SØK/ECON 535 Imperfect Competition and Strategic Interaction ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION Lecture notes 15.09.02 Introduction Asymmetric information Information exchange Signalling in order to influence expectations Static price competition with uncertainty Two firms, 1 and 2. Differentiated products: Di ( pi , p j ) = 1 − pi + p j ; i , j = 1,2; i ≠ j Constant unit costs: c1 = c1L with probability E c1 = xc1L + [1 − x ] c1H ; x and c2 = c1H with probability 1-x, c2 given. i Ex post profits: Π ( pi , p j ) = [ pi − ci ] 1 − pi + p j We look for the Bertrand equilibrium in a game in which firms choose prices * * L L * H H simultaneously: p2 , p1 = p1 if c1 = c1 and p1 = p1 if c1 = c1 . Reaction functions Firm 1: R1 = 1 2 [1 + p2 + c1 ], E R1 = 21 [1 + p2 + E c1 ] ; Firm 2: R2 = 1 2 [1 + E p1 + c2 ] L H Figure (reaction functions: R1 , R1 ,E R1, R2 Equilibrium: 3 + 2c1s + c2 , s = L, H, 3 3 + 2c2 + E c1 p2* = 3 p1s = Conclusion: prices decreasing in the probability x of low costs; ‘as if’ Firm 1 has costs E c1 Information exchange Assume Firm 1 can provide verifiable information about its costs before competition in prices take place. Note that it would always be in Firm 1’s interest that Firm 2 chooses a high price. Therefore: H if c1 = c1 , Firm 1 would inform about this; L if c1 = c1 , Firm 1 would like to conceal this information. However, realising what the incentives of Firm 1 are, Firm 2 would treat no information as evidence that costs are low (because, if costs were high, Firm 1 would have provided information about this). We consequently have a ‘separating equilibrium’; the informed party’s strategic choice depends on the realisation of events. If it is not possible to provide verifiable information, Firm 1 may try to ‘signal’ via its choice of strategy. Signalling Milgrom-Roberts (Econometrica, 1982). Two firms, 1 and 2. Three stages: 1) Firm 1 chooses its price p1 . 2) Firm 2 chooses whether to enter the market or not. 3) Firm 1 and (possibly) Firm 2 choose prices simultaneously. 2 Firm 1’s costs are low with probability x and high with probability 1-x. Firm 1’s costs are private information ex ante, but become known to Firm 2 ex post upon entry. Firm 2’s costs are given (and common knowledge). Define M1t ( p1 ) is Firm 1’s monopoly profits at price p1 , t = L,H, pmt is Firm 1’s profit-maximising (static) monopoly price, t = L,H, ( ) Mmt = M1t pmt is Firm 1’s maximum (static) monopoly profits, t = L,H, Dit is Firm i’s duopoly profits, i = 1,2, t = L,H. Note: because of the assumption that Firm 2 learns Firm 1’s costs upon entry ex post price competition is independent of the price charged ex ante. H L Assume D2 > 0 > D2 ; that is, entry is profitable only if Firm 2 has high costs. The discount factor is δ . Note: Firm 1 will want to give the impression that its costs are low in order to keep Firm 2 out of the market. It can do so by charging a low price also when costs are in fact high; this will lead to a loss in ex ante profits (since price does not maximise static monopoly profits) but this is compensated for by a monopoly market position, and hence higher profits, ex post. Firm 2 will, to the extent that it understands Firm 1’s strategy, take this into account and hence will not necessarily be ‘fooled’. Firm 1 understands this, and so on. Two kinds of equilibria: separating: the informed party’s strategy depends on its information (here p1L ≠ p1H ). Hence, the uninformed party can infer the underlying information from observing the informed party’s strategic choice; pooling: the informed party’s strategy does not depend on its information L H (here p1 = p1 = p1 ). Hence the uninformed