MIT LIBRARIES DUPL -. DEWEY j' 3 9080 03317 9042 Massachusetts Institute of Technology Department of Economics Working Paper Series Policy with Dispersed Information George-Marios Angeletos Alessandro Pavan Working Paper 07-27 October 30, 2007 RoomE52-251 50 Memorial Drive 02142 Cambridge, MA This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network Paper Collection http://ssm.com/abstractM 026 101 HB31 .M415 at Policy with Dispersed Information* Alessandro Pavan George-Marios Angeletos MIT and NBER Northwestern University October 26, 2007 Abstract This paper studies policy relevant fundamentals —such in a class of economies as aggregate productivity and can not be centralized by the government. information can fail in which information about commonly- and demand conditions — dispersed is In these economies, the decentralized use of to be efficient either because of discrepancies between private and social payoffs, or because of informational externalities. In the first case, inefficiency manifests itself in excessive non-fundamental volatility (overreaction to common noise) or excessive cross-sectional dispersion (overreaction to idiosyncratic noise). In the second case, inefficiency manifests in suboptimal social learning (low quality of information contained financial prices, is identified: and other indicators of economic in activity). In either case, itself macroeconomic data, a novel role for policy the government can improve welfare by manipulating the incentives agents face when deciding how to use their available sources of information. Our key result is that this can be achieved by appropriately designing the contingency of marginal taxes on aggregate activity. This contingency permits the government to control the reaction of equilibrium to different types of noise, to improve the quality of information in prices and macro data, and, in overall, to restore efficiency in the decentralized use of information. JEL codes: C72, D62, D82. Keywords: Optimal policy, private information, complementarities, information externalities, social learning, efficiency. 'For comments and useful suggestions, we thank Olivier Blanchard, William Fuchs, Jr., Ken Judd, Robert E. Lucas, Robert Shimer, Nancy Stokey, Jean Tirole, Nikola Tarashev, Harald Uhlig, Xavier Vives, Ivan Werning, and seminar participants at Chicago, MIT, Toulouse, the 2007 IESE Conference on Complementarities and Information and the 3rd CSEF-IGIER Symposium on Economics and Institutions. We are very grateful to NSF for financial support. Pavan also thanks the Department of Economics of the University of Chicago for hospitality during the last stages of the project. Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium Member Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/policywithdisperOOange "The peculiar character of plete problem of a rational economic order and frequently contradictory knowledge which not given to anyone in 1 Introduction The dispersion of information determined pre- but solely as the dispersed bits of incom- form exists in concentrated or integrated The economic problem of society is is knowledge of the circumstances of which we must make use cisely by the fact that the never the is ... its totality. is " all the separate individuals possess. a problem of the utilization of knowledge which (Friedreich A. Hayek, 1945) an essential part of the economic problem faced by society. This concerns not only the idiosyncratic needs and means of different households and firms, but also commonly-relevant fundamentals. aggregate productivity and and pricing For example, think of the business cycle. demand conditions decisions. Yet, such information is is crucial for individual consumption, production, widely dispersed and it is through markets, the media, or other channels of communication in As emphasized by Hayek (1945), such information can not such as the government. Instead, society the utilization of such information. One can then be stitution, their available information in the what best may must rely only imperfectly aggregated society. be centralized within a single in- on decentralized mechanisms for assured that rational agents will always use privately-efficient way. This, however, need not coincide with serves social interests. For example, complementarities in investment or pricing decisions induce firms to overreact to public information, because public information helps forecast the decisions of others; this can of most Information about common crowd out valuable private information and can noise, resulting in higher to internalize how their own non-fundamental volatility. also amplify the Furthermore, individuals impact may fail choices affect the information contained in financial prices or other indicators of aggregate activity; this can lead to inefficient social learning about the underlying economic fundamentals. A novel role for policy then emerges: even if the government cannot centralize the information dispersed in society and can not otherwise collect and communicate information, there that is may exist policies that improve efficiency in the decentralized use of information manipulating the incentives faced by individual agents. Identifying such policies of this paper. Our key result is to show how efficiency contingency of marginal taxes on realized aggregate Preview. Rather than focusing on a policy lesson. We is by appropriately is the objective achieved by appropriately designing the activity. specific application, we seek to highlight a more general thus conduct our analysis within an abstract, but tractable, class of games that allow for two sources of inefficiency in the decentralized use of information: payoff externalities and informational externalities. The former are short-cuts for a variety of strategic and other exter- nal effects featured in applications, such as those originating in production spillovers, investment . or pricing complementarities, monopoly power, social networking, potential discrepancies between private and social payoffs. The and the like; they summarize latter reflect the (imperfect) aggre- gation of information obtained through financial prices, the publication of data on macroeconomic activity, or other Our forms of social learning. analysis then proceeds in two steps. First, we compare the equilibrium in the absence of policy intervention with the allocation that maximizes welfare subject to the sole constraint that information can not be directly transferred from one agent to another; this helps detect the potential inefficiencies in the decentralized use of information. Next, implement the an equilibrium; efficient strategy as The symptoms of inefficiency that we detect this gives the we identify tax schemes that key policy result of the paper. by comparing the equilibrium strategy with the aforementioned socially optimal strategy depend on whether the inefficiency originates in payoff or informational externalities. fundamental In the volatility (overreaction to reaction to idiosyncratic noise). social learning (too much first case, common inefficiency manifests itself in excessive non- noise) or excessive cross-sectional dispersion (over- In the second case, inefficiency manifests itself in suboptimal noise in macroeconomic indicators, financial prices, or other channels of information aggregation) Yet, the same,policy prescription works for either case, as well as for economies that combine the two sources of inefficiency. Our key result is that the government can control how agents use different sources of information in equilibrium by making the marginal tax rate contingent on aggregate An activity. appropriate design of the tax system then restores efficiency in the decentralized use of information, irrespective of the specific source of inefficiency. The logic behind this result with realized aggregate activity, is simple. When individuals expect marginal taxes to decrease they also expect the realized net-of-taxes return on their own activity to increase with aggregate activity. It follows that a negative dependence of marginal taxes on aggregate activity imputes strategic complementarity in individual choices: agents have an incentive to align their choices with those of others. Symmetrically, a positive dependence imputes strategic substitutability: agents have an incentive to differentiate their choices. of individual decisions obtains when agents rely more on sources of information, whereas more differentiation obtains when agents rely more on Next note that a better alignment common idiosyncratic sources of information. It follows that the government can use the contingency of marginal taxes on aggregate activity to fashion how agents respond to different sources of mation. In particular, when marginal infor- taxes decrease with aggregate activity, by inducing strategic com- complementarity the policy also induces higher relative sensitivity of equilibrium actions to mon taxes increase with aggregate activity, by inducing information. Symmetrically, when marginal strategic substitutability the policy also induces higher relative sensitivity to idiosyncratic infor- mation. It follows that, how control by appropriately designing the aforementioned contingency, the government can agents use their available information. In so doing, the government can control, not only the impact of noise on equilibrium activity, but also the quality of information contained in prices and macroeconomic data. The government can thereby improve welfare even without centralizing or communicating information to the market. Discussion. It is cient fluctuations in who argued (1936), often argued that financial markets overreact to public news, causing both asset prices and real investment. tuations in asset prices and investment. broader theme that markets any ineffi- This idea goes back at least to Keynes that professional investors, instead of focusing on the long-run fundamental value of the assets, try to second-guess the tion to itself may 1 demands of one another, thus causing inefficient fluc- In this paper, although we are partly motivated react inefficiently to available information, specific application, nor do we examine the deeper we do not by the limit atten- origins of such inefficiency (which, unavoidably, will be specific to the application of interest). Rather, our goal is to identify policy remedies that need not be sensitive to the details of the origin of the inefficiency. This explains our choice to work with a theoretical framework that is abstract and flexible enough to allow for a variety of distortions in the decentralized use of information. Our analysis also takes as exogenous the limits society faces in aggregating dispersed informa- tion. Investigating the institutional design, offers some relevant is foundations for these limits, and their potential implications for policy and a challenging topic beyond the scope of this paper. Nevertheless, our analysis insights. In our class of economies, equilibrium welfare may decrease with addi- tional information because of possible inefficiencies in the equilibrium use of information. However, once these inefficiencies have been removed, more information can only improve welfare. Therefore, policies that provide the complement market with the right incentives for policies, or other institutions, that provide the how to use available information also market with more information. Furthermore, while our analysis focuses on how the contingency of taxes on aggregate activity contingency of monetary policy can improve the decentralized use of information, in practice, the on aggregate activity might direction. Indeed, the comes out of our analysis also help in the how is same more general insight that the anticipation of such contingencies affects the incentives agents face in using their available information, Methodological remarks. The between two dominant paradigms: and how this in turn affects efficiency. policy exercise conducted in this paper strikes a balance the Ramsey tradition to optimal policy (e.g., Barro, 1979, Lucas and Stokey, 1983, Chari, Christiano and Kehoe, 1994); and the Mirrlees tradition, or the "new public finance" paradigm We x deviate from the Ramsey This point was epitomized in (e.g., Kocherlakota, 2005; Golosov, Tsyvinski and Werning, 2006). tradition by introducing heterogeneous information and by avoiding Keynes' famous beauty-contest metaphor for financial markets, which highlighted the potential role of higher-order expectations. Elements of this role have recently been formalized in Allen, Morris and Shin (2003), Bacchetta and Wincoop (2005), and Angeletos, Lorenzoni and Pavan (2007). ad hoc restrictions on the set of available policy instruments. In this respect, our policy exercise closer to the is tradition new public finance literature. At the same time, we deviate from the Mirrlees by abstracting from redistributive taxation policies that correct inefficiencies in the response of equilibrium this respect, our policy exercise is closer to the and focusing instead on (or social insurance) Ramsey outcomes to aggregate shocks. In tradition. Furthermore, the Mirrlees literature studies environments in which agents have private infor- mation regarding purely idiosyncratic shocks, such as an agent's own whenever aggregate shocks are featured ductivity; shocks is tastes, talent, or labor pro- information regarding these in this literature, assumed to be common. In contrast, we study environments in which agents have dis- persed information regarding aggregate shocks; these shocks could be about either the underlying fundamentals or the distribution of information in absence of common knowledge The key difference then is that the regarding these shocks generates strategic uncertainty: agents face uncertainty regarding aggregate activity. of taxes society. on aggregate activity essential It is precisely this uncertainty that makes the contingency for restoring efficiency —which also explains why the results presented here are, to the best of our knowledge, completely novel to the policy literature. Finally, note that the policies make agents we identify resemble Pigou-like taxes in the sense that they internalize externalities. However, they are different with regard to the underlying distortion and the way they both the nature of restore efficiency. In standard Pigou-like contexts, the market produces/consumes too much or too of a certain commodity. little The Pigou remedy is then to impose a tax or subsidy on this commodity. In our context, instead, the market reacts too much or too little The analogue to certain sources of information. of the Pigou remedy would then consist in imposing a tax or subsidy directly on the use of these sources of information. However, this seems practically impossible. Our contribution indirectly is to show how the same goal can be achieved by appropriately designing the contingency of taxes on aggregate Other related literature. The activity. literature that studies dispersed information in macroeco- nomic contexts goes back to Phelps (1970), Lucas (1972), Townsend (1983), and the rational- More expectations revolution of the 70's and early 80's. Woodford recently, Mankiw and Reis (2000) and (2001) have raised interest on the business cycle implications of combining information heterogeneity with strategic complementarity in pricing decisions. 