MIT LIBRARIES DUPl- 3 9080 03130 2356 Qa -Z ^ Massachusetts Institute of Technology Department of Economics Working Paper Series Policy with Dispersed Information George-Marios Angeletos Alessandro Pavan Working Paper 07-28 October 30, 2007 RoomE52-251 50 Memorial Drive Cambridge, MA 02142 This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network Paper Collection http://ssrn.com/abstract=l-©2^Ul at Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from MIT Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/policywithdisper0728ange Policy with Dispersed Information* George-Marios Angeletos Alessandro Pavan MIT and NBER Northwestern University October 26, 2007 Abstract This paper studies policy relevant fundamentals — such in a class of economies in which information about commonly- as aggregate productivity and demand conditions — is dispersed and can not be centralized by the government. In these economies, the decentralized use information can fail to be efficient either because of discrepancies between private and of social payoffs, or because of informational externalities. In the first case, inefficiency manifests itself in excessive non-fundamental volatility (overreaction to common noise) or excessive cross-sectional dispersion (overreaction to idiosyncratic noise). In the second case, inefficiency manifests in suboptimal social learning (low quality of information contained financial prices, is identified: and other indicators in itself macroeconomic data, of economic activity). In either case, a novel role for policy the government can improve welfare by manipulating the incentives agents face when deciding how to use their available sources of information. Our key result is that this can be achieved by appropriately designing the contingency of marginal taxes on aggregate activity. This contingency permits the government to control the reaction of equilibrium to different types of noise, to improve the quality of information in prices and macro data, and, in overall, to restore efficiency in the decentralized use of information. JEL codes: C72, D62, D82. Keywords: Optimal policy, private information, complementarities, information externalities, social learning, efficiency. 'For comments and useful suggestions, we thank Olivier Blanchard, William Fuchs, Jr., Ken Judd, Robert E. Lucas, Robert Shimer, Nancy Stokey, Jean Tirole, Nikola Taxashev, Harald Uhlig, Xavier Vives, Ivan Werning, and seminar participants at Chicago, MIT, Toulouse, the 2007 lESE Conference on Complementcirities and Information and the 3rd CSEF-IGIER Symposium on Economics and Institutions. We are very grateful to NSF for financial support. Pavan also thanks the Department of Economics of the University of Chicago for hospitaUty during the last stages of the project. "The peculiar character of the problem of a rational economic order is determined pre- knowledge of the circumstances of which we must m,ake use cisely by the fact that the never exists in concentrated or integrated form but solely as the dispersed plete and frequently contradictory knowledge which The economic problem of society is not given to anyone in 1 Introduction The dispersion of information is ... " its totality. is all the bits of incom- separate individuals possess. a problem of the utilization of knowledge which (Friedreich A. Hayek, 1945) an essential part of the economic problem faced by society. This concerns not only the idiosyncratic needs and means of different households and firms, but also commonly-relevant fundamentals. aggregate productivity and For example, think of the business cycle. demand conditions and pricing decisions. Yet, such information is is crucial for individual consumption, production, widely dispersed and through markets, the media, or other channels of communication As emphasized by Hayek (1945), such information can not government. Instead, society the utilization of such information. One can then be stitution, such as the their available information in the what best may most Information about must rely it is only imperfectly aggregated in society. be centralized within a single in- on decentralized mechanisms for assured that rational agents will always use privately-efficient way. This, however, need not coincide with serves social interests. For example, complementarities in investment or pricing decisions induce firms to overreact to public information, because public information helps forecast the decisions of others; this can crowd out valuable private information and can also amplify the impact of common noise, resulting in higher to internalize how their own non-fundamental volatility. Furthermore, individuals may fail choices affect the information contained in financial prices or other indicators of aggregate activity; this can lead to inefficient social learning about the underlying economic fundamentals. A ' ,, novel role for policy then emerges: even if the government cannot centralize the information dispersed in society and can not otherwise collect and communicate information, there that is may exist policies that improve efficiency in the decentralized use of information by appropriately manipulating the incentives faced by individual agents. Identifying such policies of this paper. Our key result is to show how efficiency contingency of marginal taxes on realized aggregate Preview. Rather than focusing on a policy lesson. We is is the objective achieved by appropriately designing the activity. specific appUcation, we seek to highlight a more general thus conduct our analysis within an abstract, but tractable, class of games that allow for two sources of inefficiency in the decentralized use of information: payoff externalities and informational externalities. The former are short-cuts for a variety of strategic and other exter- nal effects featured in applications, such as those originating in production spillovers, investment . or pricing complementaxities, monopoly power, social networking, potential discrepancies between private and social payoffs. The and the like; they summarize latter reflect the (imperfect) aggre- gation of information obtained through financial prices, the publication of data on macroeconomic activity, or other Our forms of social learning. analysis then proceeds in two steps. First, we compare the equilibrium in the absence of policy intervention with the allocation that maximizes welfare subject to the sole constraint that information can not be directly transferred from one agent to another; this helps detect the potential inefficiencies in the decentralized use of information. Next, implement the an equilibrium; efficient strategy as The symptoms of inefficiency that we this gives the we identify tax schemes that key policy result of the paper. detect by comparing the equilibrium strategy with the aforementioned socially optimal strategy depend on whether the inefficiency originates in payoflF or informational externalities. fundamental In the volatility (overreaction to much common manifests itself in noise in excessive non- noise) or excessive cross-sectional dispersion (over- In the second case, inefficiency manifests reaction to idiosyncratic noise). social learning (too first case, inefficiency macroeconomic itself in suboptimal indicators, financial prices, or other channels of information aggregation) Yet, the same policy prescription works the two sources of inefficiency. Our key for either case, as well as for result is economies that combine that the government can control how agents use different sources of information in equilibrium by making the marginal tax rate contingent on aggregate An activity. appropriate design of the tax system then restores efficiency in the decentralized use of information, irrespective of the specific source of inefficiency. The logic behind this result with realized aggregate activity, is simple. When individuals expect marginal taxes to decrease they also expect the reafized net-of-taxes return on their activity to increase with aggregate activity. It follows that a negative own dependence of marginal taxes on aggregate activity imputes strategic complementarity in individual choices: agents have an incentive to align their choices with those of others. Symmetrically, a positive dependence imputes strategic substitutability: agents have an incentive to differentiate their choices. Next note that a better alignment of individual decisions obtains when agents common sources of information, whereas idiosyncratic sources of information. It more differentiation obtains follows that the when rely more on agents rely more on government can use the contingency of marginal taxes on aggregate activity to fashion how agents respond to different sources of information. In particular, when marginal taxes decrease with aggregate activity, by inducing strategic complementarity the policy also induces higher mon information. Symmetrically, relative sensitivity of equilibrium actions to when marginal taxes com- increase with aggregate activity, by inducing strategic substitutability the policy also induces higher relative sensitivity to idiosyncratic infor- mation. It follows that, control how by appropriately designing the aforementioned contingency, the government can agents use their available information. In so doing, the government can control, not only the impact of noise on equilibrium activity, but also the quality of information contained in prices and macroeconomic data. The government can thereby improve welfare even without centralizing or communicating information Discussion. It is cient fluctuations in (1936), who argued to the market. often argued that financial markets overreact to public news, causing both asset prices and itself real investment. ineffi- This idea goes back at least to Keynes that professional investors, instead of focusing on the long-run fundamental value of the assets, try to second-guess the tuations in asset prices and investment.^ broader theme that markets may demands of one another, thus causing inefficient fluc- In this paper, although we are partly motivated by the react inefficiently to available information, tion to any specific apphcation, nor do we examine the deeper we do not origins of such inefficiency (which, unavoidably, will be specific to the application of interest). Rather, our goal remedies that need not be sensitive to the details of the origin of the our choice to work with a theoretical framework that is limit atten- is to identify policy inefliciency. This explains abstract and flexible enough to allow for a variety of distortions in the decentralized use of information. Our analysis also takes as exogenous the limits society faces in aggregating dispersed informa- tion. Investigating the foundations for these limits, institutional design, offers some is and their potential implications for policy and a challenging topic beyond the scope of this paper. Nevertheless, our analysis relevant insights. In our class of economies, equilibrium welfare may decrease with addi- tional information because of possible inefficiencies in the equilibrium use of information. However, once these inefficiencies have been removed, more information can only improve welfare. Therefore, policies that provide the complement market with the right incentives policies, or other institutions, that for how to use available information also provide the mai'ket with more information. Furthermore, while our analysis focuses on how the contingency of taxes on aggregate activity can improve the decentrahzed use of information, in practice, the contingency of monetary pohcy on aggregate activity might also help in the same direction. Indeed, the more general insight that comes out of our analysis is how the anticipation of such contingencies affects the incentives agents face in using their available information, Methodological remarks. and how The pohcy between two dominant paradigms: the this in turn affects efficiency. exercise conducted in this paper strikes a balance Ramsey tradition to optimal policy (e.g., Barro, 1979, Lucas and Stokey, 1983, Chari, Christiano and Kehoe, 1994); and the Mirrlees tradition, or the "new pubfic finance" paradigm We deviate from the Ramsey (e.g., Kocherlakota, 2005; Golosov, Tsyvinski and Werning, 2006). tradition by introducing heterogeneous information and by avoiding ^This point was epitomized in Keynes' famous beauty-contest metaphor for financial markets, which highlighted the potential role of higher-order expectations. Elements of this role have recently been formalized in Allen, Morris and Shin (2003), Bacchetta and Wincoop (2005), and Angeletos, Lorenzoni and Pavan (2007). ad hoc restrictions on the is closer to the new set of available policy instruments. In this respect, our policy exercise At the same time, we deviate from the Mirrlees public finance literature. tradition by abstracting from redistributive taxation (or social insurance) policies that correct inefficiencies in the response of equilibrium this respect, our policy exercise is closer to the Ramsey and focusing instead on outcomes to aggregate shocks. In tradition. Furthermore, the Mirrlees literature studies environments in which agents have private infor- mation regarding purely idiosyncratic shocks, such as an agent's own whenever aggregate shocks are featured ductivity; shocks is assumed to be common. In contrast, tastes, talent, or labor pro- in this literature, information regarding these we study environments which agents have in dis- persed information regarding aggregate shocks; these shocks could be about either the underlying fundamentals or the distribution of information in absence of common knowledge society. The key difference then is that the regarding these shocks generates strategic uncertainty: agents face uncertainty regarding aggregate activity. It is precisely this uncertainty that of taxes on aggregate activity essential for restoring efficiency makes the contingency — which also explains why the results presented here are, to the best of our knowledge, completely novel to the pohcy literature. Finally, note that the policies make agents we identify resemble Pigou-like taxes in the sense that they internalize externalities. However, they are different with regard to the underlying distortion and the way they both the nature of restore efficiency. In standard Pigou-like contexts, the market produces/consumes too much or too little of a certain commodity. The Pigou remedy is then to impose a tax or subsidy on this commodity. In our context, instead, the market reacts too much or too little to certain sources of information. The analogue of the Pigou remedy would then consist in imposing a tax or subsidy directly on the use of these sources of information. However, this seems practically impossible. Our contribution indirectly is to show how the same goal can be achieved by appropriately designing the contingency of taxes on aggregate Other related literature. The nomic contexts goes back to Phelps literature that studies dispersed information in (1970), Lucas (1972), expectations revolution of the 70's and early 80's. Woodford More Townsend recently, Another line of in and the rational- Reis (2000) and We complement this line of environments that share this key combination. work, following Morris and Shin (2002), has examined whether welfare increases with more precise public information within negative result, which has then been used to have found the opposite Cornand macroeco- (2001) have raised interest on the business cycle implications of combining information work by studying policy ^See also (1983), Mankiw and heterogeneity with strategic complementarity in pricing decisions.