II.IT. LIBRARIES - DEWEY Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium Member Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/stochasticequicoOObaij Dewey HB31 .M415 f\o. <& working paper department of economics STOCHASTIC EQUICONTINUITY AND WEAK CONVERGENCE OF UNBOUNDED SEQUENTIAL EMPIRICAL PROCESES massachusetts institute of technology 50 memorial drive Cambridge, mass. 02139 STOCHASTIC EQUICONTINUITY AND WEAK CONVERGENCE OF UNBOUNDED SEQUENTIAL EMPIRICAL PROCESES Jushan Bai 94-7 Jan. 1993 Abstract This note explains why sequential empirical processes arise naturally in the context of structural change and then provides an elementary proof for their stochastic equicontinuity. and in An application is considered for testing structural change in a linear regression a single equation of a simultaneous equations system. Key words and phrases: Stochastic equicontinuity, pirical process, two-parameter Brownian bridge, structural change. weak convergence, sequential em- Stochastic Equicontinuity and Weak Convergence of Unbounded Sequential Empirical Processes Jushan Bai Massachusetts Institute of Technology (617) 253-6217 email: jbai@athena.mit.edu Revised: January 1994 APRS 1994 Introduction 1 A number empirical processes for heterogeneous and dependent observations, DeJong first [11], and Hansen A [16]. review is given by Andrews [3]. Andrews [2], In this paper we e.g., introduce a weighted sequential empirical process and then study equicontinuity. A sequential empirical process involves partial As such, an empirical process cesses. unbounded of authors have recently studied stochastic equicontinuity for case of a sequential empirical process. in the usual sense Andrews [2] sums its stochastic of stochastic pro- may be viewed as a special shows how empirical process the- ory can be used in various applications in econometrics, particularly in establishing asymptotic properties of econometric estimators and test statistics. paper that sequential empirical processes arise naturally We show in this in the context of structural change. Therefore they will be useful for testing parameter constancy in econometric models. Sequential empirical processes and their related stochastic equicontinuity are discussed by Bickel and Wichura we [9], but with no particular motivation. In this paper, The consideration consider a weighted sequential empirical process. version is motivated by structural change next section. The weights in linear regressions, as of a weighted explained in the are the regression variables or a set of instrument variables, so that the process involves unbounded summands in contrast to the one considered by Bickel and Wichura. Also regression variables are generally stochastic and correlated (e.g., autoregressive models); thus we have a in the literature. from the existing results. empirical processes Its stochastic equicontinuity In addition, the demands highly may we [10]. is and not discussed not be directly derived contemporaneous treatment of dependent technical and abstract analysis. In this paper, provide an elementary proof for stochastic equicontinuity. extension of that of Billingsley serially stochastically weighted dependent empirical process. This kind of sequential empirical process much first The argument is we a direct Because of the concrete structure of the process, are able to derive concrete sufficient conditions for its stochastic equicontinuity. In addition, an elementary proof is instructive. Application of the result to structural changes in linear regressions The cussed. analysis is is briefly dis- applicable to changes in a single equation of a