2 work by studying policy Another line of in We complement this line of environments that share this key combination. work, following Morris and Shin (2002), has examined whether welfare increases with more precise public information within specific models. 3 Some of these papers have found a negative result, which has then been used to have found the opposite 2 3 See also See also Cornand result. make a case against central-bank transparency; others In Angeletos and Pavan (2007) we showed how these apparently Amato and Shin (2006), Hellwig (2005), Lorenzoni (2006), and Mackowiak and Wiederholt (2006). Amador and Weil (2007), Angeletos and Pavan (2004), Baeriswyl and Conrand (2007), Heinemann and (2006), Hellwig (2005), Roca (2006), and Svensson (2005). conflicting results can rium use be explained by understanding the underlying For that purpose, of information. we considered an inefficiencies in the equilib- abstract framework that restricted information to be exogenous but was flexible enough to nest most of the applications examined in the literature; we then used framework this to study the social value of information (i.e., comparative statics of equilibrium welfare with respect to the information structure). In the part of the present paper, how to study we use a priately designed tax system. In the second part of the paper, which information in first generalized version of that framework for a different purpose: efficiency in the decentralized use of information environments the partially endogenous; is can be restored through an appro- we extend the analysis to we then show how dynamic similar policies also correct inefficiencies that originate from informational externalities. In this last respect, our analysis complements that in Vives (1993, 1997) and Amador and Weill (2007). These papers study the speed of social learning and the social value of information in a dynamic economy where agents learn from noisy observations of past aggregate activity. results identify policies that can control the speed of social learning exogenous information Layout. Section is also guarantee that any socially valuable. 2 introduces the baseline framework. Section 3 studies decentralized use of information due to payoff externalities. remove such and Our inefficiencies. inefficiencies in the Section 4 identifies tax systems that Section 5 extends the analysis to dynamic settings and Section 6 to settings with informational externalities. Section 7 discusses implications for the social value of information. Section 8 concludes. All proofs are in the Appendix. 2 The baseline static framework we In this section any details of outline our baseline framework: specific application but is flexible a game that abstracts from the institutional enough to capture the role of strategic interactions, external payoff effects, and dispersed information in a variety of applications. Actions and payoffs. The economy indexed by £ i imposes a tax Let tp T{ K on each agent and the dispersion £ E. In addition, there let K = f hdip(k) and Ok of individual actions. U M2 : x M+ x G — > R. The = = [J (k The — K) 2 dtp(k)] 1 The (reduced-form) a government, which is balanced. ' 2 denote, respectively, the payoff of agent i is variable 9{ C R £ fcj external and strategic effects exhibited in (1) represents a shock to agent as "investment" U may mean given by U(ki,K,ak ,8i) -n, For concreteness, in what follows we often think of shock." is subject to the constraint that the budget i, Ui some ki denote the cumulative distribution function of individual actions in the cross-section of the population and for populated by a continuum of agents of measure one, each choosing an action [0,1], £ is and 64 i's payoff. as a "productivity originate, not only from preferences and technologies, but and the social networks, specification from pecuniary externalities, monopoly power, oligopolistic competition, also What like. is we payoffs in transfers, postponed to Section is nomial and that the external f° r an (k, K, 4 decision problem; effect of dispersion we assume the — Ukn/Ukk < which imposes concavity be public at that stage. is less and Next, oji let how 6 given by h 6 F 0, and the which imposes concavity at the individual's + 2UkK + Ukk < are three stages. In stage 2, and Ukk + Uaa < 0, 1, the government announces a agents simultaneously choose their actions under dispersed is actions and aggregate productivity are publicly 3, and the game ends. 7 e as follows. Let W; (f> e $, respectively. of (0,u>) in the cross-section of the population; Q denote the information (also the "type") of The we set of possible distributions 8 / as the "state of the world." refer to F according to the probability measure common knowledge among the agents. Nature then uses / to i, with the pairs drawn independently from [6i,Ui)i£[o,i] but does not observe either own Q{ for 9i distribution / describes the joint distribution is only about the agent's Ua {k, K, o^-, 0) — denote a joint distribution for (#j,w;), with marginal distributions H and Nature draws / from a level (i.e., taxes will be collected in stage 3 as a function of information that In stage structure f £ < than one; and Ukk revealed, taxes are paid, payoffs are realized, i. own a concave quadratic poly- existence and uniqueness of both the equilibrium information (described below). Finally, in stage agent is 5 at the planner's problem. that specifies The information its U which ensures that the slope of the individual's best response Timing and information. There will we assume that depends only on following: Ukk 1> with respect to aggregate activity T Finally note that, by assuming linearity of 6. tractability, To guarantee 5)). crfc, efficient allocation, policy rule that payoffs can be reduced to the are ruling out any redistributive (or insurance) role for taxation. Payoff restrictions. To maintain (Tk- is assumed above without missing any channels of endogenous information aggregation; the analysis of the latter Uaa though, crucial, /. draw a Each agent First, T which pair (9i,Ui) for each agent i then observes his own u>j, or the distribution /. Note, though, that w, encodes information, not productivity #j, but also about the distribution / of productivities and information in the population. Although most of the analysis does not require any 4 The external effect of dispersion is restriction on the information structure, relevant for certain applications: in new-keynesian models, e.g., dispersion in relative prices has a negative welfare effect. 5 Although the intervention, our restriction —Uki</Ukk < main policy 1 is necessary for the equilibrium to be unique in the absence of government result does not rely on this restriction: the policies identified in Section 4 implement the efficient allocation as the unique equilibrium even in economies that feature multiple equilibria in the absence of policy intervention. 6 Because the government has no private information, the announcement of about the fundamentals; 7 its only role is T does not convey any information to affect the agents' incentives. Throughout, we do not require idiosyncratic productivities to be revealed at stage 3. Also, in Section 4.3 consider an extension that adds noise to the observation of actions and aggregate productivity at stage s This is with a slight abuse of terminology because / does not describe the specific (8i,uJi) for we 3. each single agent. we find it impose a certain "regularity" condition. Fix an information structure (Cl,F,F) useful to U and consider any two payoff structures, economy £ for the S — 2 (U 2 ;Cl,F,!F). such that k We ; S7, i^ JF) , and k 2 1 A; . UkK /Ukk ^ U K /Ukk or w 6 we be an equilibrium strategy * equilibrium strategy for the economy F, (Cl, F) The role of this condition 9 is to rule out trivial cases in and variance a 2,; the jjlq i's productivity latter with zero mean and variance a terms of has a simple it for a positive which changes measure of do not in incentives given by is 9i — 9+Q, where 9 is an aggregate productivity . Normally distributed with mean and independent across agents is i.i.d. 2 is Each agent's information u>{ Normally distributed of 9, consists of a private signal Xi — #i about own productivity and a public signal y = 9+e The across agents, Normally distributed with zero variable idiosyncratic noise, is £j i.i.d. and variance a 2 whereas the variable e , variance a 2 . example, / The is <f> over and £; example is cjj = + a 2 As a2 9 and variance in this noises . e are independent of one another as well as of 9 will 9i is Normal with mean measure one to y (xi,y) assigns it about the average productivity become = 9+e = Aiki — ^k 2 , with Ai — 9i 4- mean and K= aK, / kidi, 9i = In this of q. and variance ae2 and Normal 2 a ,, a 2 and a 2 Applications. The following examples are directly nested • Ui is and mean in Xi with mean imposing the "regularity" condition clear in Section 3, equivalent to imposing that the variances and 9 + £j in the market. public noise, Normally distributed with zero is a distribution whose marginal h over whose marginal CI 9 an idiosyncratic productivity shock. The former is C CI type of shocks and information structures that we allow, consider the following Gaussian example. Agent shock while if, requires that different sensitivities of individual best responses to either the it illustrate the However characterize the equilibrium. lead to any change in the use of information. To and only if fully appreciated (in fundamentals or others' activity result to different equilibrium actions types. "regular" is there exists a positive-measure set , This restriction can be fi. primitives of the environment) only once — R Cl : > : 2 k (u) for any economic meaning: U 2 Let Cl — R an and say that the information structure 2 7^ (u)) (C/ 1 1 ^ Uke /Ukk whenever Ul e /Ukk l = l x 9 in + are positive and finite. our framework: ?;, < and a < This example 1. can be interpreted as a stylized version of models with production or network externalities: the private return to investment (A) increases with aggregate investment (K) then parametrizes the strength of the spillover and q • 7T- = is 7T* effect, while 9 is a common . The productivity shock an idiosyncratic productivity shock. - ^ - p*) 2 , with p* = a9 + (1 - a) P, P = J prfi, a G (0, 1), and tt* G R. This example captures the incomplete-information new-Keynesian business-cycle models ford (2002), Mackowiak and Wiederholt (2006), Baeriswyl firms suffer a loss whenever their price (pi) deviates from 9 As it will scalar a become clear in Sections 3 uniqueness of the optimal policy (not its and 4, the only result that existence). is and Conrand some (2007), of and Woodothers: target level (p*), which in turn affected if we relax this condition is the depends on the aggregate price level (P). nominal demand conditions, while in pricing decisions (a.k.a. • = TTi {a + with K = / kidi, and Cournot and Bertrand games studied 10 papers. In • (for m = - (1 — r) (ki This example is — 6) - — r{Li (for and Heinemann and Cornand This game is and among in Raith (1996), and various other or cost shock, More is the quantity (for 2 L = J Lidi, and dj, ki) r G (0, 1). Morris and Shin (2002), Svensson (2005) (2006): an agent faces a cost whenever the distance of his own higher than the average distance in the population is supposed to capture, in a stylized fashion, Keynes' idea that financial who for will second-guess the of others. generally, as equilibrium fcj. firms' decisions. markets involve a zero-sum race between professional investors demands This example nests the large . c the degree of strategic substitutability = J (kj — game studied action from the actions of others (Li) (L). i, Bertrand) L), with