BULLETIN OF PEACE PROPOSALS to motivate research to inspire future oriented thinking to promote activités for peace O F F P R I N T V O L U M E 7 1976 UNIVERSITETSFORLAGET OSLO — BERGEN — T R O M S Ö Introduction The Politics of the 'New International Economic Order' The 'New International Economic Order' (NIEO) is not only a vague concept that a series of international conferences in 1974 and 1975 have tried to define, it is a contested and conflicting concept that is deeply political. An imminent danger with such a concept is that it can become a slogan, a weapon in the 'diplomacy by terminology' that Gunnar Myrdal pointed out is a cover-up for the lack of international development efforts. Nice words, but no deeds. New concepts are introduced to 'cover up' for real reform. The spiralling bureaucratization of international development efforts now taking place is not necessarily a sign that governments are beginning to take them seriously. It could just as well be a function of a goal which organizations are often set up to serve: to get the hot, burning issues out of the fire and into the slow and technical, non-public and business-like atmosphere of the bureaucratic process. True, some participants really do want the current negotiations to produce some concrete results. It is often the case, however, that others do not share this view, and the outcome of negotiations thus depends largely on the relative power of the respective sides. These are some of the questions that must be raised after the 7th Special UN Session and the first round of negotiations in the Conference for International Economic Co-operation (CIEC). These conferences came up with very little new when compared with what has already emerged from the series of conferences held since 1974. While the previous gatherings were particularly instrumental in mobilizing the periphery (developing) countries into a unanimous front, the strength of which surpassed what they had ever reached before, the conferences of the last fall have had a certain demobilizing effect on that same front. And whereas the previous gatherings also represented the so far most serious and persistent manifestation of the contradictions and conflicts between the center (developed) and the periphery, or rather underdeveloped world, this situation of 'confrontation' also has become less prominent in the last few months. Below, we shall look briefly at some of the main reasons for these trends. The contents of the NIEO An authoritative definition of what the NIEO means would be the one given in the resolutions and programs passed by the periphery countries themselves. To the programs resulting from the Algiers, Dakar and Lima meetings in 1974 and 1975 should be added the Action Program adopted by the 6th Special Session of the UN and the UNIDO conference in the 1975, both the results of the developing countries' majority voting, with some of the major developed countries, notably the United States, voting against. Many of the demands raised in these documents have been voiced repeatedly for more than a decade and thus represent nothing new. What is new in the situation is that demands are put more concretely than before, some points of major importance (such as the request for national control over resources) have taken on a more 'aggressive' form, and demands are backed up by real bargaining power - the OPEC position. The treatment of the six issue areas dealt with by the 7th Special Session must be evaluated on the basis of the developing countries' demands for changes in power relations: First, that periphery countries should take over control of their natural resources and economies, and, secondly, that they would form producer cartels and other forms of cooperation to bargain more effectively in vital areas of technology and trade, and, thirdly, that the power (formal) of periphery countries in multilateral international organizations be radically increased in order to improve their influence over vital decisionmaking processes. These fundamentals are set down in Articles 2, 5 and 10, respectively, of the Charter of 3 Bulletin of Peace Proposals, V o l . 7, N o . 1, 1976 Economie Rights and Duties of States (see pp. 45-46). True, the Charter also contains paragraphs which set out a 'harmony of interest' relationship between the periphery and the center. But the three paragraphs mentioned are the ones over which there is conflict, precisely because they most directly challenge the established order; in other words, they represent the political elements in the quest for a NIEO. If proposals on trade, resource transfers, technology, industrialization and food security are not related to these elements, such proposals become mere technical matters, unrelated to their deeper political roots. To make the NIEO a technical matter is a deliberate strategy on the part of several countries, particularly some of the developed ones. Of the demands and proposals which developing countries have been relating to their quest for a new political-structural order, the following would seem the most important: - As exports of raw materials are still the chief source of income of most developing countries, and as these have been systematically underpaid and/or affected by adverse terms of trade and political and economic barriers, export incomes should be stabilized and increased, through price stabilization, indexation and by facilitating the access of developing exporting countries to a higher added value in marketing, processing, etc. - While trade reforms are still considered more important than increased and improved aid and assistance, transfer of real resources which persistently occurs from developing to developed countries - should be radically reversed through increased aid volumes, codes of conduct to stop exploitative practices and an assistance more suited to the real needs of the developing countries. - The international monetary system should be radically reformed in order to abolish such institutions and practices (the IMF structure, the gold standard, monetary reserve policies and limited access to SDRs, etc.) which have adversely affected the periphery, and the spiralling debt burden of the periphery should be relieved. 