simultaneous equations system. Tests based on a weighted sequential empirical process can detect changes in regression parameters and changes in variance. tests can detect changes in error distribution functions that are not necessarily man- ifested in the form of changing variances. In other words, the test changes in higher moments of the data, whereas the type of tests 2 Most importantly, these may not be able CUSUM, is able to test and Wald fluctuation, to. Sequential empirical process For a given sequence of random variables Z\, Zi, of this sequence is V is z)-F(z)}, (k = 1,2, :..,u) t=i the distribution function of Z,. Bickel and Wichura and establish the stochastic equicontinuity of The summand process. Z„, the sequential empirical process defined as Bn (k,z) = 4=Ei 7 (^ < n where F(z) ..., in the process sequential empirical process which is is Bn for i.i.d. bounded by 1. not bounded and Z\s. This We [9] is introduce first a two-parameter shall consider a may be weighted dependent. Weighted sequential empirical processes arise naturally in the context of structural change. Consider the following linear regression model: yt where x t is = x' P + e t (* t = a vector of explanatory variables, l,2,....,n) /? is (1) an unknown vector, and e are t i.i.d. disturbances with a continuous distribution function. Define the vector process: n - < -OC < Z < In terms of parameter inference, observing this process is equivalent to observing the Sn{z) whole data set, YlxtI{Vt Z), OO. with probability one. The vector process simply orders the original data is according to the magnitude of the dependent variable. In this sense, set (may be a a sufficient statistic for "sufficient process" Sn (z) more appropriate). Now is suppose the true model obeys a two-regime regression: To estimate 0\ The belongs. and process = l,2,...,n 1 ) (2a) et (* = m + l,...,n). (2b) x't l +e yt = x't 2 + Sn (z) statistic (process) for 0\ (i = important to know to which regime a given observation it is 02, t yt does not convey this information. and 2 It is thus not a sufficient However, . Sn (z) = f:x 1 t <z) I(y t t=i and £ Sn2 (z)= <z) x t I(yt t=m+i are jointly sufficient for 0i and 02, because S„ only orders the n^ observations n — rii However, when the regime-switching point n\ is unknown, then within themselves, and similarly S% orders the selves. first last observations within them(5*, S%) longer a sufficient statistic. In this case, sufficient statistics are given by (5*, S*) for rii = all is no pairs of 1,2, ..,n. Introduce k Sn (k,z) = ^x I(y t t < z), t=i which is a sequential empirical process up to normalization and centering. For k Sn (k,z) the process when rii is unknown, As an example is simply S*(z) and Sn (n,z) - Sn (n sufficient statistics are given x ,z) is = ri\, simply S*(z). Thus, by Sn (k,z), k = l,...,n. of a dependent sequential empirical process, consider a time series regression: yt Denote x t But x t is = (l,y t -\, = fi + ••, Vt—p, z[)'. piy t -i The + •• p y - P P t + z't 6 +e t sequential empirical process serially correlated, yielding a (3) . is defined as before. dependent sequential empirical process. The above model. To do process this, Sn (k,z) only describes the data, we modify the process it does not incorporate the to k Sn (k, 2, 7) = 51 x t I(y t < z + x't j). t=\ A linear structure is introduced in the above process. Also note, under model Sn (k,z,/3) = J2 x tH £ < (1), z )- t t=l However, the parameter /? is unknown, so Sn (k, solve this problem one can replace To z, /?) is not observable or computable. by an estimator, f3 $. If we put it = yt — x't $, then k Sn (k,zJ) = ^2x <z) I(e