Li the beauty-contest R3 e common demand Bertrand) set by firm Cournot) or complementarity (a, b, c) in Vives (1984, 1998), this context, 9i represents a Cournot) or the price (for a determines the degree of strategic complementarity "real rigidities"). + cK) ki - \kf, bOi — 1 In this context, 8 represents exogenous aggregate it concerned will become —any model clear in Section 3.2, our framework nests —at least as far as in which the agents' interaction can be summarized ki =E in the following best-response structure: some for i [A(9i ,e,K)] linear function A. Clearly, the institutional details this structure and deeper micro-foundations behind vary from one application to another. Nevertheless, by conducting our exercise within an abstract framework that does not take any particular stand on these will provide in the subsequent sections are likely to hold across Remarks. Because the primary goal of this paper without centralizing the information that we restrict attention to tax so doing, we rule out direct systems that mechanisms government and then the government in Section 4, this is is we these applications. to study policies that improve welfare is dispersed in the population, throughout the analysis utilize in all "details," the lessons only information that is in the public domain. In which the agents send reports about their types to the collects taxes on the basis of such reports. As we will show actually without any loss of optimality within our framework as long as the government does not use such reports to transfer information from one agent to another before individual actions have been committed. Note, however, that this does not information in society; Indeed, we could it mean that we rule out only means that the government readily reinterpret some of the is forms of aggregation and exchange of not itself a channel of communication. exogenous information as the result of certain types of information aggregation; for example, some or 8 all all of the agents may observe a signal about the underlying fundamentals that financial market. What is crucial for the baseline analysis is given agent does not depend on other agents' strategies, nor these alternative cases are considered in Sections 6 and Finally, note that, while our prior 2007) and virtually all work on the and to a allow the shocks to be imperfectly correlated and will that the information available to any is it affected by government social value of information (Angeletos specific we policies; 7. the related literature (Morris and Shin, 2002, to the case of perfectly correlated shocks This unmodeled the outcome of an opinion poll or the price of an is etc.) and Pavan, have limited attention Gaussian information structure, here we consider more general information structures. permit us to highlight that our main policy results need not be sensitive to the specific details of the information structure. Gaussian example considered above, while = correlated (of we Nevertheless, will still illustrate certain insights in the restricting, for simplicity, the shocks to be perfectly 0). Decentralized use of information 3 In this section we show how the equilibrium and the efficient use of information depend on the payoff structure U. This permits us to identify inefficiencies in the equilibrium use of information that originate from payoff effects. Common-information benchmarks 3.1 we proceed Before to the analysis of equilibrium useful to review the case of common and efficiency with dispersed information, it is information; this will help isolate the inefficiencies that emerge only under dispersed information. To start, suppose that information were complete, so that each agent knows both his own productivity and the cross-sectional distribution h of productivities in the population, and this fact is common exists, is knowledge. unique, and is We can then show that the complete-information equilibrium strategy given by fcj where 9 = J9dh(8) own The in = Ko + KiOi + K2O, , 10 Note that, by definition, an agent's payoff depends only on productivity; that an agent's equilibrium action depends also on average productivity characterization of the coefficients (ko, allocation, which K (0i,6) denotes aggregate productivity and where the coefficients (kq ki,K2) are determined by the payoff structure. his = is in the proof of Proposition 1. rei, K2) , as well as of the coefficients (k3> k !j k 2) f° r is the first-best These coefficients depend on the reduced-form payoff structure U, turn depends on the particular application under consideration. For the purposes of our analysis, however, understanding the specific values of these coefficients is not essential. a because the latter impacts the average action of others, which in turn affects the incentives of the individual agent. We can further show that the first-best allocation exists, = ki where the K* (0i, coefficients (k^, fc*,^) are again unique, and is = «5 + K\6i + K*2 6, 6) is given by . determined by the payoff structure. Note that, as with equilibrium, the first-best action prescribed to an agent depends both on his own productivity and on aggregate productivity; however, the dependence on aggregate productivity now emerges only because of external Now effects. suppose that information is incomplete but common across all agents. Because of the quadratic specification of payoffs, a form of certainty equivalence holds: the equilibrium and cient actions common under incomplete but effi- information are the best predictors of their complete- information counterparts. Proposition ki = V denotes the E[k 1 Suppose information all (9i,6) \V], while the strategy that common information information remains common. economies there can be room maximizes welfare is given by ki = strategy is given by E[rc* (Oi,0) \V], where set. which k Clearly, in e-conomies in common. The unique equilibrium is = k* , there However, as we will for policy intervention no room is show for policy intervention as long as next few sections, even in these in the once information is dispersed. 11 Equilibrium use of information 3.2 We now there is turn to the analysis of equilibrium allocations We no policy intervention. An Definition 1 equilibrium is fc(w) when information is dispersed and when define an equilibrium in the standard Bayes-Nash fashion. a (measurable) strategy k = argmax R[U(k,K (</>), —? : fi k {<f>), such M. 6) \ u that, for all u& Q, (2) }, fc with K(<t>) = JQ k and ak ((t>) (u') dcj){J) Consider the following coefficient, = [/n [* (a/) which is - Ki^fd^J)} 1 ! 2 for all <f> e $. the slope of an individual's best response with respect to aggregate activity: a= ^r (3) k This coefficient measures the degree of strategic complementarity or substitutability among individual actions. 'None The equilibrium use of information can then be characterized as follows. of our results requires on economies in k =fc re*. Indeed, the reader may henceforth assume which inefficiency emerges only under dispersed information. 10 k, = k* if he/she wishes to focus Proposition 2 The equilibrium all wefi, with K(cf>) — JQ k (a/) dcj>(uj') Although Proposition for all G $. (p To it. see this, recall that K,(9i,9) taken had information been complete. Next, note that actions other agents are taking relative to When K{</>) — k(9, 9) actions are strategically independent (a = > 0), a form of certainty equivalence continues to When simply his expectation of the is instead actions are interdependent while he does the opposite behavior is The if would have been under complete information, it coefficient a < actions are strategic substitutes (a permit more alignment of actions when a tilted to how much thus also captures In particular, the agent adjusts his action upwards whenever he 0), expects aggregate activity to be higher than what 0. the average deviation in the is basis of his expectation of the average deviation in the population. actions are strategic complements (a a < would have i the agent adjusts his action away from the aforementioned certainty-equivalence bench- 0), mark on the if it what they would have done under complete information. action he would have taken under complete information. / the action agent is hold: an agent's equilibrium action under incomplete information (a (4) 2 does not provide a closed-form solution for the equilibrium strategy, an insightful representation of is unique, and satisfies is = E[K(6,6)+a-(K((f>)-K(6,6)) \u] fc(w) for strategy exists, In other words, equilibrium 0). > and more differentiation when agents value aligning their choices with one another. how information Proposition 2 has direct implications for relying on common Because used in equilibrium. is sources of information facilitates alignment of individual choices, while relying on idiosyncratic sources inhibits it, strategic complementarity increases the sensitivity of equilibrium actions to the former and reduces the sensitivity to the latter, while the converse is true for strategic substitutability. To see this information of agent is i is more clearly, consider the case Gaussian. In this example, consists of a private signal xi idiosyncratic noise and e ~ («i coefficients (7^,7^,71) are given by 7 = and where irg = + 7T + y 2 o-g , (1 ny and + - = a)lT x cr~ 2 , and where 9 equilibrium +7T y = a~ 2 -r (1 - is + lyV + "Ov TTg tt x i, «2) [ltiH ~ E? 7T0 k ~ N (/z, af) a public signal y — 9 + e, 9 for all The unique + k(x, y) where the = = 9+& iV (0, aVj. = 9i where the agents' shocks are perfectly correlated and 7 11 and the information where £, ~ N (/z, a2 ) then Ixx] (5) , = Ot)lT x denote the precisions public signal, and the private signal. , C TTQ of, + 1 7T y -")^ + (1 - , 6) Q) 7T X respectively, the prior, the A higher a reduces 7X and raises 7^ and 7 y tion towards the prior and the public Next, note that 7x activity. + 7y = stronger complementarity : tilts the use of informa- signal because they are relatively better predictors of others' 1 — 7^, so that the equilibrium action of agent i can also be expressed in terms of the underlying fundamentals and noises as follows: h = By k + («i + k 2 ) [7^M + (1 - 7m)# + 7y£ + 7x&] > strengthening the anchoring effect of the prior, stronger complementarity dampens the overall sensitivity of individual actions to changes in the underlying fundamentals; increases "inertia." impact of Finally, common By increasing the reliance to noisy public information, noise and hence increases the non-fundamental by reducing the reliance on noisy private information it in other words, it it also amplifies the volatility of aggregate activity. mitigates the impact of idiosyncratic noise and hence reduces the non-fundamental cross-sectional dispersion in activity. Beyond the Gaussian example, a closed-form solution of the equilibrium strategy can be ob- tained in terms of the hierarchy of beliefs regarding the underlying fundamentals. Corollary shocks and, E = 1 J E[8\u]d(fi(u)) denote the average of the agents' expectations of their own n n~ \(J\d4>{u>) denote the corresponding n-th order average for any n>2, let E = J E[E 1 expectation. Let l The equilibrium strategy is given by k{tu)=E[K(9,§)\uj} where 9 The under = £~=] ((1 - aja"" 1 ) En Vw, (7) . equilibrium action under incomplete information thus has the same structure as the one common information replacing 9 with 9. The latter is simply a weighted sum of the entire hierarchy of expectations about the underlying shocks, with the weights depending on the degree of complementarity: the stronger the complementarity, the higher the relative weight on higher order expectations. Since higher order expectations tend to be more anchored to common information, this suggests that the intuitions provided by the Gaussian example are 3.3 sources of more general. Efficient use of information We now turn to the following question. Suppose the government can not centralize information, or otherwise transfer information from one agent to another, but can manipulate the use their available information. Can the government then improve way agents upon the equilibrium use of information? In this section that may permit we address this question by bypassing the details of specific policy instruments such manipulation and instead characterizing directly the strategy that maximizes welfare under the sole restriction that information can not be centralized. strategy the efficient strategy, or the efficient use of information. 