7 Appendix: Not for publication 7.1 Proofs of Lemmas and of Proposition 2 That the capital-output ratio is higher in F firms follows Proof of Lemma 1. < immediately from the fact that κE < κF (shown in the text), since kE /yE = κ1−α E = kF /yF . Similarly, that the capital-labor ratio is higher in F firms follows from κ1−α F observing that kF kE κF κE / = / = nF nE A χA µ ¶ 1−α χ α >1 χ where the inequality again follows from Assumption 1. Proof of Lemma 2. Due to constant-return-to-scale, aggregation holds, thus we can replace individual-firm variables (lower case) by aggregate variables (upper case). Since κE ≡ KEt / (χAt NEt ) is constant and NF t = Nt − NEt , then NEt = KEt KEt , NF t = Nt − , χAt κE χAt κE (23) where κE is given by (9). ¡ l ¡ l ¢ E ¢ E E E l E l E = sE The next-period capital is given by kt+1 t +lt = R / R − ηρt st = R / R − ηρt ζ mt . Using (4), and aggregating over all entrepreneurs yields: ¡ ¢ E α KEt+1 = Rl / Rl − ηρE t ζ ψκE At NEt . (24) Dividing both sides of (24) by KEt , and substituting κE by its equilibrium expression, we obtain (10). That NEt+1 /NEt = (KEt+1 /KEt ) / (1 + z) follows from (23). Recall that the condition ν E > ν is equivalent to à µ ¶1−θ !−1 ψ ρE (1 − η) ρE Rl Rl −θ 1+β > (1 + ν) (1 + z) . l l R − ηρE R − ηρE (1 − ψ) α (25) Using the fact that, ´ 1 Rl − ηρE 1 η 1 ³ −α − 1−α α (1 − ψ) = − = χ − η . Rl ρE ρE Rl Rl and rearranging terms allows us to rewrite (25) as ´ 1 1 1 ³ ψ −α − 1−α α > χ − η (26) (1 − ψ) (1 − ψ) α (1 + ν) (1 + z) Rl µ ³ ´¶θ 1 1 1−θ −α −θ − 1−α α +β (1 − η) (1 − ψ) χ −η . Rl 1 The right-hand side of equation (26) is monotonically decreasing in χ, while the lefthand side is constant. Moreover, since the right-hand side tends to ∞ (0) as χ → 0 (∞), there exists a unique χ̂ such that ´ 1 1 ψ 1 ³ −α − 1−α α χ̂ − η = (1 − ψ) (1 − ψ) α (1 + ν) (1 + z) Rl µ ³ ´¶θ 1 1 1−θ −α −θ − 1−α α +β (1 − η) (1 − ψ) χ̂ −η . Rl Therefore, the condition ν E > ν will be satisfied when χ > χ̂. The following results are immediate. 1. The right-hand side of (26) is decresing in β, η and Rl so this inequality must hold for sufficiently large β, η and Rl . 2. The left-hand side of equation (26) is decreasing in ν and z. Thus, the condition ν E > ν is satisfied for sufficiently small ν and z. Proof of Lemma 3. Using equation (23), and recalling that κE and κF are constant, we can rewrite (12) as: ´ ³ ηρ Bt = ζ W wt−1 Nt−1 − KF t − El KEt R ¶ µ NF t ηρE χNEt W wt−1 Nt−1 At Nt − κF − l κE = ζ At Nt Nt R Nt µ ¶ ¶ µ NEt ηρE χNEt W α At−1 Nt−1 − l κE At Nt = ζ (1 − α) κF − κF 1 − At Nt Nt R Nt ¶ µ α−1 NEt W (1 − α) κF κF At Nt = ζ − 1 + (1 − η) (1 + z) (1 + ν) Nt which proves the Lemma. 1 Proof of Lemma 4. Part (i). We start by proving that ρlE = (1 − ψ) α χ 1−α α R. To this l , aim, observe that, since (assuming that the incentive constraint is binding) mt = ψPtl yEt then ¡ l ¢ © ¡ l ¢α ª (AEt nEt )1−α − wt nEt = max (1 − ψ) Ptl kEt Ξlt kEt nEt The first order condition yields: nEt kl = Et AlEt µ (1 − ψ) (1 − α) Ptl AlEt wt 2 ¶ α1 Then, plugging (19) and (20) into the first order condition yields nEt = ((1 − ψ) χ) 1 α µ Ptl α R 1 ¶− 1−α l kEt AlEt (27) Finally, plugging the optimal nEt into the profit function, and simplifying term, yields the value of a E firm in the labor-intensive sector: ³ ´1−α ³ α ´−1 ³ α ´−1 ¡ l ¢ 1 1 l l ((1 − ψ) χ) α − (1 − α) χ−1 ((1 − ψ) χ) α kEt = (1 − ψ) kEt Ξt kEt R R 1 1−α l l = (1 − ψ) α χ α RkEt ≡ ρlE kEt , (28) where ρlE is identical to ρE in the one-sector model of section 3 (see equation (6)). This is the rate of return for E firms when F firms are active in the labor-intensive industry. Next, we show that, when F firms are active in both industries, the return to investment in the capital-intensive sector for E firms, ρkE , is lower than ρlE . When F firms are active in the capital-intensive industry, the value of a E firm in the labor-intensive sector is ¡ k ¢ ¡ ¢1−α k kEt = (1 − ψ) Ptk AkEt Ξkt kEt k k = (1 − ψ) χ1−α RkEt ≡ ρkE kEt where we have used equation (21) to eliminate Ptk . Finally, Assumption 1 ensures that 1 1 ρlE > ρkE (since (1 − ψ) 1−α χ > 1 ⇔ (1 − ψ) α χ 1−α α > (1 − ψ) χ1−α ). Thus, E firms will not invest in the capital-intensive sector. This completes the proof of part (i) of the Lemma. Part (ii). We prove the argument by constructing a contradiction. Suppose that, l k > 0 and KEt > 0, KFl t > 0. Then, (19) and (20) hold true, and ρlE = when KEt 1 (1 − ψ) α χ 1−α α R as shown in the first part of the proof, see (28). Moreover, ρlE = ρkE = (1 − ψ) χ1−α R, since otherwise E firms would not invest in both industries. Solving for Ptk yields 1 R R χα ¡ >¡ ¢ ¢ k 1−α k 1−α AF t AF t ¡ ¢1−α where the inequality follows from Assumption 1, and Ptk = R/ AkF t is the condition Ptk = (1 − ψ) 1−α α that guarantees that F firms make zero profits in the capital-intensive industries. Thus, the inequality establishes that F firms would be making positive profits in the capitalintensive sector, which is impossible in a competitive equilibrium. Thus, KFl t = 0 when E firms are active in both sectors. This concludes the proof of part (ii) of the Lemma. 3 Proof of Proposition 2. The problem of the monopolist is: ¢ ¡ max P k − R K k , Kk subject to (16), and the equilibrium conditions, (17), (18) and (20). Replacing K k with ¡ ¢σ Y k = ϕP l /P k Y l (by equation 17), we can rewrite the problem as ³¡ ¢1−σ ¡ ¢−σ ´ ¡ l ¢σ l P Y . − R Pk max P k Pk l Here, Y is given by α ¶−1 µ l ¶ 1−α l 1−α α α P P ψ (χ (1 − ψ)) α KEl + AF N. Yl = R R as proven in Section 7.4. The first-order condition yields: ³ ¡ ¢−1 ´ 0 = (1 − σ) + σR P k ¶ µ ³ ¡ k ¢−1 ´ dP l P k dY l P k . σ k l + + 1−R P dP P dP k Y l µ dP l P k dP k P l (29) dY l P k . dP k Y l Differentiating (18) w.r.t. P k yields: ¡ ¢1−σ −ϕσ P k dP l P k = . dP k P l 1 − ϕσ (P k )1−σ Now we compute the elasticities and Differentiating (29) w.r.t. P k yields: ¶ µ 1 YFl dP l P k dY l P k =− 1− . dP k Y l 1 − α Y l dP k P l Therefore, the first-order condition can be rewritten as ³ ¡ k ¢−1 ´ (1 − σ) + σR P ¡ ¢1−σ ¶¶ µ µ ³ ¡ k ¢−1 ´ ϕσ P k 1 YFl = 1−R P , σ− 1− 1−αYl 1 − ϕσ (P k )1−σ which is expression (22) in the text. 7.2 Post-Transition Equilibrium (Section 3.5) In this section, we provide the details of the analysis in Section 3.5 Under log utility, the equilibrium wage, rate of return on capital, output and foreign balance are given by: wt = AEt (1 − α) (1 − ψ) (κEt )α ρt = ρE,t = α (1 − ψ) (κEt )α−1 Yt = AEt Nt (κEt )α Bt Nt β β = = wt χ (1 − α) (1 − ψ) (κEt )α At Nt 1 + β At Nt 1+β 4 If α (1 − η) (1 − ψ) > ψR β , 1 + β (1 + z) (1 + ν) (30) then capital in E firms evolves according to (14) and eventually converges to a steady state, where κ∗E = µ ψ ηα (1 − ψ) β + 1 + β (1 + z) (1 + ν) R 1 ¶ 1−α . Here we let Rl = R in the steady state. The steady state rate of return to capital is thus equal to ρ∗E = α (1 − ψ) ψ β 1+β (1+z)(1+ν) + ηα(1−ψ) R . Condition (30) ensures that ρ∗E > R; i.e., entrepreneurs never invest in bonds. Otherwise, entrepreneurs will eventually place part of their savings in bank deposits.. 