Journal of International Economics 57 (2002) 273–297 www.elsevier.com / locate / econbase A U-shaped Europe? A simulation study of industrial location Rikard Forslid a , Jan I. Haaland b , Karen Helene Midelfart Knarvik b , * a b Stockholm University and CEPR, Department of Economics, S-106 91 Stockholm, Sweden Centre for International Economics and Shipping, Norwegian School of Economics and Business Administration and CEPR, Helleveien 30, N-5045 Bergen, Norway Received 17 April 2000; received in revised form 15 July 2001; accepted 16 July 2001 Abstract We use a large-scale CGE-model to simulate the effects of gradual economic integration on the location of industrial production. Our results reveal large differences among industries. Industries with high scale elasticities typically display a non-monotonous relationship between trade liberalisation and concentration, with maximum concentration for intermediate trade costs. Other industries, more driven by comparative advantage, become monotonously more concentrated as trade costs fall. On the aggregate level we find an (inverted) U-shaped relation between trade costs and concentration. The results also show a close correlation between real income gains and growth in manufacturing production, stemming from pecuniary externalities in the manufacturing sectors. 2002 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved. Keywords: Economic integration; Agglomeration; Economic geography JEL classification: C68; F10; F12; F15; R12 1. Introduction A common worry in peripheral regions is that economic integration may lead to loss of industries and jobs in the periphery. While traditional trade theory would *Corresponding author. Tel.: 147-55-959-510; fax: 147-55-959-350. E-mail addresses: rf@ne.su.se (R. Forslid), jan.haaland@nhh.no karenhelene.knarvik@snf.no (K.H. Midelfart Knarvik). (J.I. 0022-1996 / 02 / $ – see front matter 2002 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved. PII: S0022-1996( 01 )00155-6 Haaland), 274 R. Forslid et al. / Journal of International Economics 57 (2002) 273 – 297 not give rise to such worries, a number of articles in the ‘new economic geography’ literature (e.g. Krugman, 1991; Krugman and Venables, 1995) suggest that economic integration may indeed lead to concentration and unequal regional development. These theoretical studies, however, make their argument in highly stylised models — normally a 2 3 2 3 2 framework.1 This is necessary because of the complexity of the imperfect competition and industry-linkages framework. A question then is whether the results and intuitions from simple theoretical economic geography models go through in richer models.2 The purpose of this paper is to investigate if the results from small and stylised models hold in a model of larger dimensions. We therefore simulate the effects of trade liberalisation on the location and concentration of manufacturing industries using a large-scale CGE-model. Hence, the paper aims at obtaining numeric intuition of higher order properties of standard trade and location models — an exercise that may also allow for insights beyond those obtained in simpler models. An important insight from the theoretical literature is that industrial concentration can arise because of self-reinforcing backward and forward linkages. These stem from a combination of increasing returns to scale (IRS), trade costs, and the fact that firms are linked via their input–output structures (see e.g. Fujita et al., 1999). Downstream firms use an aggregate of upstream varieties as an intermediate input. When trade across borders incur costs, a larger number of upstream firms in your region implies a lower price level for intermediate inputs. This mechanism constitutes the forward link. More downstream firms, however, also imply a larger home market for upstream firms, which increases their sales and profits. This is the backward link. In order to provide intuition for how these agglomeration forces interact with other general equilibrium forces in determining location we will discuss two ‘pure’ cases. Consider first a two-country, three-sector, two-factor economy in which countries have identical relative endowments but differ in size. Two sectors are characterised by IRS and trade costs, and are linked via their input–output structures, which create agglomeration forces due to backward and forward linkages. The IRS-sectors have identical factor intensities. The third sector produces a homogenous good under constant returns and perfect competition. This sector has a different factor intensity. The profit maximising location of a firm in any of the IRS sectors will depend on product-market considerations and on factor-market considerations. There are two different product-market considerations. On the one hand, agglomeration forces associated with supplier proximity, draw firms to the larger 1 An exception is Puga and Venables (1996), who use a framework of multiple sectors with inter-sectoral input–output linkages. 2 For instance, Davis (1998) has challenged the robustness of the home-market effects appearing in such models. He shows that the introduction of equal trade costs for both goods in a two-sector model takes away all agglomeration tendencies. R. Forslid et al. / Journal of International Economics 57 (2002) 273 – 297 275 region. On the other hand, consumer-proximity considerations work against concentration of firms in one country. That is, demand considerations encourage firms to locate in proportion to demand rather than to concentrate. On the factor market side, concentration of the two IRS-sectors in one country leads to a higher relative price of the factor used intensively in the IRS sectors in this country, which works as a force against concentration. Consider now how the forces for and against concentration depend on trade costs. For high trade costs export becomes prohibitively expensive, and firms therefore locate according to demand. That is, consumer-proximity considerations dominate firms’ location decision, and produce low concentration. In the opposite case, when trade costs are low, trade in intermediates and final goods is cheap. This implies that factor-market considerations dominate location, which also produces low concentration since a concentration of the IRS sectors would drive up the relative price of the factor used intensively in this sector. Finally, for intermediate trade costs supplier-proximity considerations dominate the other two, leading to high concentration. The combination of product-market and factormarket forces therefore makes concentration of the IRS industry non-monotonic in trade costs, producing an inverted U-shape with maximum concentration for intermediate trade costs. Consider now instead a second ‘pure’ case — a traditional 2 3 2 3 2 model with constant returns and perfect competition. Countries now differ in relative endowments. In this model there is no supplier-proximity effect. As before, at high trade costs, the consumer-proximity effect dominates, which leads to a dispersed production. For low trade costs factor market considerations dominate, but in this case factor market competition dictates specialisation according to comparative advantage, and leads production to concentrate geographically. This second pure model, thus, produces a monotonic relationship with increasing industrial concentration as trade costs fall. Note that the first model has no natural pattern of ‘comparative