t t t=i which can be considered an estimated sequential empirical process. This process embodies the model and data. The estimated parameter can be obtained from the first k observations or from the whole sample. In the former case, a sequence of estimators is needed, which may be obtained by recursive estimation. In our application, we use a whole-sample estimator. The Sn (k,z, $), Tests based on the weighted sequential empirical process are [8]. see Section 4. parameter constancy more powerful than those based on a non-weighted To study the asymptotic property Sn (k, z, /5), whose convergence The weak convergence we test for in turn of the latter is of the test, is based on the process process, as pointed out by Bai we need the weak convergence depends on the weak convergence of Sn (k, our focus. By of z, 0). normalizing and centering of Sn <z)- F(z)} (4) , define the vector process [ns] Hn (s, z) = (X'X)-^ £ x t {I(e t t=i where of Hn X = and (xi,X2, ...,x n )'. In the next section, its stochastic equicontinuity weak convergence. The weighting can be a we study the set of vector x t does not have to be the regression variables. Generally, it instrumental variables. Consider a single equation in a simultaneous equations system: yt = +e z't (5) t where z includes other endogenous variables so that et t uses limit Zt in Hn place of x t in the definition of then the process , Now because the summands do not have zero mean. of instruments that is correlated with z consider the weak convergence of t will not call this t t . t is a vector Then we can . one If have a proper suppose x but independent of e We may (4). correlated with z is still process the instrumental- variable weighted sequential empirical process. Tests based on a instrumental- variable weighted process will have nontrivial local power only if X in the sense that plim(X'X/n) and p\\m(X'Z/n) have uncorrected with £t , where Z= a set of valid instruments full column rank and X is (z[,...,z'n )'. Stochastic Equicontinuity 3 To derive the stochastic equicontinuity for weighted sequential empirical processes, impose the following conditions (A.l) The random (A. 2) The disturbances (A. 3) The is is (their implications are discussed below). variables e t are e t are we with a continuous distribution function i.i.d. independent of F contemporaneous and past regressors. all regressors {x t } form a triangular array (for simplicity the dependence on n suppressed) and satisfy; plim- 22 x n where Q(s) is t x't = Q(s) € for s [0, 1], t=i a p x p nonrandom positive definite matrix for s The convergence is necessarily uniform in 6, because the sum is and Q(0) = "monotonic" in s. > 0. (A.4) max n -1 / 2 (A. 5) For every fixed Si, there exists a that, for all s > " = ||a: t " l<t<n || ojl). pv ' random variable < - Sl )Zn si, - E t=[nsi] \\*t\\ (s Zn (may depend on s\) such with probability one. In addition, the M< and There exist - J2 n > 7 1, a > \ and 1 >C)< M/C 2(1+p) K < . 00 such that for E(x't x t y <K{v-u) and where i = [nit], j = < all < u < v and 1, for n sumption (A. 3) allows for dynamic models, is tests, see, e.g., Ploberger, and (A. 6) are unique where i = Y?t=i for is = 2, s + T = and \F{z) — when The If E(x't x 2 t x't x t ) ) 2 < M < {J2i=i[ regressors x t are for all Hn left limits. vector process Hn is We Hn will = As- (3). g{t/n), for some Assumption (A. 4) Assumptions E ( . In (A. 5), tail set Zn may probability t, then (A. 6) is is be taken to also satisfied, Zn = O p (l) satisfied uni- = with 7 2 x t x t) 2 ] 1/2 } 2 by the Cauchy-Schwarz will be with metric p({r, y}, T satisfied. {5, z}) = \s — that are right equip D[T] with