CHANGING EDUCATIONAL OBJECTIVES FOR A CHANGING NATIONAL ECONOMY: THE LABOR MARKET OF THE FUTURE Edward W. Hill Associate Professor College of UrbanAffairs Cleveland State University Students, parents, employers and educators are grappling with the future. Politicans and academic researchers are quickly following their lead, sensing that a constituency is developing for their services. Is this a new phenomenon? No, it is another cycle of concern over the course of public education, a cycle which has been repeated many times over the past 100 years.[l] Despite the great sound and fury of the current debate over public education, we have yet to see a clearly articulated set of questions. In fact, each special interest group appears to have its own. The business community -and the Reagan Administration -is harping on the perceived lack of quality of secondary education. Minority parents in many inner-city communities are concerned about violence, gang activity, and the real possibility of resegregation of urban schools. Parents, almost universally, are concerned about teenage pregnancy and chemical abuse. Advocates for the poor look to the schools as vehicles for feeding children and providing social services. Economists and policy analysts (at least this one) are not wellequipped to respond to such a wide range of politically articulated demands. Better-defined questions must be posed. In this paper, I attempt to provide data, and an organizational fr~~ework, which allow us to ask how change in the economy will shift the emphasis among the objectives which society holds for public schools. I will also try to see if these changes offer special challenges for big city schools. In the first section of the paper, I briefly outline how the labor market operates and the role which schools play in the market. Data are presented in the second section on the current and future structure of labor demand, by industry and occupation. Sources of labor supply are analyzed in the third section. -1- performance of manufacturing influences total employment. Not only is it a dominant employer in its own right, but it has large multiplier effects. The degree to which states in the East North Central region remain dependent on manufacturing is clearly demonstrated in the lower half of Table 1. All of these states, again with the exception of Illinois, have a much larger share of their employment in manufacturing than the nation as a whole. Continued reliance on manufacturing leads to the expectation of further employment losses, as manufacturing becomes less labor intensive nationally. However, we can also expect that manufacturing will remain an important component of the economic fate of the Midwest. In fact, whether the United States remains a manufacturing power depends in no small part on the performance of factories in the East North Central United States. Expected Employment Patterns by Industry Employment will grow at vastly different rates for the various industries in the nation. Table 2 provides detailed information on annual average rates of change in employment by industry, for the nation, from 1959 to 1986; it also contains the Bureau of Labor Statistics {BLS) moderate projection of employment for the year 2000.[5] The employment structure which emerged from the recession of 1979 should continue for the rest of the century. The overall rate of employment growth is expected to be lower than at any other non-recessionary time period in the post-war era. Construction is predicted to experience employment gains, but these gains will be offset by losses in the other sectors of the goods producing economy: manufacturing and mining. The good news from the manufacturing sector is that while employment will be declining, output is expected to increase at 2.3 percent per year. Productivity should increase at a faster rate. This means that value added will increase, implying that it is possible for manufacturing workers to earn increases in real income. Employment will continue to be gen~rated by the service producing sector of the economy. The rate of growth will be less than it has been in the recent past. Most of the growth will come from wholesale and retail trade and the service industry. {Service industries are a component of the service-producing sector of the -5. ~ But blue they collar project an increase of nearly 8 percent in the number of supervisors. The projections also reflect a shift from employment in manufacturing to an increase in upstream employment, distribution and sales. (This probably reflects the internationalization of manufacturing.) There will be an increase among those occupations which handle, store, and sell goods. These occupations are transportation and material moving, marketing and sales and helpers and laborers. The projections also reflect an increase in the number of skilled crafts workers in the economy. (Most are in the construction trades.) There is also an increase in the number, but not the share, of mechanics and precision production and plant systems workers. In sum, blue collar America's share of employment will continue to decline. Today 27 percent of all jobs can be considered to be bluecollar jobs; at the turn of the next century this will be reduced to 24 percent. The