advantage’ other than size differences, so at zero trade costs there is no concentration. The second model does have a natural pattern of comparative advantage, leading to concentration at zero trade costs. In summary, the two pure cases produce quite different pictures of concentration and trade costs. The first an inverted U, and the second a monotonic curve with negative slope. Both scenarios will be relevant when we turn to our large simulation model. This paper simulates the effects of economic integration using a full-scale CGE-model — the EURORA model with 14-industries and 10-regions (Forslid et al., 1999b) — which is calibrated on actual 1992 data. This model captures comparative advantage due to differences in endowments and technology, imperfect competition and scale economies, as well as backward and forward linkages through a complete input–output structure. Our results show that the locational effects of economic integration are highly 276 R. Forslid et al. / Journal of International Economics 57 (2002) 273 – 297 region- and sector-specific with some sectors being driven primarily by comparative advantage and others by agglomeration forces associated with scale economies and input–output linkages. However, the results for the overall increasing returns to scale manufacturing sector reveal an (inverted) U-shaped relationship between trade liberalisation and concentration of the manufacturing sector. Dual to this we report movements in factor prices and welfare effects. We show that welfare is positively associated with the location of the increasing-returns-to-scale (IRS) manufacturing. Finally, factor price movements tend to co-vary and are positively related to the pattern of industrial location. Relative factor price changes, on the other hand, show clear traces of Stolper–Samuelson effects. Section 2 describes the model, while Section 3 presents the results on industrial relocation and specialisation following a process of economic integration. Section 4 discusses the effects of integration on factor prices and welfare, and Section 5 offers some concluding remarks. 2. The model The model has 10 regions, and we will conduct our integration experiment among four of these (the four Western European regions). We call them Central, North, South, and West.3 In each region there are 14 production sectors. Of the 14 sectors, two are assumed perfectly competitive (energy and agriculture), while there are 12 imperfectly competitive sectors. Two of these are non-traded services sectors while the remaining 10 are traded manufacturing sectors.4 Trade in manufactured goods incurs trade costs, while the perfectly competitive, resourcebased sectors are modelled with free trade. We have kept the resource-based sectors as simple as possible, since the emphasis of the model is on manufacturing.5 The basic industrial structure of the model is shown in Table 1. The model we use builds on the CGE model developed by Haaland and Norman (1992), but with significant modifications with respect to linkage structure, various types of trade costs and market structure.6 An important feature of the model is 3 See Appendix A for details on the regions. It might be argued that private services should be modelled as internationally traded. However, although trade in services constitutes a significant share of international trade, it is still the case that there is a strong dominance of domestic supply in most services sectors (see EFTA, 1994). Hence, to simplify and at the same time focus on the potential importance of domestic supply of services as intermediate inputs, we have chosen to treat services sectors as non-traded. 5 The model includes production subsidies to agriculture and energy, but in the scenarios presented here, these policies are kept unaltered. 6 Other related CGE model-based analyses of integration and trade liberalization are e.g. Allen et al. (1998,Baldwin et al. (1996, 1997,Brown et al. (1992, 1995,Francois et al. (1995,Gasiorek et al. (1991, 1992,Harrison et al. (1995, 1996,Keuschnigg and Kohler (1996,Lopez-de-Silanes et al. (1994,RolandHolst et al. (1994). 4 R. Forslid et al. / Journal of International Economics 57 (2002) 273 – 297 277 Table 1 Industries Set Industry Description NT Public services Private services Non-traded monopolistically competitive sector linked to all other sectors through the input–output structure PC Agriculture Energy Traded perfect competitive sectors without trade costs. Each sector has a specific factor, which creates an element of decreasing returns to scale ITG Textiles Leather and products Wood products Metals Minerals Chemicals Food products Transport equipment Machinery Other manufacturing Traded sectors with monopolistic competition. Transport costs of iceberg type, plus tariffs and export taxes or subsidies. Linked to all other sectors through the input–output structure that it has a complete input–output structure, i.e. all linkages across the 14 sectors in the model are taken into account and are modelled in detail, using regionspecific input–output matrices. Hence, sectors are linked via demand for intermediate inputs, which creates agglomeration forces a` la Fujita et al. (1999). However, contrary to the typical theoretical model where there is just one industry and thus only intra-industry linkages, the simulation model includes both intra- and inter-industry linkages. This implies that agglomeration forces are not only created within industries but also between different kinds of economic activity. There are three primary factors of production — capital, skilled labour and unskilled labour; these are mobile between industries within a region, but immobile between regions. Factor demand derives from the 14 producing sectors. In addition to the three mobile factors, two of the sectors — energy and agriculture — use sector-specific natural resources. Hence, these two sectors show decreasing returns to scale with respect to the mobile factors. 2.1. Basic model equations Consumers have Cobb–Douglas preferences over a set of all goods (AG), implying that they, in each market (m), will spend a fixed share (a ) of their income (Y) on each good (i): Ym Cim 5 aim ], i [ AG Pim (1) 278 R. Forslid et al. / Journal of International Economics 57 (2002) 273 – 297 where Cim , and Pim are consumption and price of good i in market m. For perfectly competitive goods prices are world market prices given by world market clearing conditions for the respective goods. One of these goods (energy) is chosen as numeraire. Imperfectly competitive goods (the set I) are differentiated, and consumers consume a CES-composite of the individual varieties. Dual to this consumption composite is the price index SO D R Pim 5 s12 sid Nij a ijm PI ijm j51 1 / (12 si ) , i [I (2) where PIijm is the price of a variety of good i produced in country j and sold in market m, Nij the number of varieties of good i from country j, a ijm the demand share of good i from country j sold in market m, and si the elasticity of substitution between various varieties of good i. For non-traded, differentiated goods a ijm 5 0 for all m ± j, since by assumption only domestically produced varieties are consumed. The imperfectly competitive sectors are characterised by monopolistic competition a` la Dixit and Stiglitz with free entry and zero profits. The producer price (PPIij ) of good i produced in j is given as a mark-up over firms’ marginal costs (MC): si PPIij 5 ]]MCij , i [ I (3) si 2 1 while the consumer price in market m (PIijm ) for imperfectly competitive traded goods (ITG) is subject to trade costs 7 PIijm 5 PPIijs1 1 T ijmd i [ ITG (4) Demand in market m for each variety of good i produced in j may now be derived as: S D Pim Xijm 5 a ijm ]] PIijm si Cim i [ ITG (5) Prices and demand for non-traded differentiated goods are derived in the same way as for traded goods, but with no need to distinguish between producer and consumer prices since there is only domestic consumption of these goods. The price index for differentiated intermediate goods (Q hm ) is industry-specific by purchasing industry (h) and region (m). The industry uses all goods as inputs, where the share of each good is given by the parameter gihm . 