12 We henceforth call this Definition 2 An efficient strategy is a Because payoffs are linear mapping k* in transfers, the latter : Cl —> R that maximizes ex-ante utility. impact welfare only through incentives. Hence, the combination of the efficient strategy with any transfer scheme that makes this strategy incentive compatible defines the very best the government can do without centralizing information. That when implementable, the mechanism among the ones that direct to efficient strategy is welfare-equivalent to depend only on planner recommends to each agent any arbitrary strategy k this goal, consider = and Q— M > : o%(h) The term The term k\ e = (K — K) — K) — (k The = Var(fc - K\h) = (k is, e +e+ hi 2 / [k(6;h) - K{h)] dh{9) activity. The action of any given V{ common captures the impact of — K) noise in information. is common Finally, the term captures the non-fundamental variation in individual activity that is, u; Given any strategy k 1 Eu = W voL vol The let captures the impact of idiosyncratic noise. is 12 following result then shows that a similar decomposition applies to ex-ante welfare. Lemma The let captures the non-fundamental variation in individual activity that idiosyncratic to the agent; that where characterization. captures the variation in individual activity that reflects variation in fundamentals. across agents; that = show how the can be decomposed in three components: h— Vi and its will "explained" by the fundamentals. Similarly, is be the fundamental components of the mean and the dispersion of i focus on We E[k{u>)\9,h} denote the component of individual activity that K(h)=E[k\h]= I k{9;h)dh{9) we next section; here, in the k(9;h) agent the best incentive-compatible and not on the reports made by other agents. can be implemented efficient strategy Towards his report restrict the actions the is, : Q. — > M, ex-ante utility (welfare) E[U(k, K, = Ukk + 2U2 ki< + UKK < <7 fc) 9)} and W = Var (e) = Var (K) - Vax(K) first term and + dis ^W vol vol + ±W dis = Ukk + Uda < dis = Var in (8) captures the welfare effects of the (v t ) is - 0, given by dis (8) and where Var (k - K) - Var(fc - I<). fundamental-driven variation in activity. other two terms capture the welfare effects of the residual variation in activity: vol measures non-fundamental aggregate volatility, which originates fundamental cross-sectional dispersion, which originates Note that, by construction, hi, e and Vi in common in idiosyncratic noise. are orthogonal one to the other. 13 noise, while dis measures non- The coefficients W vo i and Wdis then summarize the two types of sensitivity of welfare to these noise: W vo \ measures social aversion to non-fundamental volatility, while Wdis measures social aversion to non-fundamental dispersion. Both non-fundamental How much because of the concavity of payoffs. in welfare losses and non-fundamental dispersion contribute to a reduction volatility depends on the each of them contributes to welfare under examinations: different primitive preferences, details of the application technologies and market structures induce different social preferences over volatility For our purposes, however, and Wiii s Since suffices to it summarize these and dispersion. social preferences in the coefficients W vo i Their relative contribution can then be measured by the following coefficient: . W vo \ captures social aversion to volatility, while Wdis captures social aversion to dispersion, higher a* can be interpreted as higher aversion to dispersion relative to volatility. same fundamental-driven variation Strategies that share the non-fundamental common actions to to volatility common and dispersion that they induce. differ in the levels of Intuitively, the higher the sensitivity of and hence the higher the non-fundamental noise relative to idiosyncratic noise, One should thus expect preferences over volatility and dispersion. This insight is Proposition 3 The 13 efficient strategy exists, is unique, = k(u) all may sources of information relative to idiosyncratic sources, the higher the exposure of activity relative to its dispersion. for almost in activity u, with K{4>) — E[ k*(6, 6) Jn k (u/) In equilibrium, an agent's action equilibrium action; however, K, with the weight on the replace k with k* and it was d(f>(uj') a* for (K{<f>) all was anchored to also adjusted latter given a with + by a. A volatility the efficient strategy to depend on social formalized in the following proposition. and - satisfies \u] k*(8, 9)) (10) <f>. his expectation of k, the on the basis complete-information of his expectation of aggregate activity, similar result holds for the efficient strategy once a*. It follows that, just as a summarized the we private value of aligning actions across agents, a* summarizes the social value of such alignment. That the in turn is efficient strategy is anchored to k* the inversely related to the ratio , W first-best action, vo i/Wdi s reflects is quite intuitive. That a* our preceding discussion about volatility and dispersion: the degree of alignment associated with the efficient strategy increases with social aversion to dispersion and decreases with social aversion to volatility. 13 Hereafter, when we say unique, we mean up to a zero-measure subset of Q\ this one has to make with a continuum of types. 14 is a standard qualification that Furthermore, just as a pinned down down sources of information, a* pins more see this is where the for almost all (x,j/), * ne + ny + {1 - a*yTTx follows that, just as It and ' Inefficiency only 3.4 The k%) [j*^ + JyV + J*x x] ly by + ir y + n9 - (1 a*)7r x ' {l-a*)n x _ TTy = (11) , lx irg + ir y + (1 - ' a*) irx the equilibrium levels of inertia, non-fundamental volatility As structures, the analogue of Corollary a with 1 for the case applies for the efficient strategy a*. under dispersed information further appreciate the inefficiencies that can emerge due to the dispersion of information, con- sider economies in which k whenever information a + dispersion, a* determines the levels that are optimal from a social perspective. once we replace k with k* and To (k* coefficients (7^,7y,7z) are given a determines more general information of =k* + kj_ = To then given by k(x,y) ** the corresponding relative sensitivity of efficient actions. again the Gaussian example with perfectly correlated shocks. clearly, consider efficient strategy the relative sensitivity of equilibrium actions to different y£ The is = k*. common, In these economies, the equilibrium leaving no room is (first-best) efficient for policy intervention. Nevertheless, whenever a* inefficiency emerges under dispersed information, opening the door to policy intervention. , following is then an immediate implication of the results in the preceding sections. Corollary 2 Consider an economy (i) The equilibrium (ii) When a > is efficient that is efficient under dispersed information a* and information is When a < a* and information is if and only if a— = k*). a*; Gaussian, the equilibrium exhibits overreaction information and excessive non-fundamental (iii) under common information (k to public volatility. Gaussian, the equilibrium exhibits overreaction to private information and excessive non-fundamental dispersion. 4 Optimal policy We now turn to the core contribution of the paper. affect the decentralized use of information. efficient use of We We first explain how different tax schemes then identify the tax schemes that implement the information as an equilibrium. 15 Equilibrium with taxes 4.1 Suppose that the information that fa)ie[o,i] as become wen publicly available at stage 3 includes is as aggregate productivity T where the function and satisfies Then, without any = T (ki,K,ak,8) : R2 x R+ — R x + T^ = loss of optimality (as it will by , a quadratic polynomial in (k,K,9), is > — the following properties: Ukk {K,6), and Tkk all u clear in the next subsection), consider policies defined Ti o\, 9. individual actions all Tkk < — $ k Z.t 0, k < it T (K,K,0,6) = ^> We denote the class of policies that satisfy these properties by T. Finally, note that this class includes both progressive tax schemes > 0) and for These properties preserve existence and uniqueness of equilibrium, 0. while also guaranteeing budget balance state- by-state. 15 Tkk linear in is regressive tax schemes (i.e., linear tax-schedule that does not directly < with Tkk 0). 16 One should thus (i.e., with think of this as a non- depend on individual productivity (0;), but is contingent on aggregate outcomes (K,ak,9) We then have the following result structure by setting Ukk — ~ 1| Proposition 4 Given any the general case T scheme tax G T, let l _ {l-a)KQ-Tk (0,0,0) 1 - a + Tk k + Tk K The equilibrium strategy in the appendix). is a - Tk R a _ we henceforth normalize the payoff (to simplify the formulas, + Tk k 1 . ~ 1 . _ (1 all u> G where k(9, fi, 9) = Rq a) fa + k 2 - Tk§ ) . unique, and satisfies exists, is k((j)=E[k(e,e)+a(K((l>)-k(9,e)) for - l-a + Tk k + TkK + Tkk + k\9 + k 2 9 and K(4>) = JQ k There are three instruments that permit the government \u>] (13) {&') d4>{ui') for all cf>. to influence the agents' activity: Tkk, the progressivity of the tax system; TkK, the contingency of marginal taxes on aggregate activity; and Tk §, matter the contingency of marginal taxes on aggregate productivity. While equilibrium outcomes, each of them has a distinctive for role. The all these instruments progressivity Tkk 1S the only instrument that permits the government to control k\, the sensitivity of the agents' actions to their information about their own productivity 14 We relax this assumption in Section 4.3. 15 To see / T (*, K , ak the , 6) latter d-4, (k) property, =T (K, K, note 0, 6) that, + \{Tkk for any shocks. For given Tkk, the instrument that cross-sectional distribution ip of individual activity, + Taa )al In our environment, the progressivity of the tax system will turn out to affect the decentralized use of information, but it does not interfere with redistributive concerns; this is 16 because of the linearity of payoffs in transfers. permits the government to control the degree of complementarity (a) and thereby the sensitivity of common actions to noise relative to idiosyncratic noise the contingency T^k the sensitivity of individual actions to variations in aggregate productivity on of marginal taxes 4.2 is the contingency strategy as an equilibrium. Whenever this is T that implements the the case, by the very definition of the efficient strategy, even for transfer schemes that violate budget balance and/or anonymity, and even make agents to send arbitrary messages to the planner and the planner to What the agents before they commit T that T* e Proposition 5 A essential is T — such that k\ that K2 = function T «£, this result k*. one allows the if the transfers contingent , result establishes existence and uniqueness the optimal efficient strategy T^k always increases with exists, is a and unique, and decreases with a*. follows from Proposition 4. First, note that there exists a unique Tkk is But then there an d a unique Tk are then pinned true efficient allocation. implements the has the property that, for given (k,k*) The proof of The next their choices. that is only that the planner does not send informative messages to is implements the policy in efficient no other transfer scheme that can improve upon T*. This this also guarantees that there is of a policy Tk § strategy efficient turn to the question of whether there exists a policy T* £ on these messages. on aggregate 9. Implementation of the We now of taxes and T^k, the instrument that permits the government to control Finally, for given T^k activity. is also exists a (0, 0, 0) unique T^k such that a such that Rq down by budget — Kq. The — a*, a unique Tk g such rest of the parameters of the policy balance, establishing that there exists a unique policy that implements the efficient strategy as an equilibrium. 17 The optimal policy has the property that, keeping k and n* constant, the optimal with a and decreases with a* This . tarity perceived by the agents, in information. If we thus look it is reduces the sensitivity of individual decisions to across economies that share the (i.e., properties under incomplete information TkK is (i.e., 17 The uniqueness common same equilibrium and they feature the same k, and k*) but noise efficiency differ in these they feature different a and a*), we then find that higher in economies that exhibit a larger discrepancy between the private and the social value of aligning choices; equivalently, the optimal non-fundamental increases because a higher TkK, by reducing the degree of complemen- properties under complete information the optimal T^k volatility of the equilibrium relative to its T^k is higher the more excessive the non-fundamental dispersion. result holds for "regular" information structures. For "non-regular" information structures, the degree of complementarity is irrelevant, leaving one degree of indeterminacy. See Section 4.5 17 for such a case. Implementation with measurement error 4.3 The policies considered so far do not require that the government have superior information than the agents at any time: the taxes are conditioned on information that are levied. However, the preceding analysis has many In contrast, for time. applications it is public at the time taxes assumed that actions are perfectly revealed may be more at that appropriate to assume that actions, as well as aggregate fundamentals, are only imperfectly observed. To accommodate we now consider a this possibility, productivity to be observed with noise in stage in stage 3 the noise while government — and an idiosyncratic Vi is the true aggregate productivity 9 = 9 + errors <;, where ? is 2. We —observes ki if = the government a 2 . — as well as let K = K+ 77 + fcj a'i 77 i chooses + in stage 2, fcj where v{, and a 2 ,. 