5 7.3 Analysis of Footnote 33 in Section 4.3 In this section, we provide a complete formal argument of the discussion in footnote 33. Assume, for simplicity, log preferences and η = 0. Let χi denote firm i0 s productivity and Ki be the corresponding capital stock. Then, the rate of return to capital for firm i is 1−α 1 1 ρiE = (1 − ψ) α χi α Rl = ω ρ · χiα , where ωρ is a unimportant constant. The law of motion of capital for firm i can be written as 1 KiEt+1 = ω K χiα , KiEt where ω K is also a unimportant constant. Denote ρEt = (31) P ρiE KiEt /KEt the average rate of return of E firms. We now show that ρEt grows over time, since the growth rate of Kit is increasing in χi as shown by (31). Specifically, using (31), the next-period average rate of return of E firms is equal to: ρEt+1 Standard algebra establishes that P 2 P 2 ω ρ χ α KiEt = P 1i . α χi KiEt 2 ω ρ χiα KiEt X ω ρ χiα KiEt α1 X ω ρ KiEt α1 P = χi > χ = P α1 P α1 KiEt i χi KiEt χi KiEt P 1 ωρχ α K P i iEt , KiEt implying that ρEt+1 > ρEt . Thus, the average rate of return of E firms increases over time in this case. 6 7.4 Equilibrium in Section 5.1 In this section, we provide a formal characterization of the equilibrium in the two-sector economy of Section 5.1. The equilibrium entails are four stages, described in the text. For notational convenience, we let AkJt = AlJt = AJ . Proposition 3 Stage 1 is defined as 1 KEt < ((1 − ψ) χ)− α AE N µ Ptl α R 1 ¶ 1−α (32) , where Ptl 1 ³ ¡ k ¢1−σ ´ 1−σ σ = 1 − ϕ Pt , Ptk = (33) R . A1−α F (34) In the first stage, both of the E and F firms are active in the labor-intensive industry while only the F firms produce capital-intensive goods. Specifically, prices of labor- and capital-intensive goods are determined by (33) and (34). Labor, capital and output in the labor- and capital-intensive industries are such that l l , NEt = ((1 − ψ) χ) NFl t = N − NEt KFl t = µ Ptl α R 1 ¶ 1−α AF NFl t , l KEt = KEt , Ytl = µ Ptl α R 1 α µ ¶−1 Ptl α R 1 ¶− 1−α l KEt , AE ψ (χ (1 − ψ)) ¢σ ¡ Ytk k , KEt = 0, Ytk = ϕPtl /Ptk Ytl , KFk t = 1−α AF respectively. Moreover, capital of E firms evolves according to µ ¶α βψ l KEt KEt+1 = P , AE N 1 + β t AE N 1−α α (35) µ l KEt + ¶ α Ptl α 1−α AF N, R (36) (37) (38) and the aggregate output is equal to ¡ ¢σ Yt = Ptl Ytl , (39) k Proof. When KFl t > 0 and KFk t > 0, it is straightforward from Lemma 4 that KEt = 0. (33) follows immediately from (18), whereas (34) follows from the zero-profit condition (20) for F firms in the capital-intensive industry. The first part of (36) comes from (20). 