the Skorohod metric (Pollard belongs to the Cartesian product space D[T] P equipped , implied by the stochastic equicontinuity. limiting process of [18]. Let D[T] be the set of functions defined on F(y)\. space D[T] P form x t however, to choose with the corresponding product Skorohod topology. in the , model autoregressive bounded (A.4)-(A.6) x 1Z be the parameter continuous and have [19]). sj. because £(£t-« [0, 1] a our problem. They are the main assumptions for the x t\\ provided the condition on the inequality. Finally, Let e.g., used for obtaining normality. [nsi] is fixed. It is generally impossible, formly in both and a \\ u) i<t<j Kramer, and Kontrus equicontinuity of the sequential empirical process be max* k~ l < K{y - often maintained in recursive estimation for construct- conventional for linear models and (A. 5) 't for trending regressors written in the function g. This assumption CUSUM x x tV [nv]. Assumption (A. 2) allows ing £ E(- i<t<j r\ some p > satisfies, for n, all is Zn oo: P(\Zn (A. 6) probability of tail The finite The weak convergence of Hn dimensional convergence together with latter condition also implies the be continuous with probability one. sample path of the Theorem Under assumptions 1 stochastically equicontinuous on (T,p). 8 > (A. 5), That for any is > e 0, where [8] When = x = {{t1 ,t2 );t1 t = and Wichura 1 for all [9]. When sup \\Hn (r,y)-Hn (s,z)\\>T}) {r,y),r2 = the equicontinuity of t, < (s,z),p(tu t2 ) Hn > r\ Hn is there exists a 0, <t 8} with is [8] CT implied by the result of Bickel It data that requires a different framework of proof. a big obstacle for proving equicontinuity. is the statistical dependence Dependence m-dependent processes by Andrews around the for a difficulty. smoothed And there are [2]. many by Andrews [3], also see [16] for DeJong [12] for may be [5] and only work well Levental's for The [11] for Andrews It [1] unbounded is provided bounded strong mixing for a differences (for each fixed z). used. extended to unbounded absolutely quence. For the proposed weighted sequential empirical process of Levental [17] is unbounded mixingales. A review Andrews and Pollard unbounded martingale it successful results; examples are strong mixing processes, Doukhan, Massart and Rio Hansen data could be Recent development explores ways of getting class of functions of near-epoch variables, regular processes, and in Indeed, the powerful tool of symmetriza- depends heavily on the independence assumption, although tion x T. {(x t ,e t )} are independent, equicontinuity can also be proved by extending the method of Bickel and Wichura. are the process such that for large n, P[ in and (A. 6), (A. 2), (A.l), (4), the se- summands seems that the method conditions of Levental, however, are not primitive bounded martingales, though method may be extended to unbounded it is ones. noted by Hansen [16] that Hansen's own approach, as pointed out by the author himself, does not work well for indicator types of functions. We shall offer an elementary proof. Since our purpose of processes as possible, our conditions are specific structure of our process, we feel is and primitive. Given the concrete an elementary argument also interested in the limiting process. not to cover as wide a range is more instructive. We are The proof provided in the appendix. In the proof, we focus on the vector process is [«] Yn (s,u) = n-V^Xtim <u)-u} (6) t=\ where U\, U2, •••, we Effectively, Un are uniform on i.i.d. [0,1] replace e t by F(e t ) which Yn and Corollary Hn Gaussian process H for finite z)'} , Hn Hn (s,z) = converges weakly to a = Q(iy 1/2 Q(r A s)Q(l)-^[F(z Ay)- F(z)F(y)}. dimensional convergence to a normal distribution follows from To weakly to some process H. Yn t. Q(l), a positive definite ma- the process martingale differences. This together with Theorem value of < mean and covariance matrix with zero E{H(r, y)H{s, Proof. The -?