7 The model is actually calibrated for three types of trade costs: export taxes, transport costs, and tariff equivalents of import barriers. The transport costs are of the iceberg type, while export taxes and import tariffs are transfers (to the representative consumer). The experiment of reduced trade costs implies an equiproportionate reduction in all three of these. R. Forslid et al. / Journal of International Economics 57 (2002) 273 – 297 Q hm 5 SO g ihm D 12sqd s P im ;i [I 1 / (12sq) , ;h [ AG 279 (6) where sq is the elasticity of substitution among imperfectly competitive goods used as intermediates. Observe that we use the same price index (Pim ) for industry i here as for consumer demand; hence, we assume that intermediate demand and final demand use different varieties of good i in the same proportions. The price indices for perfectly competitive goods (the set PC) as intermediates are constructed in the same way QPChm 5 SO D 12sqd gihm PPC is ;i [PC 1 / (12sq) ;h [ AG. (7) PVij is a price aggregate for all primary factors used in the production in sector i in region j. The share of each individual factor (k) is industry- and countryspecific, and is given by the parameter bijk SO K PVij 5 k 51 bijkW jk12s i D 1 / (12s i ) i [ AG. (8) Finally, the marginal cost for industry i in country j is specified as a nested CES-function, with primary inputs, differentiated intermediates, and homogenous intermediates in one second-level nest each, and with Stop as the elasticity of substitution between the nests at the top level. Using the price indices above, the marginal cost function may be written MCij 5fBVijsPVijd 12S top i 1 BZijsQ ijd 12S top i 1 BZPCijsQPCijd 12S top ig 1 / ( 12S top i ) (9) where BVij , BZij , and BZPCij are all calibrated parameters. From (9), using (6)–(8) and market clearing conditions for each good, we find the demand for primary factors and intermediate goods from each sector. Together with supply conditions, these form the general equilibrium system. As the imperfectly competitive sectors are characterised by monopolistic competition and zero profits, the scale of each firm is fixed, and any output expansion is entirely reflected through an increase in the number of firms (varieties) in the respective sector. In equilibrium there is moreover a one-to-one, inverse relationship between elasticity of substitution (si ) and scale elasticity. The use of intermediates from own as well as other industries implies the existence of inter- and intra-industry cost linkages. The presence of these linkages, together with trade costs, means that the number of firms producing in the region affects each firm’s costs. This can be seen from (9) together with (6), (4) and (2): imported varieties bear trade costs, and the more varieties of a good that have to be imported, the more costly is the good as an intermediate input (a higher Q in (9)). The supplier-proximity considerations will, thus, encourage firms to locate in a 280 R. Forslid et al. / Journal of International Economics 57 (2002) 273 – 297 region with a large number of suppliers of important intermediates, as this leads to lower marginal costs and makes them more competitive. At the same time consumer-proximity considerations pull in the opposite direction. This follows from (5), (4) and (2). A higher T increases the relative price of imported varieties, and raises the demand for locally produced varieties. This encourages producers to locate according to demand. Finally, factor market effects work through Eq. (8). In the first ‘pure’ case with identical relative factor endowments, concentration of all the industry in one country drives up the price of primary factors (PV ) relative to the other countries. Factor market competition is thus a force for de-concentration of industrial activity, but does not necessarily imply the dispersion of individual industries. With differences in relative factor endowments (the second pure case) an equal division of industry across countries produces unequal factor prices (PV ). In this case factor market competition dictates the concentration of individual industries. That is, specialization according to comparative advantage. The relative strength of concentration and de-concentration forces depends, as discussed in Section 1, on the level of trade costs. For low trade costs factormarket considerations dominate, for high trade costs consumer-proximity considerations determine location, and for intermediate trade costs supplier-proximity becomes the dominating factor. Agglomeration forces do not directly affect the perfectly competitive sectors. These sectors, however, expand or contract as a consequence of competition for factors with the other sectors. The decreasing returns in these sectors (due to a specific factor) act to dampen the expansion of the ITG sectors, as their presence implies that factors are drawn into the ITG sectors at increasing cost. 2.2. Data and calibration To calibrate the model we use actual 1992 data from Eurostat, GTAP and NBER World Trade Flows (see Feenstra, 1997) for input–output tables, trade flows and factor shares, of which more details are provided in Appendix A. With respect to other key features, such as market structure, and demand and technology parameters, on the other hand, we have to rely on secondary sources or pure assumptions. In our model with large-group monopolistic competition and free entry / exit, there is in equilibrium a one-to-one (inverse) relationship between elasticity of substitution between varieties and scale elasticity. Consequently, we can use data on scale elasticity to calculate the elasticity of substitution between varieties. The calibration procedure essentially solves the model backwards. That is, it uses data for all variables and some parameters and solves the model for remaining parameters. Table 2 provides an overview of the parameters in Eqs. (1)–(9).8 8 For the complete model and the complete set of parameters, see Forslid et al. (1999b). R. Forslid et al. / Journal of International Economics 57 (2002) 273 – 297 281 Table 2 Overview of parameters Parameters calibrated on data of production trade, and input–output tables aim , a ijm , gihm , bijk , BVij , BZij , BZPCij Parameters based on secondary data sources si , T ijm Assumed parameter values sq, s i , Stop i Without proper testing of all parameters, the empirical applicability of the simulations may be limited. Hence, the model exercise should be viewed as ‘theory with numbers’, rather than empirical results with direct policy implications. 