the various b r a n c h e s o f i n d u s t r y t h a t a r e directly, b u t a l s o Militarization of Nature those i n d i r e c t l y i n v o l v e d i n a r m s p r o d u c t i o n (which potentially means most of the m a n u f a c turing and metallurgical i n d u s t r y ) ; — it w o u l d l o g i c a l l y h a v e to i n c l u d e a l l a r m s producing nations; — a c o m p r o m i s e b e t w e e n free e n t e r p r i s e a n d n a t i o n a l state c o n t r o l w o u l d h a v e t o b e f o u n d , a l t h o u g h t h e r e i s m u c h t o b e said i n f a v o u r o f state i n t e r v e n t i o n a s t h e o n l y effective w a y o f exercising a c o n t r o l s c h e m e , p r o v i d e d p o l i t i c a l goals a r e set r i g h t a n d a r e b e i n g f o l l o w e d ; — a s y s t e m of s a n c t i o n s f o r a n y b r e a k i n g t h e scheme would have to be established. Their proposal was much inspired by the control schemes set up during World War I, and especially the one run jointly by the US and the UK during World War II. This scheme gave the state, through special boards, complete control over the imports and distribution of materials. In hindsight, the Leith proposal was in many respects completely unrealistic. Still, on several points it touched on necessary conditions for a control scheme to be operative. Also it reflected thinking in important political circles in the Allied Powers at that time. It would not be sufficient, for instance, to impose quantum regulation on imports. The importing arms-producing nation would normally be able to switch material consumption from civilian to military use. There would be no important obstacle to this in terms of a time-lag, which may be the case with regard to measures like substitution or increased recycling of materials. For import controls to be effective, some degree of supervision of national industries is necessary. This impinges on the right of self-determination. It would require some sort of an international production authority vested with the power to allocate quotas of materials usage, and to supervise that this takes place according to agreed rules. 5.2. Measures at the national level If internationally agreed control schemes and multilaterally run institutions to direct them do not seem very likely, neither does the probability that the state in major armsproducing countries will be able or even 19 willing to exercise the control over private capital necessary for such a scheme to be operative. And how could the state control the military industry when, as in the Soviet Union, the two are completely integrated? In the capitalist countries, with more public concern over militarization and its consequences, a more independent role for the state vis a vis private capital is conceivable, if not very likely. Theoretically, the decisive role of the state in financing military R & D programmes gives it the key to such factors as the rate and extent of substitution, recycling, and other measures discussed above. Action by concerned groups organizations and individuals may be more promising than direct action by the state. If key scientists walk out on military R & D institutions, this may be at least as important as a mass rally. Some of the most promising action yet taken is the diversion campaign of the Lucas workers (Elliott, 1977). Similar types of action might be considered by e. g. metal workers or dock workers handling strategic minerals. Such action may arise out of increased consciousness. In many periphery countries, the problem with consciousness-raising lies in the relative affluence of the mineral working class. Everywhere, and with the economic crisis increasingly so, there is the problem of lack of alternative employment. 