7 The first part of (37) follows from (17). Using the condition that final-good firms make zero profits, together with, (17) and (18) leads to Yt = Ptl Ytl + Ptk Ytk à µ k ¶1−σ ! ¡ ¢σ Pt Ptl Ytl = Ptl Ytl , = 1 + ϕσ l Pt which establishes (39). (35) follows immediately from (27). To derive (36), observe that µ ¶ ¡ l ¢α ψ NEt l + 1 AF N Yt = κF 1−ψ N ! α à 1 µ l ¶− 1−α µ l ¶ 1−α l 1−α 1 KEt Pt α Pt α ψχ α (1 − ψ) α + N AF = R R AE à 1 ! µ l ¶ 1−α l 1−α K 1 α R P t Et ψχ α (1 − ψ) α AF = +N AE R Ptl α α µ l ¶−1 µ l ¶ 1−α 1−α α Pt α P t l = ψ (χ (1 − ψ)) α KEt + AF N. R R Finally, (32) ensures that KFl t > 0, according to (27). The rest is immediate. Proposition 4 Stage 2 is defined as 1 µ l ¶ 1−α µ ¶ 1 1 1 Ptl α 1−α KEt Pt α −α ((1 − ψ) χ) < ≤ . R AE N χ R (40) In the second stage, F firms disappear in the labor-intensive industry. Specifically, prices l = N, of labor- and capital-intensive goods are determined by (33) and (34). NFl t = 0, NEt capital and output in the labor-intensive industries are such that ¡ l ¢α l KFl t = 0, KEt = KEt , Ytl = KEt (AE N)1−α , capital and output in the capital-intensive industry is identical to (37) in Stage 1. Moreover, capital in E firms also evolves according to (38) as in Stage 1. Proof. The first inequality of (40) implies that KFl t = 0. Now the wage rate is determined by the marginal product of labor in E firms. wt = Ptl µ l KEt AE N ¶α l KEt − ψ) AE N ¶α−1 . (1 − α) (1 − ψ) AE It is then easy to show that ρlEt = Ptl α (1 µ 8 . Suppose that E firms are active in the capital-intensive industry. We have ρkEt = (1 − ψ) χ1−α R. k However, the second inequality of (40) implies that ρlEt > ρkEt . Therefore, KEt = 0 in the second stage. Finally, (40) is non-empty by Assumption 1. Corollary 1 If α (1 + β) , (41) βψR then there are only two stages in the economy (E firms never produce capital-intensive χ1−α < goods). µ ³ σ Proof. Define P̃ ≡ 1 − ϕ (A R 1−α F) l 1 ´1−σ ¶ 1−σ as the constant price of labor-intensive goods in Stage 2. The law of motion (38) implies a upperbound of capital stock during the second stage of transition: KEt ≤ AE N à βψP̃ l 1+β 1 ! 1−α . This gives the lowerbound of the rate of return: à !−1 l βψ P̃ α (1 − ψ) (1 + β) ρlEt > P̃ l α (1 − ψ) = . 1+β βψ Recall that ρkEt = (1 − ψ) χ1−α R. Therefore, ρlEt > ρkEt always holds under the assump- tion of (41). Proposition 5 Stage 3 is defined as 1 χ µ Ptl α R 1 ¶ 1−α KEt 1 ≤ < AE N χ µ Ptl α R 1 ¶ 1−α + 1 A1−α E 1 !α µ ¶σ à µ l ¶ 1−α 1 Pt α Ptl ϕ k . χ R Pt (42) In the third stage, the E firms start to produce capital-intensive goods. Specifically, prices of labor- and capital-intensive goods are determined by (33) and (34). NFl t = 0, l = N, capital and output in the labor- and capital-intensive industries are such that NEt KFl t Ytk = 0, l KEt 1 = χ µ Ptl α R 1 ¶ 1−α ¡ l ¢α AE N, Ytl = KEt (AE N)1−α , k ¡ l k ¢σ l Ytk − A1−α k k l E KEt = ϕPt /Pt Yt , KF t = , KEt = KEt − KEt , 1−α AF 9 (43) (44) respectively. Moreover, the total capital of E firms evolves according to the law of motion µ µ µ l ¶α ¶¶ l KEt+1 KEt KEt βψ KEt l k 1−α = Pt − . (45) + Pt AE AE N 1+β AE N AE N AE N k Proof. Lemma 4 implies that KFl t = 0.37 KEt > 0 implies equalized rates of return across two industries. ρkEt = ρlEt 1−α ⇒ (1 − ψ) χ l KEt 1 = χ Ptl R= µ Ptl α R µ l KEt (1 − ψ) α AE N 1 ¶ 1−α ¶α−1 ⇒ AE N. l will be allocated to the capital-intensive inGiven total capital of E firms KEt , KEt −KEt ¢ ¡ ¡ l ¢α k (AE N)1−α + Ptk A1−α dustry. Enterpreneurs’ total income is equal to ψ Ptl KEt E KEt , k which gives the law of motion of capital (45). Finally, we need Ytk > A1−α E KEt to ensure KFk t > 0. This is given by the second inequality of (42). Proposition 6 Stage 4 is defined as KEt 1 ≥ AE N χ µ Ptl α R 1 ¶ 1−α + 1 A1−α E 1 !