2.3. Industry and region characteristics Before we turn to model simulations, we present key characteristics of potential importance for the results. In particular we focus on features that are expected to influence the location of sectors as trade costs are lowered. Five factors affect the strength of the backward and forward linkages in this model: trade costs, elasticities of substitution, economies of scale, the input–output structure, and the size of regions (home market effects). However, as noted above, there is a one-to-one (inverse) relationship between elasticity of substitution between varieties and scale elasticity. Location of industries is moreover affected by standard comparative advantage — especially for low trade costs — due to differences in endowment and technology. Column (a) in Table 3 ranks industries in descending order according to trade distortions (i.e. the combined effect of transport costs, import barriers and export Table 3 Key industry characteristics (average values for the four integrating regions) Textiles Leather and products Wood products Metals Minerals Chemicals Food products Transport equipment Machinery Other manufacturing (a) Trade distortions a (b) Scale elasticity a (c) Own input share (d) Intermediate share (e) Unskilled / skilled ratio (f) Labour / capital ratio 4 7 5 6 2 3 1 10 9 8 10 9 5 4 6 2 7 1 3 8 0.294 0.187 0.268 0.366 0.130 0.297 0.158 0.145 0.169 0.026 0.561 0.543 0.555 0.634 0.486 0.603 0.655 0.570 0.489 0.335 3.40 3.44 2.16 2.43 2.33 1.58 2.43 2.02 1.53 2.30 3.28 3.46 3.41 3.94 1.84 2.51 1.74 4.09 3.76 3.87 0.204 0.543 2.36 3.19 Average a Rank in decreasing order. 282 R. Forslid et al. / Journal of International Economics 57 (2002) 273 – 297 taxes or subsidies). In the trade liberalisation experiments we lower trade costs equiproportionately in all sectors, which implies that we would expect more ‘action’ in sectors with initially high trade costs. Let us therefore note that food products, minerals, chemicals and textiles are all sectors with relatively significant trade distortions. Column (b) in Table 3 ranks industries in descending order according to scale economies, and shows that scale economies are most important for transport equipment, chemicals, machinery and metals.9 According to theory (see Krugman, 1980; Krugman and Venables, 1995; Amiti, 1998) we would, ceteris paribus, expect these to agglomerate the most. Industries purchase intermediates from own sector as well as from other sectors. Columns (c) and (d) of Table 3 give a summary of key characteristics regarding the average intermediate use. Column (c) shows the use of input from own sector as share of output value; column (d) gives total use of intermediates from all sectors as share of value of output. The ratio (c) /(d) hence indicates the importance of intra- relative to inter-industry intermediate inputs. These shares — disaggregated at country and industry level — are used to calibrate the parameters in the cost function (9). A higher share of own industry inputs means that supplier-proximity to firms from the same sector becomes more important. An expansion of the own sector at home comes in the form of more domestically located firms, which leads to a lower price index Q and therefore to lower marginal costs. Hence, the use of intermediates from own industry creates a positive feedback and makes agglomeration self-reinforcing. However, the use of intermediates from other sectors may work both for and against agglomeration depending on the location of the supplying sectors. A strong dependence on sectors that are rather dispersed across regions or alternatively concentrated in another region than the purchasing sector, discourages agglomeration. In general, we would ceteris paribus expect industries with a strong bias towards use of inputs from own industries (high (c)), and with intra-industry linkages that are stronger than inter-industry linkages, to be relatively more concentrated geographically.10 From Table 3 we can see that textiles, wood products, metals and chemicals are industries with an above average use of inputs from own sector and which also have stronger within than between industry linkages. For low trade costs, agglomeration forces become weak. Instead comparative advantage forces will tend to dominate. Industries have different factor intensities, which opens up for location of production based on comparative advantage. This does, however, not necessarily imply a greater geographical dispersion of production in an industry; depending on the interaction between the total set of forces determining location, comparative advantage may reinforce or discourage 9 Our ranking of industries according to economies of scale follows Pratten (1988). See Fujita et al. (1999) for a discussion of the impact of inter- versus intra-industry linkages on agglomeration. 10 R. Forslid et al. / Journal of International Economics 57 (2002) 273 – 297 283 geographical concentration of industries. The final two columns of Table 3 show factor intensities (averages for the four integrating regions). Chemicals, transport equipment and machinery are skill-intensive sectors. Textiles and leather use unskilled labour intensively (and will hence be labelled labour intensive), while food products and minerals are capital intensive. Table A.2 in Appendix A provides some regional characteristics for the four integrating regions. It should be observed that South is relatively abundantly endowed with unskilled labour, while North is relatively abundant in skilled labour. As for capital endowment, Central and North are relatively more capital abundant than South and West. In terms of relative size of the regions, West and Central are of about the same size, while South is considerably smaller, and North is only around 1 / 7 of the large core regions. Since we know that home market effects may have a strong impact on the location of production, the relative size of the regions may play an important role. 3. Economic integration and the location of production We now turn to the question of how the pattern of industrial production may change as trade impediments are dismantled between the four integrating regions in our model. We first discuss the relocation of individual manufacturing sectors resulting from trade liberalisation. In a simple two-region model it is obvious what increased industrial concentration means, while in our case with four integrating regions it is less clear. We therefore proceed by analysing changes in locational patterns using concentration indices. These indices provide us with an overall picture of the degree of industrial concentration. We first study such a concentration measure for each manufacturing industry individually, and then we look at the total geographical concentration for all traded manufacturing production. This latter measure indicates whether industries tend to agglomerate in the same or in different regions. Our model experiments consist of successive lowering of all three types of trade costs (transport costs, tariffs and export taxes) with 10% per step, starting from the benchmark situation.11 We do, however, also show the result for a few steps of increase in trade costs. We focus on the imperfectly competitive, traded goods (ITG) sectors. Agriculture and energy are modelled with perfect competition and free trade, which implies that agglomeration forces are absent in these sectors. Still, decreasing returns to scale in these sectors — due to specific factors — act to 11 It is well known from theoretical work that there may be multiple equilibria in models like this. We cannot rule out such possibilities in the present model. However, extensive model experiments have not revealed such multiple equilibria. One possible reason why multiple equilibria do not occur, may be the non-negativity restrictions that are placed on most economic variables in the model. 