5.3. Summary: some proposals Despite these obstacles, there are a number of concrete measures that could be considered within the framework of international and nationally binding action in particular. T h e following suggestions are offered as examples. a) An open military information act for the international community, showing not only the consumption of military hard-ware (end product), but also consumption of inputs such as raw materials and energy, R & D , manpower, etc. b) A progressive tax on the use of materials for military purposes. T h e case for a tax on all use of natural resources, particularly on 20 Helge Hveem non-renewable minerals and ocean resources, has been made elsewhere (Pisani, 1977). A first tier of the tax could be imposed progressively according to certain criteria, the most important of which would be renewability of the material, its rareness, and its particular relevance to Third World countries. A second tier would relate to its importance as a raw material to the military industry. Thus, titanium would be heavily taxed, natural rubber moderately. T h e tax ought to be levied on production/extraction, exports and imports in order to distribute the burden as widely and equally as possible among nations. T h e capital finally would be made available for development purposes through UN institutions. Except for obvious political opposition that it would encounter, there do not seem to be insurmountable difficulties in administering such a tax. Production and trade figures are usually known; consumption of stockpiled and recycled materials might create more of an information problem. The tax should not, on the other hand, be made unnecessarily complicated by applying too many and too specific criteria when the tax level is determined. It might take into account the processing level at which the material enters military-industrial production and the substitutability of the material used. c) Quantum regulations on use of natural resources for military purposes. Such regulation would require that states adhering to the control scheme be willing to be supervised, even if supervision need not be so detailed as the Leith proposal suggested. Problems of implementing this proposal would probably not be any greater than in implementing an arms control scheme. T h e problem might be considerable, however, if some international organ were to assess and continuously check technologically determined changes in material usage without the voluntary assistance of national state and industry institutions. d) An agreed upon level of 'security': minimum consumption standards. Such a scheme would somehow have to tackle the intricate problem of 'what is enough': what quantities of materials consumption are necessary for legitimate national defence purposes. One initial approach might be to impose restrictions in proportion to the amount of arms produced which is exported as compared to the amount used for the national military apparatus. This might then also contribute to restricting exports of arms. e) Unpackaging and prohibition of arms-formaterials deals and the like. This proposal implies that it will be formally prohibited to arrange for material supply through some quasi barter deal, in particular where sales of arms, military know-how etc. are involved. The aim would be to attack a trend which at present seems to be strongly on the increase — in the nuclear field, clearly, but also with regard to other materials. f) Offer a premium to countries/firms diversifying from production and sales of natural resources for military purposes. The main purpose here would be to disincline periphery governments not completely integrated into some centre country protectorate, from continuing exports of resources because of short-term economic and employment needs. These proposals are aimed at reducing the economic incentives for arms-producing countries to continue the internationalization of militarization. Countries mainly exporting natural resources should find an incentive to support and comply with international agreements for measures of type (f), on the implicit premise that capital accumulated