77 and a 2 = o~\ +a 2 is a then common Similarly, instead of any other agent —observes a signal All these noises could be interpreted as to be independent of the fundamentals then agent with respective variances noise, 9, In particular, 3. other agents noise with variance and are assumed have in stage all variant that allows actions and average measurement and of the information that agents denote, respectively, the cross-sectional average and dispersion of k, and consider tax schedules of the form tz where the function T T is assumed E T). The tax an agent expects E[T(fc 2 ,A-,a fc ,0)M = T(ki,K,a k ,9), to satisfy the pay to is same properties as in the previous section (i.e. then given by: = mF{ki,K,akt 9)\u)i) + 2(Tkk + 2TkK + TKK )a 2 + ±(Tkk + Taa )av2 + 1 ri The last three terms in (14) Tgecjl capture the impact of measurement errors on the expected tax. Because these terms are independent of the agents' actions, they have no impact on individual incentives and hence they do not interfere with the incentives provided by the tax system. It follows that, not only the noise does not interfere with the ability to implement the efficient strategy, but also it does not affect the properties of the optimal tax system. Of course, the last property relies on the noise being additive actions). When, instead, the noise is multiplicative, it measurement error once again does not efficient strategy, although Proposition 6 The it now may efficient strategy this result, for the without any significant undo the incentive effects of the noise. interfere with the ability to affect the details of the It implementable the optimal tax system. can be implemented regardless of whether activity and fun- damentals are observed with measurement Given separable from the agents' does impact incentives. However, by appro- priately adjusting the policy, the government can fully follows that (i.e., error. remainder of the analysis we can abstract from measurement error loss of generality. 18 — . Inefficiency only under dispersed information 4.4 As mentioned in Section 1, financial-market observers how information are often concerned about many work believe that financial markets — at both the academic and the policy front processed in financial markets. In particular, while is many well on average, also feel that financial markets often overreact to noisy public news, causing excessive non-fundamental volatility in both asset and prices At some real investment. the restriction that k = k* and a > level, this possibility a*. More generally, can be captured in our framework by economies which k in — k* but a ^ a* offer an interesting benchmark because in these economies policy intervention becomes desirable only when information dispersed. is We now thus examine the properties of optimal policy for this special class economies. Because a ^ a* means that the equilibrium is inefficient in its relative sources of information and hence to different types of noise, co- varies with the = letting e components of K—K it is is necessary that the marginal tax by the fundamentals. In activity that are not explained denote the component of activity that response to different due to common particular, we have the noise, following result. Corollary 3 Consider economies When a > converse is a* , the optimal policy has true This result under dispersed information. in which inefficiency emerges only T^k > and the marginal tax co-varies positively with e. The when a < a* is intuitive. In situations in which, if it were not for policy intervention, the equilib- rium would exhibit overreaction to common sources of information and excessive non-fundamental volatility, the optimal marginal tax co- varies positively with the fundamental volatility. from overreacting to It is common noise that drives this non- then precisely this property of the tax system that discourages agents common sources of information and dampens non-fundamental Note, however, that this appealing property of the tax system is volatility. achieved only in an indirect way, without any need to monitor and quantify the various sources of information available to the agents. This particular, is done by making marginal taxes contingent on observable aggregate outcomes. In when a > a* , the optimal policy reduces the complementarity in individual actions, and thereby dampens the reaction of the equilibrium to common of marginal taxes on realized aggregate activity positive (T^k noise, > 0). by making the contingency The optimal guarantees that the overall response of the equilibrium to aggregate productivity by making the marginal tax 4.5 not distorted also a decreasing function of realized aggregate productivity (Tk g < 0). Idiosyncratic vs aggregate shocks Another special case of the is policy then new interest is public finance literature. the case of independent private values typically considered in Studying this particular case helps appreciate 19 how our policy depend on the dispersion results of information regarding aggregate shocks, as opposed to purely idiosyncratic shocks. Within our framework, that 9i is this case can be captured as follows: the private information of agent distribution h is common i and <f> knowledge, so that there — is that h, and hence 8, is commonly known and that the unique equilibrium by k = (uji) efficient allocations. to condition the tax What renders environment is is As a k* (Qi,Q) We is no uncertainty about the cross-sectional given by k (wj) result, neither also common the fact that = K (0i,6~) a matters a and a* and hence , common is &i is known to agent i, this implies Similarly, the efficient allocation . is it is not necessary 18 also the contingency in the TkK, irrelevant aforementioned not per se the fact that private values are independent but rather that there no strategic uncertainty: no agent faces uncertainty regarding the distribution of actions population. Indeed, that h if we relax either the assumption that common knowledge is distribution of actions is also #; is known but maintain the assumption that common knowledge in equilibrium. is to agent common behavior nor a* matters for the We efficient allocation i in the or the assumption knowledge, then the a matters — and therefore nor T^k for equilibrium essential for achieving is conclude that the key distinctive property of the correlated-value environments consider in this paper is is This in turn eliminates the problem of forecasting aggregate activity, once again guaranteeing that neither efficiency. given nor a* matters for for equilibrium behavior, activity. dis- knowledge. Together with the fact conclude that in the case of independent private values system on realized aggregate so 6{, second, suppose that the cross-sectional h; tribution of types in society. Because 0, the cross-sectional distribution of information, knowledge, in equilibrium aggregate investment = suppose that Ui first, we the strategic uncertainty created by the dispersion of information regarding aggregate shocks. Corollary 4 When edge, the cross-sectional distribution of information in society the contingency of taxes on aggregate ((f)) activity (TkK) is i}°t essential for is common knowl- implementing the efficient strategy. 5 A The analysis so far has been confined to a static game. dynamic economy be embedded in a dynamic setting with a more macro helps further appreciate 1 and how our results can be relevant We now flavor. show how This serves two goals. for applications. Second, it 9. Moreover, should the tax be k.2 made First, it accommodates In particular, the efficient allocation can be implemented with a tax schedule that depends only on through game can this static own activity contingent on K, this contingency would matter for equilibrium behavior only (the sensitivity of the complete-information equilibrium to 9), not through the contingency on 9 should then be adjusted to perfectly offset the effect of 20 TkK on a k.2- (the degree of alignment); the possibility that interesting dynamics in actions originate in the dynamics of information. we this section, start by taking the dynamics analysis of endogenous information in Section There are N+ > periods, with TV 1 chooses an action Investing ki t G (kij) mean and G and F 6j jt and , = t 1, ..., his level of N, each agent consumption, £ R, which we henceforth interpret as capital invested ki >t costs t at are the shock, and 6. In each period 2. of investment in a riskless discount bond, and to the up Set 5.1 we turn of information as entirely exogenous; In in period and t F (hij, Kt, delivers the dispersion of activities in period To are real-valued functions. o>t, t, is A,i+i The agent . also in a risky technology. t+1, where Kt an exogenous productivity is simplify the exposition, that 9 t denotes the it Aij+i) in period that the productivity shocks are perfectly correlated across agents, so that (The timing convention we adopt here Q chooses his level i common we henceforth impose — ./U.t+i shock that &t f° r is au *»* relevant for period-^ decisions.) The agent's period-i budget Ci,t + G{k i>t ) given by is + = qt b iit F(ki tt -i,Kt-i,at -i,9t-i) +b iit where qt denotes the period-i price of discount bonds (the reciprocal and r^ denotes the period-t taxes the agent pays rate) 19 government. -n -\ it , period— t of the risk-free to (or the transfers he receives from) the Finally, the agent's intertemporal preferences are given by N+l where Ut is a real-valued function. This framework is quite flexible. can be nested by setting U(c,k) assumed a firm) costs X > . is in those statics G (k) = and then c (e.g., nested by letting U (c, k) = c, F (k, K, t to Cj,n+i agent's ct, 9) = benchmark —G(k) + (3F(k,K,a,6) equal the 9k, and effort, in payoffs as the profit of model with convex investment G (k) = which case k + it x/c 2 , for some constant would be natural to let U (c, k) = c — H(k), with H{k) = k representing the disutility of effort. Finally, one allow U and G to depend on (K,a,9), as to capture externalities in leisure, pecuniary 2 externalities in the costs of investment, For in the static —G{k) + @F(k, K,a,8) can be interpreted could also interpret k as individual and could further 19 letting Alternatively, a stylized version of the neoclassical growth One 0. examples = we considered All the applications = N+ = F (ki 1, t N, endowment we impose that ki,t Kn, on, An+i) — = &i,t G (0) and so on. = 4- bi,/v for all — to zero so that F(ki,o,Ko,(Jo,Ai) i, in which case the last-period budget constraint reduces tj,n+i- Furthermore, for = bj,o 21 = for all i. t = 1, without loss, we normalize each If agents had common information about the shocks in periods, then the analysis could all G proceed essentially without any further restrictions on the functions F, where agents have heterogeneous information. To keep the analysis are interested in cases we impose two we assume restrictions. First, some function H. Second, we for and U. Here, however, we that U —c— H(k), the function U in the bond market clears consumption: U(c,k) linear in is tractable, let V {k, K, a, 0) = -[G (fc) + H{k)} + 0F {k, K, a, 9) and assume that static V satisfies model. The and only = /3 if q% the same properties with respect to first restriction ensures that, in which case the demand (in life-time utility of agent (in i (k, K, a, 9) as periods and states, the all bond for the risk-free is if indeterminate) and that the the absence of taxes) reduces to N Ui^Y^p^V {kiiU K ,a ,6 t t t) t=\ The second restriction then permits to extend our previous static analysis to the The key knows this, in period t is to rule out informational externalities about {&t,Wi,t}tLi> in period with marginal distributions the cross-sectional distribution of 6 LOi tt {6t,u)i t}tL\ in F by 4>t 6 i, with t for all t, then irrelevant. 20 It is i then without efficiency, to restrict attention to strategies that Given that information is exogenous in all dates efficient allocations parallels that in the static Vjt (k, k, 0, 6) — and let equilibrium action in period 20 An distribution / also describes drawn independently from and t. /. This ensures that there depend only on is Finally, we nothing to —whether such actions loss of generality, for either equilibrium or w;^. t and states, the analysis of benchmark. Let k = argmax K V (k, k, 0,9) k* (6) would be k (9 t ) , ; if both the equilibrium and denote the (unique) solution (9) information were complete, the while the first-best action would be k* (9 t ) alternative that would also guarantee that agents do not learn anything about (9 S of past actions 21 for Equilibrium, efficiency and policy 5.2 to To ensure denote a joint distribution learn about (8 s ,4> s )g =t from the observation of other agents' (past) actions is t. the population. First, Nature draws / from a set {9t,(^i,t}tLi (a>i,t-i,0t-i,0t-i) belongs to Ui are observable < The (exogenous) information The $t- in periods s what an agent according to the probability measure T. Nature then uses / to draw a sequence {Oti^i^tLi f° r each agent assume that F Let / G fit- for u> lit given t of possible distributions possibility that of the information structure as follows. represented by is t —the depends on the actions other agents took Ot we model the dynamics an agent of here dynamic model. is to assume that Both k and k" are for all t linear functions of > 6. 1, uJi it is a sufficient statistic for In particular, k.(9) = ko + (m + : , <t>s)^=t 1 Next, from the observation (^i,s,<^s,^s)s=i) with respect to = kJ + (kJ + U with V. and k'(8) K.2) the coefficients (ko,ki,K2, «o iK*,^) determined as in the proof of Proposition 22 (u>i t, 21 . replacing k,1)6 with let a with W vo i = Vki< = + 2VkK + Vkk Vkk W a=1 ~w^' * , and 'v^ = and Wdis + Vaa Vjtfc \ voi , once again, a summarizes the private value of aligning choices (the equilibrium degree of complementarity), while a* summarizes the The equilibrium value of such alignment (the relative social aversion to dispersion and volatility). and under incomplete information are then characterized efficient allocations propositions, which are direct extensions of Propositions 2 and Proposition 7 The equilibrium w* € two 3. unique, and satisfies, for is in the following all periods t and all fit, = fct(wt) withK t {4> t ) E[ K (e t ) + a-(K (<j> t t )- \ut Kt (6 t )) ], =/fct (u/)#t(w'). Proposition 8 The all strategy exists, social efficient strategy exists, is unique, and for satisfies, periods all t and almost wt £ Of, kt(6H) with K t ((p t ) The efficient efficiency about = fQ K t kt = E[ k* (6 8t ) + a* (K t {&) - k* (6t )) \ u t ], (to') d(f> t (u>'). strategy can be implemented in a similar fashion as in Section can be induced in period and t t by making taxes that becomes publicly available at t in period + 1. As t + 1 when they make In particular, contingent on information in the static model, the optimal policy does not require any informational advantage on the side of the government. the agents anticipating 4. It merely depends on their decision that the marginal tax they will pay in the future will be contingent on public information about aggregate economic conditions. 