284 R. Forslid et al. / Journal of International Economics 57 (2002) 273 – 297 dampen the expansion and concentration of the ITG sectors as labour and capital have to be drawn into the ITG industries at increasing cost. 3.1. Changing patterns of production We shall here describe the simulated production patterns, while leaving further analysis of geographical concentration to the next section. Fig. 1 shows how production in different sectors changes as trade costs are lowered between the four regions.12 The horizontal axis depicts trade costs relative to the base case, i.e. trade cost51 in the base case (e.g. 0.5 means half of base-case trade costs). Three sectors — textiles, leather, and food products — show the most dramatic patterns in terms of changing locations. Textiles move out of Central and into West and South. Leather expands in South, while contracting in all other regions. Food production leaves South and Central, moving into North but particularly into West. Consider first textiles. For very low trade costs production abruptly disappears from Central and agglomerates in West and South. The possibility of abrupt changes in location as trade costs are lowered, is well known from theory (e.g. Krugman, 1991). Table 3 shows that within-industry linkages are relatively strong in textiles production, which implies that self-reinforcing forces of agglomeration are likely to be important for the location of production; thus, the sector is a candidate for strong relocation effects. It should also be noted that textile production is a relatively small industry, implying that large swings in this sector can occur without causing much pressure in the factor markets. The reason why textiles expand so substantially in South seems rather clear: textile production is one of the most (unskilled) labour-intensive industries, and South has a comparative advantage in the production of labour-intensive goods. But why does production of textiles move out of Central and into West, and not vice versa? Factor endowments cannot explain this change in production patterns. The presence of agglomeration forces, however, implies that even small, initial difference may suffice to tip the balance in favour of one location. In our case West does have a slightly larger initial textiles production than Central. Another small industry is the leather industry, which exhibits a locational pattern similar to textiles — with low trade costs leading to a core-periphery outcome. The difference is that the relocation of production is more continuous and that agglomeration only takes place in one region: South. The characteristics of the leather sector are similar to textiles. However, in the base case the leather production of South is more than twice as large as in any other region, which together with South’s comparative advantage in labour-intensive production, is 12 For clarity, two sectors have been left out of the presentation when discussing the individual sectors. These are other manufacturing which is a fairly heterogenous group of industries and wood products which are strongly affected by subsidies in the North. The locational effects for all sectors are presented in the working paper version of this paper: Forslid et al. (1999a). R. Forslid et al. / Journal of International Economics 57 (2002) 273 – 297 285 Fig. 1. Production (billion US $). certainly the main explanation for the resulting agglomeration in this region. The more continuous relocation of this sector is consistent with a relatively low own input share, and thus less significant intra-industry linkages. The large swings in production of food products are linked to this industry’s 286 R. Forslid et al. / Journal of International Economics 57 (2002) 273 – 297 initially high trade costs (cf. Table 3). One surprise, perhaps, is that this industry starts to agglomerate in North for low trade costs, even though this region initially has production that is only one third or less of the other regions’ production volume. The explanation seems to be that food products are relatively capitalintensive, which gives North a comparative advantage. Food products are also characterised by rather low (increasing) returns to scale and a low own input share, which ceteris paribus make proximity to a large market less important for its location, and further justify the movement into the northern periphery when trade costs go down. What about the remaining ITG industries? Most of these industries exhibit relatively stable patterns of localisation. It should, however, be noted that they generally display a non-monotonous relationship between trade liberalisation and location. Among these industries are the four sectors with the most significant increasing-returns-to-scale technology (see Table 3): metals, chemicals, transport equipment and machinery. In the base case they are all rather concentrated in the two largest regions: Central and West. Substantial increasing returns to scale and the presence of intra-industry linkages suggest that proximity to markets and self-reinforcing agglomeration forces are important determinants of the location of production in these industries. As trade costs are reduced, the sectors remain concentrated in the core of Europe — close to the larger markets. This may, on the one hand, reflect very strong IRS and intra-industry linkages. However, it could also be the case that market size and factor abundance effects pull in the same direction — maintaining concentration in the core as trade costs are reduced. If a capital intensive industry initially is concentrated in a large capital abundant country, a fall in trade cost reduces the market size incentive to stay concentrated, but increases the factor market incentive to do so — and the result may typically be relative stable patterns of localisation. Taking a more aggregated perspective, Fig. 2 displays the share of ITG-industry Fig. 2. ITG shares across European regions. R. Forslid et al. / Journal of International Economics 57 (2002) 273 – 297 287 in each of the regions. North, being by far the smallest region, shows a distinct U-shaped pattern with a loss of ITG-industry for intermediate trade costs for which agglomerative forces reach a maximum. The large region Central exhibits an inverse relationship between ITG share and trade costs. The region’s dominant position in the ITG sectors is reinforced for intermediate trade costs, while it may decline as trade costs are further reduced. West shows a monotonous increase in ITG-share as trade costs are lowered, while the ITG share of South actually follows a bell-shaped pattern, although it is not very distinct. To conclude this section, we see that comparative advantages as well as economies of scale and intra-industry linkages interact in determining the location of industry. Due to differing industry characteristics, there are, however, large differences across industries as to which factors are relatively more important as determinants of location. 