through taxing, tariffs, and so on would be channelled to development purposes through the U N . Throughout this paper I have stressed that proposals like those suggested here are confronted with a world of strong vested interests. This calls for rigid analysis of those interests and for realism. Many of the proposals would seem completely unrealistic today. Yet, action is possible. A first prerequisite is that the intimate link between state and private capital Militarization of Nature interests, the role of international rivalry over access to resources and the trend towards militarization of the periphery be recognized. Thereby, it will also become possible to recognize the link between armaments and development. NOTES * T h i s is a s e c o n d a n d e n l a r g e d r e p o r t on a project which analyzes t h e relationship b e t w e e n t h e p r o c e s s o f m i l i t a r i z a t i o n a t t h e g l o b a l level and the control and use of natural resources. T h e p r o j e c t is an offspring of a l a r g e r p r o j e c t on r a w m a t e r i a l politics a n d d o m i n a n c e t h e o r y s u p p o r t e d by the Norwegian Research Council for Science and the Humanities. This sub-project on militariz a t i o n a n d r e s o u r c e conflict h a s r e c e i v e d s u p p o r t from the Norwegian Government's Advisory Council on A r m s Control and D i s a r m a m e n t . Morten Andersen and Tor-Arne H a u g have helped i n collecting a n d a n a l y z i n g i n f o r m a t i o n a n d i n o r ganizing t h e statistical m a t e r i a l . I r e c e i v e d v a l u a b l e c o m m e n t s a n d criticism o n a n e a r l i e r d r a f t from Klaus-Jurgen Gantzel, Peter Lock, and Jan 0 b e r g . A preliminary version was published in t h e Bulletin of Peace Proposals, n o . 1, 1978 u n d e r u n d e r t h e title ' A r m s C o n t r o l t h r o u g h R e s o u r c e C o n t r o l ' . T h e p r e s e n t p a p e r c a n b e identified a s P R I O P u b l i c a t i o n n o . S-13/78. 1. F o r a m o r e d e t a i l e d d i s c u s s i o n w i t h p r e c i s e definitions of t h e s e c o n c e p t s , see A l b r e c h t , 1977 a n d K l a r e , 1978. 2 . See i n t e r a l i a A l b r e c h t e t al, 1 9 7 5 ; K a l d o r , 1975; L u c k h a m , 1977; K l a r e , 1978; L o c k & Wulf, 1977; a n d T h e e , 1978 f o r a d i s c u s s i o n of t h e s e a n d other factors. 3. Such arrangements usually are not m a d e formally and hence not recorded publicly. This means they cannot normally be documented. T h e r e i s w i d e s p r e a d belief i n p o l i t i c a l a n d b u s i n e s s circles, h o w e v e r , t h a t t h e y n o t o n l y a r e p r a c t i s e d , but are also on the increase. US a n d F r e n c h deliveries o f a r m s t o s o m e k e y O P E C a n d M i d d l e E a s t c o u n t r i e s t h u s a r e said t o h a v e b e e n m a d e i n e x c h a n g e for oil s u p p l i e s . T h e S o v i e t U n i o n p r a c tises b a r t e r d e a l s as a n o r m a l w a y of d e a l i n g w i t h periphery countries, and quite probably also has m a d e deals involving a r m a m e n t s . 4 . T h e basis f o r t h i s a s s u m p t i o n i s a d m i t t e d l y n o t v e r y solid. I t i s k n o w n t h a t e x p e n d i t u r e s o n a r m a m e n t s i n t h e t w o s u p e r p o w e r s differ c o n s i d e r a b l y b e c a u s e Soviet p e r s o n n e l costs a r e m u c h lower than US ones. On the other hand, a counting o f h a r d w a r e i t e m s ( w e a p o n r y a n d i n f r a s t r u c t u r e ) m i g h t give a c l u e to t h e a n s w e r and w o u l d probably show m u c h m o r e similarity between the two with respect to absolute consumption of 21 natural resources for military purposes. It m a y well be that the difference, m a k i n g Soviet cons u m p t i o n a b s o l u t e l y a n d r e l a t i v e l y less t h a n t h e US one, is d u e to higher US levels of a r m a m e n t s exports. 