6 Informational externalities A key functioning of modern economies that is missed in our preceding analysis is the aggregation of dispersed information in various indicators of aggregate activity, such as financial prices, trade volume, aggregate employment, output and investment data. What that the informational content of these indicators depends on the information in the first place: informative aggregate activity mation aggregation and taken into account We study the is more individuals on crucial for our purposes way agents use The its more various channels of infor- social learning thus introduce informational externalities that and is their available their private information, the of the underlying fundamentals. when determining this issue, rely is have to be the socially optimal use of information. policy implications, within a variant of the dynamic framework introduced in the previous section. Past shocks are no longer directly revealed to the agents. Rather, 23 the agents learn about these shocks from the observation of a noisy signal of past aggregate activity. This signal a proxy for the informational role of macroeconomic data, financial prices, and other is channels of information aggregation and social learning. up 6.1 Set To be able to analyze the endogenous dynamics of information in a tractable way, some rifice we have permitted of the generality exogenous information to be Gaussian. all and variance \x The ag. In particular, and we assume that realization of 8 — 9 + et public signal y t 9, and private is it is we assume that the component t t and of the we constant over time, drawn from a Normal distribution with mean = # + &,*, where e t ~ Af(0, cr^ t ) agents observe a t, and ~ Af{0, cr^ £j jt and independent of are noises, independent of one another, independent across time, also independently is never revealed. Instead, at any date signals Xi sac- preceding analysis: we henceforth restrict in the fundamentals about which the agents have heterogeneous information denote this component by we must any date identically distributed across agents. In addition, at t > 2, ) ^ with 9, t agents observe the following three random variables, which affect payoffs and convey information about K _i 9: t and at ~ = K _i t + T] t M(0, a^ t ) a , t = -i a are shocks, t -i +v t A = and , common 9 t + at , where Cij The variable mean A + G{k i>t ) + qt b iit = F(k That the it t-i,Kt-i,a -i,A t variables Kt-i F) coincide with the signals about past t ), ) activity rest of the model ft^U (ci t,ki,t) , is where t as in Section 5. ~ J\f{Q,al t ), and independent given by is t vt +b it t-i -r iit . is the underlying and Ot-l that enter period— t income (through not essential. is observation of income does not perfectly reveal either 9 or J2t=i Af(Q,tf can be interpreted as the period— t productivity shock, while 9 t (trend) productivity. The ~ across agents, independent across time, any other random variable. The period-i budget of the agent of rj t K -i- essential is that the payoff of an agent is given by is t The intertemporal U (c^t, fc^t) = c^— h{ki t)- What 22 That preferences are linear in consumption t ensures once again that q t — (3, that the trades of riskless bonds and the timing of consumption are indeterminate, and that the intertemporal payoff of an agent (in the absence of taxes) reduces to N+l Y,0 t ~1 V-(kiitl Kt i *i,Ai+ i t=i V (k, K, a, A) = where the 22 same + /3F (k,K,a,A) . The function V is quadratic and satisfies restrictions as in the previous sections. Also, the results that follow do not depend on whether the signals about past actions are public or private. we could In particular, Ai,t —[G(k) + H(k)} = 6 + a,i lt , allow the agents to receive private signals Ki,t-\ in addition to, or in substitution for, the = Kt-i + aforementioned public signals. 24 7?i,t, ot-\ = ot-\ + 1^,0 an d , Equilibrium 6.2 The is between the economy of essential difference the endogeneity of information: information about 8 the strategy agents follow in period (Kt ,at) and hence contained in is t in Section 5 determines how much behavior in periods affects the agents' In the absence of policy, this informational externality on. and the one examined this section t+ 1 not internalized by the agents: the is fact that the use of information in the present affects the information available in the future does — solution to Vk (k,k,0,6) — Thus, letting once again k(0), not alter private incentives. and a Proposition 9 The equilibrium = kq + + («i K2)9 denote the unique —VkKJVkk-, we have the following result. strategy exists and unique. Let {^j,^t} i=1 denote the (unique) is Then, for information structure generated by the equilibrium strategy. all t, the strategy and the information structure jointly satisfy = E[K(6) + a-(Kt kt(ut ) for all u) t e Hi, with K t = JQ k (4> t ) 1 t (to ) d(p t {uj') for (ct>t all )-K(9)) \ut $ <E <j) t t (15) ] - This result does not require the information structure to be Gaussian. However, once we 8 and the exogenous noises signals of past activity available in is to be Gaussian, this result ensures that the information contained in the also Gaussian. All the information any given period can then be summarized and the other for restrict two in — exogenous and endogenous—that sufficient statistics, one for is the private the public signals; the dynamics of these two statistics admit a simple recursive structure and the equilibrium strategy reduces to an affine combination of the two. Proposition 10 The equilibrium strategy h,t (ui,t) = is given by k {ltXi,t (1 - Tt y + It) Yt) with •* The variables Xij and = (l-a)TTf n ^ +7lf and public information about 8 Yt are sufficient statistics for all the private that is available to agent i in period while nf t, and tt\ are their respective precisions. The sufficient statistics are given recursively by Xi,t = (J-j —^-Ai.t-i + —r x 7rf_! 7Tf i,t Y= and t iff a'} a~ 2 7 y-Yt-i + -%- yt + -By-A t + y -k\_ — vrf iri where Vt = K _i t - k -. —+ {ki + («1 25 k2 ) v (l K2 )7i_l ir t - lt-\)Y -i t 2 t -i («i + ^2? g£? y _ —Vt (17) IT? , /1Q (18) and Similarly, the precisions irf a linear transformation of the signal of past activity. is are ir\ given recursively by TT?=Kti+°x 2 t ^= and Finally, the initial conditions are Xifi The logic behind condition (16) is — 0, the 7rf_ 1 l^o same +a- 2 + a- 2 + = t Mi 7o t — as the one 0, tTq ( +AC 2 ) Kl = and 2 2 7t = 7Tq we encountered -i^ o~ 2 4 (19) - . e in the static benchmark. For given degree of complementarity a, the relative sensitivity 7* of the equilibrium strategy to private information increases with the precision of private information and decreases with the a precision of public information. At the same, for given precisions, a higher tilts the equilibrium strategy away from private information and towards public information, as agents find it optimal to better align their choices. Conditions (17)-(19), on the other hand, describe the endogenous evolution of the information, which can be understood as noise, aggregate activity in period t K -i =k t Y ~\ Because t K -\ +r] t t now note is publicly in period t is First note that, because follows. — 1 is + («i known (and is given by + K2 ) = 0+ 7 — simply a Gaussian signal with precision be combined in the sufficient statistics averages of all + (lt-10 (1 - Y -\) 7t-i) t k-i . and 7t-i), observing t 7f t in the sufficient statistic Y t . = 2 7 _j Xi t But Vt, r t, (k\ + while K2) all o~~ t . It follows that all private public signals can be combined Condition (17) then states that these statistics are simply weighted the available signals, with the weights dictated by the respective precisions of these signals, while condition (19) states that the precisions of these statistics are precisions of the component The key property increasing in 7t_i. 23 to notice This is simply the sums of the signals. pends on the strategy followed is K -\ = informationally-equivalent to observing the variable y t defined in (18). that signals can it so are the coefficients kq, k\, Vt which Xi -\ equals 6 plus idiosyncratic is that the precision of information available in one period de- in previous periods. In particular, for all t, 7Tj and thereby nf is because the informative content of the signals of aggregate activity higher the more sensitive the strategies of the agents to their private information. 24 This important informational externality that the equilibrium fails is an to internalize in the absence of policy intervention. 23 When 9 changes over time, the period-t precision of information regarding the period-t fundamental need be monotonic over time; but 24 A it remains an increasing function of the sensitivities of past strategies to private information. similar property typically holds in rational-expectation-equilibria models: price increases with the sensitivity of individual asset demands 26 the information contained in the to private information. , and policy Efficiency 6.3 We now turn to the policy implications of the aforementioned informational externality by charac- terizing the strategy that maximizes ex-ante taking into account this externality. However, utility we now unlike the cases of exogenous information examined in the previous section, restrict at- tention to strategies that are linear in the available private signals. Without this restriction, the endogenous signals are no longer Gaussian and the analysis becomes intractable. Suppose, for follow in period t a moment, that the government affects the information available in subsequent periods. Suppose further that the summarized period-i private and public information were and respective precisions nf 7rf , so that ^N = E and let 2Vfc/<- k* (6) = argmax K V(k, k, 0,6) = + VKKJKYkk + Vera)- to recognize that the strategy the agents fails in sufficient statistics Xi^ and Vj with ^ ^, + + k*q (k* + k%)9 and a* = — 1 W vo i/Wdi s = Proposition 8 would then imply that the efficient strategy 1 is — {V^k + given by with (l-«*)7Tf , 1 Now + 7^ (1-0*) 71? suppose the government takes into account the endogeneity of the information. As long as welfare in the subsequent periods is increasing in the precision of available information, be desirable to adjust the current use of information so as to induce more learning periods. Because more learning is it should in subsequent- achieved only by the aggregation of private information, this suggests that the informational externality raises the sensitivity of efficient strategies to private information. The following result verifies this intuition. Proposition 11 The linear strategy that maximizes ex-ante utility Kt Kt) = k* ( 7£jfM + is given by - tT) Yt ) (1 where (l-a*)7i? It (1 for all all t < N, the private - a*) while 7^* 7T? = (1 + n? - P (1 — a*) it x n/ [(1 - 7£ x ) 2 a*) (l — a*) ir x N+ Trfyrf 7r^] and public information about 6 available to . Xi {^y t t agent and i 2 («J Y t + k*) 2 2 a~ t+1 are sufficient statistics for in period t, while ir x and their respective precisions; they are obtained recursively using (17)-(19), replacing (7t,Ko> with (7t**, Kq, Kj, K2) 27 irf are K i> K 2) The key result here that, holding constant the current precisions of private is information, the optimal weight on private information higher than is what it and public would have been had information in the subsequent periods been exogenous: ** 7i As anticipated, on private information mation and hence higher welfare The in <**)*? (l-a*)n? + nl from the internalization of the informational externality: by this follows directly raising the reliance > in one period, society achieves higher precision of infor- subsequent periods. 25 following alternative representation of the optimal strategy helps translate the result here terms of the degree of complementarity that the policy must induce in equilibrium. in Proposition 12 Consider mation structure. = a*^ a* efficient strategy fc?