^ ^See also activity. result. specific models.'^ make a In Angeletos Some of these papers have found a case against central-bank transparency; others and Pavan (2007) we showed how these apparently Amato and Shin (2006), Hellwig (2005), Lorenzoni (2006), and Mackowiak and Wiederholt (2006). Amador and Weil (2007), Angeletos and Pavan (2004), Baeriswyl and Conrand (2007), Heinemann and (2006), Hellwig (2005), Roca (2006), and Svensson (2005). be explained by understanding the underlying conflicting results can inefficiencies in the equilib- rium use of information. For that purpose, we considered an abstract framework that restricted information to be exogenous but was flexible enough to nest most of the applications examined in the hterature; we then used framework to study the this social value of information (i.e., comparative statics of equilibrium welfare with respect to the information structure). In the part of the present paper, how to study we use a priately designed tax system. In the second part of the paper, in which information first generalized version of that framework for a different purpose: efficiency in the decentralized use of information environments the is partially endogenous; can be restored through an appro- we extend the analysis to we then show how dynamic similar policies also correct inefficiencies that originate from informational externalities. and Amador and In this last respect, our analysis complements that in Vives (1993, 1997) Weill (2007). These papers study the speed of social learning and the social value of information in a dynamic economy where agents learn from noisy observations results identify policies that exogenous information Layout. Section is of past aggregate activity. Our can control the speed of social learning and also guarantee that any socially valuable. 2 introduces the baseline framework. Section 3 studies inefficiencies in the decentralized use of information due to payoff externalities. Section 4 identifies tax systems that remove such inefficiencies. Section 5 extends the analysis to dynamic settings and Section 6 to settings with informational externalities. Section 7 discusses implications for the social value of information. Section 8 concludes. All proofs are in the Appendix. 2 The baseline static framework we outhne our In this section details of any baseline framework: specific application but is flexible game a that abstracts from the institutional enough to capture the role of strategic interactions, external payoff effects, and dispersed information in a variety of applications. Actions and payoffs. The economy indexed by i e imposes a tax Let ip r^ [0,1], G R and the dispersion each choosing an action on each agent let K = J kdip{k) and a^ of individual actions. C/ : R^ x E+ x 6 — > E. For concreteness, in what follows shock." k^ G M. In addition, there is a government, which subject to the constraint that the budget i, u, some populated by a continuum of agents of measure one, is balanced. denote the cumulative distribution function of individual actions in the cross-section of the population and for is The The we = = [/(A; - K)^dt/)(fc)]^/^ denote, respectively, the The (reduced-form) payoff of agent i is given by U{k^,K,ak,9^)-Ti, variable 0; G often think of 6 CM k^ external and strategic effects exhibited in 5 (1) represents a shock to agent as "investment" U may mean and 6^ as a, i's payoff. "productivity originate, not only fi-om preferences and technologies, but and the social networks, specification also from pecuniary What like. assumed above without missing any channels the analysis of the latter we payoffs in transfers, postponed to Section is effect of dispersion Uaaf^k for To guarantee efficient allocation, decision problem; (jfc, ^)).^ we assume the —UkK/Ukk < which imposes concavity will be public is less uji its [/ is own a concave quadratic poly- level (i.e., Ua{k, K, ak,d) 0, which imposes concavity at the individual's + 2(7^/^ + Ukk < and U^k how are three stages. In stage 1, let structure f G given hy h £ F is 3, actions </> as follows. Let G ^, and w,; respectively. G aggi'egate productivity are we Q with marginal distributions / as the "state of the world."* refer to F the agents. Nature then uses / to draw a pair i, with the pairs drawn independently from own /. Each agent or the distribution /. Note, though, that productivity 0,, First, according to the probability measure J^ which common knowledge among di for di distribution / describes the joint distribution is but does not observe either pubhcly denote the information (also the "type" ) of for {6i,u)i), The set of possible distributions {Oi,(^i)i£[o^\] under dispersed and the game ends.^ of {6,Lo) in the cross-section of the population; only about the agent's 0, taxes will be collected in stage 3 as a function of information that denote a joint distribution H and Nature draws / from a + U^a < the government announces a at that stage. ^ In stage 2, agents simultaneously choose their actions Next, = at the planner's problem.^ that specifies The information and < than one; and Ukk revealed, taxes are paid, payoflfs are realized, i. that and uniqueness of both the equilibrium and the existence information (described below). Finally, in stage agent we assume which ensures that the slope of the individual's best response 1, Timing and information. There T of endogenous information aggregation; depends only on following: Ukk with respect to aggregate activity rule that payoffs can be reduced to the Finally note that, by assuming hnearity of 6. tractability, nomial and that the external all (A;, A', is oligopolistic competition, are ruhng out any redistributive (or insurance) role for taxation. Payoff restrictions. To maintain pohcy though, crucial, is monopoly power, externalities, i {6i,iOi) for each agent then observes his own w^, uji encodes information, not but also about the distribution / of productivities and information in the population. Although most of the analysis does not *The external recjuire any restriction on the information structure. effect of dispersion is relevant for certain applications: in new-keynesian models, e.g., dispersion in relative prices has a negative welfare effect. ^Although the restriction -UkK/Ukk intervention, our main policy result < 1 is necessary for the equilibrium to be unique in the absence of government does not rely on this restriction: the policies identified in Section 4 implement the efficient allocation as the unique equilibrium even in economies that feature multiple equihbria in the absence of policy intervention. ^Because the government has no private information, the announcement of about the fundamentals; its only role is T does not convey any information to affect the agents' incentives. ^Throughout, we do not require idiosyncratic productivities to be revealed at stage 3. Also, in Section 4.3 consider an extension that adds noise to the observation of actions and aggregate productivity at stage *This is with a shght abuse of terminology because / does not describe the specific e {6i,lui) for we 3. each single agent. we find it useful to impose a certain "regularity" condition. Fix an information structure and consider any two payoff structures, U^ and U~. Let — {U^\Q,F,T) and /c^ 17 We say that the information for the economy £^ £^ = : {U^;Cl,F,!F). ^ whenever U^q/UI^, such that k^(u)) ^tel^kk for k'^(uj) 7^ ^kx/^kk ^'^ any lu £ economic meaning: it ^ fi : be an equilibrium strategy structure {fl,F,J^) The and only if if, C Q appreciated (in terms of fully However characterize the equilibrium. it has a simple requires that different sensitivities of individual best responses to either the fundamentals or others' activity result to different equilibrium actions types. "regular" is economy for the exists a positive-measure set fi This restriction can be we E an equilibrium strategy » ^kx/^kk^ there t^ Cl. primitives of the environment) only once — R A;^ F,J-) {fl, role of this condition which changes to rule out trivial cases in is for a positive measure of do not in incentives lead to any change in the use of information.^ To illustrate the type of shocks Gaussian example. Agent q shock while IJ,0 i's and information structures that we productivity given by is = 9i ^+q, where an idiosyncratic productivity shock. The former is and variance a^; the latter with zero mean and variance across agents is i.i.d. ct^. allow, consider the following 6 is Normally distributed with mean is and independent Each agent's information an aggregate productivity of Normally distributed 9, consists of a private signal Xi uii = O^ about own productivity and a public signal y = 9+e The across agents, Normally distributed with zero variable and variance variance ay. example, / is S,i cr^, noises and s are independent of one another ^i 9 and variance </> cr^ example is over + iOi ct^. = As {xi,y) assigns it 9i is = ^+e — Aiki - equivalent to imposing that the variances \k1, with Ai = 6^ + aK, K = f kidi, and of mean and In this c^. 9i = and is Normal in Xj with mean imposing the "regularity" condition clear in Section 3, a^ and ay are positive and CTq, Applications. The following examples are directly nested • Ui as well as of ^ mean Normal with mean 9 and variance a^ and measure one to y become will in the market. public noise, Normally distributed with zero is a distribution whose marginal h over whose marginal in this i.i.d. whereas the variable e The is idiosyncratic noise, about the average productivity + ^i 9 in our + <;,, finite. framework: < and a < This example 1. can be interpreted as a stylized version of models with production or network externalities: the private return to investment (A) increases with aggregate investment (K) then parametrizes the strength of the spillover and . TTi ^i is = TT* effect, while ^ is a . The scalar a common productivity shock an idiosyncratic productivity shock. - (pi - p*f , with p* = a9 + {I - a) P, P = J Pidi, a G (0, 1), and n* G M. This example captures the incomplete-information new-Keynesian business-cycle models of Woodford (2002), Mackowiak and Wiederholt (2006), Baeriswyl firms suffer a loss whenever their price (pi) deviates from ^As it will become clear in Sections 3 uniqueness of the optimal policy (not its and 4, the only result that existence). is and Conrand some target affected if level [p*), we and others: which in turn (2007), relax this condition is the depends on the aggregate price level (P). nominal demand conditions, while in pricing decisions (a.k.a. • TTi — {a — 1 with K = J kidi, and (a, Cournot and Bertrand games studied • Ui (for — — {I - r) [ki This example is - 9)" - - r{Li and Heinemann and Cornand L), with Li game This game c the degi'ee of strategic substitutabihty among — J or cost shock, ki the quantity (for {kj firms' decisions. - kif dj, L = J Lidi, and is More is it concerned will become —any model following best-response structure: in some in for who framework nests = the primary goal of this paper without centralizing the information that restrict attention to and deeper micro-foundations behind mechanisms government and then the government is is is all in "details," the lessons we these applications. to study policies that improve welfare dispersed in the population, throughout the analysis tax systems that utilize only information that rule out direct in Section 4, this in the from one application to another. Nevertheless, by conducting our exercise within Remarks. Because we least as far as E^[A{e,,e,K)] provide in the subsequent sections are likely to hold across so doing, —at ^ an abstract framework that does not take any particular stand on these we second-guess the will which the agents' interaction can be summarized linear function A. Clearly, the institutional details this structure vary will own a stylized fashion, Keynes' idea that financial clear in Section 3.2, our k^ for his of others. generally, as equihbrium (0, 1). higher than the average distance in the population markets involve a zero-sum race between professional investors demands £ r studied in Morris and Shin (2002), Svensson (2005) supposed to capture, is and Raith (1996), and various other an agent faces a cost whenever the distance of (2006): action from the actions of others (Li) (L). i, Bertrand) (for the beauty-contest £ R^. This example nests the large common demand Bertrand) set by firm Cournot) or complementarity 6, c) in Vives (1984, 1998), this context, 9i represents a Cournot) or the price (for a determines the degree of strategic complementarity "real rigidities"). + bOi + cK) ki - \k'^, 10 papers. In In this context, 6 represents exogenous aggregate is in the public which the agents send reports about collects taxes domain. In their types to the on the basis of such reports. As we will show actually without any loss of optimality within our framework as long as the government does not use such reports to transfer information from one agent to another before individual actions have been committed. Note, however, that this does not information in society; Indeed, we could it mean that we rule out all forms of aggregation only means that the government readily reinterpret some is not itself and exchange of a channel of communication. of the exogenous information as the result of certain types of information aggregation; for example, some or 8 all of the agents may observe a signal about the underlying fundamentals that financial market. What the outcome of an opinion poll or the price of an unmodeled is crucial for the baseline analysis is is given agent does not depend on other agents' strategies, nor these alternative cases are considered in Sections 6 and work on the Finally, note that, while our prior 2007) and virtually all that the information available to any is it affected by government policies; 7. social value of information (Angeletos and Pavan, the related literature (Morris and Shin, 2002, etc.) have limited attention to the case of perfectly correlated shocks and to a specific Gaussian information structure, here allow the shocks to be imperfectly correlated and we we consider more general information structures. This will permit us to highlight that our main policy results need not be sensitive to the specific details of the information structure. Nevertheless, Gaussian example considered above, while correlated = (ct^ we will still illustrate certain insights in the restricting, for simplicity, the shocks to be perfectly . 0). . Decentralized use of information 3 we show how the equilibrium and the In this section efficient use of information depend on the payoff structure U. This permits us to identify inefficiencies in the equilibrium use of information that originate from payoff effects. Common-information benchmarks 3.1 Before we proceed to the analysis of equilibrium useful to review the case of common and efficiency with dispersed information, it is information; this will help isolate the inefficiencies that emerge only under dispersed information. To start, suppose that information were complete, so that each agent knows both his own productivity and the cross-sectional distribution h of productivities in the population, and this fact is common knowledge. exists, is unique, and is We can then show that the complete-information equilibrium strategy given by ki where 9 = = K {9i,9) = Ko + KiOi + K2O, f9dh{9) denotes aggregate productivity and where the coefficients (ko,ki,K2) are determined by the payoff structure.