economy will shed less skilled blue-collar occupations and retain those which require more judgment, expertise and learning. The decline will be much more dramatic if demand for workers by the construction industry does not keep pace with the moderate projections of the BLS. White collar occupations will continue to generate the most new jobs. Nearly a quarter of all workers will be classified as executives, managers, or professional workers by the end of the century. The current rate of growth in these occupations will be maintained. Natural scientists and computer specialists and workers in the health professions face the best employment prospects. Educational Attainment Employment projections are nice abstractions, especially when considering an end point which is 15 years in the future. The economy is dynamic and projections are based on a raft of assumptions and constructed with a set of elegant straight line techniques. It is highly likely that actual levels of employment in 2000 will not exactly match those generated by the BLS's analysts and computers. But they serve a purpose. They help us understand the rough competitive position of the economy and alert us as to what the demand side of the labor market (employers) will be looking for from the supply side (people and schools). The labor -7. Two limitations to this analysis are presented at the outset. I do not address matters of teaching modality. [2] And I do not examine the internal organization of schools. These subjects are not policy issues. They are questions about appropriate educational technology -better left to my colleagues in schools of education. I examine demands which will be placed upon schools by the economy. A TOUROFTHELABOR MARKET Consumers do not purchase labor directly. They buy products, goods and services. Products contain varying amounts of labor content and demand for labor is derived from, or created by, product demand.[3] Before the demand for labor can be forecast, product demand by consumers, businesses and government must be known. The labor market is one of the most important markets in the economy because it is the dominant source of income and it is a critical link in macroeconomic policy. Yet, policy-makers are not concerned about the market for a particular product by and of itself; they are concerned about workers in particular industries. When I teach about the workings of the labor market and digress into discussions about products my students become confused and I begin to feel like Copernicus. My students feel that the labor market is the center of the universe. Yet, I insist that they think about products. Which is the true center of the universe? It is the product market. Employers combine labor and capital in a production process. The amount of each factor used depends on technical requirements and the relative cost and productivity of each factor used. However , producing the good, supplying it to consumers on the product market, is not enough. Demand and supply must interact. The amount sold depends on the producers' price and consumers' level of demand at that price. If the pattern of demand shifts over time, with products entering and leaving the marketplace, consumers' willingness to buy at a given price will change. All of these forces directly influence the amount and type of labor which is demanded by employers. In the smooth and orderly world of theoretical economics, employers line up potential workers in a queue, ranking them by their potential productivity. Employers calculate how much additional output each worker will contribute and the value of that output on the product market. Employers will negotiate a wage offer -2- labor. There will be substantial, but declining demand for workers with limited skills and educational backgrounds. The labor prospects for dropouts, illiterates and those incapable of learning throughout -their work-lives will continue to crumble. There will be increased demand for workers who can think and learn abstract concepts. What is not known is the degree to which the labor market will monetarily reward those capable of the latter type of learning. This depends on the supply of such labor and the reservation wages of our more learned workers. In sum, it m.eans that schools will become more important economic development resources. CURRENT AND FUTURE DEMAND FOR LABOR Recent History A great deal has been written in the popular press and by academicians about changes in employment in the United States and in the nation's historical manufacturing belt since 1979.