3.2. Industrial concentration So far we have investigated the reallocation of industry sectors triggered by economic integration. It is, however, not clear from this analysis whether industrial production becomes more or less concentrated in Europe as a consequence of integration. To take only a few examples, it is not obvious from Fig. 1 whether the production of transport equipment gets more or less concentrated as integration takes place; it is also difficult to see what happens to the concentration of e.g. production of chemicals. In this and the next section we shall focus on industrial concentration using summary indices of concentration. We start by analysing the concentration tendencies of individual industries, using a measure for absolute industrial concentration of the following form,13 œSNO s 2SO s D D /NsN 2 1d, Ci 5 ]]]]]]]]] 2 2 j ij j ij with s ij 5 Xij / o j Xij being the share of production in industry i taking place in region j, and with N depicting the number of integrating regions (i.e. four). The index of absolute concentration, Ci , is the standard deviation of the distribution of s ij . A high value of this statistic indicates a highly concentrated industry. Fig. 3 illustrates how increased integration affects the degree of concentration of the ITG industries. There appear to be two groups of industries. Consider first metals, chemicals, transport equipment and machinery — a group of industries where concentration displays an (inverted) U-shaped curve as the regions are integrated. These industries all have high scale elasticities (cf. Table 3), indicating strong agglomera13 The differing sizes of the units (the regions) make relative indices a less attractive choice as a measure of industrial concentration. See Haaland et al. (1999) and Midelfart Knarvik et al. (2000) for discussion of the use of relative and absolute measures of concentration. 288 R. Forslid et al. / Journal of International Economics 57 (2002) 273 – 297 Fig. 3. Industrial concentration. tion forces. When trade costs are reduced from a high level, concentration initially increases. However, lower trade costs also decrease the agglomeration forces so that, when a critical level of trade costs is reached, the process is reversed as factor market pressures start to dominate. These pressures will tend to dampen the overall tendency of industrial agglomeration, but whether this will make individual R. Forslid et al. / Journal of International Economics 57 (2002) 273 – 297 289 industries concentrate more or less, depends on the interaction between industry intensities and regional characteristics. We would expect industries with high economies of scale to concentrate in large markets. Hence, it comes as no surprise that initially they are all rather concentrated in the large regions Central and West, with Central having the dominant position in all four industries. Metals and chemicals moreover exhibit relatively strong intra-industry linkages. Even though the changes in concentration that we observe are modest, there is a clear pattern: when trade costs are reduced, agglomeration is first reinforced, confirming that the forces of agglomeration are strongest for ‘intermediate’ levels of trade costs. Declining concentration then follows this development. Metals experience the most significant decline in geographical concentration (around 19%): Central’s dominant position is reduced, while especially West increases its share of the industry. Textiles, leather, and food products constitute the second group of industries, and these become increasingly concentrated as integration proceeds. Hence, the industries where lower trade costs imply agglomeration, are exactly the same industries as the ones that exhibit the most dramatic changes in location patterns. As argued in the previous section, comparative advantage is a dominating factor for textiles and leather, amplified by strong intra-industry linkages and the initial pattern of production. Significant initial impediments to trade constitute an important explanation for the large movements of the third sector in this group (food products). 3.3. Overall concentration Having studied concentration effects for individual industries, a natural question is whether industries — to the extent that they become more concentrated — tend to concentrate in the same or in different regions. In other words, will all manufacturing activities tend to concentrate in the core, with de-industrialisation of the periphery? We measure the degree of overall industrial concentration by the following index: ]]]]]]]]] 2 2 H5 N jhj 2 /NsN 2 1d, j hj œS O SO D D with h j 5 o i Xij / o j o i Xij being the share of overall manufacturing production taking place in region j, and with N depicting the number of regions subject to integration. Fig. 4 shows the concentration of the ITG sector. Agglomeration forces tend to dominate for intermediate trade costs, while factor market effects become more important for low trade costs. Although this U-shaped pattern is well known from simple theoretical two-sector models, it is not obvious from theory that we should get such a pattern in a multi-sector model. Even if agglomeration forces in each 290 R. Forslid et al. / Journal of International Economics 57 (2002) 273 – 297 Fig. 4. Overall industrial concentration. sector would work like this, it could well be the case that the sectors would be pulled in different directions. Whether they actually end up in the same or different regions will depend on the trade-off between on the one hand agglomeration forces through inter-industry linkages, and on the other hand general equilibrium factor price effects. Fig. 4 indicates that — at least for intermediate trade costs — agglomeration forces may yield increased overall concentration of manufacturing activities as a consequence of economic integration. 4. Factor prices and welfare Whereas the patterns of industrial concentration and specialisation are interesting phenomena in their own right, the main reason for the political interest received by the new economic geography, is probably the theoretically based presumption about a relationship between the pattern of production and specialisation and real national income. Moreover, from neoclassical trade theory there are strong reasons to expect changes in national income to be unevenly distributed among different factors of production. We therefore next investigate the effects of economic integration on factor prices. 4.1. Factor prices In a Heckscher–Ohlin framework, regional specialisation will have very different impact on the factors of production in a region. The relatively abundant factor will gain whereas the scarce factor will lose according to the Stolper– Samuelson theorem. Indeed, it has been put forward as a serious problem of economic integration that in regions well endowed with skilled labour — in our R. Forslid et al. / Journal of International Economics 57 (2002) 273 – 297 291 Fig. 5. Real factor prices. case North and West — integration tends to benefit skilled labour at the expense of unskilled. Fig. 5 shows changes in real factor returns in the four integrating regions relative to the benchmark situation (t 5 1). Two features should be noted. Firstly, changes in factor prices are in general rather correlated with the ITG-shares in the region (Fig. 2). Secondly, although there is substantial co-variation in factor prices within a region, relative factor prices do indeed mirror Stolper–Samuelson effects. For instance, for low trade costs, skilled labour is a relative winner both in North and West, as skill-intensive industries agglomerate in these regions, while low-skilled workers are the relative winners in South. 