^° Note that, by definition, an agent's payoff depends only on his own productivity; that an agent's equihbrium action depends also on average productivity ^"The characterization of the allocation, which is in turn in coefficients (recfci, K2) the proof of Proposition 1. These , as well as of the coefficients (k3,kJ,k5) for the first-best coefficients depend on the reduced-form payoff structure U, depends on the particular application under consideration. For the purposes of our understanding the specific values of these coefficients is is not essential. analysis, however, because the latter impacts the average action of others, which in turn affects the incentives of the individual agent. We can further show that the where the first-best allocation exists, is unique, and given by is determined by the payoff structure. Note that, as with coefficients {kq, Kj, K2) are again equilibrium, the first-best action prescribed to an agent depends both on his own productivity and on aggregate productivity; however, the dependence on aggTegate productivity now emerges only because of external Now effects. suppose that information is common incomplete but across all agents. Because of the quadratic specification of payoffs, a form of certainty equivalence holds: the equilibrium and cient actions common under incomplete but effi- information are the best predictors of their complete- information counterparts. Proposition 1 ki — V denotes the E[k Suppose information all maximizes welfare {9i,6) \V], while the strategy that common information = economies there can be room k* , there However, as we information remains common. given by is k^ = strategy is given by E[k* {di,d) IT'], where set. which k Clearly, in economies in common. The unique equilibrium is is will for policy intervention no room show for policy intervention as long as few sections, even in these in the next once information dispersed.-'^ is Equilibrium use of information 3.2 We now there is turn to the analysis of equilibrium allocations We no policy intervention. An Definition 1 equilibrium is fc(cj) with K{4>) = J^ k Consider the following is dispersed and when define an equilibrium in the standard Bayes-Nash fashion. a (measurable) strategy = argmax and (cj') d(t>{u;') when information ak{4>) coefficient, = E[ : fi — M {u;') is - such > [/(fc,K((^),o-fc(g!)),6i) [J^ [k which /j 1 a; that, for all a; G Q, (2) ], K{(f))]'^d(t){io')]^/^ for all (/> G $. the slope of an individual's best response with respect to aggi'egate activity: a=——. (3) This coefficient meastues the degree of strategic complementarity or substitutability among individual actions. ^^None of our on economies in The equilibrium use of information can then be characterized as follows. results requires re ^ re*. Indeed, the reader may henceforth assume which inefficiency emerges only under dispersed information. 10 re = re* if he/she wishes to focus Proposition 2 The equilibrium = € n, with K{4>) all a; unique, and satisfies is = E[K{e,e)+a-{K{(P)-K{8,0)) k{ij) for strategy exists, J^ k (u)') d(l){u)') for all \uj] e^. 4> Although Proposition 2 does not provide a closed-form solution is an insightful representation of it. To see this, recall that n{9i,6) taken had information been complete. Next, note that K{(j)) actions are strategically independent (q = — K(d, 6) actions ai'e complements (a > strategic while he does the opposite behavior 0. the average deviation in the When is simply his expectation of the instead actions are interdependent basis of his expectation of the average deviation in the population. The actions ai'e would have been under complete information, it strategic substitutes (a permit more alignment of actions when a tilted to is if coefficient a thus how much also captures In particular, the agent adjusts his action upwards whenever he 0), expects aggi-egate activity to be higher than what a < would have the agent adjusts his action away from the aforementioned certainty-equivalence bench- 0), mark on the if is i it a form of certainty equivalence continues to 0), action he would have taken under complete information. ^ the action agent is hold: an agent's equilibrium action under incomplete information (q the equilibrium strategy, for what they would have done under complete information. actions other agents are taking relative to When (4) < 0). > In other words, ecjuilibrium and more differentiation when agents value aligning their choices with one another. how information Proposition 2 has direct implications for common relying on is used Because in equilibrium. sources of information facihtates alignment of individual choices, while relying on idiosyncratic sources actions to the former inhibits it, strategic complementarity increases the sensitivity of equilibrium and reduces the sensitivity to the latter, while the converse clearly, consider the case where the agents' shocks are perfectly correlated and is true for strategic substitutability. To see this information of agent is i is more Gaussian. In this example, consists of a private signal Xi idiosyncratic noise ~ and e where the ^ and where = 9+ iV (0,0-^). k{x,y) = ire = + TTy + {1 (Jg'^, i^y - = a) t:^' ay"^, 9 for £,i all i, where 9 and a public The unique ^ and n^ N is (12, a^) — 9 + e, , and the information where £,t ^ N [fi, ay) then + 7yy + 7x2;], „ , (5) by ne = ^ signal y equilibrium Ko-F (ki -hK2) [7^M coefficients (7^2,7^,73;) are given TT0 = 9i + TTy + {1 - a) TTx' "" a~^ denote the precisions public signal, and the private signal. ,- 11 K0+Try of, + {1 - a)Trx' respectively, the prior, the A higher a. reduces 7^ and raises 7^ and 7^: stronger complementarity and the public tion towards the prior Next, note that activity. 7a; + 7i/ = the use of informar tilts signal because they are relatively better predictors of others' — 1 so that the equilibrium action of agent 7/^, can also be i expressed in terms of the underlying fundamentals and noises as follows: h = By Ko + + (ki K2) [7^// + (1 - 7^)^ + 7!/£ + lxii\ , strengthening the anchoring effect of the prior, stronger complementarity dampens the overall sensitivity of individual actions to changes in the underlying fundamentals; By increases "inertia." impact of Finally, common increasing the reliance to noisy public information, noise and hence increases the non-fundamental by reducing the reliance on noisy private information and hence reduces the non-fundamental noise it in other words, it also amplifies the it volatility of aggregate activity. mitigates the impact of idiosyncratic cross-sectional dispersion in activity. Beyond the Gaussian example, a closed-form solution of the equilibrium strategy can be ob- tained in terms of the hierarchy of beliefs regarding the underlying fundamentals. E^ = j"E[9\iu]d4>{u}) shocks and, for any n > 2, let Corollary 1 expectation. Let denote the average of the agents' expectations of their E^ = J E[E"''^\iu]d(l){uj) The equilibrium strategy is denote the corresponding n-th order average given by k{iu)^E[K{e,e)\Lj\ w/iere (9 The under = X;^=i ((1 - own vw, (7) Q^)""~^) ^"• equilibrium action under incomplete information thus has the same structure as the one common information replacing 6 with 9. The latter is simply a weighted sum of the entire hierarchy of expectations about the underlying shocks, with the weights depending on the degree of complementarity: the stronger the complementarity, the higher the relative weight on higher order expectations. Since higher order expectations tend to be more anchored to common information, this suggests that the intuitions provided by the Gaussian example are 3.3 sources of more general. Efficient use of information We now turn to the following question. Suppose the government can not centralize information, or otherwise transfer information from one agent to another, but can manipulate the use their available information. Can the government then improve way agents upon the equilibrium use of information? In this section that may permit we address this question by bypassing the details of specific policy instruments such manipulation and instead characterizing directly the strategy that maximizes welfare under the sole restriction that information can not be centrahzed. strategy the efficient strategy, or the efficient use of information. 12 We henceforth call this Definition 2 An mapping efficient strategy is a Because payoffs are A;* linear in transfers, the latter : n— R > maximizes ex-ante that utility. impact welfare only through incentives. Hence, the combination of the efficient strategy with any transfer scheme that makes this strategy incentive compatible defines the very best the government can do without centraUzing information. That when implementable, direct to the efficient strategy mechanism among the ones that depend only on his report is welfare-equivalent to the best incentive-compatible restrict the actions the Towards planner recommends to each agent and not on the reports made by other strategy can be implemented in the next section; here, eflficient this goal, consider is, any arbitrary strategy A: : il we — M focus on and » We agents. its will show how the characterization. let k{e;h)^E[k{Lj)\e,h] denote the component of individual activity that = k{h) = f k {9; h) dh{e) E[k\h] and "explained" by the fundamentals. Similarly, is a|(/!,) = Var(fc - k\h) = / be the fundamental components of the mean and the dispersion of agent i The term The term The action of any given e {k = {K — K) + e + Vi ~ki — K) — (k is, captures the non- fundamental variation in individual activity that e captures the impact of — K) captmes idiosyncratic to the agent; that The = captures the variation in individual activity that reflects variation in fundamentals. fcj across agents; that = activity. - k{h)fdh{e) h) can be decomposed in three components: ki Vi [k {0; is, common noise in information. is common Finally, the the non-fundamental variation in individual activity that captures the impact of idiosyncratic noise. i), is ^^ 1 Given any strategy fc : H ^ M, ex-ante utility (welfare) is given by Eu^E[uCk,k,ak,9)] + ^Wyorvol + ^Wd^,-dis where W^oi vol The term following result then shows that a similar decomposition applies to ex-ante welfare. Lemma The let = = Ukk Var first + 2C/2fcA' + Ukk < (e) term = Var (A') and Wdts - Var(X) and = Ukk dis = + Var U^a < {vi) = 0, (8) and where Var (fc - K) - Var(fc - K). in (8) captinres the welfare effects of the fundamental-driven variation in activity. other two terms capture the welfare effects of the residual variation in activity: vol measures non-fundamental aggregate fundamental volatility, which originates cross- sectional dispersion, ^Note that, by construction, ki, e and Vi which originates in common in idiosyncratic noise. are orthogonal one to the other. 13 noise, while dis measures non- The coefficients Wyoi and Wdis then summarize the two types of sensitivity of welfare to these noise: Wyoi measures social aversion to non-fundamental volatility, while Wdis measures social aversion to non-fundamental dispersion. Both non-fundamental in welfare losses volatility and non-fundamental dispersion contribute to a reduction How much because of the concavity of payoffs. depends on the each of them contributes to welfare under examinations: different primitive preferences, details of the application technologies and market structures induce different social preferences over volatility and dispersion. For our purposes, however, and Wdis- Their it suffices to relative contribution summarize these — social preferences in the coefficients Wyoi can then be measured by the following coefficient: '^> I;- Since Wyoi captures social aversion to volatility, while Wdis captures social aversion to dispersion, higher a* can be interpreted as higher aversion to dispersion relative to volatility. Strategies that share the non-fundamental actions to to volatility common same fundamental-driven variation and dispersion that they induce. of activity relative to its Proposition 3 The dispersion. One should thus expect is efficient strategy exists, is unique,^^ = E[K*{eJ) + •• ' - all u}, differ in the levels of Intuitively, the higher the sensitivity of and hence the higher the non-fundamental to idiosyncratic noise, preferences over volatihty and dispersion. This insight for almost may sources of information relative to idiosyncratic sources, the higher the exposure common noise relative ' in activity k(uj) = Jq^ (a;') d4>{uj') with K{(j)) the efficient strategy to depend on social formalized in the following proposition. and satisfies a* {K{^)-K*i9,e)) for all volatility \iv] (10) (p. In equilibrium, an agent's action was anchored to his expectation of k, the complete-information equihbrium action; however, K, with it was also adjusted the weight on the latter given by a. replace k with k* and a with A on the basis of his expectation of aggregate activity, similar result holds for the efficient strategy once a*. It follows that, just as a summarized we the private value of aligning actions across agents, a* summarizes the social value of such alignment. That the in turn is efficient strategy is anchored to k*, the first-best action, is quite intuitive. That a* inversely related to the ratio Wyoi /Wdis reflects our preceding discussion about volatility and dispersion: the degree of alignment associated with the efficient strategy increases with social aversion to dispersion and decreases with social aversion to volatility. ''Hereafter, when we say unique, we mean up to a zero-measure subset of one has to make with a continuum of types. 14 fi; this is a standard quaUfication that i I : '. . Furthermore, just as a pinned down the relative sensitivity of equihbrium actions to different down sources of information, a* pins more see this clearly, consider efficient strategy is again the Gaussian example with perfectly correlated shocks. almost ''' all ng {x,y), + TTy + where the {1 - follows that, just as It - a*) 'y 7T^' 3.4 To k, K*2) b;/^ + YyV + + 7ry + (l-a*)7rx' (11) , by '^ TTg + tt^ + (1 - a*) tt^' ^ ' the equilibrium levels of inertia, non-fundamental volatility levels that are a with 7x2;] optimal from a social perspective. As for the case 1 applies for the efficient strategy a* under dispersed information further appreciate the inefficiencies that can emerge due to the dispersion of information, con- sider economies in which k whenever information Q + [l^l structures, the analogue of Corollary with k* and Inefficiency only + 7re a determines more general information once we replace kS coefficients (7^,7^,7^) are given and dispersion, a* determines the of The then given by fc(x, y) for To the corresponding relative sensitivity of efficient actions. 