-+ So that [0,1]. for j are equivalent in terms of stochastic equicontinuity. Under assumptions (A.1)-(A.6), 1 independent of Xj t uniform on is (X'Xln)- x l 2 Yn {s,F{z)). By assumption, (X'X/n) trix, so U with for r < s implies that Hn CLT converges verify the covariance matrix, consider the expected = and u 1 (7) F{z) < v = F(y). Using double expectation and martingale property, we obtain [nT] E{Yn (r,u)Y^s,v)} which tends to Q(r)(u We now tests for - uv). 1 = -E \ ( \Tx x'A t From (X'X/n)-' / 2 1 -^ - (u Q(l) _1 , uv) we introduce a Brownian bridge type process which parameter constancy arrive at (7). is Xk = Let in linear regressions. (8) closely related to (xi, ...,Xk)', X = (xi,x 2 ,...,x n )', and A k = [x'xy^ix'Mix'x)The matrix A[ns converges ] Q(s) = sQ matrix. for some to A(s) = 1 '2 Q(l)~ 1 ^ 2 Q(s)Q(l)~ 1 / 2 positive definite matrix Q, A(s) = si, (9) . . In the special case that where / is a p x p identity the assumptions of Corollary Corollary 2 Under Vn (s,z) = Hn (s,z) - A V converges weakly to a Gaussian process E{V(r,y)V(s,z)'} = {A(r As)- [ns] the process A(r)A(s)}{F(y A by Corollary (10) follows easily As noted s. F(y)F(z)}. Hn The (10) and the conver- limiting process of from = H(s,z)-A(s)H(l,z). (7). when Q(s) = sQ earlier, covariance matrix of is - 1, V(s,z) Now z) from that of follows ] is, defined as and covariance matrix zero gence of A[ ns to a deterministic matrix A(s) uniformly in Vn Vn Hn {l,z) mean with Vn Proof. The stochastic equicontinuity of 1, V becomes said to be a two-parameter (r for Q > some A(s) becomes si and the 0, As — rs){F(z Ay) — F(z)F(y)}I. A Brownian bridge on [0, l] 2 if it is process B(s, u) a zero-mean Gaussian process with covariance function EB(r, u)B(s, We see that V(s,z) has the same v) = (r A s — rs)(u A v — uv). distribution as B'(s,F(z)), where B* is a vector of p independent Brownian bridges. An 4 Application in Structural Change Consider the structural change model Ho ' = ft\ 02 with Hi unknown. example, Andrews process. by it = We yt — [4]. Define the p x Tn (-, z) = (X'X)- 1 ' 2 1 The There Here we construct a OLS estimate model (1) by x't /3. (2). is objective t I(i t to test the null hypothesis a rich literature on the problem, for test using or other vector process £x is an estimated sequential empirical methods and compute the residuals Tn , <z)- A k (X'X)-^ JT x 2 t I(i t <z) (11) and the test statistic M k where \\y\\<x> = max{|t/i|, ..., n 2 different values, so the M maximum n z maximum the \y p \}, ||Tn (-,z)||oo norm. The process value always exists. £x (X'X)- 1/2 - A k (X'X)- 1/2 t so that I(£ t < Therefore, . z) < can be replaced by I(£ t Tn is actual computation of £x t = for all k z) — F(z) without changing the value of centered (only approximately centered because of e ( ). Recognizing this, Tn takes at most t=i t=i Tn The Tn straightforward. If x t contains a constant regressor (we do assume this), then is n k - max sup n we see that Tn uses estimated residuals while Vn Using the result of Bai this paper, a root-n consistent estimator of /?, is Vn the same as F is not the d.f. defined in Corollary 2 except uses true disturbances. [7] shows that if the residuals are obtained from then Tn ^-,z)=>B*(s,F(z)) [ ( where B* = (Bi,B 2 ,.