4.2. Welfare Traditional trade models would predict gains from specialisation according to comparative advantages, but the theory would not predict that some industries are ‘more worth’ than other industries. New trade theory models allow industries to differ — saying that there are potential gains from getting a larger share of industries in which there are pure profits. In our model, free entry and exit of firms in all industries eliminate pure profits. Yet, the interaction between the desire for variety, imperfect competition, and industry linkages generates ‘agglomeration rents’. These rents show up in the returns to factors of production and in the price 292 R. Forslid et al. / Journal of International Economics 57 (2002) 273 – 297 indices for imperfectly competitive goods sectors. For these sectors, trade costs and the number of varieties matter for the price level of an industry aggregate (see (2) and (4)); hence, the more local varieties there are, the lower is the price level and the higher is real income and welfare. Since the magnitude of such rents differs between industries, the location of manufacturing activities may have important welfare implications. Ceteris paribus a region gains from getting more of the industries with large agglomeration benefits relative to other industries. Whether these gains are strong enough to outweigh other effects of relocation of industry, is an empirical question; in this section we present some indicative ‘evidence’ of the importance of such rents for real income. Fig. 6 shows the real GDP in each of the four integrating regions, relative to the benchmark level (t 5 1). Two things should be noticed. Firstly, for successive steps of liberalisation for trade costs between 1 and 0.5 all regions gain, in spite of increased concentration (see Fig. 4). The welfare effects are, however, modest for these intermediate trade costs. For high and low trade costs, on the other hand, there are winners and losers. Secondly, the results in Fig. 6 together with Fig. 2 reveal a close link between a region’s specialisation in imperfectly competitive traded goods (ITG) industries and real income. Fig. 2 shows the aggregate share of total value of production taking place in the ITG industries. In reality, the ITG-share is only a crude measure of the agglomeration rents created in the imperfectly competitive sector, as there is significant variation with regard to these rents across the ITG industries. Nevertheless, the results are quite illustrative, suggesting that there are tight links between specialisation in ITG industries and real GDP. Fig. 6. Real GDP relative to benchmark case (t 5 1). R. Forslid et al. / Journal of International Economics 57 (2002) 273 – 297 293 5. Conclusions This paper applies a full-scale CGE model to study the locational effects of economic integration. Our experiment is to gradually reduce trade costs, and study the pattern of industrial concentration in individual industries as well as for manufacturing as a whole. This should be viewed primarily as an exercise to get numeric intuition about higher order properties of simple theoretical trade and location models (e.g. Fujita et al., 1999). We use the EURORA model (Forslid et al., 1999b), which has a complete input–output structure in the sense that all linkages across the 14 sectors in the model are taken into account and are modelled in detail. From stylised theoretical models we know that in a setting with imperfect competition, trade costs and intra- and inter-industry linkages, there is a trade-off between forces working for and against agglomeration. Location is determined by the interaction of consumer-proximity considerations, supplier-proximity considerations, and factor-market competition. On the basis of the theoretical economic geography models there is moreover one possible outcome of economic integration that has been especially emphasised; a bell-shaped (inverted U-shape) relationship between trade costs and geographical concentration of the imperfectly competitive sector; where agglomeration forces dominate for intermediate trade costs. The question, however, is to which extent this result comes through in a multi-sector, multi-factor, multi-region framework — and if so, at what level do we typically see it? At the level of the individual industry, or at the level of the manufacturing sector? Several results follow from our simulations. Firstly, on the industry level the locational response to lower trade costs depends on industry characteristics. For a number of industries we find an (inverted) U-shaped relationship between integration and concentration — industrial concentration is low for high and low trade costs, and higher for intermediate trade costs. A common feature for these industries is that there are significant increasing returns to scale and important intra-industry linkages. For other industries there is a monotonous increase in concentration as trade costs are lowered. These industries are typically industries in which scale economies are less important, but where initial trade costs have prevented sufficient specialisation according to comparative advantage. Secondly, on the aggregate level of the imperfectly competitive sectors, we find that the (inverted) U-shaped relationship between economic integration and overall concentration in manufacturing, well known from stylised theoretical models, actually carries over to a more realistic higher-order setting with multiple product and factor markets. Thirdly, we investigate the effects on factor prices and welfare. Our simulations show how agglomeration forces as well as standard comparative advantage forces drive factor prices. On the one hand factor prices in a region tend to co-vary because of agglomeration forces, but on the other hand relative changes go in the 294 R. Forslid et al. / Journal of International Economics 57 (2002) 273 – 297 Stolper–Samuelson direction. This implies that the concerns regarding intraregional income distribution associated with trade liberalisation in a traditional trade model may possibly be muted, while the distribution of real income between regions is a potential issue of concern. Our results show a correlation between real income gains and growth in manufacturing production. However, in our simulations, contrary to stylised theoretical models of trade and location where real wages and welfare fall sharply in the periphery when agglomeration occurs, all regions may actually gain during a large part of the integration process in spite of increasing concentration. Acknowledgements An earlier version of this paper has been presented at the SNEE conference, ¨ Molle, and at the European Research Workshop in International Trade (ERWIT) in Bergen, both in June 1999. Thanks to the participants, and in particular to Richard Baldwin, Karolina Ekholm, Joe Francois, Michael Gasiorek, Jim Markusen, Victor D. Norman and Diego Puga for comments and suggestions. We are also grateful to two anonymous referees and the editor for very useful comments. Financial support from the Research Council of Norway grant no. 124559 / 510 and from the European Commission (TMR) is gratefully acknowledged. Appendix A Data Data sources for input–output tables, trade flows and factor shares are EUROSTAT (EU input–output tables), GTAP (Global Trade Analysis Project) database and NBER World Trade Flows (see Feenstra, 1997). A