4 - Radically new forms of technology transfer to periphery countries should be established and agreed upon (a code of conduct prior to 1977) so that modern technology is really aiding the development of (and not, as is presently often the case, is underdeveloping) the periphery. - A system of food security should be organized internationally in a way which guarantees an international distribution of food surpluses to poor nations and thus increases the security of any country against hunger and malnutrition, without impairing its political-economic independence. What are the probabilities that such reforms will be implemented in the 1970s? The strategy of the dominant centers The means which the global periphery possesses to bargain and enforce the reforms it requires, are limited. And a policy of restructuring international exchange patterns into more cooperation among periphery countries to substitute the historically determined dependence on the center has just been initiated. If a NIEO is to come about, thus, it will to a considerable extent have to come through concessions by the dominant economic units, the big transnational firms and their 'home' nations. The resolutions and the policy statements made at international conferences are only part of the basis on which the intentions of policymakers is evaluated. But even that part is revealing. A close look at the statements of the representatives of the three dominant center nations - the United States, the Federal Republic of Germany, and Japan - shows that they are in fact arguing in favor of the old order. All of them refer to growth and the transnational firms as main prerequisites, in fact the way by which development globally comes about. But it is precisely in a period, in the 50s and 60s, when economic growth through the firms globally has been unprecedented both in volume and in endurance, that the process of unequal development - an increasing center-periphery gap and development mostly for the center - has been most advanced. In the same period the principles of free trade which the Japanese foreign minister so strongly advocates, even for the post-1975 period, have led to a growth in international trade also unprecedented in history. But at the same time, the share of the periphery countries in world trade has been halved over the last twenty years (oil being excluded) and their relative (in many cases even absolute) export income reduced. And periphery societies linked to the center in a colonial type of production-export dependence have become even more marginalized, insecure and dependent on fluctuating markets. Events in the oil industry, notably the OPEC actions, have not appreciably affected these general trends for which the dominant economic units over the decades have carried and still carry the main responsibility. There are, however, certain signs of a new conciliatory mood among center leaders. The oil experience and a more united periphery front may have had an effect toward creating such a mood. But most probably the main reason for it is the increased competition between the various centers and the growing economic crisis in the centers themselves, the roots of which predate the 'oil crisis'. The new mood could perhaps best be characterized as a 'stick and carrot' policy. The stick is still there, when common interests (safeguarding investments) prevail, to be jointly applied toward periphery interests through center-dominated institutions like GATT and IMF, or bilaterally as when national business interests are challenged (cf. the tough West German response to oil countries' bid to buy up shares in West German industry). The carrot is there because the various centers are competing for materials, markets and positions in the periphery and offer a carrot in return for some 'special' favor. The resultant mixture of cooperation and competition among the centers and the double policy of sticks and carrots in their relationship to the periphery will heavily influence the outcome of current negotiations on a NIEO. The policy of the United States is perhaps the best illustration of this new and complex game. From the 'oil crisis' and until after the first preparatory Paris meeting in April 1975, the US policy was one of applying a stick and carrot medicine toward her center allies trying to enforce a united front against OPEC, while prescribing only the stick for treating the periphery. OPEC was castigated as the major new threat to international welfare. The aim was to destroy OPEC and the new all-periphery front cemented around the OPEC countries. The strategy turned out to be a complete failure. It was a first warning that the US position at the 6th Special Session of the UN in April 1974 became rather isolated, even Japan and the Germans maintaining some distance to it (see Bulletin of Peace Proposals, 1974, No. 3). The failure was obvious at the French-sponsored, but US-mastered Paris meeting. In the course of a few months, the State Department got the upper hand with the Treasury and reformulated US policy. Instead of threatening the non-oil rich periphery to keep away from OPEC front operations and accept the old order pretty much as it was before the 'oil crisis', the new policy was to speak more softly about 'confrontation' and 'cartels' and promise some carrots to enlist support in the periphery in the positive way. The goal would be the same: to preserve of the old order what it would be in the interest of US firms and government to preserve and to prevent a strong united periphery front from entrenching itself under radical leadership. It is in this context that the US intervention at the 7th Special Session must be viewed - an