[4] A longterm trend away from manufacturing toward service industry employment was accelerated by two recessions, in 1979 and 1982. In the Midwest the recovery between these recessions never materialized. The Midwest lagged, in large part, because higher paying service employment, which buoyed the recovery, was located outside of the region. The secular shift in product demand, combined with the recessions and slow recovery, makes it difficult to understand what happened to this regional economy. We are only beginning to disentangle the events using recently released statistics. Data presented in Table 1 measure changes in employment for the nation and various regions from the 1978 business cycle peak to year-end 1986. All data are annual averages. They clearly indicate that the regions which were most dependent on manufacturing employment have lagged in the recovery, the only exception being New England. The difference lies in the fact that New England's manufacturers specialized in electrical equipment, computing products and defense industries. The largest loss in manufacturing employment was during the first recession, 1978-1982. These losses were concentrated in the East North Central Census region. Manufacturing employment recovered to a limited extent from 1982 to 1986 in all of the East North Central states, with the exception of Illinois. What is most striking about the employment figures ~s the extent to which the -4. ~ economy .) The BLS expects that almost 80 percent of all employment will be in the service producing sector of the economy. (See Table 3) Employment in manufacturing will drop to 15 percent of non-farm wage and salary employment, from 26 percent in 1972 and 19 percent today. This is a loss of an additional 830,000 manufacturing jobs. But manufacturing will remain a significant employer. Jobs in manufacturing will be generated by turn-over, not by growth, due to the high average age of manufacturing workers. It is easier to understand the future structure of employment by examining the net number of jobs which will be created in each industry over the next 15 years. Some industries are expected to expand, others contract. The net numbers of jobs created, by industry, are displayed in Table 4. The last column shows the percent distribution of new openings. Nearly 87 percent of new openings will be in service-producing sector; 43.17 percent in the service industries. The three industries which will generate the largest employment increases are Retail Trade, Business Services, and Health Care Services. The next largest source of employment growth will be among the self-employed; they will count for 9 percent of all new jobs. Finance, Insurance and Real Estate and Wholesale Trade will both grow slowly. The continued shift in employment demand from manufacturing to services has three important implications for society: the pattern of occupations will change; the distribution of earnings available in the economy will shift; changes in labor demand by industry and occupation wiR influence the educational requirements which must be met by American workers. Each will be addressed in the remainder of thispaper. The Occupational Picture Table 5 presents information on the occupational distribution of employment in the nation in 1986 and the ~LS's projected distribution, under the moderate scenario, for 2000. Growth rates from 1972 to 1979 and from 1979 to 1986 for major occupational groupings are also displayed. Employment in manufacturing is expected to decline by about 4 percent from 1986 to 2000. Yet the change in all traditional manufacturing occupations does not decline by an equal percentage. The BLS projects that there will be declines of about 4 percent for machine setters and operators, assemblers and other hand -workers. -6- up to the value of the worker's marginal product. If the potential employee is willing to work for that wage a deal is struck and the job is filled. In the real world, choices are not quite as obvious. It is difficult to evaluate the potential productivity of workers without having them actually demonstrate their ability on the job. In many situations even this will underestimate productivity, as workers often become more efficient as they perform the job; this is called learning-by-doing or on-the-job training. Instead, employers look at a number of factors which serve as predictors of productivity. In some cases, they pay attention to references, at other times formal credentials such as diplomas, and in a few situations they will perform job-specific testing. Economists view schools as providing three products. The first is learning. Individuals invest in their own careers by attending school and obtaining human capital. The second is vocational training, which tends to be more job specific -it is not valued by a wide variety of employers. Economists also view schooling as a consumer good. This is the component of learning which is not directly valued by the labor market; it has entertainment value. Schools, and degrees, are an essential part of the supply side of the labor market. Education helps transform people into valued ingredients for the production process. Wages, when based on productivity, are indirectly related to the quality and quantity of education. It is assumed that in the short run educational credentials are what employers hold dear, as indicators of the potential productivity of the employee. But as employers gain experience in evaluating credentials, they are discounted accordingly. If some schools provide credentials of inconsistent value, or are consistently of little value, they will be ignored. Returns to labor, and indirectly to education, are driven by competition in the product market. The United States has lost its comparative advantage in routinized manufacturing. We have seen our growth rate decline when compared to both the industrialized nations and the newly industrialized countries of the Pacific rim. Our advantage lies