detailed description of data, data sources, and how the benchmark data set was constructed, can be found in Forslid et al. (1999b) or obtained from the authors upon request. Forslid et al. (1999b) also provides a descriptive analysis of the data material, focusing on the distribution of production across regions, trade flows and trade volume, differences in technology and factor use across industries. Our data on economies of scale have been taken from Cawley and Davenport (1988), who base their estimates on Pratten (1988). Transport costs and data on trade barriers are from GTAP versions 3 and 4. Regions and regional characteristics Table A.1 gives details of the regions. Table A.2 presents some key characteristics for the four integrating regions. As R. Forslid et al. / Journal of International Economics 57 (2002) 273 – 297 295 Table A.1 Regions Regions Description Central North South West Austria, Denmark, Germany, Switzerland Finland, Iceland, Norway, Sweden Greece, Italy, Portugal, Spain BeNeLux, Ireland, France, UK Europe East Bulgaria, Hungary, Czech. Rep., Poland, Romania, Slovakia, Slovenia Former Soviet Republics including Estonia, Lithuania, Latvia China, India, Bangladesh, Bhutan, Maldives, Nepal, Pakistan, Sri Lanka South East Asia including Japan USA and Canada Other nations not elsewhere included Former Soviet Union China and South Asia South East Asia USA and Canada Rest of the world Table A.2 Relative factor endowments and relative size Unskilled / skilled labour force Labour / capital stock Share of European GDP a Central North South West 4.02 1.69 7.41 2.77 0.019 0.017 0.038 0.037 34.5% 5.8% 24.3% 35.5% Mean 2.99 0.028 a Base case (1992) model data. we cannot separate factor prices and factor stocks in our benchmark data, we use the factor endowments data provided by Maskus and Penubarti (1995). References Allen, C., Gasiorek, M., Smith, A., 1998. The competition effects of the single market in Europe. Economic Policy 27, 439–486. Amiti, M., 1998. Inter-industry trade in manufactures: does country size matter? Journal of International Economics 44, 231–255. Baldwin, R.E., Forslid, R., Haaland, J.I., 1996. Investment creation and investment diversion in Europe. The World Economy 19, 635–659. Baldwin, R.E., Francois, J.F., Portes, R., 1997. The costs and benefits of eastern enlargement: the impact on the EU and central Europe. Economic Policy 24, 125–176. 296 R. Forslid et al. / Journal of International Economics 57 (2002) 273 – 297 Brown, D.K., Deardorff, A.V., Stern, R.M., 1992. A North American Free Trade Agreement: analytical issues and a computational assessment. The World Economy 15, 11–30. Brown, D.K., Deardorff, A.V., Fox, A.K., Stern, R.M., 1995. Computational analysis of goods and services liberalization in the Uruguay Round. In: Martin, W., Winters, L.A. (Eds.), The Uruguay Round and the Developing Economies. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp. 365–380. Cawley R., Davenport M., 1988. Partial equilibrium calculations of the impact of internal market barriers in the European Community. In Commission of the European Communities: Research on the cost of non-Europe, Vol. 2: Studies on the economics of integration, Luxembourg. Davis, D.R., 1998. The home market, trade and industrial structure. American Economic Review 88, 1264–1276. EFTA, 1994. European Economic Integration. Effects of ‘1992’ on the Services Sectors of the EFTA Countries. EFTA, Occasional papers, no. 49. Feenstra, R.C., 1997. World Trade Flows, 1970–1992, with Production and Tariff Data. NBER, Working paper no. 5910. Forslid, R., Haaland, J.I., Midelfart Knarvik, K.H., 1999a. A U-shaped Europe? A simulation study of industrial location. CEPR, Discussion paper no. 2247. Forslid, R., Haaland, J.I., Mæstad, O., Midelfart Knarvik, K.H., 1999b. Integration and Transition: Scenarios for Location of Production and Trade in Europe. NHH, Discussion paper no. 13 / 99. Francois, J.F., McDonald, B., Nordstrom, H., 1995. Assessing the Uruguay Round. In: Martin, W., Winters, L.A. (Eds.), The Uruguay Round and the Developing Economies. Cambridge University Press. Fujita, M., Krugman, P.R., Venables, A.J., 1999. The Spatial Economy: Cities, Regions and International Trade. MIT Press. Gasiorek, M., Smith, A., Venables, A.J., 1991. Completing the internal market in the EC: factor demands and comparative advantage. In: Venables, A.J., Winters, L.A. (Eds.), European Integration: Trade and Industry. Cambridge University Press. Gasiorek, M., Smith, A., Venables, A.J., 1992. ‘1992’: trade and welfare — a general equilibrium analysis. In: Winters, A. (Ed.), Trade Flows and Trade Policy after ‘1992’. CEPR and Cambridge University Press. Haaland, J.I., Norman, V.D., 1992. Global production effects of European integration. In: Winters, A. (Ed.), Trade Flows and Trade Policy after ‘1992’. CEPR and Cambridge University Press. Haaland, J.I., Kind, H.J., Midelfart Knarvik, K.H., Torstensson, J., 1999. What determines the economic geography of Europe? CEPR, Discussion paper no. 2072. Harrison, G.W., Rutherford, T.F., Tarr, D.G., 1995. Quantifying the Uruguay Round. In: Martin, W., Winters, L.A. (Eds.), The Uruguay Round and the Developing Economies. Cambridge University Press, pp. 215–284. Harrison, G.W., Rutherford, T.F., Tarr, D.G., 1996. Increased competition and completion of the market in the European Union: static and steady state effects. Journal of Economic Integration 11, 332–365. Keuschnigg, C., Kohler, W., 1996. Austria in the European Union: dynamic gains from integration and distributional implications. Economic Policy 22, 155–212. Krugman, P.R., 1980. Scale economies, product differentiation, and the pattern of trade. American Economic Review 70, 950–959. Krugman, P.R., 1991. Increasing returns and economic geography. Journal of Political Economy 99, 483–499. Krugman, P.R., Venables, A.J., 1995. Globalization and the inequality of nations. Quarterly Journal of Economics CX, 857–879. Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Markusen, J.R., Rutherford, T.F., 1994. The auto industry and the North American Free Trade Agreement. In: Francois, J.F., Shiells, C.R. (Eds.), Modeling Trade Policy: Applied General Equilibrium Assessments in North American Free Trade. Cambridge University Press, pp. 223–255. Maskus, K.E., Penubarti, M., 1995. How trade related are intellectual property rights? Journal of International Economics 39, 227–248. R. Forslid et al. / Journal of International Economics 57 (2002) 273 – 297 297 Midelfart Knarvik, K.H., Overman, H., Redding, S., Venables, A.J., 2000. The Location of European Industry. Report Prepared for the Directorate General for Economic and Financial Affairs, European Commission. European Commission, Brussels, Economic papers no. 142. Pratten C. 1988. Partial equilibrium calculations of the impact of internal market barriers in the European Community. In Commission of the European Communities: Research on the cost of non-Europe, Vol. 2: Studies on the economies of integration, Luxembourg. Puga, D., Venables, A.J., 1996. The spread of industry: spatial agglomeration in economic development. Journal of the Japanese and International Economies 10, 440–464. Roland-Holst, D.W., Reinert, K.A., Shiells, C.R., 1994. A general equilibrium analysis of North American economic integration. In: Francois, J.F., Shiells, C.R. (Eds.), Modeling Trade Policy: Applied General Equilibrium Assessments in North American Free Trade. Cambridge University Press.