7^ The is = k* common, In these economies, the equilibrium . leaving no room is (first-best) for policy intervention. Nevertheless, efficient whenever Q*, inefficiency emerges under dispersed information, opening the door to policy intervention. following is then an immediate implication of the results in the preceding sections. Corollary 2 Consider an economy (i) The equilibrium (ii) is efficient When a > a* and that is When a < under common information (k under dispersed information information is a* and information is if and only if a— = k*). a*-, Gaussian, the equilibrium exhibits overreaction to public information and excessive non-fundamental (iii) efficient volatility. Gaussian, the equilibrium exhibits overreaction to private information and excessive non-fundamental dispersion. 4 Optimal policy We now tvirn to the core contribution of the paper. affect the decentralized use of information. efficient We We first explain how different tax schemes then identify the tax schemes that implement the use of information as an equilibrium. 15 Equilibrium with taxes 4.1 Suppose that the information that all and {K, 6}"^ Then, without any clear in the next subsection), consider policies defined where the function erf, pubhcly available at stage 3 includes as well as aggregate productivity (^i)i€[o,i] become is satisfies : 6 R" x M+ x ^ M + T^a = individual actions loss of optimality (as it will by a quadratic polynomial in {k,K,9), is - the following properties: Ukk and T^k 9), T all Tkk < -%^;E^ < 0, it is T{K,K,0,e) = 1, We denote the class of policies that satisfy these properties by T. Finally, note that this class includes both progressive tax schemes > and regressive tax schemes 0) for These properties preserve existence and uniqueness of equilibrium, 0. while also guaranteeing budget balance state- by-state. ^^ Tkk hnear in (i.e., linear tax-schedule that does not directly < with Tkk 0).^^ One should thus (i.e., with think of this as a non- depend on individual productivity but (^,), is contingent on aggregate outcomes {K,ak,0) We then have the following result (to simplify the formulas, we henceforth normalize the payoff structiure by setting Ukk = — 1; Proposition 4 Given any tax the general case T scheme £ T, let a - TkK , a 1 _ (l-a)Ko-n- (0,0,0) l-a + Tkk + TkK . The equilibrium strategy exists, is in the appendix). is + Tkk 1 , l + - _ (1 all a; e Q, where k{6, 9) = ko g) (m + K2) - T^e . l-a + Tkk + TkK Tkk unique, and satisfies k{io)^E[k{9,9)+a{K{^)-R{e,9)) for - + k\9 -f k29 and K{<j>) = f^ k \ to (13) ] {lj') dcpico') for all (f). There are three instruments that permit the government to influence the agents' activity: Tkk, the progressivity of the tax system; TkK, the contingency of marginal taxes on aggi'egate activity; and r^.g, matter the contingency of marginal taxes on aggregate productivity. While for equilibrium outcomes, each of them has a distinctive role. The all these instruments progressivity Tkk is the only instrument that permits the government to control ki, the sensitivity of the agents' actions to their information about their own productivity ^*We relax this assumption in Section 4.3. ^^To see the latter property, note that, for any shocks. For given Tkk, the instrument that cross-sectional distribution tp of individual activity, jT{k,K,ak,e)d^{k) = T{K,K,0,e)+^{Tkk + T^oW. ^®In our environment, the progressivity of the tax system will turn out to affect the decentralized use of information, but it does not interfere with redistributive concerns; this is 16 because of the linearity of payoffs in transfers. permits the government to control the degree of complementarity (a) and thereby the sensitivity of common actions to noise relative to idiosyncratic noise and T^k, the instrument that permits the government to control Finally, for given T^k activity. the contingency Ti-k of taxes on aggregate is the sensitivity of individual actions to variations in aggi'egate productivity of marginal taxes 4.2 on the contingency efficient strategy turn to the question of whether there exists a policy T* G strategy as an equilibrium. Whenever this also guarantees that there this is T that implements the efhcient the case, by the very definition of the efficient strategy, no other transfer scheme that can improve upon T*. This is even for transfer schemes that violate budget balance and/or anonymity, and even agents to send arbitrary messages to the planner and the planner to on these messages. What is essential is T T* G Proposition 5 A has the property such that Ki that K2 = function K,2, T = policy in T that The next implements the for given {k,k*) this result Kj. true one allows the transfers contingent result establishes existence and uniqueness that implements the efficient allocation. that, The proof of make the if is only that the planner does not send informative messages to the agents before they commit their choices. of a policy Tj^g 0. Implementation of the We now is is follows But then there and a unique are then pinned , the optimal efficient strategy T^x from Proposition always increases with 4. First, such that kq down by budget = Kq. The a and unique, and decreases with a*. note that there exists a unique Tkk also exists a unique Tf^n such that T/^ (0, 0, 0) exists, is a = a* rest of the a. , unique Tf^g such parameters of the policy balance, establishing that there exists a unique policy that implements the efficient strategy as an equihbrium.^^ The optimal policy has the property that, keeping k with Q and decreases with a*. This tarity perceived by the in information. If agents, we thus look it is because a higher T^k, by reducing the degree of complemen- reduces the sensitivity of individual decisions to across economies that share the properties under complete information (i.e., properties under incomplete information the optimal T^fc is and k* constant, the optimal Tkx increases they feature different a and a*), noise efficiency differ in these we then find that higher in economies that exhibit a larger discrepancy between the private and the social value of aligning choices; equivalently, the optimal T/.^ non- fundamental volatility of the equilibrium relative to ^^The uniqueness same equilibrium and they feature the same k and k*) but (i.e., common its is higher the more excessive the non-fundamental dispersion. result holds for "regular" information structures. For "non-regular" information structures, the degree of complementarity is irrelevant, leaving one degree of indeterminacy. See Section 4.5 17 for such a case. Implementation with measurement error 4.3 The policies considered so far do not require that the government have superior information than the agents at any time: the taxes are conditioned on information that many In contrast, for applications it pubhc at the time taxes assumed that actions are perfectly revealed are levied. However, the preceding analysis has time. is may be more at that appropriate to assume that actions, as well as aggregate fundamentals, are only imperfectly observed. To accommodate we now this possibility, productivity to be observed with noise in stage in stage 3 the noise while government —and an idiosyncratic Ui is the true aggregate productivity 9 = 6 errors + where <;, <; 2. We ki = agent + ki i chooses + rj Vi, ki in where 77 stage is a 2, then common the government cr^. — as well as any other agent —observes a signal measurement All these noises could be interpreted as be independent of the fundamentals and of the information that agents to then —observes if with respective variances a^ and a^. Similarly, instead of noise, (9, In particular, 3. other agents noise with variance is and are assumed have in stage all consider a variant that allows actions and average let K=K+ rj = and a^ a^ + cr^ denote, respectively, the cross-sectional average and dispersion of k, and consider tax schedules of the form where the function T &T). The T is assumed to satisfy the tax an agent expects to pay E[T{ki,K,ak,e)\io^] = is same properties as in the previous section (i.e. then given by: ' E[T{ki,K,ak,e)\uJi] ^^ +i The last {Tkk + 2TkK + Tkk) ^l + \ {Tkk + TaaWv + Tee<y-, three terms in (14) capture the impact of measurement errors on the expected tax. Because these terms are independent of the agents' actions, they have no impact on individual incentives and hence they do not interfere with the incentives provided by the tax system. It follows that, not only the noise does not interfere with the abihty to implement the efRcient strategy, but also it does not affect the properties of the optimal tax system. Of course, the last property rehes actions). When, instead, the noise is on the noise being additive multiplicative, it measurement efficient strategy, it now may efficient strategy affect the details of the this result, for the without any significant effects of the noise. It optimal tax system. can he implemented regardless of whether activity and fun- damentals are observed with measurement Given undo the incentive error once again does not interfere with the ability to implementable the although Proposition 6 The separable from the agents' does impact incentives. However, by appro- priately adjusting the policy, the government can fully follows that (i.e., error. remainder of the analysis we can abstract from measurement error loss of generality. • 18 — . under dispersed information Inefficiency only 4.4 As mentioi^ed in Section 1, financial- market observers are often concerned about many how information work believe that financial markets — at both the academic and the policy front processed in financial markets. In particular, while is well on average, many also feel that financial markets often overreact to noisy public news, causing excessive non-fundamental volatility in both asset prices and real investment. = the restriction that k k* At some level, this possibility and a > a*. More offer an interesting benchmark because only when information is dispersed. our framework by in which k generally, economies in in these We now can be captured = k* but a ^ a* economies policy intervention becomes desirable thus examine the properties of optimal policy for this special class economies. Because a ^ a* means that the equilibrium is inefficient in its relative sources of information and hence to different types of noise, CO- varies with the letting € = K necessary that the marginal tax components of activity that are not explained by the fundamentals. In K — it is response to different denote the component of activity that is due to common particular, we have the noise, following result. Corollary 3 Consider economies When a > converse is a* , the optimal policy has true This result Ti^j^ > and the marginal tax co-varies positively with is intuitive. In situations in which, to common if it were not volatility. It is from overreacting to for policy intervention, the equilib- sources of information and excessive non-fundamental the optimal marginal tax co- varies positively with the fundamental The e. when a < a* rium would exhibit overreaction volatility, under dispersed information. in which inefficiency emerges only common noise that drives this non- then precisely this property of the tax system that discourages agents common sources of information and dampens non-fundamental Note, however, that this appealing property of the tax system is volatility. achieved only in an indirect way, without any need to monitor and quantify the various sources of information available to the agents. This particular, is done by making marginal taxes contingent on observable aggregate outcomes. In when a > a*, the optimal and thereby dampens the reaction pohcy reduces the complementarity of the equihbrium to common of marginal taxes on realized aggregate activity positive [Tj^k noise, > in individual actions, by making the contingency 0). The optimal guarantees that the overall response of the equilibrium to aggi-egate productivity by making the marginal tax 4.5 not distorted also a decreasing function of reaUzed aggi'egate productivity {Tj^g < 0). Idiosyncratic vs aggregate shocks Another special case the is policy then new of interest is public finance literature. the case of independent private values typically considered in Studying this particular case helps appreciate how our policy 19 results depend on the dispersion of information regarding aggregate shocks, as opposed idiosyncratic shocks. , Within our framework, that this case can be captured as follows: the private information of agent 6i is distribution h is common and i cj), and hence that the unique equilibrium by = k{u}i) K* {8i,d) . given hy k{u)i) is As a We efficient allocations. is is result, neither = k common renders {0i,9) environment is that h distribution of actions we is known to agent z, this implies is given it is not necessary ^^ ai'e also independent but rather that there is faces uncertainty regarding the distribution of actions in the relax either the assumption that 0, is known but maintain the assumption that common knowledge behavior nor a* matters for the We common equilibrium behavior, nor a* matters for for in equilibrium. is (j) to agent common efficient allocation i or the assumption knowledge, then the This in turn eliminates the problem of forecasting aggregate activity, once again guaranteeing that neither efficiency. dis- , common knowledge is so a* and hence also the contingency T^k, irrelevant in the aforementioned no strategic uncertainty: no agent if is Similarly, the efficient allocation . not per se the fact that private values population. Indeed, is conclude that in the case of independent private values a and $i, knowledge. Together with the fact fact that 6i a matters — oji second, suppose that the cross-sectional h\ to condition the tax system on realized aggregate activity. What suppose that no uncertainty about the cross-sectional also commonly known and the 6, is — first, the cross-sectional distribution of information, knowledge, in equilibrium aggregate investment /i, cj) knowledge, so that there tribution of types in society. Because that to purely a matters —and therefore nor T^pc for equilibrium essential for achieving is conclude that the key distinctive property of the correlated-value environments we consider in this paper is the strategic uncertainty created by the dispersion of information regarding aggregate shocks. Corollary 4 When the cross-sectional distribution of information in society edge, the contingency of taxes on aggregate activity {T^k) is (</>) is common knowl- not essential for implementing the efficient strategy. ' • \ 5 A The analysis so far has been confined to a static game. dynamic economy be embedded in a dynamic helps fiu-ther appreciate setting with a how om- results ^*In particular, the efficient allocation can be and 9. Moreover, should the tax be through k;2 more macro can be relevant We now flavor. show how this static This serves two goals. for applications. Second, it game can First, it accommodates implemented with a tax schedule that depends only on own activity made contingent on K, this contingency would matter (the sensitivity of the complete-information equihbrium to 9), not through the contingency on 6 should then be adjusted to perfectly offset the effect of 20 TkK on for a ti2- equihbrium behavior only (the degree of alignment); the possibility that interesting dynamics in actions originate in the dynamics of information. we this section, by taking the dynamics of information start analysis of endogenous information in Section There are + A'^ 1 periods, with > A'' chooses an action and 6. In each period 2. of investment in a riskless discount bond, Investing to the up Set 5.1 we turn as entirely exogenous; In shock, and G (ki^t) mean and at are the G and F and — 1, each agent ...,N, his level of consumption, £ ^, which we henceforth interpret as capital invested k^^t costs ki^t b^^t, t in period t and F {ki^t, K^, at, A^^t+i) delivers the dispersion of activities in period To are real-valued functions. Ai^t+i t, chooses his level i in is that Of in period i + 1, where Kt an exogenous productivity is we henceforth impose simplify the exposition, common denotes the also a risky technology. that the productivity shocks are perfectly correlated across agents, so that Ai^t+i (The timing convention we adopt here The agent Cj^j. — shock that ^t for all i,t. is relevant for period-i decisions.) The agent's period-i budget Ci,t where rate) + G{ki^t) + is given by qtbi,t = F {ki^t-i,Kt-i,at-i,6t-i) + 6i,t-i - n^t, denotes the period-t price of discount bonds (the reciprocal of the period— i risk-free qt and denotes the period-i Tj^j tax;es the agent pays to (or the transfers he receives from) the goverimient.