in capital intensive and innovative manufacturing and in services. What does this imply for production of goods and services schools? It implies requires two different that the types of . -3- force of the year 2000 is largely with us -the oldest are currently 41 years of age, the youngest are 4. The oldest part of the labor force will be aging baby boomers, the core of the labor force will be members of the birth dearth generation, and the entrants will be the echo -children of the boomers. In sum, the performance of our schools over the next decade will go a long way toward determining our economic fate, the wealth of the nation. The occupational groups listed in Table 6 are classified by the degree of educational attainment required to qualify for the jobs of the future. There is a positive relationship between the level of educational attainment required for an occupational group and its growth rate. Product demand has shifted, and will continue to shift, towards goods and services which require people with more sophisticated skills as part of their production process. The last column of the table shows the distribution of new jobs created, by occupation, from 1986 to 2000, grouping them by the required level of educational attainment. The smallest number of oper.ings will be generated in those occupations requiring the lowest level of education, Group III. This reflects absolute declines in factory and farm work. The data reveal that those Americans with the lowest levels of education will be assigned to driving trucks and working in service industries . cleaning buildings, preparing and serving food, working as nursing aides and other medical assistants, and performing unsophisticated personal services. The highest growth rates are reserved for those occupations requiring the greatest academic achievement. Educational Group I will account for nearly 38 percent of net new job openings generated by our economy. In fact, the number of openings for professional workers alone will nearly match all of those available for Educational Group III. These projections are for the gross number of j()bs in the year 2000. They do not reflect the gross number of job openings, which is influenced by the age distribution and labor force participation rates of those currently holding the positions. For example, the growth rate for teachers is 15.6 percent. But the median age of all teachers in 1983 was 39 years old, compared to 33 in 1972. Only 22 percent of all teachers are younger than 30.[6] At least 35 percent of today's teachers will retire before the year 2000; this is after making the (unlikely) assumption that there will be no turnover for reasons -8- precursor for increased productivity in a technologically advanced society. ~ There will be wide differences among the growth rates of different age-sex -race cohorts in the labor force. The group which traditionally has the greatest attachment to the labor force, men from age 25 to 54, is expected to have an annual average growth rate of 1.3 percent. Women of the same age will have a growth rate of 2.2 percent. Three cohorts in the labor market are expected to decrease in size over the next fifteen years. The labor force participation of males of retirement age will decrease by 2.0 percent per year and the female rate will decrease by 1.1 percent per year . This is at a time when these cohorts will comprise an increasing share of the population. The youngest age group in the labor force, those age 16 to 24, will also have a negative growth rate. The male rate will be -0.4 percent while that of women will hover near no growth. The composition of the working-age population will be different in the next century. It will be proportionately less white, 83.6 percent versus the current 86.1 percent. The black share of the population will climb from 11.1 percent to 12.1 percent. And the fastest growing portion of the population is composed of those with Hispanic surnames, increasing from 6.8 to 10.0 percent. The population will also be proportionately older. The largest gain will be among those age 25 to 54; the largest loss will be those aged 16 to 24. Growth rates in the size of the labor force are a product of two factors, changes in the size of the population and in the labor force participation rate (LFPR). The LFPR is the portion of a cohort which will enter the labor force. I will examine the 16 to 24 year old cohort of men and women to illustrate the interaction between these two variables. -~ The actual size of the 16 to 24 year old cohort, the raw population, for men and women will decrease. The LFPR for young men is currently 73.0 percent; it is expected to increase to 74.7 percent in the year 2000. But the increase in the LFPR will not counteract the expected 1,284,000 person decrease in the population. This is contrasted with the expected behavior of young women. Their LFPR should increase from 64.3 percent to 69.5 percent, nearly offsetting the expected 1,294,000 person decrease in the size of the -11- ~ ~ cohort. The decrease in the size of both groups is nearly equal but their labor force growth rates will be different due to their LFPRs. ~ The largest changes in the work force will not be due to the composition of the population but to changes in