α µ ¶σ à µ l ¶ 1−α 1 Pt α Ptl ϕ k . χ R Pt In the fourth stage, economic transition is complete in the sense that F firms vanish even in the capital-intensive industry. Specifically, prices of labor- and capital-intensive goods are determined by (33) and (46). Ptk = R . (1 − ψ) A1−α E (46) l NFl t = 0, NEt = N, capital and output in the labor- and capital-intensive industries are identical to (43) and (44), except that KFk t = 0. The law of motion of capital in E firms also follows (45) in the third stage. The proof is immediate and is omitted. Finally, we revisit the foreign balance. The balance sheets of the banks must take into account the investments of F firms in both industries: KFk t+1 + KFl t+1 + Bt = 37 β wt Nt . 1+β Alternatively, KFl t = 0 can be ensured by the first inequality of (42). 10 Proposition 7 In the first stage, the country’s asset position in the international bond market increases if ¡ ¢σ−1 α (1 − ψ) > ϕσ P l /P k , ψ (47) where P l and P k follow (33) and (34), respectively. Proof. Using (19) and (20), standard algebra shows that: Bt+1 AF N Kk Kl β wt − F t+1 − F t+1 1+β AF N AF N α µ l ¶ 1−α α β P = P l (1 − α) AF 1+β R ⎛ ⎞ 1 ³ l ´− 1−α 1 1 P α µ l ¶ 1−α l α KEt+1 ⎟ ((1 − ψ) χ) R Pα ⎜ − ⎝1 − ⎠ R AE N = ¡ l k ¢σ õ α ! ¶−1 µ l ¶ 1−α l 1−α K ϕP /P P lα P α Et+1 . + ψ (χ (1 − ψ)) α − R A R A1−α FN F l Since KEt+1 is increasing, Bt+1 is an increasing sequence if (47) holds. The main results of Proposition 1 therefore carry over to this extended model economy. 11 Figure A1 (Panel 2) Capital-Output Ratios by Ownership and Sector in Manufacturing in 2006 Manufacture of Artwork and Other Manufacturing Manufacture of Communication Equipment, Computers and Other Electronic Equipment Manufacture of T ransport Equipment Manufacture of General Purpose Machinery Smelting and Pressing of Non-ferrous Metals Manufacture of Non-metallic Mineral Products Manufacture of Rubber FIE Manufacture of Medicines DPE Processing of Petroleum, Coking, Processing of Nuclear Fuel SOE Printing,Reproduction of Recording Media Manufacture of Furniture Manufacture of Leather, Fur, Feather and Related Products Manufacture of T extile Manufacture of Beverages Processing of Food from Agricultural Products 0 0.5 1 Note: We use net value of fixed assets as a proxy for capital. Data source: CSY 2007 1.5 2 2.5 3 3.5 Figure A1 (Panel 1) Capital-Labor Ratios (thousand yuan per worker) by Ownership and Sector in Manufacturing in 2006 Manufacture of Artwork and Other Manufacturing Manufacture of Communication Equipment, Computers and Other Electronic Equipment Manufacture of T ransport Equipment Manufacture of General Purpose Machinery Smelting and Pressing of Non-ferrous Metals Manufacture of Non-metallic Mineral Products Manufacture of Rubber FIE Manufacture of Medicines DPE Processing of Petroleum, Coking, Processing of Nuclear Fuel SOE Printing,Reproduction of Recording Media Manufacture of Furniture Manufacture of Leather, Fur, Feather and Related Products Manufacture of T extile Manufacture of Beverages Processing of Food from Agricultural Products 0 100 200 300 400 500 600 700 800 900