^^ Finally, the agent's intertemporal preferences are given by Ui^Y.f3'-'U{c^,t,k,^t). where Ut is a real-valued function. This framework is can be nested by setting U{c, k) assumed we considered quite flexible. All the applications in those statics examples = c and then (e.g., + letting -~G{k) (3F{k, —G{k) + (3F{k,K,a,6) can be in the static K, a, 6) benchmark equal the payoffs interpreted as the profit of a firm). Alternatively, a stylized version of the neoclassical growth model with convex investment costs X > nested by letting is One 0. G (k) = c, F [k, K, a, 6) — could also interpret k as individual and could further U (c, k) = and effort, in and so = k + it xfc^, for some constant would be natural to let on. -I- /ci,t i, to Ci,N+i agent's (fc) which case = A/^ 1, we impose that = bi,t = for all in which case = F (fci,Af,i^Af,(7Ar, An+i) — G (0) +bi,N — Ti,jv+i. Furthermore, endowment to zero so that F{ki,o, KQ,ao, Ai) = 6,,o = for ah t G U {c,k) = c- H{k), with H{k) = k"^ representing the disutility of effort. Finally, one allow U and G to depend on (A', a, 9), as to capture externalities in leisure, pecuniary externalities in the costs of investment, '^For Ok, i. 21 the last-period budget constraint reduces for i = 1, without loss, we normalize each If common agents had information about the shocks in periods, then the analysis could all proceed essentially without any further restrictions on the functions F, for we assume restrictions. First, H some function . Second, we V static model. The and only \i qt — satisfies (in c — H{k), ensures that, in all the function periods and states, the bond market the risk-free for K, a, 6) as {k, bond is U in the clears if indeterminate) and that the the absence of taxes) reduces to (in i — = -[G (k) + H{k)] + (3F (k, K, a,0) which case the demand life-time utility of agent analysis tractable, consumption: U{c,k) linear in is the same properties with respect to first restriction (5 U we let V{k,K,cj,9) and assume that that U. Here, however, To keep the are interested in cases where agents have heterogeneous information. we impose two G and N - W, The second restriction then permits to extend our previous static analysis to the The key knows this, in J]/3*-iF(/c,,i,i^4,ai,et). here period is to rule out informational externalities about t {6t,uJi^t}tLi^ is t possibility that depends on the actions other agents took 9t we model the dynamics of an agent in period —the with marginal distributions for G Wj^j given by uji^t F Let f G f2(. (f)t in periods s what an agent < i. To ensure The (exogenous) information of the information structure as follows. represented by dynamic model. denote a joint distribution for G $f. The distribution / also describes the cross-sectional distribution of {6t,iOi^t}tLi in the population. First, Nature draws / from a set of possible distributions sequence F {6tjUJi,t}tLi for assume that according to the probability measure each agent {iOi^t-iift^t-i^St-i) i, with belongs to {6t,L0i^t}tLi uji^t: for all i Nature then uses / to draw a J-. drawn independently from and t. This ensures that there learn about {9s,(t>s)^=t from the observation of other agents' (past) actions are observable irrelevant. ^° then is It is then without loss of generality, efficiency, to restrict attention to strategies that depend only on w^ is Finally, we nothing to —whether such actions for either ecjuilibrium or f. Equilibrium, efficiency cind policy 5.2 Given that information is exogenous in to Vk{K,K,0,9) = equihbrium action An and in let period t all dates and states, the analysis of both the equilibrium and the static benchmark. Let k (9) denote the (unique) solution efficient allocations parallels that in ^° /. = axgmax^V {k,k, 0,9) k* (9) would be k {9t) , ; if information were complete, the while the first-best action would be k* {9t) ."^ Next, alternative that would also guarantee that agents do not learn anything about {Os,4>s)s=t from the observation of past actions is to assume that for all i > 1, uit^t is a sufficient statistic for (a;,,!, (aJi,s,'/>s,^s)s=i) with respect to i6s,<t>s)s=f ^^Both K and k' are Unear functions of the coefficients («;o,«;i,fi;2,«;o,«;i, 6. In particular, k(S) = ko + (ki + K2) ^2) determined as in the proof of Proposition 22 = kq + [ki + K2)0 U with V. and n*{6) 1 replacing with let a= with Wyol ^ Vkk + 2VkK + -—- and Wdis V/tA' = + Va^; V^k =1--^, a and a summarizes once again, of aligning choices (the equilibrium degree of complementarity), while a* the private value summarizes the The equilibrium value of such alignment (the relative social aversion to dispersion and volatihty). and under incomplete information are then characterized in the following two efficient allocations propositions, which ^ Kt{(t>t) = J kt unique, and satisfies, for is periods all t and all = E[k {9t) + a all ujt G efficient strategy exists, is unique, ktiujt) The - \ujt], Kt (Ot)) and satisfies, for periods all t and almost - fit, Kt{(l)t) {Kt {^t) {uj') dcptiuj'). Proposition 8 The with strategy exists, 3. fit, ktiujt) with and direct extensions of Propositions 2 aj-e Proposition 7 The equilibrium U!t social = = n'^*{Ot) a*-{Kt{<Pt)-K*{et)) J^kt{uj')d(pt{Lo'). efficient strategy , can be implemented efHciency can be induced in period about Kt and + 9t t in , a similar fashion as in Section by making taxes that becomes pubhcly available at \uJt], f in period + 1. As t + 1 when they make In particular, contingent on information in the static model, the does not require any informational advantage on the side of the government. the agents anticipating 4. It optimal policy merely depends on their decision that the marginal tax they will pay in the future will be contingent on public information about aggregate economic conditions. 6 Informational externalities A key functioning of modern economies that is missed in our preceding analysis is the aggregation of dispersed information in various indicators of aggregate activity, such as financial prices, trade volume, aggregate employment, output and investment data. What that the informational content of these indicators depends on the information in the first place: informative aggregate activity mation aggregation and taken into account We study this crucial for om- purposes way agents use their available is of the underlying fundamentals. The various channels of infor- social learning thus introduce informational externalities that and is the more individuals rely on their private information, the more when determining issue, is its have to be the socially optimal use of information. policy implications, within a variant of the dynamic framework introduced in the previous section. Past shocks are no longer directly revealed to the agents. Rather, 23 the agents learn about these shocks from the observation of a noisy signal of past aggregate activity. This signal is a proxy for the informational role of macroeconomic data, financial prices, and other channels of information aggregation and social learning. up 6.1 Set To be able to analyze the endogenous dynamics of information in a tractable way, some rifice we have permitted of the generality exogenous information to be Gaussian. all we assume /i and variance public signal yt The u'l. = 9 + et and we assume that 6, realization of 9 and private it is signals Xi^f = + ^j,f, where et ~ A/'(0, ay^) t, agents observe a and ~ A^(0, a^i) ^j,t are noises, independent of one another, independent across time, and independent of and also independently 9: kt-i and Ot ~ = Kt-i + A/'(0, o"^ ^ Tjt, ) = variables, + at-i Ut, common The variable. Ci,t The at-i random are shocks, random of any other any date identically distributed across agents. In addition, at observe the following three which ^ and At 9 + at, where 77; ~ >2, ^i^t agents X{0,(jl^t), and independent + b^^t-l-T^,t is the underlying That the variables Kt-i and at-i that enter period— i income (through (trend) productivity. F) coincide with the with given by is variable At can be interpreted as the period— i productivity shock, while 9 mean ~ ^f(0,o'^t)^ ^t across agents, independent across time, F{ki^t^l,Kt-l,at-l,At) t 9, and convey information about affect payoffs period-^ budget of the agent + G{k^^t) + qtbi,t^ we drawn from a Normal distribution with mean never revealed. Instead, at any date is of the constant over time, is sac- restrict component that the fundamentals about which the agents have heterogeneous information denote this component by we henceforth in the preceding analysis: In particular, we must signals about past activity is not essential. What essential is that the payoff of an agent is given by is observation of income does not perfectly reveal either 9 or i\i_i.^^ The rest of the Xltll^ /?*"' t/ model (cj^t, ki^t) 1 ensures once again that is where qt — as in Section U (cj^j, /?, fcj^t) = 5. The intertemporal Ci^t^h{ki,t)- That preferences are linear in consumption that the trades of riskless bonds and the timing of consumption are indeterminate, and that the intertemporal payoff of an agent (in the absence of taxes) reduces to N+l J2P'''v{k^,t.Kt,at,At+l), t=i where V (fc, K, a, A) = -[G (fc) + H{k)] + (3F (fc, K, a, A) . The function V is quadratic and satisfies the same restrictions as in the previous sections. ^^Also, the results that follow do not depend on whether the signals about past actions are public or private. In particular, Aj,t = 6 + at^t, we could allow the agents to receive private signals K,,t-i in addition to, or in substitution for, the = Kt-i + aforementioned public signads. 24 7?i,t, fft-i = at-i + Vi,t, and , Equilibrium 6.2 The is essential difference between the economy of the endogeneity of information: information about is the strategy agents follow in period t in Section 5 determines how much contained in (Kt^^t) a^nd hence affects the agents' behavior in periods In the absence of policy, this informational externality on. and the one examined this section fact that the use of information in the present affects the information available in the future solution to T4 {k,k,0,6) = and a Proposition 9 The equilibrium = — k,q + and is + {kj —Vkx/Vkk, we have the following strategy exists + 1 not internalized by the agents: the is not alter private incentives. Thus, letting once again K{d) t does K2)0 denote the unique result. unique. Let {^t,^t}tLi denote the (unique) information structure generated by the equilibrium strategy. Then, for all t, the strategy and the information structure jointly satisfy ^ E[Kie) + a-{Kt{(Pt)-Km ktiojt) for all ujt ^ ^t, with Kt{4>t) = Jq kt {lo') d(j)t{ijj') for all 4>t & ,- \u>t] (15) ^t- This result does not require the information structure to be Gaussian. However, once we 6 and the exogenous noises to be Gaussian, signals of past activity available in this result ensures that the information contained in the also Gaussian. All the information is any given period can then be summarized and the other for restrict two in —exogenous and endogenous—that sufficient statistics, one is for the private the public signals; the dynamics of these two statistics admit a simple recursive structm'e and the equilibrium strategy reduces to an affine combination of the two. Proposition 10 The equilibrium - with '' strategy ^i,t (Wi,i) == is given by K (7t^i,i (1 - ' 7i) ^t) > . - (1 The variables that + is q) TTf + Trf Xi^t o-nd Yt are sufficient statistics for all the private available to agent i in period while t, irf and and public information about 9 n^ are their respective precisions. The sufficient statistics are given recursively by ^., = ^AV-i ^x,, ^Aj,i_i + — ^Xi,i and Y, y^ _,„-,- ^'"^ =— %F,-, ^. + ^y, + ^A, + where ~ Vt _ = Kt-i - KQ-, + —+— K2){l-'Yt-i)yt-i ^ {ki [Kl , 25 K2) 7t-i ^"' + "^^ "^"^ y, (17) /^a^ U«J is a linear transformation of the signal of past activity. Similarly, the precisions and -n'f are -k" given recursively by Trf = 7rf_i + and cT-2 ^rf Finally, the initial conditions are Xifi The behind condition logic is (16) = = + ^-f + a^; + 7rf_i 0, Yifl = /u, 70 = the same as the one 0, ttq (ki = + K2)Nti<T-?. and ttq we encountered = (19) a-g'^. in the static benchmark. For given degree of complementarity a, the relative sensitivity 74 of the equilibrium strategy to private information increases with the precision of private information and decreases with the precision of pubhc information. At the same, for given precisions, a higher a tilts the equilibrium strategy away from private information and towards public information, as agents find it optimal to better align their choices. Conditions (17)-(19), on the other hand, describe the endogenous evolution of the information, which can be understood as noise, aggregate activity in period Kt-l Because Yt-i Kt-i + rif now note is publicly in period t is First note that, because Xj_4_i equals 9 plus idiosyncratic follows. = - t Ko 1 is given by + {Ki+K2)ht-lO+il--ft-l)Yt-i). known (and so are the coefRcients kq, ki, K2 and 7f-i), observing Kt-i informationally-equivalent to observing the variable yt defined in (18). is (K1 simply a Gaussian signal with precision signals can be combined averages of all +K2)7t-1 ttj = 7^_j {k\ + K2) cr~f . It follows that all private in the sufficient statistic Xi^t, while all public signals in the siifRcient statistics Yf. Condition (17) then states that these can be combined statistics are simply weighted the available signals, with the weights dictated by the respective precisions of these signals, while condition (19) states that the precisions of these statistics are precisions of the component The key property to notice increasing in jt-i-^^ This is simply the sums of the signals. pends on the strategy followed is But that ' which = is that the precision of information available in one period de- in previous periods. In particular, for all t, nt and thereby yrf is because the informative content of the signals of aggregate activity higher the more sensitive the strategies of the agents to their private information.