the LFPRs of the different cohorts. This is a continuation of a trend which first appeared in the mid-1960s. ~ All male participation rates will decline, with the exception of the 16 to 24 year old cohort. But the decline in the LFPRs of men will be partly offset by increases in the female LFPRs, again with the single exception of those older than 65. The LFPR of prime age males will decrease from 93.8 to 92.6 percent; that of prime age women will increase from 70.8 to 80.8 percent. The largest decrease in LFPRs will be among older men. The rate for men age 55 to 64 will drop from 67.3 to 63.2 percent and for men 65 years or older it will decrease from 16.0 to 9.9 percent. Declines in the LFPRs of young black male workers has become a major concern. The decline is evident for 16 to 19 year old men, as well as 20 to 24 year olds.[9] The LFPR of black male teens in 1965 was 51.2 percent, the 1985 rate was 44.6 percent. (The corresponding white rates were 54.1 percent and 59.7 percent respectively .) The LFPR for black men age 20 to 24 has also decreased dramatically. The LFPR in 1965 was 89.8 percent, in 1985 it was 79.0 percent. ( The white rates were 85.3 percent and 86.4 percent.) In both cases, white rates have increased and corresponding rates for blacks have decreased. In both cases, the black population was also starting with a lower participation rate.[10] All of these factors will have major impacts on the composition of the labor force in the year 2000. The labor force will become slightly older, more female, and less white. And, most importantly, it will be slow growing. The way in which the labor force can achieve a growth rate which comes near that of GNP is to increase the LFPRs of groups which will be under-represented in the labor force. This , means that the LFPR of women of all ages will hJ.ve to increase ~ ~ further. It also means that black Americans must become fully involved in the labor force. Currently, blacks are 11.8 percent of the working-age population but only 10.8 percent of the labor force. In the year 2000 this gap is expected to remain. The prospect of a shortage of workers in the year 2000 is real. Currently, the surplus of workers from the baby boom generation competes for entry level jobs with the birth dearth generati~n. This -12- Table A verage Annual Rate 2 of Change 1959-69 Total Nonfarm Wage & Salary GOODS-PRODUONG Mining Construction Manufacturing Durable Nondurable SERVICE-PRODUCING Private Tranportation & Pub Wholesale Trade Retail Trade Finance,Insurance,Real Services Government Agriculture Private Households Nonfarm Self-employed sources: Personick. 1987, 1.9 0. -2.' 1. 1. 2. 1. 2. 2. 7 O 1 9 3 2 6 2 in Employment 1969-79 1979-84 2.2 0. 8 3. 5 3. O 0. 4 0. 7 0. O 2. 9 3. O 1979-86 1986-2000 I. 4 I. 5 -I. O -2. .8 I. 4 -I. 4 -I. 8 -0. 9 2. 4 3 3 0. O -0. 6 1. 2 -0. 3 -0. 3 -0. 3 1. 9 3 4 2. 5 3. 4 4. 3 0. 7 -0. 6 -0. 9 1. 8 8 8 1. 9 1. 9 2. 9 0. 9 -0. 6 0. a 1. 7 1.0 -1 .1 -1 .6 0 .1 -1 .6 -2 .0 -0 .9 1 .9 2 .5 Utilities Table 0. 1. Estate 4.2 -4.2 1; Kutscher 2.7 -0.8 and Personick. 0.0 -0.3 1986, Table 1. 1. 1. 0. 1. Table 3 Percent Distribution and Rate of Change of Employment by Major Sector, 1972, 1979, 1986, and Projected to 2000 Percent Sector 1972 1979 Distribution Moderate Projection 1986 2000 Change (in thousands) 1986 to 2000 TOfAL Nonfarm 21 ,407 Wage & Salary GOODS-PRODUCING Mining Construction Manufacturing Durable Nondurable SERVICE-PRODUCING Tranportation & Public Wholesale Trade Retail Trade Finance,Insurance,Real Services Government Utilities Estate 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 20, 112 32.2 0.9 5.3 26.1 15.0 11.0 29.6 1.1 5.0 23.5 14.3 9.3 24.9 0.8 5.0 19.2 11.4 7.8 20.7 0.6 4.9 15.2 9.0 6.2 -3 -59 890 -834 -513 -321 67.8 6.2 5.6 16.1 5.3 16.5 18.1 70.4 5.7 5.8 16.8 5.6 18.7 17.8 75.1 5.3 5.8 18.0 6.4 22.7 16.9 79.3 4.8 6.1 19.1 6.6 27.3 15.4 20,115 475 1,531 4,857 1620 10,014 1,618 Agriculture Private Households Nonfarm Self-employed source: Personick. -253 -7 2,191 1987, Table 1. 3 ~ ;;I,~ .,"C~' ~~e~ ;f;1 ~gT c11-' , " L , """, ~iU~~1, I', ",. . other than retirement at age 65. Turnover and early retirements will greatly expand the number of actual openings. The age distribution within different occupations greatly influences the number of jobs which will be available to the population over the next decade and a half. Analysts and planners will have to monitor age related turnover as well as the net number of jobs created. Minimum , Wage Employment Recent work indicates that the distribution of wages within occupational groups has increased from 1973 to 1985.