-.,Bp bridges defined on [0, l] 2 . is ) A n a vector of p independent two-parameter Brownian similar result is obtained by Bai weighted) sequential empirical processes based on [6] ARMA residuals. for By bounded (nonthe continuous mapping theorem, M n — max ||2?*(5,u)||oo- 0<s,u<l The test M [8]. It is interesting to realize that the limiting process T„ does not n is asymptotically distribution free. estimated parameters. The underlying reason The estimation terms. This is effects are that the process canceled out in the first in contrast with the classical goodness-of-fit test does not go away, see Durbin As is Critical values are tabulated in Bai [13] for the limiting distribution and Tn depend on the consists of two term and the second term. where the estimation effect [14]. under tion in a simultaneous equations system. local alternatives, we consider a The model under the 10 single equa- null hypothesis is given by Suppose the alternative hypothesis postulates that (5). = z' pt + e yt where f3 t = (3[l + t A^g(t/n)] with g a vector-valued function defined on Riemann-Stieltjes integrable. Suppose x t assume plicity, in (A. 3) sQxz, a p x r matrix. Mn where p(u) if if g column rank. M n will hypotheses. test is [8] 0<5,U<1 and G(s) 0. Also assume plim^- J2™{ x t z = 2 + p(u)Q^ Q xz G(s)\\ 00 J* g(v)dv - Note that G(s) sftg{v)dv. a constant vector, implying no change in local power = 't shows that -±+ max \\B*(s,u) have non-trivial test to that Then Bai and [0, 1] a vector of instrumental variables. For sim- is = sQ xx for some Q xx > Q(s) = /(F -1 ^)) and only (12) t non-constant for "all" g's, t = In order for the . must have a Q xz Q xz G(s) e Otherwise, there exists a non-zero G(s) such that full so have the same limiting distribution under both the null and alternative In summary, when valid instruments are available, changes in a simultaneous equations system and M n can be used to M n possesses non-trivial local power. Regressors themselves constitute valid instruments when they are independent of error disturbances. The same test can also detect changes in the following type: Vt with e* having a continuous t > ni. Bai [8] argues that even variance, as long as and Wald tests may F^ fail G, F d.f. if it is = for t x't P < + rii e't and a* having a continuous the two distributions have the same detectable by Mn , G for mean and same whereas the fluctuation, to diagnose this kind of shift. 11 d.f. CUSUM A Appendix Lemma A.l Assume such that for all Si < the conditions of and s2 u\ — Si < a > - Ul ) {s 2 Ul ) , a s,, u, +r 7l ,u 1 )|| = < < oo, 1,2) 2 'Y + n-^-^K(u 2 - Sl ) K Ul )(s 2 - 7, since \u 2 si). — < Ui\ and 1 Moreover, when 1. 0, lemma the This inequality Proof. Write ,ui) and j 1 (z there exists a I U2 _ Ul rn -(-y-D/2(Q -i)< and = is r\ t t- 2 1*-V](u 3 I(ui + Yn (si,ui) < U < t for the u2) is t gale differences, where Tt is - u2 + = Q Sl ) (14) . 198). = Yn (s 2 ,u 2 - Yn (si,u 2 ) n~ x l 2 Y^i<t<i^tT}t ) with i = [ns\] a sequence of (nonstationary) vector martin- the u-field generated by inequality of Rosenthal (Hall and - ([10], p. and Y* ui moment. Then Y* Note that {x t T} ^t) [ns 2 ]. (13) + Yn (s uUl )\\^ a Ul ) (s 2 - analogous to (22.15) of Billingsley = _ Si S2 implies < K[\ + 2 < ( Sl E\\Yn (s 2 ,u 2 )-Yn (s 1 ,u 2 )-Yn (s 2 ,u 1 ) Yn (s Then 1 hold. one can assume that a loss of generality, Tn -(7-i)/2M)< for r < where , ) < K(u 2 - I-52 u2 - Yn (s u u 2 - Yn (s 2 E\\Yn (s 2 ,u 2 ) Without the < Theorem Heyde [15] p. ...,x t ,x t+ \] ...,Ut -i : U t 23), there exists a constant . By the M < 00 only depending on 7 and p such that e\\y:\F =EI ( U£ xtnt]' <ME[-J2 n \ Note that x t addition, Erft is £ x hVh ) ) ^{(zJxO^t-i}) +Mn~T i<t<j j measurable with respect to Tt-\ and <u — u\ 2 and En^ < u2 — U\. 