5. In a recent study, Leontief a n d others present a m o d e l f o r m a k i n g s u c h a n a n a l y s i s . Cf. V a s i l y Leontief, 1978. 6 . M i l i t a r y c o n s u m p t i o n o f jet fuel a c c o u n t s f o r a b o u t 1/3 of a l l c o n s u m p t i o n of jet fuel in t h e U n i t e d States (Sivard, 1974). 7 . A n A l g e r i a n official i n p r i v a t e c o n v e r s a t i o n with the author. REFERENCES A b b o t t , K. H . , 1975. Army utilization management of metallic minerals. A r m y M a t e r i a l s a n d Mechanics Research Center, Waterton, October, microfiche. Albrecht, Ulrich, Dieter Ernst, Peter Lock, & Herbert Wulf, 1975. 'Militarization, Arms P r o d u c t i o n in P e r i p h e r a l C o u n t r i e s ' , Journal of Peace Research n o . 3. A l b r e c h t , U l r i c h , 1977. ' T e c h n o l o g y a n d M i l i t a r i z a t i o n in T h e o r e t i c a l P e r s p e c t i v e ' , Bulletin of Peace Proposals, n o . 2. Broekmeijer, 1963. Developing Countries and NATO. S t r a t e g i c e c o n o m i c i m p o r t a n c e o f i m ports of ran materials. B r o w n , G e o r g e S., 1 9 7 5 . A d d r e s s b e f o r e t h e 76th N a t i o n a l C o n v e n t i o n of the V e t e r a n s of Foreign W a r s of the U n i t e d States, L o s Angeles, August 21. B r o w n , G e o r g e S., 1 9 7 5 H a n d 1976. C h a i r m a n o f o f t h e J o i n t C h i e f s o f Staff, S t a t e m e n t b e f o r e the Senate A r m e d Services C o m m i t t e e , F e b ruary. Council on International E c o n o m i c Priorities, 1974. Special Report, D e c e m b e r 1974. W a s h i n g t o n D C , G o v e r n m e n t P r i n t i n g Office. D r e s c h , S t e p h e n P . , 1972. Disarmament: Economic Consequences and Development Potential. Yale University, m i m e o . Eckel, E d w i n C, F. E. L a t h e , & S. J. C o o k , 1935. ' T h e Control of Minerals N e e d e d for W a r as an I n t e r n a t i o n a l S a n c t i o n ' , Indepence, v o l . 12, N o s . 2-3. Elliot, D a v e . ' T h e L u c a s A e r o s p a c e W o r k e r s ' Campaign', Young Fabian Pamphlet, n o . 4 6 . G a l t u n g , J o h a n , 1976. ' S o c i a l I m p e r i a l i s m ' , World Development, v o l . 4, n o . 3, M a r c h . Harrigan, Anthony, 1976. 'Resource Control Strategy', National Defense, March-April. H e l l e i n e r , G . K., 1978. ' F r e e d o m a n d M a n a g e m e n t in Primary Commodity Markets: US Imports from Developing Countries', World Development, v o l . 6, n o . 1, J a n u a r y . 1 Hughes, E. E., S. S. Baum, E. Just, & M. D. 22 Helge Hveem Levine, 1975. Strategic Resources and National Security. An Initial Assessment. Stanford Research Institute, M e n l o Park, April, microfiche. H u i s k e n , R o n a l d , 1975. ' C o n s u m p t i o n o f R a w M a t e r i a l s f o r M i l i t a r y P u r p o s e s ' , Ambio, n o . 6 . H u l t m a n , 1976. ' A c c e s s t o S u p p l i e s : A N e w C o n cept in US Commercial Policy', in S. Raichur & C. L i s k e , e d s . , The Politics of Aid, Trade and Investment. H a l s t e d P r e s s . Hveem, H., 1973. 'The Global Dominance S y s t e m ' , Journal of Peace Research, N o . 4. H v e e m , H . , 1977. The Political Economy of Third World Producer Associations. Oslo, Universitetsforlaget. H v e e m , H . , 1978, ' A r m s C o n t r o l t h r o u g h R e s o u r c e C o n t r o l ' , Bulletin of Peace Proposals, N o . 1. J a p a n E c o n o m i c C o u n c i l , 1970, The Resources Problem in a Period of Internationalisation, R e port of the Research Committee on Resources. K a l d o r , M a r y , 1975, Toward a theory of the arms trade. U n i v e r s i t y of Sussex, m i m e o . K e o h a n e , R o b e r t O., & J o s e p h S . N y e , 1977. Power and Independence. B o s t o n , L i t t l e , B r o w n . K e v i t z , E. A . , 1975. The Future Availability of Strategic Raw Materials and Possible NATO Actions. F o r t L e a v e n w o r t h , U S A . S t u d y c o m missioned by the US A r m y C o m m a n d , microfiche. K l a r e , M i c h a e l , 1978, ' M i l i t a r i s m : T h e I s s u e s T o d a y ' , Bulletin of Peace Proposals, n o . 