[7] While it is not possible to calculate the wage distribution in the major occupational groups in Table 6, it is possible to project the portion of new jobs which will be at the current minimum wage, assuming that the portion which existed in 1986 holds constant (see Table 7). The projection is distressing. The number, and portion, of minimum wage jobs should grow over the next 15 years. Nearly 9,000,000 of the jobs available to those with the lowest level of educational attainment will pay at, or below, the current minimum wage. This is at a time when the total number of jobs available to this group is expected to increase by 5,660,000. In other words, all new jobs available to this group, plus an additional 3,222,000 positions, will pay poorly. In 1986 approximately 8 percent of all jobs paid at, or near, the minimum wage. This will increase to 10 percent in the year 2000 due to changes in the industrial and occupational structure of employment. The largest number of these low paying jobs are in the "other service workers" category, followed by the marketing and sales occupational group. Most of the positions in the latter group are sales workers and cashiers. I concede that these projections assume that current labor market conditions will hold steady, which is unlikely. Future labor shortages will drive up real wages in these occupations a bit, but they will remain relatively low paying. The important point to be made is not about the wage level. It is about the economic prospects of the poorly educated. They are bleak and will get worse. Compare the prospects of the badly educated to those in Educational Group II. The number of positions open to Group II is expected to increase by 7,600,000. The total number of poorly paying jobs will be about 3,500,000. The earnings prospects of those -9- in Group II will deteriorate. improve. The prospects for those in Group III will SOURCES OF SUPPL y Who will fill these new positions? The labor market questions of the future will focus on the supply side of the market. The birth dearth generation is with us and selected local labor markets have become tight. The future performance of the American economy will depend on groups who have, in the past, been relatively unimportant components of the labor pool. The e~onomy's growth depends on employers hiring minority workers and it will increasingly depend on the level of academic achievement of minority youth. The only wild card which the American economy will have available, if our minority population does not succeed in the labor market, is immigration policy. The coming labor supply problem is illustrated by figures provided by New York City's Educational Priorities Panel. Nine job openings out of ten in New York require applicants with a high school diploma. Yet, 40 percent of the City's adults, age 25 years or older, are dropouts. In addition, the dropout rate from the City's public schools is in excess of 40 percent. The Job Training Partnership Program (JTPP) provides training in reading which it considers to be the minimum necessary for success in the labor market -this is at the seventh grade reading level. Fully 22 percent of adult New Yorkers, between I and 1.5 million people, are below this level.[8] Nationally only 66.5 percent of all adults, age 25 years or older, have a high school diploma. The United States has a labor problem. Changes in the Labor Force Howard N. Fullerton, Jr. estimates that the labor force will grow at 1.2 percent per year from 1986 to 2000 (see Table 8). This contrasts with annual increases in real Gross National Product (GNP) of 2.4 percent. The only way in which the labor market can support GNP growth is through average annual increases in productivity of 1.2 percent. This will be difficult for two reasons. First, the nation must increase its savings rate to support capital deepening. Second, the largest increases in the potential labor force will be among those who have historically low levels of academic achievement, a -10- tends to compensate for the lack of new entrants. However , shortages will occur, given current and projected LFPRs, when the boomers retire and before the echo fully participates in the labor market.[II] The degree of difficulty which the economy will experience due to a lack of entrants depends on four factors: the LFPRs of women of all ages, the LFPRs of all who reach the traditional retirement age, the educational achievement of all young people and the labor market participation of minority youth. CHANGINGEDUCATIONALOBJECfIVES Public primary and secondary schools respond to a wide variety of social functions, some are educational others are not.[12] Administrators of schools respond to environmental pressures and constantly adjust the allocation of resources and the emphasis among these functions. The relationship between the different functions are displayed in Figure 1. Data presented in this paper indicate that there will be major changes in the economic environment which will affect public schools in general. There is also a cumulation of evidence that the social conditions in older inner-cities are also changing and having deleterious impacts on public education.