party does not learn from observing the strategic choice of the informed party. Separating equilibrium Equilibrium conditions include H Firm 1, when it has low costs, must not benefit from choosing price p1 L instead of p1 , and vice versa; 3 Expectations upon out-of-equilibrium moves must be specified (here: what L H Firm 2 believes if observing a price different from either p1 or p1 ). Since Firm 2 will enter when believing that Firm 1 has high costs, Firm 1 may H H as well choose p1 = pm in this case. Firm 1’s equilibrium profits is H H consequently Mm + δ D1 . L Suppose Firm 1 where to choose p1 when its costs are high. Given that Firm 2 would not enter (believing that Firm 1 do have low costs), Firm 1’s profits H L H would be M1 p1 + δ Mm . A necessary condition for equilibrium is therefore ( ) ( ) MmH + δ D1H ≥ M1H p1L + δ MmH To make the problem interesting, we assume this condition is not satisfied for p1L = pmL ; in other words, the low-cost type must charge an ex ante price below the (static) monopoly price in order to signal convincingly that costs are low. L L Note that Firm 1, when having low costs, could ensure a profit of Mm + δ D1 , and hence we must have ( ) M1L p1L + δ MmL ≥ MmL + δ D1L . Under reasonable assumptions, these two conditions define an interval < pL . i ,p p p m 1 1 with 1 Example: Linear specification Let demand be Q m ( p1 ) = 3 − p1 in the duopoly case and Qi ( p1, p2 ) = 1 − pi + pi in the duopoly case; L H costs be c1 = 0, c1 = 1 and c2 = 0 ; entry costs be f = 1; and discount factor be δ = 1 . Then we have pmL = 1.5, pmH = 2, MmL = 9 4 and MmH = 1; D1L = 1 and D1H = 4 9 ; 4 D2L = 0 and D2H = 7 9 . Furthermore, we have ( ) ; D1H ≥ M1H p1L ⇒ p1L ≤ 1.25 = p 1 ( ) i . M1L p1L ≥ D1L ⇒ p1L ≥ 0.38 = p 1 Returning to the general model, equilibrium may be described as follows: H H L Firm 1: in the first period, choose p1 = pm if costs are high and p1 = pˆ1 , otherwise. L Firm 2: if p1 ≤ p1 expect entry to be unprofitable and stay out; otherwise, enter. Note: out-of-equilibrium expectations is that entry is profitable if a high price is L observed (this is what deters Firm 1 from deviating from p1 when costs are low); L there exists a continuum of similar separating equilibria, with p1 ∈ p1, pˆ1 . Conclusion: ‘limit-pricing’, but Firm 2 becomes perfectly informed’; limit-pricing is necessary in order not to be considered a high-cost firm; welfare is greater than in the case of full information (since price is lower in the low-cost event). Pooling equilibrium L H A pooling equilibrium does not exist if xD1 + [1 − x ] D1 > 0 . To see this, note that Firm 2 would enter if Firm 1 played a pooling strategy (no information revealed). However, given this, Firm 1 would rather want to charge the relevant (cost dependent) monopoly price. L H Assume xD1 + [1 − x ] D1 ≤ 0 . For pooling to be part of an equilibrium requires 5 M1H ( p1 ) + δ MmH ≥ MmH + δ D1H M1L ( p1 ) + δ MmL ≥ MmL + δ D1L There generally exists an interval of prices p1 that satisfies these conditions. If Firm 2 believes, upon observing (out-of-equilibrium) prices different from the equilibrium (pooling) price p1 , that entry is profitable, a pooling equilibrium can be supported. Conclusion: Firm 2 remains uninformed; there is less entry than with symmetric information; implications for welfare are not obvious. Variations on the model Alternative formulations: if Firm 2’s costs are not known to Firm 2, but correlated with the costs of Firm 1, Firm 1 will want to choose a high price in order to signal that costs are high; if demand, rather than costs, are unobservable to Firm 2, Firm 1 will want to choose a low price to signal that demand is low. 6