ECON 4820 Strategic Competition STATIC OLIGOPOLY MODELS Lecture notes 02.02.04 Nash Equilibrium Describes strategic interaction by equilibrium in non-cooperative games. Strategies: ai , i = 1,2,..., n . Payoff (profit) functions: Π i ( ai ; a− i ) . Definition: a strategy combination (a * 1,...,a * n) constitutes a Nash equilibrium if, for i = 1,...,n, ∀ai : Π i (ai∗ , a−∗ i ) ≥ Π i (ai , a−∗ i ) The Cournot model Strategies are quantities (supply/output): qi , i = 1,2,...n . Firms choose simultaneously (i.e. without knowing their competitors’ strategies). Duopoly (n = 2) Homogeneous products. Profit functions: Π i ( qi , q j ) = P (Q ) qi − Ci ( qi ) ,Q = q1 + q2 , i = 1,2 . Π i is assumed strictly concave and two times differentiable. FOC: P ′ (Q ) qi + P (Q ) − Ci′ ( qi ) = 0 Negative external effect on competitor’s profit P ′ (Q ) q j ; therefore producers choose a larger quantity than that which would maximise total profits: P (Q ) − Ci′ ( qi ) = −P ′ (Q ) qi < −P ′ (Q ) Q ⇒ Qd > Qm Price is lower and output greater than in monopoly (perfect cartel). At equilibrium, marginal costs are equal only if firms are symmetric; therefore, for given aggregate output, total costs are generally not minimised. From the FOC we obtain the Lerner index: Li ≡ P − Ci′ α i = ε P where α i = qi Q is i’s market share and ε = − ⎡⎣P ′ (Q ) Q P ⎤⎦ elasticity of demand. −1 is the price Reaction functions (from FOC): Π ii (Ri (qj ),qj ) = 0. 1 Ri′ = − Π iij Π iii <0 if marginal profits decrease as a function of the competitor’s supply (because Π iij = P ′′qi + P ′ , a sufficient condition for this result is that the inverse demand function is convex, i.e. P ′′ < 0 ). If so, quantities are strategic substitutes. Figure (equilibrium described by reaction functions) Example: Linear demand and cost functions: Ci ( qi ) = ci qi and P (Q ) = 1 − Q Ri ( q j ) = 1 − q j − ci 2 Note: a reduction in ci shifts the reaction curve outwards and increases i’s profit-maximising supply. Oligopoly (n ≥ 2) Profit functions: Π i ( qi ;Q− i ) = P (Q ) qi − Ci ( qi ) ,Q− i = ∑ j ≠ì q j Same FOC as above, and same formula for Lerner-indices. From the individual Lerner-indices: L≡ 1 We define P − C′ H = P ε Π ii = ∂Π i ∂qi , Π iii = ∂ 2 Π i ∂qi 2 and so on. 2 where H = ∑ i =1[α i ] is the Hirschmann-Herfindahl concentration index and n 2 C ′ = ∑ i =1α i Ci′ the (weighted) average marginal cost. n Example: linear demand and cost functions Symmetric model: ci = c, i = 1,2,..., n : 1 n 1 q= [1 − c ] n +1 n Q= [1 − c ] n +1 1 p=c+ [1 − c ] → c as n → ∞ n +1 H= Concentration indices Summary statistics for market ‘concentration’, i.e. distribution of market shares. Ideally, an index should treat firms symmetrically; not decrease in value if part of a firm’s market share is transferred to a larger firm; and decrease in value if, in a symmetric industry, the number of firms increase. Order firms such that α1 ≥ α 2 ≥ ... ≥ α n : m-firm concentration ratio: K m = ∑ i =1α i Hirschmann-Herfindahl index: H = ∑ i =1[α i ] m n 2 These indices satisfy the above conditions: take on values between 0 and 1; maximised (= 1) at monopoly; for a given number of firms n, the index reaches its lowest value when firms are equally large. Hirschmann-Herfindahl index puts more weight on smaller firms. 3 Concentration indices may be useful if there is a relationship between market concentration and competition, or, more specifically, performance/welfare. This is the case in the Cournot model (under certain conditions, see above). I other cases, this may not necessarily be true (cf. the Bertrand model). The Bertrand model Strategies: prices pi , i = 1,2,..., n . Firms choose strategies simultaneously. Homogenous duopoly (n = 2) Buyers will shop where the price is lowest (if firms charge same prices we assume they share the market equally). Demand: ⎧D ( pi ) if pi < p j ⎪ Di ( pi , p j ) = ⎨ 21 D ( pi ) if pi = p j ⎪0 if pi > p j ⎩ where D ( p ) is market demand. Assume marginal costs are constant and identical (= c). Nash equilibrium: p1 = p2 = c . ( pi > p j cannot be an equilibrium because j can increase profits by raising price; pi = p j > c cannot be an equilibrium because either firm would want to undercut; pi = p j < c cannot be an equilibrium because either firm would want to raise its price.) Conclusion: duopoly equals perfect competition! In the case of asymmetric costs ( c i > c j ), the only equilibrium involves j obtaining a monopoly at price equal to the cost of i; that is, p j = pi (technical assumptions to guarantee existence. The "Bertrand Paradox" Solutions to the paradox: product differentiation. 