intervention which also has laid much of the 'tone' in the CIEC negotiations this winter. It contains few proposals of concrete measures to be taken. Those which are concrete and address themselves to major periphery demands, like on export income stabilization, are mostly conceived within the older order: the IMF, World Bank and G A T T systems. Continued US opposition to restructure power relations within these institutions (as e.g. at the IMF annual meeting just before the 7th Special Session) indicates that the US ' N I E O ' at best is a modification or an adjustment of the old order and at the same time a 'technical economic' solution. Also, the US proposal to create a number of new institutions where institutions 5 already exist within the UN family to handle the fields concerned, is indicative of the same strategy: take the development effort out of institutions which the periphery controls politically and now wish to revitalize and reorganize to make them more effective development instruments (cf. the recommendations to reorganize UNIDO and the whole of the UN development bureaucracy). What way of development? The ability of the periphery to respond to the strategies of the dominant centers and stick to its demands for radical changes will depend on several factors: Firstly, the capacity of the periphery to maintain a strong and homogeneous common front in current bargaining processes. In the lobbies of the 7th Special Session and the CIEC, a number of periphery negotiators have shown enthusiasm toward the US proposals and ECACP (Lomé Convention) type of market arrangements, a very modest improvement of the old order and not really restructuring it. That is no surprise when the neo-colonial or 'elitist' character of some of the regimes which these negotiations represent, is taken into account. The 'softer' US policy and a widespread preparedness among periphery leaders to respond favorably to it has no doubt weakened periphery unity. When in addition OPEC has been too slow in responding to requests from other periphery countries for financial contributions out of the huge oil surpluses, the problems of maintaining the unity have been aggravated since last spring, when unity was at its height. Secondly, the ability of the periphery to impose its agenda on current negotiations. One of the crucial points in the periphery's demands has been the comprehensive approach: problems of development and underdevelopment should be viewed and treated together because they are linked up de facto. This view won through in the first CIEC rounds. It will be up to the periphery negotiators, however, to ensure that it is not lost in the tedious and technical deliberations now taking place. Also, while there is a certain understanding that the CIEC negotiations should be related to the agendas and 6 time-schedules of the UN process, notably preparations of UNCTAD IV, the work of UNIDO and of FAO, there is a considerable danger that these processes will become competing ones and the net result will simply turn out to be the type of bureaucratic fragmentation and red-tape that we referred to at the beginning. Preparations of UNCTAD IV, for instance on the integrated commodity program, obviously already to some extent suffer from the fact that CIEC commissions have taken some of the steam out of their engine. The periphery, which enjoys considerable power over the UN process and at the same time has limited capacities in terms of manpower and organization to coordinate negotiations, would do best in concentrating its efforts on the UN process. Thirdly, the periphery will have to define more concretely what it wants and under what time-perspectives. Lack of homogeneity and unity, which was referred to above, is not simply a political and organizational problem. It also refers to the fact that the very concept of development, of what purposes international restructuring serve, remains pretty much a question-mark too. This was the gist of the report from the Dag Hammarskjôld Foundation and it is a prominent feature in the first statements of the Third World Forum, the association of Third World intellectuals, international and national civil servants. The problem may be subdivided in two. First, there is the obvious lack of consensus over what development really means to people in the periphery, not the least among periphery leaders themselves. And if consensus is there verbally, in actual practice there are vast differences. Secondly, and related to the first aspect, there remains a problem with precisely the meaning of the international restructuring to the national and local development work. Are export income improvements positive if they increase both the export orientation of the economy and the power of upper class export interests, and result in few, if any, benefits 'trickling down' to the people? Does increased aid matter if it is prevented by political and social barriers from reaching the people in the village? cont. on p. 33 'The Politics of the "New International Economic Order'", cont. from p. 6. The meaning of a 'true' NIEO is not that it will solve the development problem, but that the processes of underdevelopment and maldevelopment which largely originates in the center of the international system are checked and eventually stopped. It is not even certain that a NIEO constructed more or less in line with the Action Program of the 6th Special Session will result in the decisive, massive development effort which many people, includ- ing 'progressive' governments in the center, seem to believe. Here lies the challenge of the selfreliance, local, national or 'collective', as a development strategy. Periphery leaders who increasingly believe in that concept would do well in thinking more about how a new international order should be constructed to serve increasing self-reliance, or, in other words, to make the periphery a center of its own. Helge Hveem International Peace Research Institute Oslo