2. L e e , J o h n M . ( G e n e r a l ) , 1974. A d d r e s s d e l i v e r e d at the US Naval W a r College, June, quoted in H a r r i g a n 1976. L e i t e n b e r g , M i l t o n , 1976. ' O n t h e d i v e r s i o n o f r e sources for military purposes in developing nat i o n s ' , Journal of Peace Research, n o . 2. L e i t h , C . K., J . W . F u r n e s s , & C l e o n a L e w i s , 1943. World Minerals and World Peace. Washington D . C , T h e Brookings Institution. L e o n t i e f , V a s i l y e t al, 1978, ' P r e l i m i n a r y s t u d y o f world-wide e c o n o m i c and social implications of limitation on military spending ( A n input-output approach)'. New York: New York University, D e p t . of E c o n o m i c s , m i m e o . L e v i n e , M. D . , & I. W. Y a b r o f f , 1975. Department of Defense Materials Consumption and the Impact of Material and Energy Resource Shortages. Stanford Research Institute, M e n l o Park, N o vember, microfiche. L o c k , P e t e r , & H e r b e r t Wulf, 1977, ' T r a n s f e r of T e c h n o l o g y a n d t h e D e v e l o p m e n t P r o c e s s ' , Bulletin of Peace Proposals, n o . 2. L u c k h a m , R o b i n , 1977, ' M i l i t a r i s m : A r m s a n d t h e Internationalisation of C a p i t a l ' , IDS Bulletin, U n i v e r s i t y o f Sussex, v o l . 8 , n o . 3 , M a r c h . M a r s h a l l , J o n a t h a n , 1973. ' S o u t h e a s t A s i a a n d U S Japan Relations, 1940-41', Pacific Research, March-April. M i l e s , E d w a r d , 1978, i n a s e m i n a r a t t h e F r i d t j o f Nansen Foundation, Polhøgda, Oslo, in April. M o w , C. C, & J. K. Ives, 1974. Energy Consumption by Industries in Support of National Defense: An Energy Demand Model, a report p r e p a r e d for Defense A d v a n c e d Research P r o jects A g e n c y , b y R a n d C o r p o r a t i o n . N A T O , 1976, Rational Use of Potentially Scarce Metals, R e p o r t of a N A T O S c i e n c e C o m m i t t e e Study G r o u p . N ' D o n g o , Sally, 1972. La 'coopération francoafricaine. P a r i s , M a s p e r o . N o r t h , R o b e r t C , & N a z i l C h o u c r i , 1974. Nations in Conflict: National Growth and International Violence, S a n F r a n c i s c o . O t t , G e o r g e , 1975. ' G e o g r a p h y a n d G e o p o l i t i c s : S t r a t e g y f o r t h e A m e r i c a s ' , National Defense, March-April. P i s a n i , E d g a r , 1977. ' H e r e ' s to U t o p i a ' , Ceres, F A O Review, January-February. SIPRI 1978, World Armaments and Disarmaments Yearbook. Stockholm, Almquist & Wiksell; London, Taylor & Francis. S I P R I , 1975. Oil and Security. S t o c k h o l m , A l m quist & W i k s e l l . Sivard, Ruth, 1977. World Military and Social Expenditures. WMSE Publications, Leesburg, Virginia. S t e h r , U w e , 1977. ' U n e q u a l D e v e l o p m e n t a n d D e p e n d e n c y S t r u c t u r e s i n C O M E C O N ' , Journal of Peace Research, n o . 2. U n i t e d N a t i o n s , 1972. Economic and Social Consequences of the Arms Race and of Military Expenditures. Report of t h e Secretary-General, New York. U n i t e d N a t i o n s , 1977. Economic and Social Consequences of the Armaments Race and Its Harmful Effects on World Peace and Security. Report of the Secretary-General, N e w York. 1 US C o n g r e s s , 1973. 