[13] The growth and concentration of the underclass in our cities is placing extreme pressures on big city schools. Poverty, chemical abuse, gang violence, teenage pregnancy are all problems which are external to schools but disrupt learning within schools. All are threats to the learning environment. In addition, schools are now part of our social safety net. Schools as institutions have inherited these two functions from society as a whole; they must provide a secure learning environment and act as part of the social safety net. If they cannot, education will be disrupted. This is the reason why Heidi Marie Rock and I call these two purposes of public education " foundational functions " . The challenge which confronts big city school systems is to insure that the foundation for learning is in place. This means that they must provide secure buildings and environments which are conducive to learning. Schools must also work, and intervene, so that social problems which exist in the community or in students' families do not interfere with education. Anecdotal evidence indicates that large urban systems are failing to provide secure learning environments. Schools cannot replace the family and other -13- . institutions, such as social welfare agencies. Yet schools have become the social safety net of last resort for many children because they do not close their doors. The second major environmental change in public education is being generated by the economy. In the recent past the educational requirement for many well-paying jobs in the economy was relatively low. They were in occupations which the BLS classified as Educational Groups II and III. This corresponds to employability in Figure 1. Today's economy demands higher levels of learning from applicants for good paying jobs -Educational Group I. This corresponds to life-long learning in Figure 1. Workers today need to be able to learn abstract concepts and be able to retrain themselves throughout their work-lives. This is a level of learning which was required of the college bound. Mass education in the next 15 years must become equivalent to elite education of the past 15 years. Will our big city school systems be up to the challenge? " .0 -14- Table 6 Expected Employment Change by Occupation 1986 to 2000: Growth Rates and Distribution of Total Employment Change 1986 Employment (000) Occupation TarAL 111,620 Change in Employment (000) 21,405 Growth Rate (%) Distribution Change in Employment(%) 19.18 100.00 EDUCATIONAL GROUP I Management & Related Managerial & Admin Management Support Professional Workers Engineer, Architects Natural Science & Computer Teacher, Librarian, Counselor Health & Related Other Professionals Technicians & Support 27,771 10,583 7,369 3,214 17,188 1,567 738 4,949 2,592 3,692 3,650 8,090 3,033 2,071 962 5,057 495 339 772 1,081 967 1,403 29.13 28.66 28.10 29.93 29.42 31.59 45.93 15.60 41.71 26.19 38.44 37.79 14.17 9.68 4..49 23.63 2.31 1.58 3.61 5.05 4.52 6.55 EDUCATIONAL GROUP II Marketing & Sales Admin Support & Clerical Precision Prod, Craft, Repair Blue Colar Supervisors Construction Trades Mechanics Precision Production 46,030 12,606 19,851 13,573 1,823 4,006 4,678 3,066 7,655 3, 728 2,258 1,669 144 704 687 134 16.63 29.57 11.37 12.30 7.90 17.57 14.69 4.37 35.76 17.42 10.55 7.80 0.67 3.29 3.21 0.63 EDUCATION GROUP III Service Workers Cleaning, except household Food Preparation Food Health Personal Private Household Protective Agriculture, Forest, Fish Operators Machine Setters Assemblers Transport Workers Helpers 37,819 17,536 3,107 7,104 4,204 1,819 1,799 981 2,055 3,556 16,727 4,964 2,701 4, 789 4,273 !,660 5,381 712 2,601 1,628 730 460 -26 645 -163 442 -194 -113 500 249 14.97 30.69 22.92 36.61 38.73 40.13 25.57 -2.65 31.39 -4.58 2.64 -3.91 -4.18 10.44 5.83 26.44 25.14 3.33 12.15 7.61 3.41 2.15 -0.12 3.01 -0.76 2.06 -0.91 -0.53 2.34 1.1-6 source: Silvestri, George T. and John M. Lukasiewicz. 1987, various " tables. ~,~,~, ' .,; Table 7 Percentage of Employed Wage and Salary Workers Paid Hourly at or Below the Prevailing Minimum Wage, 1986 Annual Average and 2000 Moderate Projection Occupation Percent At or Below 1986 Minimum Wage in 1986 EDUCATIONAL GROUP I Executive, Administrative, Managerial Professional Workers Technicians & Related Support Moderate Projection 2000 (000) Rates Projected Number At or Below Minimum Wage 2000 (000) 1.9 1.1 2.7 1.2 35,862 13,616 17,193 5 ,053 675 150 464 61 EDUCATIONAL GROUP II Marketing & Sales Administrative Support & Clerical Precision Production, Craft, Repair Construction Trades & Extractive Mechanics & Repairers 6.5 14.0 3.9 1.4 1.3 1.3 53,685 16,334 22,109 15,242 4,710 5,365 3,493 2,287 862 213 61 70 EDUCATIONAL GROUP III Operators, Fabricators, Laborers Machine Setters Operators Transportation & Material Moving Helpers & Laborers Farm, Forestry, Fishing Private Household Workers Other Service Workers 20.0 5.7 4.4 3.4 9.4 18.4 53.0 26.0 44,435 17, 170 4, 770 5 ,289 4,522 3,393 955 22,917 8,882 979 210 180 425 624 506 5,958 source: Silvestri, George T. and John M. Lukasiewicz. Melior, Earl F. 1987, Table 2. 1987, various tables; and Table 8 Civilian Participation Rate 1986 2000 GROUP Total, Labor Force and Panicipation Rates by Sex, Age, and Race, Actual 1986 and Moderate Projection 2000 16 and over Cbange (000) 1986-2000 Men, 16 and over 16-24 25-54 55-64 65 and over 76.3 73.0 93.8 673 16.0 74.7 74.3 92.6 63.2 9.9 7.713 -745 8,618 284 -444 0.8 -0.4 1.3 0.3 -2.0 55.5 10.4 37.7 5.9 1.5 52.7 8.3 38.2 5.2 1.0 47.5 9.3 262 5.7 6.3 Women, 16 and over 16-24 25 -54 55-64 65andover 553 64.3 70.8 42.3 7.45.4 61.5 695 80.8 45.8 13,225 8 12,597 792 -172 1.6 (1) 2.2 1.1 -1.1 44.5 47.3 9.4 8.0 29.8 34.4 4.2 4.1 1.00.79.0 52.5 96 27.5 6.5 White, 16 and over Men Women 65.5 76.9 55.0 68.2 75.3 615 14,900 5,036 9,864 1.0 0.6 1.4 86.4 48.6 37.8 84.1 44.9 39.2 86.1 41.2 44.9 Black, 16 and over Men Women 635 71.2 57.2 66.0 70.7 62.1 3,650 1,553 2,097 1.8 1.6 2.1 10.8 5.4 5.4 11.8 5.7 6.1 11.1 5.0 6.1 Asian, 16 and over Men Women 64.9 74.9 55.9 65.8 72.4 60.1 2,388 1,124 1,264 3.9 3.5 4.5 2.8 1.6 1.3 4.1 2.1 2.0 2.9 1.4 1.5 Hispanic Men Women 65.4 810 50.1 68.7 80.4 56.9 6,010 3.355 2.655 4.1 3.8 4.5 6.9 4.2 2.7 10.2 6.0 4.2 6.8 3.4 35 source. Fu1lenon. 