12 These £ E{(x't x t r^}. (15) i<t<j r\t is independent of Tt-\. results together In with assumption The (A. 6) provide bounds for the two terms on the right of (15). term first bounded is by M(u 2 and the second term yE is bounded by I- T Mn-^- x \u 2 - ux)- A. 2 Under \\Yn (s,u) (x't x t < MK(u 2 - ) ) <MKn~ E{x'x t V MK as K, the lemma follows from (u Renaming Lemma £ Ui - < J;(«i,ui)|| where the term we have for (A. 5), O p (l) \\Yn (s 2 ,u 2 ) uniform is rn - < s\ > in s (s < s ( Sl , 2 — s2 ' ( 1 - x) ui) 7 {u 2 < -u (u 2 — a - Ul y(s 2 Sl )(s 2 l Ui) ) -s a , and u\ < u < u 2 l ). for > 7 a. , Ul )|| + O p (l)n 1/2 [(u 2 - u x ) + Si), does not depend on u and u\ and - (s 2 Sl )] satisfies P(\0 P (1)\ > C) < Proof. First notice that Otherwise write x t and x^(i) = = (0, ..0, M/C 2(1+p) of the all VC>0, , = (0, ..0,i t ,-,0, ...,0)' —x Yn can be written as a linear tt , 0, ..., 1 0)' if < x (1 t xtI(U < u) < a, 6, for all Yn (s,u) -Tn (5 1 1 A new < \\x t [ns] / +n 1/2 (-E^)("2-u) + n is -Yn (s ) 1 /2 and \\ and xj{i). ||x t It is (0ll — x ll *ll- 1 - t > 0, easy to show 1 ,ui) [nsj] ^ x {I(U t t 1 ( Sl , Ul )-Yn (s,u)<nV 2 / ["«] (-J2xt)(u-Ui) + n 1/2 13 1 - <u )-u 2 } 2 M £ So 6, the vector functions and Yn > thus enough to piece of notation, for vectors a and in u. It < Yn (s 2 ,u 2 ,ui) ||x*(i)|| components. Since x and x t u are nondecreasing \lx t i most 2p processes with each process having satisfied for xf{i) assume that the x are nonnegative. mean In this way, 0. or -1) of at assumptions (A. 5) and (A. 6) are b to 0. components of x t can be assumed to be nonnegative. nonnegative weighting vectors. In addition, < > Y%=i x t(i)~ Ef=i x 7(i) where xf(i) combination (with coefficients take a for some p x / {7(f/t < u) - Ul } The lemma follows from the boundedness of the indicator function Proof of Theorem We 1. shall evaluate directly the u 5 (Yn ) = sup{\\Yn (s',u')-Yn (s",u")\\; \s'-s"\ We show that shall any for > e and > rj 0, < modulus \u'-u"\ 8, < there exist a 8 and (A. 5). of continuity. Define 8,s',s",u',u" > € [0, 1]}. and an integer n , such that P{u s (Yn ) > Since [0, l] < e) n > n 77, 2 has only about 8~ squares with side length 2 every point (si, Ui) £ [0, l] 2 every , e > and > 77 0, . 8, it suffices to show that for there exist a 8 £ (0,1) and an integer no such that <28 2 P(sup\\Yn (s,u)-Yn (s 1 ,u 1 )\\ >5e) n > n r), (16) . (6) where (8) = {(s, u); Si For a given 8 > < < s and > 77 + Si 0, 8, ux < u < choose C U\ large + 8} 2 f] [0, l] . O p {\) enough so the in Lemma A. satisfies P(|O p (l)| > C) < By Lemma A.2 -yn (-si,^i)|| < = e/(n^ 2 C) and m= X(iJ) = max 3 ||y„(.si l<i,]<m (S) en (17) (see also (22.18) of Billingsley [10], p. 199), sup||rn (5,ii) where 8\ [n^ 2 C8/e] Yn (si + 1. +ie n ,u 1 + +ie n ,ui + when |O p (l)| < C, - jc n ) 3^(si,ui) : || + 2e Write je n ) -Yn (si,Ui). Then P(sup ||yB ( a ,«)-yB ( ai ,u 1 )|| > 5e) < P(|Op (l)| > C)+P( max l<i,j<m (5) Now for fixed i and k (i > k) write Z(j) = X(i,j) (e/C)n-W( a -V < el{Cn" 2 = ) 14 — en \\X(iJ)\\ X(k,j). Notice that < jen , j > 1, > e). (18) < n -i/2 which follows from n -(T-i)/2(«-i) E\\Z(j) - 2 Z(/)|| ^ = where, from (14) with r C = e Thus by Theorem P( max where K\ let ^% - l)e n } a 1 , 2(Q ' 1) - < / for small < (14), m < j Ki = 2 a (19) e. we have ^[(i - k)t n }°8° < k)e n }°(me n )° K\K. The (20) last inequality follows from <max\\X(i,j)-X(kJ)\\=max\\ZU)l is then (20) implies k)t n 12.2 of Billingsley once again sum 5, of random > \V(i)\ e) variables £;, a ] 6 [let l<k<i<m. a , £h = V(h) — V(h — 1), so that we obtain in Billingsley's notation], S^me,)"^ < ^*> < ~ 