22nd Annual Report of the Activities of the Joint Committee on Defense Production, P a r t 2 , W a s h i n g t o n D C , 5 . F e b ruary. US C o n g r e s s , 1 9 7 5 , Annual Report of the Joint Committee on Defense Production, Wash. DC, GPO. US Congress, 1975H. P e r m a n e n t Subcommittee on I n v e s t i g a t i o n s of t h e S e n a t e , Staff Study on the Procurement of Petroleum Products by the Military, April. US C o n g r e s s , 1976. Annual Report of the Joint Committee On Defense Production, W a s h . D C , 19 January, G P O . US C o n g r e s s , 1977. Hearings before the Committee on Armed Services, United States Senate, FY 1978, Authorization for Military Procurement, Research and Development etc., P a r t 8: Research and Development. V â y r y n e n , R a i m o , 1977, ' T r a n s n a t i o n a l C o r p o r a t i o n s a n d A r m s T r a n s f e r s ' , Instant Research on Peace and Violence, n o . 3-4. W a l l e n s t e e n , P e t e r , 1976, ' S c a r c e G o o d s a s P o l i t 1 Militarization of Nature ical W e a p o n : T h e C a s e of F o o d ' , Journal of Peace Research, n o . 4. W e s t i n g , A r t h u r , 1977, i n p r i v a t e c o m m u n i c a t i o n at SIPRI, Stockholm, 2nd December. W u , Y u a n - l i , 1975, Raw Material Supply in a Multipolar World. National Strategy Informa- tion Center. P u b l . by Crane, Russak & C o m pany, N e w York. Z e i n e r - G u n d e r s e n , H . F . ( G e n e r a l ) , 1978, C h a i r m a n of the N A T O Military Committee, in an interview with Halvor Elvik in Dagbladet, Oslo, 17 June. APPENDIX Table 1. Military share in the US national consumption of natural resources and major enduses, i n p e r c e n t . Mineral thallium germanium garnet thorium cobalt copper beryllum cadmium silicon tantalium zinc lead mica molybdenum iron manganese tungsten chromium antimony nickel columbium lithium fluorspar aluminium tin graphite ytterium mercury platinum silver asbestos rank no. 1963-72 1 2 3 4 5 24.2 23.3 22.0 20.4 19.5 17.6 14.3 11.2 11.1 10.8 10.1 10.1 9.8 9.5 9.1 8.9 8.8 8.2 8.1 7.9 7.7 7.3 7.3 7.3 7.2 6.9 6.8 6.5 6.4 6.0 3.3 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 20 21 22 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 36 41 55 1963-66 1969-72 — 24.5 26.8 21.8 15.8 15.5 15.5 10.5 10.8 10.9 9.0 9.3 10.0 10.8 9.8 8.5 8.0 8.5 8.0 8.8 8.3 5.8 18.0 20.8 24.5 21.8 19.3 17.3 10.5 — — 8.7 — 7.7 8.0 9.2 9.0 8.5 7.8 7.2 8.3 — — 7.3 8.3 6.5 7.3 — 5.3 — 5.8 3.0 23 — 6.8 5.8 7.5 6.3 4.5 6.8 6.2 6.0 3.5 Most important military end-use by sector aircraft (78) aerospace engines (62) electroplating general (45) electronics (67) transportation (43) electrical appliances (72) transportation (40) machinery (43) transportation (33) batteries (40) aircraft (54) transportation (45) fluor, o r g a n i c s ( 3 1 ) electrical e q u i p m e n t (32) transportation (34) foundries (39) electrical e q u i p m e n t (28) electronics/telecomm. (31) p h o t o g r a p h i c supplies (26) construction (60) S o u r c e s : H u g h e s et al., 1974. Strategic Resources and National Security. An I n i t i a l A s s e s s m e n t . S t a n f o r d R e s e a r c h I n s t i t u t e , M e n l o P a r k , A p r i l , m i c r o f i c h e , f o r first f o u r columns. Annual Report of the Joint Committee on Defense Production. Congress of t h e U n i t e d S t a t e s f o r F i s c a l Y e a r 1975, f o r final c o l u m n . 24 Helge Hveem T a b l e 2 ( 1 ) , G e o p o l i t i c a l data: Mineral Thallium Germanium Garnet Thorium Cobalt Copper Beryllum Cadmium Silicon Tantalium Zinc Lead Mica Molybdenum Iron Manganese Tungsten Chromium Antimony Nickel Columbium Lithium Fluorspar Aluminium Tin Graphite Yttrium Mercury Platinum Silver Asbestos Concentration o f w o r l d reserves and exports. R e s e r v e s in % of t o t . w o r l d r e s . (main three reserve countries) (A) Surplus disposal: E x p o r t s in % of t o t . w o r l d e x p o r t s ( M a i n three exporting countries) (B) (Canada, USSR, Australia) (Zaire, USA, USSR) (USA, India, U S S R ) (India, Canada, Australia ) ( Z a i r e 34, N e w C a l e d o n i a 19, Z a m b i a 1 7 ) ( U S S R 22, U S A 2 1 , C h i l e 1 6 ) (Brazil, Argentina) (Canada, Australia) (USSR, USA, Norway) (Zaire, Nigeria, C a n a d a ) ( N o . A m e r i c a 36, E u r o p a 2 5 , A s i a 1 8 ) ( U S A 28, O c e a n i