4 capacity constraints (Edgeworth); inter-temporal (dynamic) competition (threat of price wars); Product differentiation Demand does not necessarily evaporate even if price exceeds those of the competitors. ( ) Profit functions: π i ( pi , p j ) = pi Di ( pi , p j ) − Ci Di ( pi , p j ) , i = 1,2. π i assumed strictly concave and twice differentiable. ( ) Reaction functions (from first-order conditions): π ii ri ( p j ) , p j = 0 . ri′ = − π iji >0 π iii if marginal profit is increasing in competitor’s price. If so, prices are strategic complements. Figure (equilibrium described by reaction functions) Price competition with capacity constraints Example (costly capacity): Demand: D ( p ) = 1 − p Unit capacity costs: c ∈ ⎡⎣ 34 ,1⎤⎦ Variable costs are constant and normalised to 0 Capacity constraints: qi ≤ qi , i = 1, 2 . Rationing Assume p1 < p2 and D ( p1 ) > q1 : Who gets to buy from Firm 1? Efficient rationing: residual demand equals D ( p2 ) − q1 if D ( p1 ) > q1 , 0 otherwise. Figure (efficient rationing) 5 Two-stage game 1) Firms choose capacities simultaneously. 2) Firms choose prices simultaneously. Trade takes place and profits are realised. We are looking for a Subgame Perfect Equilibrium, in which, from each stage of the game, strategies constitute a Nash equilibrium of the continuation game. Solve the game by backward induction. STAGE 2: Gross monopoly profits equal 1/4. Therefore, no firm will ever choose q > 31 because that would lead to negative profits. Given q ≤ 31 , i = 1, 2 , there exists a unique Nash equilibrium in which p1 = p2 = p* = 1 − q1 − q2 . Proof of existence: There is no point in reducing prices because capacity constraints bind. Profits for Firm 1 when p1 > p2 = p * equals p1 [1 − p1 − q2 ] . At the margin profits are 1 − 2 p1 − q2 < 1 − 2 [1 − q1 − q2 ] − q2 = 2q1 + q2 − 1 ≤ 0. STAGE 1: Reduced-form profit functions, given equilibrium play at Stage 2, are [ ] Π i (q i , q j ) = 1 − q i − q j q i , i = 12 , . In other words, Cournot profits. Conclusions: The two-stage game leads to the same equilibrium outcome as in the Cournot model and, as such, provides a micro-foundation for this model; the difference is that here prices are set by firms rather than by some Walrasian auctioneer or other equilibrating ‘mechanism’. The choice of modelling approach (i.e. between Betrand and Cournot models) may be seen as depending upon the relevance of capacity constraints. Caveats: 6 For larger capacities ( qi > 31 ), an equilibrium in pure strategies generally does not exist and one may have to consider mixed strategies (KrepsSheinkman, 1983). The equivalence with the Cournot model does not necessarily hold for other rationing rules (for example, proportional rationing, such that everyone with willingness to pay above the lowest price has equal probability of getting to buy at this price). Institutional detail – pricing rules and capacity constraints Market outcomes may depend on the finer details of market institutions; in particular, how firms are remunerated. The choice of pricing rule have been important for instance in the debate over reforms of the England & Wales electricity market. A market model Assume demand D is perfectly inelastic. There are two (symmetric) firms with capacities k and unit costs c. Firms set prices simultaneously: pi ∈ ⎡⎣c, P ⎤⎦ . When a firm offers the lowest price it captures the entire market. Its capacity will be fully utilised if demand is sufficiently large. When a firm offers the highest price, it captures residual demand only: ⎧min {D, k } if pi < p j ⎪⎪ 1 Di ( p1, p2 ) = ⎨ 2 D if pi = p j ⎪ ⎪⎩max {0, D − k } if pi > p j Uniform pricing rule A market price is set equal to the price of the marginal supplier; that is, ⎧⎪ min { p1, p2 } if D ≤ k P=⎨ ⎪⎩max { p1, p2 } if D > k Profits: π iu ( p1, p2 ) = [P − c ] Di ( p1, p2 ) , i = 1,2. The equilibrium outcome of the market game depends on the level of demand. 7 LOW-DEMAND PERIODS ( D ≤ k ): There is a unique (Bertrand-like) equilibrium in pure strategies in which p1 = p2 = c . HIGH-DEMAND PERIODS ( D > k ): There are many equilibria, all having outcomes with one firm pricing at P and the other pricing so low as to avoid undercutting; that is, pi = P and p j = b ≥ c, bk ≤ P [D − k ] . Note that in low-demand periods industry profits are zero, while in highdemand periods they are maximised and equal to π 1u + π 2u = ⎡⎣P − c ⎤⎦ D . Ref: N-H von der Fehr and D Harbord (1993): Spot market competition in the UK electricity industry, The Economic Journal, 103, 531-46. Discriminatory pricing rule An alternative pricing rule has each firm being paid its own offer price for all output that it supplies (cf the Bertrand model): π id ( p1, p2 ) = [ pi − c ] Di ( p1, p2 ) , i = 1,2. Again the equilibrium outcome depends on the level of demand. LOW-DEMAND PERIODS ( D ≤ k ): There is a unique (Bertrand-like) equilibrium in pure strategies in which p1 = p2 = c . HIGH-DEMAND PERIODS ( D > k ): There is no equilibrium in pure strategies. There is a (unique) equilibrium in mixed strategies in which firms mix over the interval ⎡⎣c, P ⎤⎦ , with Pr { pi = c} = 0 and Pr pi = P < 1. { } Note that in low-demand periods industry profits are zero, while in highdemand periods they are positive but less than under the uniform pricing rule, that is, 0 < π 1d + π 2d < ⎡⎣P − c ⎤⎦ D . The analysis may be extended in various directions, to include oligopoly, multiple bids and price-elastic demand. Ref: N Fabra, N-H von der Fehr and D Harbord (2004): Designing electricity auctions, CSEM WP-122, University of California Energy Institute. 8