1987, Tables I. 2 and 5. 100.0 100.0 Populat % Dis 1986 67.8 -0.05 and 0.05 percent. 1.2 Labor Force % Distrib 1986 2000 65.3 (1) the rate is between 20,938 Annual Orowth Rate 1986-2000 100.0 NOTES 1] Edward W. Hill and Heidi Marie Rock (1988). 2] I contend that the search for a single "best practice" modality -an educational panacea -is either an exercise in futility or an exercise in creative grant writing. It is difficult for an economist to envision a world where there is one best practice production technology for all circumstances, whether the product is a manufactured good or student learning. 3] An extremely readable introduction to the functioning of labor markets, and to a range of theories on how they operate, can be found in: Clark Kerr and Paul D. Staudohar (1986), Ch 7, "How Labor Markets Operate," Economics of Labor in Industrial Society. 4] A large number of articles have recently appeared which examine the impact of the last recession and of structural change on the economy. Among them are: Allardice and Schnorbus (1987), Bluestone and Harrison (1982), Bradbury (1986), Jacobson (1987), Kutscher and Personick (1986), Lawrence (1984), McMahon and Tschetter (1986), Olsen (1987) and Rosenthal ( 1985). 5] The Bureau of Labor Statistics published their labor market projections to the year 2000 in the September issue of the Monthly Labor Review. Data presented in this issue are used extensively in this paper. see: Fullerton (1987), Kutscher (1987), Personick (1987), Saunders (1987) and Silvestri and Lukasiewicz ( 1987). 6] U.S. Department/ of Education. Center for Educational Statistics. Digest of Educational Statistics: 1987. Table 43 "Characteristics of Private School Teachers, By Level and Affiliation of School: United States, 1985-86." p. 54; Table 49 "Selected Characteristics of Public School Teachers: United States, Spring 1961 to Spring 1983." p.60. 7] McMahon and Tschetter (1986) and Rosenthal (1985). 24 . 8] Chall (1985) examined labor market conditions in New York City and found that the employment prospects for dropouts deteriorated from 1980 to 1983. The proportion of employed City residents without diplomas fell from 28 percent to 22 percent. This decline was broadly based, as the employment share of these residents fell in every major industrial sector . Chall's surprising finding is that New York's over-supply of dropouts is mostly attributable to migration -poorly educated individuals are moving to, and failing in, New York's labor market. While the dropout problem in New York's public school system is substantial it does not produce the majority of the dropouts in the City's residential labor supply. 9] Holzer and Freeman (1986) contains a series a papers on the black youth employment problem. The paper by Ronald Ferguson and Randall Filer is of special interest. The labor market performance of black men from 1940 to 1980 is reviewed in Smith and Welch (1986). 10] The 1985 data are from Table 3, "Employment Status of the Civilian Noninstitutional Population by Age, Race and Sex." Employment and Earnings, January, 1986. The 1965 data were obtained from Table A-4 and A-13 in the Employment and Training Report of the President, 1982. pp.151 and 168. 11] Nardone (1987) 12] A description of the functions, their development over the past 100 years, and the way in which they relate to each other are contained in Hill and Rock (1988). 13] See Wilson (1987), especially pp. 57-58, and Sullivan (1987). . 25 c'- REFERENCES ~ ~ Allardice, David R. and Robert H. Schnorbus (1987). "The Ordeal of Change: Working it Out in the Midwest." Chicago Fed Letter. September. Bluestone, Barry and Bennett Deindustrialization of America. Harrison New York: The (1982). Basic Books. ~ Bradbury, Katherine L. (1986). "The Shrinking Middle Class". New England Economic Review, September/October: pp. 41-55. ~ Chall, Daniel E. (1985). "New York City's 'Skills Mismatch."' Reserve Bank of New York Quarterly Review, Spring: Federal pp.20-27. Ferguson, Ronald and Randall Filer (1986). "Do Better Jobs Make Better Workers? Absenteeism from Work Among Inner-City Black Youths," in Richard B. Freeman and Harry J. Holzer (eds.) The B lack Youth Employment Crisis. Chicago: University of Chicago Press: pp.261-298. -~ Freeman, Richard Employment B. and Crisis. Harry I. Chicago: Holzer 1986. University of The Chicago Black Youth Press. Fullerton, Jr., Howard N. (1987). "Labor Force Projections: 1986 2000." Monthly Labor Review,.9 (September): pp.19-29 Hill, to Edward W. and Heidi Marie Rock ( 1988). "Different Ends for Different Times: Surviving 100 Years of Educational Reform Reports." Working Paper. College of Urban Affairs, Cleveland State University. Jacobson, Lewis S. (1987). "Perspective on Economic Development in West Michigan." Business Outlook for West Michigan, Vol. III, (Spring): pp.1-3. '-, "..., Kerr, Clark and Paul D. Staudohar (eds.) (1986). "How Labor Markets Operate." in Economics of Labor in Industrial Society. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass: pp.192-226. 26