^'* This important informational externality that the equilibrium fails is an to internalize in the absence of policy intervention. ^^When 9 changes over time, the period-i precision of information regarding the period-i fundamental need be monotonic over time; but it remains an increasing function of the sensitivities of past strategies to private information. ^*A similar property typically holds in rational-expectation-equilibria models: price increases with the sensitivity of individual asset demands 26 the information contained in the to private information. M ; , and policy Efficiency 6.3 We now turn to the policy implications of the aforementioned informational externality by charac- terizing the strategy that maximizes ex-ante taking into account this externality. However, utility unlike the cases of exogenous information examined in the previous section, we now restrict at- tention to strategies that are linear in the available private signals. Without this restriction, the endogenous signals Suppose, a moment, that the government for follow in period no longer Gaussian and the analysis becomes ai-e fails to recognize that the strategy the agents subsequent periods. Suppose further that the affects the information available in t intractable. period-i private and public information were summarized in sufficient statistics Xi^t respective precisions and k* {6) let 2Vfc/f -I- = 7rf and 7rf, + Ktct)- Yt with so that = argmax,^V{K,,K,0,6) VKK)/{Vkk and Kq + (k| + ^2)^ and a* = 1 - Wyoi/Wdis = Proposition 8 would then imply that the efficient strategy = ki,t (a;^,t) K* (7;X,.i + - (1 - 1 is {Vkk + given by 7*) Yt) with il-a*)7rf 7i Now (l-a*)7rf + 7rr suppose the government takes into account the endogeneity of the information. As long as welfare in the subsequent periods is increasing in the precision of available information, be desirable to adjust the current use of information so periods. Because more learning is more learning as to induce it should in subsequent achieved only by the aggregation of private information, this suggests that the informational externality raises the sensitivity of efficient strategies to private The information. following result verifies this intuition. Proposition 11 The ' = K* (7r*Xi,i + (1 - 7?*) Yt) given by ... , ' * all t all the itOi,t) utility is ' where for ht ^ ' maximizes ex-ante linear strategy that < N, (1 - while a*) TTf 7^ = + ^f _ (1 — /3 (1 a*) tt^/ _ [(1 a*) (1 — - 7;;i)' a*) nf^ TTf ttI' + tt^] . «i)-' (^ + K\f a'^^, Xi^t private and public information about 6 available to agent and i Yt are sufficient statistics for in period t, while nf their respective precisions; they are obtained recursively using (17)-(19), replacing with {-ft*,K.Q,Kl,K2) 27 - and {-yt, no, vrf are 1^1, 1^2) The key result here that, holding constant the cuii'ent precisions of private is information, the optimal weight on private information is higher than what it and public would have been had information in the subsequent periods been exogenous: As anticipated, this follows directly from the internaUzation of the informational externality: raising the reliance on private information mation and hence higher welfare The in in in one period, society achieves higher precision of subsequent infor- periods.'^^ following alternative representation of the optimal strategy helps translate the result here terms of the degree of complementarity that the policy must induce Proposition 12 Consider mation structure. a^ — the efficient linear strategy and let There exists a unique sequence {o^rii^i ' in equilibrium. {^t,^t}'^=i be the associated infor'"'^^'^ ^t* < <^* f°''" clU t < a*, such that the efficient strategy and the information structure jointly satisfy, for N for almost ut & society choices. fit, with Kt{(pt) = K Jq {uj') d(j)t{u>') for all 4>t without informational externalities, the weight in the case how much own all would and all t, k*ii^t)=n'^*iO) + ar-{Kt{<f>t)-K*{9t))\oJt] As by (20) ^ ^t- aj"* in condition (20) summarizes the agents to factor their expectations of other agents' choices in their like Unlike the case without informational externalities, this weight now depends on the information structure. Nevertheless, condition (20) remains a valid and insightful representation of the optimal strategy: the result that a^* informational externaUty is < a* highlights that having the agents internalize the isomorphic to having them perceive a lower complementarity in their actions than the one they should have perceived had information been exogenous. This in turn guides policy analysis: the optimal hnear strategy can be implemented with similai' tax schemes £is in the benchmark model, but now the must be higher than what it sensitivity T^^ of the marginal tax to aggregate activity would have been with exogenous information. Corollciry 5 Informational externalities unambiguously contribute to a higher optimal sensitivity of the marginal tax to aggregate activity. This result is true irrespective of the specific payoff interdependencies and irrespective of whether the equilibrium would have been it easily extends to richer Of hold at t had information been exogenous. Moreover, Gaussian information structures, with multiple private and public signals course, this informational externality = efficient is absent in the very A^. 28 last period, which explains why the result does not of aggregate activity. It relies merely on two properties: (i) by increasing the sensitivity of actions to private information; and learning We is TkK induces more that a higher learning that the social value of such (ii) positive because the optimal policy removes any inefficiencies in the use of information. further discuss the importance of this last point in the next section, where we study how the policies we have identified affect the social value of information. Before turning to this issue, however, we study the properties of optimal policy for a special case of interest: economies in which inefficiency emerges only because of informational externalities. This special case is motivated by the following observations. In certain settings economies with no externalities), one may or near perfect, coincidence of private and (e.g., Walrasian expect that competitive market forces achieve a perfect, social payoffs. Although such a coincidence may fail to obtain in the absence of complete markets or in the presence of other market distortions, this case still same time, when information represents an important benchmark. At the expect that individual market participants fail to internalize how is dispersed, one may their choices affect the quality of information contained in financial prices, macroeconomic indicators, and other endogenous signals of the underlying fundamentals. information and is endogenous but where inefficiency The In our set up, these settings correspond to economies in which (k, a) = («;*,a*), so that private and social payoffs coincide emerges only because of informational externalities. following is then an immediate implication of Corollary 5 along with the fact that, for these economies, the optimal tax would be zero had information been exogenous. Corollary 6 In economies ties, the optimal policy This result may be is in which inefficiency emerges only because of informational externali- such that TkK > 0. relevant for understanding optimal policy over the business cycle. Consider standard real-business-cycle models in which all firms and households share the The assumption regarding aggregate productivity and taste shocks. same information of frictionless competitive markets along with the absence of direct payoff externahties then guarantees that the equilibrium business cycle is efficient. Now consider a small, yet realistic, modification of these models: information be dispersed and only imperfectly aggregated through prices and macro data. modification is likely to render the business cycle inefficient as agents choices affect the information of others. by having marginal taxes increase with Our fail to internalize results then suggest the following realized aggregate macroeconomic how let This their poUcy remedy: activity and decrease with realized productivity, the government can improve the information contained in prices and macro data, and can thereby reduce the non-fundamental component of the business cycle fluctuations that are driven by noise in information regarding aggregate conditions). •' 29 demand and (i.e., the productivity J • 7 Implications for the social value of information Throughout our if analysis, we have ruled out policies that convey information to the agents. However, the government possess information that is not directly available to the market nomic data collected by government agencies such as the Bureau Bureau, or the Federal Reserve Banks), then desirable to communicate such information it is Labor macroeco- Statistics, the US Census important to understand whether to the market. Indeed, as long the equilibrium use of information available information can have a detrimental effect of (e.g. is A positive answer inefficient, is an increase on welfare. For example, if it is socially not obvious. in the precision of a> may a*, agents overreact to any additional public information, exacerbating the already excessive non-fundamental volatihty. is However, this can not be the case if the equilibrium use of information is efficient. This because the equihbrium strategy then coincides with the solution to a planning problem where the planner directly controls how agents use their available information. An argument analogous to Blackwell's theorem then guarantees that additional information can not reduce welfare.^® following result is Corollary 7 In then a direct implication of these observations. general, more precise information can reduce The ,. welfare. However, policies that store efficiency in the decentralized use of information also guarantee a positive social value for re- any information disseminated by policy makers or other institutions. In an influential paper, Morris and Shin (2002) used an elegant example to illustrate the possibility that more precise public information can reduce welfare: a "beauty-contest" game, the strategic complementarity perceived by the agents is where not warranted from a social perspective, causing overreaction to public news.^*^ This example has lead to a renewed debate on the merits of transparency in central in isolation bank communications.^® Whereas this question has been studied largely from other aspects of policy making, our results indicate that a central bank's optimal communication policy is far from orthogonal to the corrective In a related but different line of reasoning, Amador and roles of monetary and fiscal policies. ^^ Weill (2007) argue that, by crowding out private information, an increase in the precision of exogenous public information can reduce the precision of the endogenous information contained in prices and other indicators of economic ^^For further details on how the welfare effect of additional information depends on the inefficiencies, if any, of the equilibrium use of information, see Angeletos and Pavan (2007). ^^Their example inefficiency is nested in our baseline static framework with k emerges only under dispersed information and manifests ^*See, for example, Amato and Heinemann and Conrand Woodford (2005). ^^An exception is = k* itself in and q > a*; it is an economy where excessive non-fundamental volatility. Shin (2006), Angeletos and Pavan (2004, 2007), Baeriswyl and Conrand (2007), (2006), Hellwig (2005), Morris and Shin (2002, 2005), Roca (2006), Svensson (2005), Baeriswyl and Conrand (2007), which focuses on the signaling effects of monetary policy. 30 activity and can thereby slow down Amato and Shin Shin (2005) and A social learning.'^° (2006). Our theme similar is explored in Morris and imply that the government can improve the results informational content of prices, can raise the speed of social learning, and can guarantee that any public information it disseminates is welfare improving, once it sets in place policies that correct the underlying inefficiency in the decentralized use of information. Concluding remarks 8 —such aggregate productivity conditions or the profitability of available technologies — highly dispersed Information about commonly-relevant fundamentals in society, is perfectly aggregated through markets, institution. ized As first necessarily mean for an this means that effective utilization of society has to rely such information. and on decentral- However, this does not social incentives in the use of such information the equilibrium's response to certain sources of information The key only im- that the government should not interfere with the decentralized use of informa- tion: to the extent that private non-fundamental is and can not be centralized by the government or any other emphasized by Hayek (1945), market mechanisms and demand volatility, excessive dispersion, or may be do not coincide, leading to excessive inefficient, suboptimal social learning. contribution of the paper was to identify policies that correct such inefficiencies: by appropriately designing the contingency of marginal taxes on aggregate activity, along with other properties of the tax system, the government can manipulate the incentives the agents face in using different sources of information and can thereby improve welfare even disseminate information or create We if it new channels through which information cannot is itself collect and aggregated in society. established this result within an abstract but fiexible framework in order to highlight the potential generality of the insight. Of course, the details of the optimal contingency will the details of the application under examination. news and excessive non-fundamental If volatility, as the key inefficiencies are overreaction to public it is often argued to be the case for financial markets, then marginal taxes must increase with aggregate activity. inefficiency is depend on The same is true if the key the failure of markets to internalize the endogeneity of the information contained in financial prices and macroeconomic data. so that agents rely less on common In both cases, it is desirable to provide incentives sources of information; this can be achieved by introducing a positive contingency of marginal taxes on signals of aggregate activity. The opposite policy prescription applies to markets exhibiting overreaction to private information and excessive crosssectional dispersion. Nevertheless, the key principle on aggregate economic conditions —remains valid —the optimality of marginal taxes contingent for any economy featuring dispersed information regarding commonly-relevant fundamentals. ^"Amador and Weill models are nested (2007) extend Vives (1993, 1997) to situations with both private and pubhc learning. in our analysis of Section 6 as special cases that rule out payoff externalities. 31 Both Examining the practical, political-economy, considerations that tion of explicit aggregate contingencies in the tax code However, it is is clearly might complicate the introduc- beyond the scope of this paper. important to note that there are various direct and indirect ways through which such contingencies can obtain in practice. contingent taxes and subsequently activity. Alternatively, the make For example, the government could first collect non- rebates whose magnitude depends on realized aggregate tax code could be revised over time on the basis of past macroeconomic performance. To the extent that such rebates or revisions are systematic, they can have similar incentive effects as the type of contingencies envisioned in this paper. Moreover, the contingency of monetary policy to macroeconomic performance could serve a similar role: how firms use different sources of information tion choices depends when making their pricing and produc- on how they anticipate monetary policy to respond to the information about aggregate employment, output and prices that arrives over time. For example, to the extent that higher interest rates have similar incentive effects as higher taxes, the Central contingency of its interest-rate policy on aggregate economic conditions, not only stabihzation purposes, but also to improve the information that data. Further exploring how design of monetaiy policy is the policy objectives a fi'uitful Bank can use the we have studied is contained in prices and macro in this paper filter in the optimal direction for future research. 