6 ' (_ a generic constant and K$ = 2°K[K2- Note that max, \V(i)\ =max, maxj \\X(i, j] (18) P(sup (19), the - Yn {s \\Yn (s,u) By Lemma 1 ,u 1 > )\\ be) < 8\ + second term on the right hand side above ^1 hand 2(C/e) >e)< ^^[(i - V{k)\ l<t<m By < ] ||X(t,y)||, P( max Thus by 2(a - l) (Clt) - max \\X(k, j] — maxj V(i) the partial where K[ - [(j and : Thus by Theorem is a } (13) Because for large n. P(\V(i) V(i) k)t n By 7. e/C, >e)< \\Z(j)\\ 1 we - e [{i <a < 1 12.2 of Billingsley ([10], p. 94), max||X(z,;)|| if KC a generic constant and is (me n ) < 28 + [1 < because 2 S ° C = A. 2, one can choose side (21) becomes K(e, choose 8 such that K(e, r))8 a T])8 < a r), < , 8 2 is K'zCt z 2 -Ar~L 6 bounded by ™\A C8f^\ ' (M/t)) 2 ( 1+p > where K(e, (16) follows. D 15 77) is (21) 8~^ t+p' to assure (17) a constant and a The proof of the and the = 2 ^~ theorem is 1 > p > 0. left By completed. References [1] An Andrews, D.W.K. empirical process central limit theorem for dependent non-identically distributed random variables. Journal of Multivariate Analysis 38 (1991): 187-203. [2] Andrews, D.W.K. Empirical process methods of Econometrics, Vol [3] Andrews, D.W.K. cess theory for An 4. in econometrics. In Amsterdam: North-Holland, The Handbook 1993. introduction to econometric applications of empirical pro- dependent random random variables. Econometric Reviews 12 (1993): 183-216. [4] Andrews, D.W.K. Tests unknown change [5] for parameter instability and structural change with point. Econometrica 61 (1993): 821-856. Andrews, D.W.K. and D. Pollard. A functional central limit theorem for strong mixing stochastic processes. Cowles foundation Discussion Paper No. 951, Cowles Foundation, Yale University, 1990. [6] Weak Bai, J. Forthcoming [7] Bai, J. On convergence of sequential empirical processes of in the ARMA residuals. Annals of Statistics, 1991. weighted sequential empirical process of regression residuals. Manuscript, Department of Economics, MIT, 1993. [8] Bai, J. Testing for parameter constancy in linear regressions: an empirical distri- bution function approach. Manuscript, Department of Economics, MIT, 1993. [9] Bickel, P.J. cesses and M.J. Wichura. Convergence for multiparameter stochastic pro- and some applications. Annals of Mathematical Statistics 42 (1971): 1656- 1670. [10] Billingsley, P. Convergence of Probability Measures. 16 New York: Wiley, 1968. [11] DeJong, R.M. Stochastic equicontinuity Amsterdam, University, [12] Doukhan, for unbounded mixing processes. Free 1993. Massart and E.Rio. Invariance principles for absolutely regular P., P. empirical processes. University de Paris, 1992. [13] Durbin, J. Weak convergence of the sample distribution function when parameters are estimated. Annals of Statistics [14] Durbin, J. Kolmogorov-Smirnov ical Distributions (1973): 279-290. 1 tests when parameters are estimated. In Empir- and Processes, Springer- Verlad Lecture Notes in Mathematics, 1976. [15] Hall, P. and C.C. Heyde. Martingale Limit Theory and Its Application. New York: Academic Press, 1980. [16] Hansen, B.E. Stochastic Equicontinuity for Unbounded Dependent Heteroge- neous Arrays. Manuscript, Department of Economics, University of Rochester, 1993. [17] Levental, S. A uniform CLT for uniformly bounded families of martingale differ- ences. Journal of Theoretical Probability 2 (1988): 271-287. [18] Ploberger, W., W. Kramer, and in the linear regression [19] K. Kontrus. A new test for structural stability model. Journal of Econometrics 40 (1988): 307-318. Pollard, D. Convergence of Stochastic Processes. 1984. 17 New York: Springer- Verlag, O o 0Z40 032 ") / MIT LIBRARIES 3 TDfiO D0flSh22T ?