(wt) for almost As u € t in the case how much own all and let {fi t There exists a unique sequence {a£*} t=1 such that the , the efficient linear strategy fit, with = Kt(<f>t) and E[ k* {9) = Jq k% ,$ t } i=1 < with a^* , be the associated infor- a* for all t < N the information structure jointly satisfy, for all + a? (K (&) - k* (a/) for t d(f> t {ui') all (9t )) </> t e $t | u t and t, (20) ] . without informational externalities, the weight a*t * in condition (20) summarizes society would like the agents to factor their expectations of other agents' choices in their choices. Unlike the case without informational externalities, this weight now depends on the information structure. Nevertheless, condition (20) remains a valid and insightful representation of the optimal strategy: the result that a*[* informational externality is < a* highlights that having the agents internalize the isomorphic to having them perceive a lower complementarity in their actions than the one they should have perceived had information been exogenous. This in turn guides policy analysis: the optimal linear strategy can be implemented with similar tax schemes as in the benchmark model, but now the must be higher than what it Corollary 5 Informational sensitivity T^k of the marginal tax to aggregate activity would have been with exogenous information. externalities unambiguously contribute to a higher optimal sensitivity of the marginal tax to aggregate activity. This result is true irrespective of the specific payoff interdependencies and irrespective of whether the equilibrium would have been it easily extends to richer 25 Of hold at = had information been exogenous. Moreover, Gaussian information structures, with multiple private and public signals course, this informational externality t efficient is absent in the very N. 28 last period, which explains why the result does not on two properties: of aggregate activity. It relies merely by increasing the learning We is that a higher (i) sensitivity of actions to private information; positive because the optimal policy removes any and (ii) T^k induces more that the social value of such inefficiencies in the use of information. further discuss the importance of this last point in the next section, where the policies however, we have inefficiency we study how Before turning to this issue, identified affect the social value of information. we study the learning properties of optimal policy for a special case of interest: economies in which emerges only because of informational externalities. This special case is motivated by the following observations. In certain settings may economies with no externalities), one or near perfect, coincidence of private and (e.g., Walrasian expect that competitive market forces achieve a perfect, social payoffs. Although such a coincidence may fail to obtain in the absence of complete markets or in the presence of other market distortions, this case same represents an important benchmark. At the still expect that individual market participants fail time, when information to internalize how is may dispersed, one their choices affect the quality of information contained in financial prices, macroeconomic indicators, and other endogenous signals of the underlying fundamentals. information and is endogenous but where (k,ch) = and (k*,cy*), so that private social payoffs coincide emerges only because of informational externalities. inefficiency The In our set up, these settings correspond to economies in which following is then an immediate implication of Corollary 5 along with the fact that, for these economies, the optimal tax would be zero had information been exogenous. Corollary 6 In economies ties,, in which inefficiency emerges only because of informational externali- the optimal policy is such that This result may be T^k > 0. relevant for understanding optimal policy over the business cycle. Consider standard real-business-cycle models in which all firms regarding aggregate productivity and taste shocks. and households share the same information The assumption of frictionless competitive markets along with the absence of direct payoff externalities then guarantees that the equilibrium business cycle is efficient. Now consider a small, yet realistic, modification of these models: information be dispersed and only imperfectly aggregated through prices and macro data. modification is likely to render the business cycle inefficient as agents choices affect the information of others. Our fail to internalize how results then suggest the following policy let This their remedy: by having marginal taxes increase with realized aggregate macroeconomic activity and decrease with realized productivity, the government can improve the information contained macro data, and can thereby reduce the non-fundamental component fluctuations that are driven by noise of the business cycle in information regarding aggregate conditions). 29 in prices demand and (i.e., and the productivity Implications for the social value of information 7 Throughout our if analysis, we have ruled out policies that convey information to the agents. However, the government possess information that is not directly available to the market nomic data collected by government agencies such Bureau, or the Federal Reserve Banks), then desirable to communicate such information it as the is Bureau of Labor (e.g. macroeco- Statistics, the US Census important to understand whether to the market. Indeed, as long the equilibrium use of information is A positive answer is an increase inefficient, available information can have a detrimental effect on welfare. For example, if it is socially not obvious. in the precision of a > may a*, agents overreact to any additional public information, exacerbating the already excessive non-fundamental volatility. is However, this can not be the case if the equilibrium use of information is efficient. This because the equilibrium strategy then coincides with the solution to a planning problem where the planner directly controls to Blackwell's how agents use their available information. An argument analogous theorem then guarantees that additional information can not reduce welfare. 26 The following result is Corollary 7 In store efficiency then a direct implication of these observations. general, iji more precise information can reduce welfare. However, policies that re- the decentralized use of information also guarantee a positive social value for any information disseminated by policy makers or other institutions. In an influential paper, Morris and Shin (2002) used an elegant example to illustrate the possibility that more precise public information can reduce welfare: a "beauty-contest" game, the strategic complementarity perceived by the agents causing overreaction to public news. of transparency in central in isolation 27 is where not warranted from a social perspective, This example has lead to a renewed debate on the merits bank communications. 28 Whereas this question has been studied largely from other aspects of policy making, our results indicate that a central bank's optimal communication policy is far from orthogonal to the corrective In a related but different line of reasoning, Amador and roles of monetary and fiscal policies. 29 Weill (2007) argue that, by crowding out private information, an increase in the precision of exogenous public information can reduce the precision of the endogenous information contained in prices and other indicators of economic 26 For further details on how the welfare effect of additional information depends on the inefficiencies, if any, of the equilibrium use of information, see Angeletos and Pavan (2007). 27 Their example inefficiency 28 is nested in our baseline static framework with k emerges only under dispersed information and manifests See, for example, Amato and Shin Heinemann and Conrand Woodford 29 An (2006), Angeletos = k* and itself in a > a"; it is an economy where excessive non-fundamental volatility. and Pavan (2004, 2007), Baeriswyl and Conrand (2007), (2006), Hellwig (2005), Morris and Shin (2002, 2005), Roca (2006), Svensson (2005), (2005). exception is Baeriswyl and Conrand (2007), which focuses on the signaling effects of monetary policy. 30 activity and can thereby slow down Shin (2005) and Amato and social learning. 30 A theme similar is explored in Morris and Shin (2006). Our results imply that the government can improve the informational content of prices, can raise the speed of social learning, and can guarantee that any public information it disseminates is welfare improving, once it sets in place policies that correct the underlying inefficiency in the decentralized use of information. Concluding remarks 8 —such aggregate productivity highly dispersed in conditions or the profitability of available technologies — Information about commonly-relevant fundamentals and demand society, is is only im- perfectly aggregated through markets, and can not be centralized by the government or any other As institution. ized first emphasized by Hayek (1945), market mechanisms necessarily mean for an this means that effective utilization of such information. and social incentives in the use of the equilibrium's response to certain sources of information The key on decentral- However, this does not that the government should not interfere with the decentralized use of informa- tion: to the extent that private non-fundamental society has to rely volatility, excessive dispersion, or such information do not coincide, may be inefficient, leading to excessive suboptimal social learning. contribution of the paper was to identify policies that correct such inefficiencies: by appropriately designing the contingency of marginal taxes on aggregate activity, along with other properties of the tax system, the government can manipulate the incentives the agents face in using different sources of information and can thereby improve welfare even new channels through which information disseminate information or create We if it cannot is itself collect and aggregated in society. established this result within an abstract but flexible framework in order to highlight the potential generality of the insight. Of course, the details of the optimal contingency will the details of the application under examination. news and excessive non-fundamental volatility, If as the key inefficiencies are overreaction to public it is often argued to be the case for financial markets, then marginal taxes must increase with aggregate activity. inefficiency is depend on The same is true if the key the failure of markets to internalize the endogeneity of the information contained in financial prices and macroeconomic data. so that agents rely less on common In both cases, it is desirable to provide incentives sources of information; this can be achieved by introducing a positive contingency of marginal taxes on signals of aggregate activity. The opposite policy prescription applies to markets exhibiting overreaction to private information and excessive crosssectional dispersion. Nevertheless, the key principle on aggregate economic conditions —remains valid —the optimality for of marginal taxes contingent any economy featuring dispersed information regarding commonly-relevant fundamentals. 30 Amador and Weill (2007) extend Vives (1993, 1997) to situations with both private and public learning. Both models are nested in our analysis of Section 6 as special cases that rule out payoff externalities. 31 Examining the practical, political-economy, considerations that tion of explicit aggregate contingencies in the tax code However, it is is clearly might complicate the introduc- beyond the scope of this paper. important to note that there are various direct and indirect ways through which such contingencies can obtain in practice. For example, the government could first collect non- contingent taxes and subsequently make rebates whose magnitude depends on realized aggregate activity. Alternatively, the tax code could be revised over time on the basis of past macroeconomic performance. To the extent that such rebates or revisions are systematic, they can have similar incentive effects as the type of contingencies envisioned in this paper. Moreover, the contingency of monetary policy to macroeconomic performance could serve a similar role: how firms use different sources of information tion choices depends when making on how they anticipate monetary policy to their pricing and produc- respond to the information about aggregate employment, output and prices that arrives over time. For example, to the extent that higher interest rates have similar incentive effects as higher taxes, the Central contingency of its interest-rate policy on aggregate economic conditions, not only stabilization purposes, but also to improve the information that data. Further exploring how design of monetary policy is Bank can use the the policy objectives we have studied is 32 contained in prices and macro in this a fruitful direction for future research. for the familiar paper filter in the optimal Appendix 9 Proof of Proposition We 1. respectively, the complete-information equilibrium results to the case of incomplete Step 1. any given 0. but common U first-best allocation. Step 3 extends the information. i is pinned down by the first-order condition quadratic in (k,K,9), the first-order condition is Uk Aggregating across agents (0, 0, 0) integrating over (i.e., with (21) K (22), and is [Ukk Uk (ki, k, for K,9{) = equivalent to + Ukk ki + UkK K + Uke 9i = Uk (0, 0, 0) + Combining and the and 2 characterize, 1 Consider the complete-information equilibrium. Because payoffs are concave in K the optimal action for agent Because Steps prove the result in three steps. 