32 for the familiar 9 Appendix Proof of Proposition We 1. prove the result in three steps. equihbrium and the respectively, the complete-information common results to the case of incomplete but Step 1. any given 0. U first-best allocation. Step 3 extends the information. i is Aggregating across agents (i.e., (0, 0, 0) -I- . and (21) with (22), _ + [Ukk 6i), is UkeO^ = equivalent to = 0. (21) we thus have that + UkK]K + Uk96 = Q. (22) letting _ Uke ^'-^Ihk (0,0,0) t/fc Ukkh + UkKK + integrating over Uk{Q,Q,Q) ' k, for pinned down by the first-order condition Uk [h, K,6i) quadratic in {k,K,9), the first-order condition is Uk Combining and 2 characterize, 1 Consider the complete-information equilibrium. Because payoffs are concave in K the optimal action for agent Because Steps ^'- -{Uk, + UkKy Uke ,„„, ^^^^ ^'=-{Uuu + UkK)~^'' , gives the result. Step 2. A Next, consider the first-best allocation. of a strategy k : Q H x R ^> K{h) = Jk{6\ and dispersion h) dh (6) combination and a system of budget-balanced transfers across agents. For any given cross-sectional distribution of productivities h £ let feasible allocation consists of a and ct/,(/i) = (/ h) [k [6] H and any given strategy - K{h)f dh fc x // : {6)^^^ be the corresponding behind the utility strategy k. An allocation w{k;h). Because U is is thus M, mean for simplicity L= efficient ^{Ua, if + UkkH + f k{0)dh {0) Uk {K, K, 0) \ — if the strategy k Uca'^kj \uee<yl of fc, K + Uek -\-2ti L with [k{0) {U,, + f/fcfc) 33 U - h. +M= x + dh Then H — > M. maximizes A = (0) - K0 let Kf dh {0) - respect to [7^^^ Q [k (6) 0] -K]^0 + Uk {K, K, 0) - : we then have that and ak on ~k\-ix(J [k{0) denote the Lagrangian for this problem. Optimizing Uke0 depends only on the in transfers, ex-ante utihty and only we dropped the dependence w-x( (24) ignorance (equivalently, welfare under an utilitarian aggre- quadratic, and Ua{k,K,ak,0) w = U{K, K, 0, §) + where veil of Because of the quasi-linearity of payoffs gator). > of activity in the cross section of the population. Next, let w{k;h)= j U{k{e\h),K{h),(7k{h),e)dh{e) denote ex-ante — al K, a^ and k{0) we have that ;' ,'i.i Combining, we have UkeO tliat + Uk{K, K, 9) + Uk{K, K, 6) - UkeO + {U^^ + Ukk) [k(.9) -K] = Q (25) or equivalently UkeO + Uk{0, 0, 0) Integrating over 9 K + UKeO + {U^a + Ukk) [Kd) - K{h)] + Uk (0, 0, 0) + [U^k + 2UkK + Ukk] (26) we then have that ^^ ^ UkjO, + 0, 0) Uk{0, (Ukb 0, 0) -[UkK + 2UkK + UKK] + Uke) -[UkK + 2UkK + UKK] , . ^ ' ' ' Substituting (27) into (26), and letting + ^K (0,0,0) + 2UkK + Ukk) Uke t/fc(0,0,0) ° ~ -{Ukk "' ^ - - {Ukk + Uke U..) "' ~ ' + UKe * + 2UkK + Ukk) -{Ukk "'' .„„. ^ ' gives the result. Step Now 3. suppose that information common, the aggregate for agent i is K activity also is commonly known + Ukkh + UkKK + V denotes the commonly- available information set agents, and noting that the + (0, 0, 0) [Ukk Note that the above two conditions are 9i in equilibrium. + UkK] K + i is = Since all information The first-order is condition ^, (whatever this is Uk0nOi\'P] £[^17^]. It is Aggregating this across is). simply E[^|P], we get = identical to conditions (21) and 9 have been replaced by E[0i|P] and action for agent UkenOi[P] cross-sectional average of E[^,|'P] Uk that incomplete but common. thus given by Uk{^.Q.^) where is 0. and (22), except for the fact thus immediate that the equilibrium given by h^¥.[K{9M'P]- A similar argument implies that the efficient action is given by ki^¥.[K*{9,,9)\'P], which completes the proof of the Proof of Proposition result. We 2. prove the result in two steps. Step 1 proves that condition (4) characterizes any equilibrium. Step 2 proves existence and uniqueness. Step strategy Take any strategy 1. A;' : Q— M » such that, fc : Q — R and > for all a;, let K{(j)) k' (w) solves = j k [uj) . A best-response is a the first-order condition nUk{k',K{(j,),9)\Lo]=Q. 34 dcf) [uj) (29) Using the fact that Uk{k', K, where k stands = O for E[Ukk — or equivalently k'{u}) which gives Step 2. + Uk{K{e, e),K{e, 9), 6) Ukk - {k' + UkK {K - k{0, d)) all (0,0) (k' - E[k{0, 0) (29) reduces to , + UkK k{0, 0)) + a {K - k{0,0)) {(f>) -k{0,0))\u] = {!< (^) to]. \ 0, What remains to prove is that the equilibrium exists and is the class of payoff functions U that satisfy the properties specified in Section = {U,Q,Q,,F) equiUbrium strategies an economy e' efficient strategy for measure-zero set of w. Proof of Corollary K{4>) = fact that ki / E[ = R-om 1. k{0, 0) — k,2{1 k* U - a,s exists an equilibrium (4), U eU. and for the is As shown aK{0, 0) u) ]d(^{uj) \ + a f E[ K denote An economy 2. e' \ set of coincide with the in Proposition 3, the exists {(P) is efficient strategies uniquely determined for economy e U immediate that the we have that aggregate investment and is all but a unique. satisfies iojd^iu). a) /a, = {l-a)Ko + Ki0,0)-aKi0,0) Ki0. that K{(t))^{l-a)Ko + KiE^ + a fElKicp) \oj]d<l){uj) - and hence that E[K Iterating it is and a* corresponding to as long with U' & e' follows that It U Moreover, U' e any economy use of information. Let 9, Q, F) coincides with the set of {?7, {U',Q,Q,F) such that the e. efficient conditions (4) and (10), = the economy e for — By comparing . K and a corresponding to It follows uj, unique; this can be done which characterizes the Using the k{uj) for all (4). 3, for = In equilibrium, k'(u;) with the help of Proposition given by e Kid, 9)), complete-information equiUbrium allocation and the fact that k solves for the UkiK{e,e),K{e,e),e) = 6) {(f)) \u]^{l- and then substituting a)Ko + + aE[ KiE[E^\uj] f E[ K (4>) \ J ]d(p(uj') \ u ]. into (4) gives oo ;,. ' ': k{uj) . = E[Ko + Ki0 + KiY^a''E'' \u], (30) n=l which together with ki = Lemma 1. Proof of Eu = E[ U{k,K,ak,0) K2(1 A + — a)/a and the definition of gives the result. Taylor expansion oi U(k, K, 0-^,0) around {k,K,ak, 0) gives Uk{k,K,ak,0){k +\Ukk{k - kf + \ukk{K - - k) kf + + UK{k,k,ak,0){K - K) + \u„„{ak - dkf m Ua{k,k,Uk,0){<Jk + UkKik - k){K - K) ]. - - .. <Jfc) - f' .. By the law of iterated expectations, E[K\h]^E[E[K\9,h]\h]=E[E[E[k{uj)\4>]\e,h]\h] = It follows = that E[K\ E[kie;h)\h] = k{h). E[k] and that E[Uk{kk,ak,e){k Furthermore, because = E[E[k{Lj)\e,h]\h] U is linear in - = Ua{k,k,ak,0) (t|, Ucr{k,k,ak,0){ak = E[UK{k,k,dk,6){K - k)] + 6-fc) -Ucraiak U^a^kio'k = k)\ - 0. ^k)- It follows that - a^f = -U^^ [f^l - ^l] Next, note that - kf = {k = Because E[k] E[K] [{k = - K) - = E[k] - k)f + (K - {k kf + 2{K - k)[{k -K)- E[k] and because {K - k) is orthogonal to [{k {k - k)]. - K) - {k - K)], we then have that E[{k - = icf] Vax[{k - K) - {k - k)] + Ys.r[K - K]. Finally, note that E[{k because (fc — K) Combining -k){K- k)] = E[{K - kf~] + E[(fc - K)(K - k)] = E[{K - kf] is {K — k). orthogonal to all the above results, Eu = E[U{k, k, ak,e)] +^[/fcfcVaj:[A' Using the we thus have that + ^Uaa Wl - - k] + ^l] it/A'A-Var(A' + lUkky&v[{k - K) - A') - + UkK^MK - {k - k)] A). fact that Var[(Jt and rearranging, then - A') - (fc - A)] = Var[fe - A] - Var[fc - A] = al - af gives the expression in (8). Proof of Proposition 3. A strategy Eu= is efHcient if and only if it maximizes U{k{Lj),K{<l>),ak{(p),0)dfiu;,0)dnf), JFJn,e with K{4>) = Jq distribution over k{ui)d(t> {u)) fi and generated by aki^P) /. = [/f;['>^(<^) The strict - K{4))\^d4) (a;)] with (p denoting the marginal concavity and the quadratic specification of 36 U ensures that a solution to this problem exists and distribution of distribution Z {9\(j)) and (f) ^= unique almost for and first imphed by as their joint ^/e/j,f/(^-M,A-(,^),afc(</>),e)d(^(u;)dZ(e|0)dG(0) order conditions with respect to K{4>), sufficient for optimality, are given by the and (Tk{(t>), + (cj) dZ{9\<l,) X{4>) k(u}), which are necessary = (31) almost for ^ UAHuj), dG{<P) following: /e /n UK{k{Lo)J<{ci)),9)dcj) Jq cj), denote the marginal problem can be written as for this + /^ \{cj>) [K{4>) - f^ k{uj)dcf> (a;)] dG(,^) + UV{<P) Hi^) - QH^) - A'(<^)]2#(a;)] Therefore, the G {4>) Let all u). denote the distribution of 9 conditional on The Lagrangian J^. is K{(l>),ak{c^),e)dcj) {u) dZ{9\cf>) all (f) + 2'n{cP)ak{4>) = (32) for /ex* [Uk{k{^),K{<P), 9) - - Xi<P) 2r?((/))(fc (u;) - almost iC(<^))]dP(^, (\>\uj) denotes the cumulative distribution function of Using the facts that UK{k,K,9) that Ua{k,K,ak,9) = is = - [ <\>\uj) {9, almost = and all u; on 0) conditional linear in its arguments, that K{(j)) Uaa^^k^ conditions (31) A(<^) (f) (33) for where P[9, all = J^ k lo. {oj) dcp {co) , and (32) reduce to UK{Kicl>),K{cP),9)dZ{9\cP) = -UKiKicf>),K{(l>),e) Je = -hUa V{4>) O'-'iTcr- Substituting the above into (33), it satisfies we conclude the following condition for almost E[ C/fc(fc, K, 9) that the strategy all u; £ f2 E[ UkiK*i9,9),K*{9,9),e) +Uk{i^*{9,9),k*{9,9),9) Now ment note that, is when given by Proposition 1, iv all = : Q ^M is efficient if and only + Uk{K, K,e) + Uaa[k-K]\u] = linear, condition (34) if : where, for simplicity, we have dropped the dependence of Uk{k,K,9) and Uxik, K,9) are A; /c on u; and of (34) K on </>. Because both can be rewritten as + Ukk (k - k*{9,9)) + U^k [K - K*{9j)) + + {UkK + Ukk) {K - ti*{9,9)) + U,^{k - K) Uke{9 | a; ] - 9) = 0. ^^^^ agents follow the first-best allocation, then in each state aggregate invest- k*{9,9). Replacing k*{9,9) we thus have that the first and k*{9,9) into condition (25) in the proof of best strategy solves Uk{^^l9),K^9,9),9) + UK{K*i9,9),>i*{9,9),9) + Uke{9'9) + {U,, + Ukk)[K%9,9)~K*{9,9)] =0 (36) 37 , Substituting (36) into (35) and rearranging gives (10). Proof of Corollary Part 2. degenerate" information structure unique solution to (10) is if and only , if a= = given « «;*, and (2) (3): for any "non- the unique solution to (4) coincides with the a*. Next, consider parts and (ii) When (iii). information Gaussian and shocks are perfectly correlated = Ko + {ki + K2) i'Jij.H + -jyV + JxX] K = Kq + {ki + K2) triilJ' + hy + Ix) + + + -/x) d] k k = KO + (ki + K2) = k It T from Propositions follows (i) [yf,fj- {-^y , -yys] follows that vol The = results then follow directly Proof of Proposition + K2) jyf al [(ki from (6) and [(ki + ^2) Ixf o-| ' and - (12). T Given any policy 4. = dis £ T, let U [k, K, ak,e,e)=U {k, K, ak,e) - T{k, K, ak, 0) denote an agent's payoff, net of taxes. Now offs Ukik let k : Q U are given by {6; h) ,k{h), — H X f M Because . 9, 9) = 0, denote the complete-information equilibrium strategy U is concave in fc, k ^ Jk (9'\ h) dh [9') with k{h) must {6; h) . when pay- solve the first-order condition Because U quadratic in is (fc, K, 9, 9), the first-order condition can be rewritten as Uk Integrating over 9, (0, 0, 0, 0) we then have Uk Combining (37) + + UkKK Ukk~k {0; h) + [Ukk with (38) then gives k + {9; h) Ukx] = k (h) + k{9, 9) -Ukk + UkK -Ukk -Ukk = Ukk [Uk0 ko - UkK + = 0. + + ki9 Uks] ^ + = 0. k29 with Tkk + TkK + + Tkk Uke Ki — UkfO Uke Uke Kl Uke + [/fc(0,0,0)-T^- (0,0,0) f/fc(0,0,0,0) Ko K2 Uke9 (37) that (0, 0, 0, 0) Ukk + {h) -Ukk + UkK 38 Uko-n^ke -Ki - UkK + Tkk + TkK (38) (' • ' ^. ( — — Using can then be conveniently rewritten as foUows: (23) the coefRcients (kqi'^Ii^o) '^o = Ki = '^2 = (l-a)ACo+tr77fc ^— rV^ (0,0,0) r^=r- (39) 1 ri^«i -— = —1 Normalizing Ukk r^-^i rrf^ (41) then gives the formulas in the proposition. Next, consider the K{(t)) + K2) +^?;-e- a) (Ki (1 (40) game under incomplete — J k{uj) d(j) {uj) A . best-response information. Take any strategy a strategy is fc' ^ R such that, Q : /c Q — R and > : for all uj, let k' {cu) solves the first-order condition K (0) ,ej)\uj] = E[Ukik', Using the and the fact that Uk{k', fact that K, = 6, 9) Uk{k{e, e),k{0, k solves Ukik{9,0),k{9,e),9,9) = k'{Lu) E[ki9,9) (42) + Ukk 6), 6, 6) = 0. {k' for all (9,9) , + d{K{(P)-k{9,9)) - k{e, 6)) + UkK {K - k{e, 9)) (42) reduces to \uj] with ^ UkK ^ UkK - TkK ^ ^ + it-Tf^K -Ukk + Tkk -Ukk i-wrJkk' - In equilibrium, fc'(a;) follows from the = same arguments Proof of Proposition a* ko , = Kq, it is ki = thus suffices to prove that there exists a policy T* € unique. This only is easily shown from conditions to (13) exists and is unique 2. J-. For the equilibrium necessary and sufficient that k2 Kj, T that and (39)-(41) = h^. (44) satisfies (44) (43). and that First, note that ki this policy — kJ if is and if Tu- Because Ukk a= That a solution as in step 2 in the proof of Proposition efficient strategy, a= a* if + Ucra < C/fcfc(l-Kl/Kl) this also guarantees that = -Ukk {a - That Tkk and TkK With = Ukk = (45) -C/aa. — Tkk < 0. Next, note that, given T^k = —Uaa, and only TkK 0. (13). Take any generic information structure 5. with policy to coincide with the It which gives k{u}) for all tu, {Tkk, satisfy a*) - Tkka* = - ^^^I^^^' < 1 -UkkOc + {Ukk + U,a) a* = U,, - UkK - Ukk- then follows firom the fact that Wyoi = Ukk+'^UkK+UKK < TkK) thus determined, and with both T^g and Tk (0,0,0) being unconstrained, 39 (46) it is then immediate that there exist a unique '^0 = ^0' these are given T^g = Ukk - Tf, (0, 0, 0) and that T to balance Tkk + T^a — 0. that this is = R,2 + kD - a) [{k\ - Ukk (1 - (Ki + - acq) a) (kS - K2)] - {Tkk it = re-(o,o,o) Tj^(0,0,0) = -Tfc(0,0,0) = -'^k0 era — -'kk 6. 0(1 + T is unique. % = = = A ¥.[T{h,k,akM^i] , (0, 0, 0) i\ , 0, ^) (47) . =0 for all [K, 6) then easy to verify it is o TkK < increases with and W^js = a and + Ukk decreases with U^a < 0. terms in (14) do not let fcj = ki{l + + Ui), 'rj around affect individual decisions. K = K{1 + 77), a-| K, (Jk,6) then = a-|(l For + r?)^ Taylor expansion of T{ki,K, o-fc, = E[Tiki,K,ak,e)+^Tkk + a^) k1+TkK'jlk,K+\TKKCjlK''+\T,,ayk\ (a^ a 6) gives ^i\ redefined as follows: Kl = "' _ ~ a - UkK + TkKil + ^P + + a2 + a2) -Ukk-UkK + TkKa + '^^^)+Tkk{l + <7^ + -Ukk Tkk (1 Uk0 -Ukk + Tkk{l + a^ + al) Uke UkK-TkKJl + a^^) + Tkk{l + + -Ukk <T^, - Tk§ ~ "' <^^) C7i) implication. Proposition 5 also continues to hold, although a^. T(fc,:, t/fc(0,0,G)-Tfc (0,0,0) Kq depend on a^ and T (i\ = -Uko, For the case of additive measurement error, the result follows Proposition 4 thus continues to hold with k and By K^) t/x (0,0,0) Finally, that (14) noting that the last three ?). + = Uk9 the case of multiplicative measurement error, = such that = -2TkK-Tkk = -U,, + 2UkK + '2Ukk TkS Proof of Proposition (Kt identified above, a* follows directly from (46) along with the facts that Ukk and 9 (0, 0, 0) folloviring: r(o, 0,0,0) This also implies that the policy + Uk) must be that Along with the other properties equivalent to imposing the from ^ unique T^ + TkK) ^5 = -Uk {Tkk the budget (state by state) Tkk directly ''''^^'^ 1^2 by (1 Finally, for such that Tf,g u now the optimal tax contingencies ' - 40 Proof of Corollary Prom 3. (45), (46) and we have that the (47), restriction k — k* implies that Tkk The tax system = TkK = -Ukk {a-Oi*), and T^e = -TkK 0, thus linear in is , Next, recall that 6 and JK. It positive, , K = E[K\h] which in turn is true Tk{K, J?" of 9 (which n = e is and only Because 4. measurable in 0) is common knowledge and (p is 9) and hence if ^2) with a marginal tax rate given by foUows that Cov{Tk{K,d),e) Proof of Corollary because fc, + («i also = K — K is orthogonal to any function = TkKVar{e), which is positive if and if (p is + UkK + T^gO. (0, 0) q > a* only if T^k is . common knowledge, the n-th order average expectation common knowledge and equal to E^, for aU n. Moreover, = E [9\h] = E [9\h, because 9 of h, including cf)] , we have that E^ =E[E[9\Lo]\<p]=E[E[9\uj,(P]\(P]=E[9\4>]^E[E[9\h,(t)]\(t>]^E[9\<i)], Combining these results, , we have that 00 -. = ^ ^ ((1 - Q)a"-i) ^" = E [^|(^] = E [%] . n=l Prom Corollary 1 it ;,:-,. in which case a is then follows that the unique equilibrium , .