a 13, C a n a d a 11) (Brazil, India, M a l a g a s y ) ( U S A 58, C a n a d a 17, S o . A m e r i c a 1 2 ) ( C a n a d a 15, B r a z i l 1 1 , A u s t r a l i a 6 . ) ( S o u t h A f r i c a 46, U S S R 46, B r a z i l 2 ) ( C h i n a 5 3 , U S S R 12, C a n a d a 1 2 ) (South Africa 63, Rhodesia 33, U S S R 1) ( C h i n a 5 5 , B o l i v i a 10, S o u t h A f r i c a 8 ) ( U S A 72, C a n a d a 2 1 , A u s t r a l i a 4 ) ( B r a z i l 6 7 , C a n a d a 13, K e n y a 6 ) 1 70 59 1 79 52 1 87 32 94 77 97 73 97 86 1 1 63 64 2 4 (Mexico, Thailand, Africa - ) (Australia, Guinea, J a m a i c a ) ( I n d o n e s i a 2 5 , C h i n a 16, T h a i l a n d 1 3 (Malagasy, Mexico, Austria ) (USA, Australia, USSR) (Spain, Yugoslavia, I t a l y ) ( U S S R , S o . A f r i c a , Canada3) (Mexico, Canada, P e r u ) ( C a n a d a , So. A f r i c a ) Notes and sources: See T a b l e 2 ( 2 ) . 1 48 73 99 74 81 45 1 73 68 89 ( C a n a d a 2 5 , A u s t r a l i a 13, P e r u 1 0 ) ( Z a i r e 46, N a m i b i a 17, C a n a d a 1 0 ) ( I n d i a 60, U S A 38, A u s t r a l i a l ) ( A u s t r . 30, I n d i a 2 9 , M a l a y s i a 1 5 J ( Z a i r e 66, Z a m b i a 9 , M o r o c c o 6 ) ( C h i l e 17, Z a m b i a 14, C a n a d a 1 4 ) 2 (Brazil, A r g e n t i n a ) (Canada, Australia) ( N o r w a y 15, S o . A f r i c a 3 , I n d i a 2 ) ( T h a i l a n d 36, N i g e r i a 2 1 , Z a i r e 1 0 ) ( C a n a d a 30, A u s t r a l i a 17, P e r u 1 5 ) ( A u s t r a l i a , P e r u 12, C a n a d a 1 2 ) ( I n d i a 6 1 , B r a z i l 15, M a l a g a s y 5 ) ( U S A 63, C a n a d a 2 1 , Chile l ) ( A u s t r a l i a 22, B r a z i l 20, C a n a d a 1 1 ) 2 ( S o . A f r i c a 2 8 , G a b o n 18, Brazil 1 3 ) 2 ( C h i n a 24, T h a i l a n d 12, Boliv. 1 0 ) (So. Africa, Rhodesia, U S S R ) ( S o . A f r i c a 2 9 , Bolivia 2 7 , C h i n a 1 7 ) i ( C a n a d a 4 3 , N e w C a l e d . 18, A u s t r . 7 ) ( B r a z i l 74, C a n a d a 9 , N i g e r i a 6 ) 42 64 59 ( M e x i c o 2 7 , T h a i l a n d 10, S o . A f r i c a 5 ) ( A u s t r . 26, G u i n e a 22, J a m a i c a 1 6 ) ( M a l a y s i a 37, B o l i v i a 12, I n d o n . 1 0 ) 66 52 74 64 62 ( U S A 40, A u s t r . 18, M a l a y s i a 8 ) ( S p a i n 34, C a n a d a 10, A l g e r i a 8 ) ( S o . A f r i c a 62, U S S R 8 , C a n a d a 4 ) ( C a n a d a 24, P e r u 2 1 , M e x i c o 1 9 ) ( C a n a d a 50, S o . A f r i c a 1 2 J 1 1 1 1 1 1 20 67 62 46 81 85 53 59 46 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 2 2 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 Militarization of Nature 25 Table 2(2), Geopolitical data. Import dependency: absolute and 'critical'. US Import dependency of Mineral major powers AI (% of current consumption US FRGermany<' import France6 USSR8 'Critical dependency' imported) (el Thallium Germanium Gamel Thorium Cobalt Copper BeryJlum Cadmium Silicon Tantalium Zinc Lead Mica Molybdenum Iron Manganese Tungsten Cromium Antimony Nickel Columbium Lithium Fluorine Aluminium Tin GrapbHe Yttrium Mercury Platinum Silver Asbestos (%) (0) 1132 35' 0 1()()4 79 16 27 41 1()3 99 101 70 76 84 90 49 18 94 0 27 68 55 69 48 81 84 na 81 88' 69 80 41 69 83 51 90 100 93 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 N o t e s t o tables 2 ( 1 ) and 2 ( 2 ) 99 30 90 100 467 28' 103 na 0 na na 0 0 0 na na na na 0 na na 0 0 35 0 na 0 oa na na 30 20 na na na 0 0 na 371 19 2 0 na 54 7 25 18 2 44 16 11 94 0 14 49 28 57 22 10 662 na 61 63' 67 75' 10 32 34 23 1 o f M i n e s , W a s h . , D C , Jul. 75. Estimated f r o m data in U n i t e d N a t i o n s Negotiating Conference on a C o m m o n Fund under the Integrated P r o g r a m m e for C o m modities: Statistics of International T r a d e in C o m m o d i t i e s c o v e r e d b y the Integrated P r o g r a m m e for C o m m o d i t i e s , 1970-1975. P u b l . n o . T D / I P C / C F / C O N F / M i s c . 5 G e . 77-70465, Oct. 1977. 