( . , k{u) =E[k(6',^) 1, irrelevant. Similar is also irrelevant. = Along with the given by , arguments imply that the kiuj) so that a* \uj] is efficient allocation is E[K*{9,9)\uj], result in Proposition 4, strategy can always be implemented with a tax scheme for which Proof of Propositions 7 and Proof of Proposition first 8. period, that the equilibrium strategy at Proposition 2. Now consider t — 2. t t — = 1 is 1. = 0. for i Because information = structure 1. 2 establishes the result. 41 is 3. exogenous in the is now endogenous but uniquely That the equihbrium strategy unique and solves (15) thus follows again from Proposition > T^k eflBcient unique and solves (15) follows directly from The information determined by the unique equilibrium strategy t we then have that the These are direct extensions of Propositions 2 and Start with 9. given by 2. at t Repeating the same argument = 2 is for all — . Proof of Proposition with = uJi^i Start with 10. = t 1. In the first period, information exogenous is Ai). Standard Gaussian updating then gives (xj,!, j/i, IE[%u]-^^U + ^n, = k{9) = Xi,i ko + x^j, {ki + = Trf K2)0, = cr-j, Fi -2 ^-2 -2 where ^^ + ^2/1 + -^Ai we then have (48) tt^ = that the unique solution to (15) is and a^^ _^ ^-2 ^-2_ ^gj^^g _^ given by + {Kl+K2)hlX^,l + {l-Jl)Yl), kl{u!^,l)^Ko (49) with 7i^[(l-a)7rf]/[(l-a)^f + To see this, start by guessing that the equilibrium strategy Next, use this guess to compute aggregate activity as and Finally, use the latter along with (15) Next, consider signal is t = 2. = + (ki + 6 contained in Ki is Ko Ki- Ko- a),:^2 = ^^1,1 K2) (71^ + (1 + U (xi,2,y2,-^2,-^i. = ^2/[('^i + K2)7i] is common knowledge. - {I - ^i)Yi). ^^i). The endogenous ^'l) +% + K2){l-'yi)Yi + K2)Ji Gaussian noise with variance It 7l) 6, cr? 2 = '^^,2/ ('^i + because (49) imphes that '^2) cti — 7i • (ki The signal + follows that the period-2 public information about 9 can K2) ai, 7iC^,ii be summa- on {yi,Ai,Ki, rized in a sufficient statistic Y2 such that the posterior about 6 conditional is + K2) [jiO {ki on the other hand, conveys no information about is {ki thus the same as that contained in (Ki which + given by The information about 772 kq coefficient 71. (48) to derive the equilibrium 71. In the second period, Ki where some satisfies (49) for = A'l 7rf]. i5-i,j/2, ^2) — Gaussian with mean V2 + 7i(ki+K2)^T^.y^ ^IV ^^^2 ^ ^^^ ^^ = ^^^ + + ni ii^' . , , , and precision summarized is tt^ = tt^ + cf~1 + a~^ + jf (ki in the sufficient statistic Xi^2 + K2)^ cr,7J- Similarly, the private information conditional on such that the posterior about Gaussian with mean Trf and precision Trf = ti"! + cr^ 2- The ^2 (Wi,2) With 72 = [(1 - a) ^f / ] [(1 - a) unique solution to (15) = Trf Trf Ko + + (ki + K2) (72^i,2 Tr|] 42 is + then given by (1 - 72) ^"2) , ': can be (x^^i, a;j,2) , It is t > immediate that the construction of the eciuihbrium strategy for i = 3 with the statistics Xi^t an Yj defined recursively as in the proposition. unique equilibrium strategy 7f = - [(1 a) nf] I [(1 - Proof of Proposition We any conclude that the is = ki,t ii^i,t) with 2 applies also to q) + Trf vrf 11. Ko + ] + {ki K2) (7t^i,t + (1 - It) Yt) . We prove the result in two steps. Part (i) characterizes the efficient linear strategy in the absence of payoff externalities; this helps isolate the role of informational externalities. Part Part (ii) then extends the result to general payoff structures. Suppose (i). V {k,K,a,9) does not depend on {K,cr) and, without any further loss of generality, let V{k,K,a,e)^~{k-0f Let hf = . {yi,Ai,Ki,...,yt-i,At-i,Kt-i:yt:^t} denote the public history in period agents follow a strategy k = and suppose t {fcf}^i such that t h = {^l,t) Pt {ht) + ^ Qt,TXz,T, T=l where Pt (ht) is a deterministic function of ht and Qt^r are deterministic coefficients. h,t = -Pi + 7t^ It follows that + X] QtAhT, T=l and hence Kt = Pt + 7t^ + 7?t+i, where Pt is a shortcut 7t for Pt {ht) and 74 is defined as Y^Qi.r. r=l Next consider welfare. ' Given any Wt = E[v linear strategy, ex-ante utility (fci,t, = E [v {h,t,0)] - At+i)] is Eu — J2t=i ^t, where alt+, and where E[v{k^^t,e)] = E E = E Now consider a strategy k -{{Pt + {Pt = t, + Y!,^, QtA^,r) - 0}' ,ht + itO-e)'-J2[^,QlAr_ {kt}^=i that constructed as follows. First, pick an arbitrary period ite is t and let ki^s{'^i,s) = k ki^s{^i,s) for all s < t. = It, initial pick an arbitrary function Pt and any coefficients Qt^r such that ^^.^i Qt,T t ki(^l,t) = Pt (ht) + ^ T=l 43 Qt,TXi,T- = strategy a variation of the {fct}f=i Next, in and let — Finally, for all s > let t, s T=l where the functions Pg are such that By ^ construction, at any period s implication the same per-period k condition for the strategy welfare level wt, as the initial strategy k. that, for all is argmax^E s.t. is the case and only if = Pt{ht) Next note Kt + T]t = Pt + 'Jt.O + rjt for ail t and and follows that a necessary all ht, ht It all ht and {l-^tW'[0\ht\ that, because Pt ^ y1t=i Qt,T if, t It + jtO -9) - Y!^^^ QlAr [Pt Pt,Qt.r This in turn k induces the same outcomes, and by the strategy t, to be efficient G {PtAQt,T)r=i) + Pt{ht) ^Ps[...,kt-Pt{.ht) P,(^...,Kt,..) Qt,, = -2 ^^- ^f 7t public information, the observation in period is (50) • t + \ oi Kt = informationally equivalent to the observation of a signal is yt+i — = =0 + m+i (51) It where r]t+i — rit+i/jt linear strategy, the is common precision n^, where Yt and conditions Yi — y-j^t-i — v-yt~^ -I -2 = <-l + (^y,t + V 1/ — t is lt'^^,t+\- ^^ follows that, given Gaussian with mean hq and , I tt^ = —2 ^a,t y'^t'^ 2 TTf — irf + nf Xi,t with initial conditions Xj j , cr^^. Similarly, — and yt ' the private posteriors are Gaussian with where = -^Xi^t-i + = Yt -2 + lt-\^ri,t , y mean and precision E [d\ht] = any are defined recursively by — n initial posterior about 6 in period 7rf yt with = Gaussian noise with precision o-^f+i x'j^i and nf -~Xi,t = a^-y. 44 and nf = Trf.j + ajf . !(- Now note that ^^2 r=l 2^j=l ^x,j which together with (50) gives s r=l We k maximizes conclude that a Unear strategy h^t for some coefficient To determine "ft G = (wm) ex-ante utihty only - (1 + It) Yt if, for all t and all ui^^t, (52) 'itX^^t ^ when the optimal 7's, note that, E [v )-i =- {h,,e)] agents follow a strategy as in (52), (TTf {7? + (1 - 7t)' i-^!)-'} and hence Eu ^ Wfb Ylti where 6). WpB ^*"' b' + (^*'^)"' (^ - ^^)' ^""tV'}, the first-best level of welfare (the one obtained under complete information about is Because the evolution of nf does not depend on the choice of the optimal linear strategy 7t, reduces to the following problem: mm i?E; (<)"'+ (1-^*)' ./5*-^{^' (-')"'} {7, s-t. with initial condition = iv[ a^"^ , = Trf^i where Af Trf = + Ai + C7-272 cr^j^ -I- a~J is Vi the exogenous change in the precision of public information. Consider the value functions Lt L,(7rf,^f) = : M+ — < N, Lt i, (rrf ,7rf) (Trf, Trf) must = min (7? 7f is 4+, = 4 + A, + (T-h^ (Trf)-i 7rf+i = + (1-7^)2 (Trf )-^+/3Li+i(Trf+i,Tr,V)} + At + ^tlt nf the solution to the following 7,(7r,) vs>t satisfy s.t. and hence the optimal (l-7«)'(7rf)-'} /s=t s.t. all t defined by ffi+ ^""z^-' {7,^(0-^ + min 1.7s For > -(l-7.)(-/) 45 FOC: +2^a^^^=0- , ^From the envelope theorem, Finally, from the low of motion for rrf -2 It alH < follows that, for = N, t (ii). the optimal 7j satisfies 1, 'y'^ 7if = nfj/ (tt^ no more an informational Part — _ *, Finally, for A^ = must information. Ex Xn and where Wacr < Wfb = 0, Wkk Et^i < U Vr is (k, k, 0, ^) with V. A and = similar kJ let + + ^2)6 {k.\ argument as in part (i) ensures that the = + k5 {k\ + K*^) {-itXit + (1 - It) Yt) , and public (^'-' ('^* iA + -2) I (^) '0' ^) W^K/^aa = 1 '"' "% 2 (7.)^ (-f '^')-^ + "%(!Itf «)-^ 2 is the first-best level of welfare. — Q*, we conclude Using the s.t. (rrf ,7rj') Lt(7rf,7rf) FOC = ^f + A, + (k* + K*2f a-jl^ denote the associated value function in period = niin{7,'(7rf)-^ s.t. The nf^^ Trf+i = Vf t, we have + (l-a*)(l-7*)'K')"'+/3imK+i,^f+i)} Trf^i = 7rf + Aj + (k^ + ^2)^ <^nh'i for 74 gives ^'W)--(I-a-)(.-.,)W)- + 46 fact that that the optimal 7's must solve the following problem: Letting Lt is then given by . /3*~^^ and 0, V Yt are the relevant sufficient statistics of available private ante utility E. = W,s + the last period and hence there is satisfy kt {uJit) with max V arg in (28) replacing efficient linear strategy 74, simply because this , Consider now the more general payoffs with {kq,i<[,K2) as some tt^) externality. K* [6) for + 7rf i^f^^=0, The envelope condition for gives 7r^^.j while the law of motion for gives 7rj'^_j '^"t+i It o / * -2 *\2 , follows that the optimal 7's satisfy il-a*)nf = 7t nf + (1 - a*) TTf -(3 {I -a*) {I- j^;,)' nfnf «i) (k* + ac*)^ a'J^, which completes the proof. Proof of Proposition 12. linear strategy as in Proposition 11 {7"}^i be Let and a" The efficient linear strategy. be the unique solution to (l-ar)^f it is result then follows from . (1 In fact, be the corresponding precisions of private let {Trf ,7rj'}f^^ and public information generated by the letting the coefficients that characterize the efficient - ar) nf + ^.,.. ^* TTf then and only then the unique solution to (20) coincides with the strategy obtained in Proposition 11. Proof of Corollary Gaussian signals studied 12, where it is shown 7. Consider the environments with both exogenous and endogenous in Section 6. The that, for all periods from the proof of Proposition result follows directly t, the present-value welfare losses Lf obtained along the efficient linear strategy are decreasing functions of nf and public information available in the beginning of period t. 7rf , the precisions of private and Putting aside informational externalities, the result can also be established for non-Gaussian signals using a Blackwell-like argument for the planner's problem that chai'acterizes the efficient strategy. 47 References [1] Amador, Manuel, and Pierre-Olivier Weill (2007), "Learning from Private and Public obser- vations of Others' Actions," Stanford University /UCLA mimeo. [2] Amato, Jeffrey, and Hyun Song Shin (2006), "Imperfect mation Value of Prices," Economic Theory [3] the Infor- 27, 213-241. Angeletos, George-Maxios, and Alessandro Pavan (2004), "Transparency of Information and Coordination 94, 91-98 [4] Common Knowledge and in Economies with Investment Complementarities," American Economic Review (AEA P&P). Angeletos, George-Marios, and Alessandro Pavan (2007), "Efficient Use of Information and Social Value of Information," Econom.etrica 75:4, 1103-1142. [5] Angeletos, George-Marios and Alessandro Pavan (2007b), "Socially Optimal Coordination: Characterization and Policy Implications," Journal of the European Economic Association, 5:2-3, 585-593. [6] Angeletos, George-Marios, Guido Lorenzoni, and Alessandro Pavan (2007), "Wall Street and Silicon Valley: [7] A Delicate Interaction," MIT and Northwestern mimeo. Baeriswyl, Romain, and Camille Cornand (2007), "Monetary Policy and its Informative Value," University of Munich/Universite Louis Pasteur mimeo. [8] Bacchetta, Philippe, and Eric van Wincoop (2005), "Can Information Heterogeneity Explain the Exchange Rate Determination Puzzle?," American Economic Review 95. [9] Barro, Robert (1979), omy [10] "On the Determination of the Chari, V.V., Lawrence Christiano, and Patrick Kehoe Economy (1994), '' NBER "Optimal Fiscal Policy in a 102, 617-652. Golosov, Michael, Aleh Tsyvinski and Ivan Werning (2006), Guide, [12] of Political Econ- 87, 940-71. Business Cycle Model," Journal of Political [11] Pubhc Debt," Journal "New Public Finance: A User's Macroeconomics Annual 2006. Hayek, Friedreich A. (1945), "The Use of Knowledge in Society," American Economic Review 35. [13] Hellwig, Christian (2005), UCLA "Heterogeneous Information and the Benefits of Transparency," mimeo. 48 [14] Heinemann, Prank, and Camille Cornand (2006), "Optimal Degree of Public Information Dis- semination," Economic Journal, forthcoming. [15] Kocherlakota, Narayana (2005), "Advances in Dynamic Optimal Taxation," 9th World Congress of the Econometric Society. Demand MIT [16] Lorenzoni, Guido (2006), "A Theory of [17] Lorenzoni, Guido (2007), "News Shocks and Optimal Monetary Policy," [18] Lucas, Robert E., Jr. (1972), "Expectations and the Neutrality of Money," Journal of Economic Theory [19] 4, Shocks," Lucas, Robert E., mimeo. and Nancy Jr., L. Stokey (1983), "Optimal Fiscal and Monetary Pohcy in 12, 55-93. Mackowiak, Bartosz, and Mirko Wiederholt (2007) "Optimal Sticky Prices under Rational Inattention," [21] MIT 103-124. an Economy without Capital," Journal of Monetary Economics [20] mimeo. Humboldt University/Northwestern University mimeo. Morris, Stephen, and Hyun Song Shin (2005), "Central Bank Transparency and the Signal Value of Prices," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity. [22] Hyun Song Shin Morris, Stephen, and American Economic Review [23] Phelps, Edmund (2002), The New Microeconomics tion Theory," in A. A. Alchian, C.C. Holt et [24] Raith, Michael (1996), Economic Theory [25] al., in Employment and Infla- Microeconomic Foundations of Employment York: Norton. "A General Model of Information Sharing in Oligopoly," Journal of 71, 260-288. Roca, Mauro (2006), "Transparency and Monetary Policy with Imperfect edge," [26] New of Public Information," 92, 1521-1534. (1970), "Introduction: and Inflation Theory, "The Social Value Common Knowl- Columbia University mimeo. Svensson, Lars (2005), "The Social Value of Public Information: Morris and Shin (2002) is Actually Pro Transparency, Not Con," forthcoming in American Economic Review. [27] Townsend, Robert M. (1983), "Forecasting the Forecasts of Others," Journal of Political Econ- omy [28] 91, 546-588. Vives, Xavier (1984), "Duopoly Information Equilibrium: Cournot Economic Theory 34(1), 71-94. 49 and Bertrand," Journal of [29] Vives, Xavier (1988), "Aggregation of Information in Large Cournot Markets, " Econometrica 56, 851-876. [30] Vives, Xavier (1993), "How Fast Do Rational Agents Leain?" Review of Economic Studies 60, 329-347. [31] Vives, Xavier (1997), Behavior [32] "Learning from Others: Games and Economic 20, 177-200. Woodford, Michael (2002), "Imperfect icy," in P. a Welfare Analysis," Aghion, R. Prydman, Common Knowledge and the and M. Woodford, J. Stiglitz, eds., and Expectations in Modern Macroeconomics: In Honor of Edmund Effects of Monetary Pol- Knowledge, Information, S. Phelps, Princeton Uni- versity Press. [33] Woodford, Michael (2005), "Central Bank Communication and Policy Effectiveness," paper given at the 2005 Symposium of the Federal Reserve The Greenspan Era: Lessons for the Future. 50 Bank of Kansas City at Jacksons Hole,