2 ( A ) Sources: a ) U S D e p a r t m e n t o f C o m m e r c e , N a t i o n a l T e c h n i c a l Information Service, D o c u m e n t n o . A D A 0 1 7 7 9 2 . K. H. Abbott: Army Utilization Management of Metallic Materials. A r m y Materials and M e c h a n i c s R e search Center, Oct. 75. b ) Congressional R e s e a r c h Service, Library of Congress. A l l e n F. A g new: Brief Backgrounder on Mineral Commodities in the US Stockpile, 1975. free w o r l d except U S A five countries in Africa platinum group ore ( B ) Estimated f r o m production data in N T I S d o c u m e n t no. P B 2 5 2 9 9 4 . Minerals in the US Economy: Ten-Year Supply-Demand Profiles for Mineral and Fuel Commodities. Bureau 1 2 3 4 1 (C) 1 Estimated average for 1972 ( s o u r c e : E. E. H u g h e s , e t al.: Strategic R e s o u r c e s and N a tional Security: A n Initial A s s e s s m e n t ( e t c . ) Stanford R e s e a r c h Inst., M e n l o Park, Calif. N T I S d o c . n o . A D A 0 1 0 6 2 4 ) , 1973 ( s o u r c e : ( A ) a ) ) and 1975 ( s o u r c e : ( A ) b ) ) . 2 1972 3 1973 4 1975 bauxite o n l y ( U S A : 1973 data on metal, a l u m i n a and b a u x i t e g i v e an import d e p e n dency of 79 % ) . 5 26 Helge Hveem 6 source: Thomas Bertelman: Politik och råvaror, Liber forlag, Stockholm, 1977. Mi meo. ferro-nickel and nickel metal. George S. Brown, Statement before the Senate Armed Services Committee regarding 7 8 D o D Appropriations, Fiscal Y e a r 1976. ( D ) Estimated average for 1972 and 1973. Sources N T I S doc. n o . A D A 0 1 0 6 2 4 and ( A ) b ) . 1 1972 data o n l y 1973 data o n l y estimated average 1972, 1973, 1975. 2 3 T a b l e 3 . E c o n o m i c and t e c h n o l o g i c a l data '0 ~~'" EO ... Supply in percent of consumption. 1974. (USA) release (net,) Consumption ~ ;) ~ Stockpile Total Consumption ~ ~~ e~ i Consumption Own prod. Imports Consumption Consumption Imp.-Exp. Consumption o.c.ri e u ~ c -0.= ~ ~-s8 Thallium! Germanium Gamet Thorium Cobalt Copper Beryllum Cadmium Silicon Tantalium Zinc Lead Mica Molybdenum Iron2 Manganese3 Tungsten Chromium 4 Antimony Nickel Columbium Lithium Fluorspar Aluminium Tin Graphite Yttrium Mercury Platinum Silver Asbestos 3,000 43,000 18,772 80 9,400 2.3 mill. 350,000 6,940 660,000 0.93 mill. 350,000 1.5 mill. 3,100 73 mil\. 135 mill. 1.8 mill. 8,060 1.42 mill. 42 mill. 210 mil\. 2.0 mill. na 1.32 mill. 17.3 mill. 69,300 68,000 20.209 59,600 1.9 mill. 178.4 mill. 874,000 p Ibs 51 51 5t $t sl sl 5t Ib' sl sl sl Ibs sl st sl 5t sl sl Ib' st Idl sl 51 5t nasks t.OZ. I.oz. sl na 86 121 100 3 161 oa 50 88 0 129 133 0 158 78 0 48 0 89 30 0 na 15 12 29 na 124 18 20 91 13 na 35 0 100 77 27 19 31 11 105 211 13 113 35 -21 100 na 21 0 78 -38 -9 61 -4 na na -23 -2 32 -24 na 27 -26 18 20 14 -10 na 30 16 -10 5 1 27 63 94 7 66 20 19 30 8 105 211 7 -15 -110 30 56 51 75 49 88 120 na 91 88 50 26 -25 85 116 65 84 90 0 32 67 71 88 51 102 120 na 91 88 63 46 118 86 153 75 89 0 3 21 5 5 43 24 5 10 41 15 7 15 17 20 40 N o t e s and sources: 1 2 3 4 5 1972, estimate, 1973, Mn ore ( F e M n : 1,1 m i l l , s t ) , C r 0 ( F e C r : 0.58 mill, s t ) , bauxite p l a t i n u m group, v a l u e 1 indicates g o o d subs, possibility, v a l u e 10 indicates small subs, possibility, rare earth e l e m e n t s and yttrium. st: short tons, t. oz..: troy o u n c e s , lbs: p o u n d s , mill.: m i l l i o n , ldt: l o n g dry tons. E. E. H u g h e s et al.: Strategic R e s o u r c e s and N a t i o n a l Security. N A T O , 1976. Projektgruppen 'Ressurser o c h råvaror', Sekretariatet for framtidsstudier: Substitution — att byta ut resurser. Liber forlag, S t o c k h o l m , 1977. A g n e w , A l l e n F.: Brief Backgrounder on Mineral Commodities in the US Stockpile, 1975. C o n g r e s sional R e s e a r c h Service. 16 M a y , 1975. M o r g a n , J o h n D . : World Distribution and Flow of Major Mineral Commodities, Bureau of M i n e s , 2 6 8 7 3 ?;> :; .c' ~~ ;:::I:'::' .~ :s ~·Vl ~& 5 3 2 4 7 6 6 4 6 6 2 5 4 3 8 7 7 5 7 4 4 6 6 6 3 5 0 7 8 8 5