0. (21) we thus have that 9i), + UkK K + Uke 9 = ] 0. (22) letting C4 (0,0,0) Uke °--(ukk + ukK y M -=!w Uk e K2 ~-(ukk + ukK ,,„* (23) Ku ) gives the result. Step 2. A Next, consider the first-best allocation. of a strategy k x : H —* R and feasible allocation consists of a system of budget-balanced transfers across agents. For any given cross-sectional distribution of productivities h G let K{h) = J k {6; h) dh (9) and dispersion of activity and ak (h) = (J [k {9; w(k;h)= strategy k. An allocation w(k;h). Because U is 2 - K{h)} dh veil of is thus efficient quadratic, and (6>)) if and only if Ua (k,K,a k ,9) = Uaa a k , denote the Lagrangian the dependence of k, ( I k{9)dh for this (24) (6)-k\-ix[I problem. Optimizing B \k[6) L with [k h. - (Uaa respect to -U9k 9 + X = + Ukk )+fi = 33 (9)9} [9) H — > K maximizes that dh Then - K} 2 dh Uke 9 -X-2fi \k(9) -K\ = Uk (K, K, 9) + UK [K, K, 9) x : we then have and a k on =w-A R, let the strategy k K L * ex-ante utility depends only on the in transfers, +U kU we dropped H— be the corresponding mean Next, w = U(K,K,0,0) + \{Uau + Ukk )4 + -Uoeo e2 for simplicity 1/2 x : ignorance (equivalently, welfare under an utilitarian aggre- l where and any given strategy k U{k{9;h),K{h),a k (h),9)dh(9) Because of the quasi-linearity of payoffs gator). h) H in the cross section of the population. denote ex-ante utility behind the a combination (9) - K9 let - a\ K, a\ and k(9) we have that Combining, we have that Uk6 9 + Uk (K, K, §) + UK (K, K, §) - Ukg 6 + {Uaa + Ukk [k{6) ) - K] = (25) or equivalently Uke 6 + Uk (Q, 0, 0) + UK (0, 0, 0) + [UkK + 2UkK + UKK ]K + UKB + {Uaa + Ukk Integrating over 6 [HO) ) - K(h)} (26) we then have that = Uk (0,0,0) + UK (0,0,0) {Urn + ^ Uke) g Substituting (27) into (26), and letting . "° _ Uk (0,0,0) + t/fc (0,0,0) " -(C/ + 2Cfc* + C/k/c) Kl ~ ~ ' fcfc ^ (Ukk + Uaa) ~Uk e + UK6 K2 ^ m * ~ -{Ukk + 2UkK + Ukk) ' , [ ' gives the result. Step Now 3. suppose that information common, the aggregate activity for agent i is commonly known also is in equilibrium. + Ukkh + UkK K + Ukg E[0i\P] = (0, 0, 0) V denotes the commonly-available agents, incomplete but common. + pkk + (o, o, o) UkK) E^T 7 ] is and 6 have been replaced by action for agent i is E[5j|7 ? similar is first-order condition ] and Ef^lT3 ]. It is is). Aggregating this across (21) 0. and (22), except for the fact thus immediate that the equilibrium given by ki A information simply E[#|P], we get k + u^ne^v] = Note that the above two conditions are identical to conditions 0i The all 0, information set (whatever this and noting that the cross-sectional average of uk that Since thus given by Uk where K is argument implies that the efficient action is =E[K*(0 ki which completes the proof of the Proof of Proposition 2. = E[K(6i,0)\P]. i given by ,§)\P], result. We prove the result in two steps. Step 1 proves that condition (4) characterizes any equilibrium. Step 2 proves existence and uniqueness. Step strategy Take any strategy k 1. k' : Q— K > such that, : Q. for all — R u>, > and let K((j>) k' (u>) solves (u) dip (to) . A best-response is a the first-order condition E[Uk(k',K(<l>),e)\u] 34 = Jk = 0. (29) Using the Uk (k',K,9) = Uk (K,(9 fact that where k stands for all (9,9) E[Ukk or equivalently k'(u>) Step 2. , , , + Ukk - (k' + UkK k{9,9)) — - (k' (29) reduces to , k(0, §)) + a (K E[k(9, 9) + UkK (K (<f>) — {$) k(9,9)) - k u>]. | (8, = 0, $))\u] What remains to prove is that the equilibrium exists and the class of payoff functions U that satisfy the properties specified in Section = (U, Q,Q,F) . By comparing equilibrium strategies for the economy e an economy e' = efficient strategy for measure-zero set of = conditions (4) and (10), (U, 0, fi, U use of information. Let efficient denote An economy 2. immediate that the it is F) coincides with the is set of set of efficient strategies (f/',0,fi,F) such that the k* and a* corresponding to e' coincide with the k and a corresponding any economy uj. K{4>)= fact that Ki U to e. Moreover, U' £ e' as long as U with U' £ exists U I"e[ = From 1. k{9 ,9) — k,2(1 (4), G U. As shown and follows that an equilibrium for the It Proof of Corollary <i> \ ]d<p(u)) +a in Proposition 3, the uniquely determined for is economy e exists we have that aggregate investment - ok(9 ,8) K f E[ (<j>) | and is all but a unique. satisfies u]d4>{u). a)/a, k(9,9) It follows all ui, unique; this can be done is which characterizes the Using the k(u) for (4). 3, for = In equilibrium, k'(u>) with the help of Proposition given by e (K-k(O,0)), the complete-information equilibrium allocation and the fact that k solves for Uk (K{9,6),K{6,6),6) = which gives 9) k{9 9) 9) , - olk%6) = (1 - a)K + ki6. that K{(f>) = -^Ko + KiE +a 1 (1 [e[K(<P) u]d<j){u) I and hence that E[K((j>) Iterating \u] = {l-a)K + KiE[E and then substituting 1 \(j] + aE[ fE[K{^>) | J ]d(f>(oj') \ u ]. into (4) gives oo k(ij) = E{K + K1 9 n + K J2 an E 1 w], (30) I n=l which together with K\ — Lemma 1. Proof of K2(l A — a) /a and the definition of 9 gives the result. Taylor expansion of U(k, K, a k ,9) around (k, K, a k ,9) gives En - E[UCk,K,ak ,9) + Uk Ck,K,a k ,9)(k-k) + UK (k,k,a k ,9)(K-K) + Ua (k,K,a k ,9)(a k +\ukk {k - kf + ~UKK (K - 2 l K) + -Uaa {a k - b k f + 35 UkK (k - K)(K - K) ]. -a k ) a By a the law of iterated expectations, = E[K\h] =E[E[K\e,h]\h] = It follows that = E[K] , E[E[k(u)\6,h]\h] =E[k(6\h)\h] = K(h). E[K] and that E[Uk (k, K, a k ,9)(k Furthermore, because E[E[E[k(u)\<f>]\e h]\h] U linear in o\, is Ua {k,K,a k ,9)(a k - = E[UK (k, K, k)] k ,6)(K - Ua (k,K,a k ,8) = Uaa a k (a k ~ -Uaa (a k - ak ) + ak ) 2 = K)} 0. <?>) It follows that = -Uaa [a k - ak ] Next, note that - {k Because E[k] k) = 2 = E[K] [(k = -K)= E[k] (k - + (K- K) 2 + 2{K - K)} 2 E[K] and because {K - K) is K)\{k -K)-(k- K)}. orthogonal to \{k -K)-(k- K)}, we then have that - E[(fc k) = 2 } -K)- Var[(fc - K)} + Vai[K - (k K). Finally, note that, E[(fc because (k — K) Combining - K){K is all Eu = = E[(K - k) 2 + K)\ } the above results, we thus have that l k ,6)} 2 + -Uaa l [ak - ak2 + ^Ukk Vac[{k - K) ] (k - K)] 1 + -Ukk Vzx[K -K}+ -Ukk Vm{K -K) + UkK V&r(K Using the } [K — k). orthogonal to E[U(k, K, - K)(K - K)\ = E[[K - K) 2 E[(k K). fact that Var[(fc -K)- (k - K)] and rearranging, then gives the expression Proof of Proposition 3. A = - K] - Var[& - K] = a\ - b\ in (8). strategy Eu= Var[fc is efficient if and only if it maximizes U(k(u),K(cj>),a k (cP),6)df(cj,6)dnf), Jf Jn,e with K(<f>) = J^ distribution over k(u)d(f> (lo) D, and generated by <y k ((j)) /. = The [Jn [k(uj) strict — 2 K((f>)] d(fi (to)] with (f> denoting the marginal concavity and the quadratic specification of 36 U ensures that a solution to this problem exists and and distribution of distribution J- Z for almost all u>. G Let denote the distribution of 9 conditional on (6\(j>) The Lagrangian '. unique is (<f>) denote the marginal by their joint as implied <j), problem can be written as for this A = UIq In U(k(u), K(cj>), uk {<l>),e)d<t>{u)dZ{d\(j>)dG{<j>) + /4 \(<f>) [K(4>) - Jn k(u>)d<j> (u)] dG(<f>) ~ fniH") ~ K(<t>)M (w)] dG(cf>) + U M) HM Therefore, the and first order conditions with respect to K(4>}, a k ((j>), and sufficient for optimality, are given by the following: (31) for almost Ua (k(u), K(4>),a k (cP),6)d4> (_j) dZ{9\4>) + all X(4>) - 2r,mk (w) - almost Using the facts that Ujc(k,K,6) almost Ua (k,K,a k ,9) = Ua acr k (j>) UK (K(<j>),K(<f ),8)dZ(e\4>) = -UK (K ) / = -\Uaa Substituting the above into (33), it satisfies where, _____ ment note that, is when given by Proposition 1, K all = all us £ fi strategy k Jq k (u>) d<f> (u>) , and (<f>), K(4>), 6) : Q— K > is and only efficient if - fc on w and of (34) K on <f>. Because both can be rewritten as + UkK (K - + Uke (9 + (UkK + UKK )-(K-K*(9,9)) + Ucra (k-K)\u>} = (k k*(9, §)) if : the dependence of linear, condition (34) Uk {K*{6, e),K*(9, 9), 9) + Ukk +UK (K*(9,6),K*(9,9),9) Now = ui. Uk (k, K, 6) + UK (K, K, 9) + Uaa [k -K]\u] = Uk{k,K,8) and UK(k,K,9) are E[ we conclude that the we have dropped for simplicity, u all . the following condition for almost E[ = conditional on Je 7]{(p) <f) conditions (31) and (32) reduce to , = - (9, linear in its arguments, that K{<j>) is all (33) denotes the cumulative distribution function of H4>) = K(</>))]dP(0,<l>\Lj) for that {4>) (32) /9x , [Uk (k(u>),K(<l>),0) - cf>\ui) <f> 2r1 {4>)a k for where P(9, which are necessary UK {k{u), K(<j>), 8)d$ (w) dZ{6\<t>) + A(0) = Je In IQ Jn k(u>), k*(S, 9)) 9) (35) 0. agents follow the first-best allocation, then in each state aggregate invest- k*(8,8). Replacing k*(9,6~) and k*(9,8) into condition (25) in the proof of we thus have that the first best strategy solves Uk (K^9j),K*(9,9),9) + UK (K%9j),K%l9),9) + Uke (9-9) + (Uaa + Ukk )[K*(9,9)-K*(9,8)} =0 (36) 37 a , . Substituting (36) into (35) and rearranging gives (10). Proof of Corollary Part 2. degenerate" information structure T, given n unique solution to (10) is if and only a= = k* (2) and (3): for any "non- the unique solution to (4) coincides with the , a*. Next, consider parts (ii)„ and (hi). When information Gaussian and shocks are perfectly correlated = n + (ki + k2 K = K + (rti + k K= = k It if from Propositions follows (i) + k p ) [if fj, K 2 ) bVM («i + k2 ) + 7j,y + 7iz] + + 7x)0 + (ly [7M /i + (7y 7y £] + 7X , 0] ) follows that vol The = from results then follow directly Proof of Proposition U + k2 [(kj 7y (6) ] 0^ and dis and K, ak , 9, 6) = [(ki + 2 k, 2 ) -y x} <j\ (12). Given any policy 4. (k, 2 ) T 6 T, = U (k, K, k ,8) let - T(k, K, a k 6) , denote an agent's payoff, net of taxes. Now offs let k x : H are given by U. — > R Because Uk (k(9;h),K(h),6,6) = 0, denote the complete-information equilibrium strategy when pay- U is concave in = with K{h) k, k(9;h) must solve the first-order condition Jk{9';h)dh{9'). Because U is quadratic in (it, K, 9,9), the first-order condition can be rewritten as Uk Integrating over 9, (0, 0, 0, 0) we then have + Ukk k (9; h) + UkK K (h) + Uke 8 + UkS 8 = (37) + Ukk + Uk K K(h) + Uke + Uk e- with (38) then gives k K = (9; Uk {0,0,0,0) Ukk (37) that 154(0,0,0,0) Combining 0. + ^fetf h) — k(9, 9) = Rq + Uk (0,0,0) -Tk ~Uk k - UkK Uk e -Ukk + Tkk -Ukk Uke + UkS Ki = - Ukk + UkK R\9 + = 0. (38) k 2 9 with (0,0,0) + Tfcfc + TkK Uke «i K-2 38 -Ukk Uk e - T,ke ~ UkK + Tk k + 7)kK K\ Using (23) the coefficients (ko,Ri,K2) can then be conveniently rewritten as follows: -Q- 1 = «i : ~ 1 Tkk w TkK ~ k Jk (ui) d<i> (u>) 4 °) m and let Tkk ^-r g fc m ~ a ~ urk Tkk ~ 2 kK then gives the formulas in the proposition. Next, consider the game under incomplete information. Take any strategy k K{4>) —. ( T-^-^i ) 1 Ukk — — 1 k (l-q)( Kl+ « 2 + _ Normalizing w . A best-response is a strategy k' — R fi : > such that, for : — R fl > all to, k' (uj) solves the first-order condition E[Uk (k', K(cf>), 6, 6) Using the fact that and the fact that Uk {k' , = 0. (42) = Uk {k{9, 9),k{9, 9), 9, 9) + Ukk (k' - k{9, §)) + UkK (K-k(9, §)) Uk (k(9,9),k{9,9),9,9) = for all (6,6) (42) reduces to K, h solves \uj} 9, 9) , k'{to) = E[k(e, 6) + a(K -k(9,9)) {<f>) \ u] with a TkK = UkK ~ TkK = +tt -Ukk + Tkk l-jfcTkk UkK_ = - -Ukk In equilibrium, k'(u>) follows = k(uj) for all u, from the same arguments as Proof of Proposition (13). in step 2 in the efficient strategy, a = only is easily a*, Ko = Kq, it is ACi shown from conditions = is unique 2. J-. For the equilibrium K*, K2 T that and = «2- ( satisfies (44) (43). and that First, note that k\ 44 ) this policy — re| if is and if Because a* Ukk + Uaa < if That this also guarantees that l /K\) = -Uaa Ukk — Tkk < 0. (45) . Next, note that, given Tkk = —Uaa , and only TkK = -Ukk 0. = and necessary and sufficient that (39)-(41) Tkk = Ukk {\-n a to (13) exists proof of Proposition thus suffices to prove that there exists a policy T* £ unique. This That a solution Take any generic information structure 5. with policy to coincide with the It which gives m ' Tkk and Tk j< (a satisfy - a*) - Tkk a* = -Ukk a + (Ukk + Uaa — $ K ^^ K < 1 ) a* = Uau - UkK - UKK then follows from the fact that With (Tkk ,Tk x) thus determined, and with both 39 Tk § and W Tk (0,0,0) vo i . (46) = Ukk +2Uk ^+UxK < being unconstrained, it is a a then immediate that there exist a unique ^0 = T fc - (1 (0, 0, 0) and that T to balance Tkk + Taa — 0. that this is Finally, for such that £2 — Tk (0, 0, 0) ^2 an<^ a unique such that by Kq\ these are given Tk g = Ukk Tk § a) [« + k*2 ) - Ukk (1 - a) («S («! + - «o) «a)] - (T fe * + TfcK - {Tkk + TkK ) the budget (state by state) Along with the other properties «3) 4 = -UK = -UKe (0, 0, 0) identified above, it is (47) , . T (K, K,0,6) =0 must be that it + (kJ ) for all (K, 6) then easy to verify equivalent to imposing the following: = T(0, 0,0,0) = Tm = 7X0,0,0) TK (0,0,0) = -T (0,0,0) = UK (0,0,0) Tkk = -%TkK - Tkk = -Uaa + 2Uk K + ZUkk fc TK§ = ~ Tk§ - UK8 = Taa This also implies that the policy -Tkk T is unique. Finally, that Ukk < a* follows directly from (46) along with the facts that Proof of Proposition 6. TkK the case of multiplicative measurement error, — 6(1 E[T(ku K, + c). A and Wdi s let k\ = k\{\ do not = E[T(ku K, k , 6)+\Tkk (a 2 + av2 a Proposition 4 thus continues to hold with k and K K = K(l + + + Vi), 77 ) k 2 + Uaa < 0. <J k ,6) 77), a\ = a\(l For + rj) 2 then gives ^TkKG%hK^\TK KolK2 ^\taa c^Gl\ Wi redefined as follows: Uk (0,0,0) -Tk (0,0,0) 2 + Tkk (1--+ -Ukk - UkK + TkK (l + a Uk6 -Ukk + Tkk (l + a 2 + a 2 UkB ~ Tk g -Ukk -UkK + TkK (l + a 2 )+Tkk (l + UkK -TkK (l+a 2 -Ukk +Tkk (l+a 2 + a 2 ) «i Ukk decreases with affect individual decisions. Taylor expansion of T(ki,K, a k ,6) around T(ki, K, k ,6)\u)i} = a and For the case of additive measurement error, the result follows directly from (14) noting that the last three terms in (14) and 6 increases with cr 2 + a2 ) ) - = 2 = a a2 + a2 ) ' ) ) By implication, Proposition 5 also continues to hold, although 2 depend on a and a 2 , m 40 now the optimal tax contingencies ] Proof of Corollary Prom 3. and (45), (46) we have that (47), the restriction k = implies «;* that Tkk = The tax system is TkK = -Ukk {a-a*), 0, thus linear in k, K= and K. 9 positive, It follows which that turn in is Proof of Corollary E n of 9 (which because <f) is true and only if Because 4. in <p) is common knowledge and E = = l Combining these E\E[6\u]\<l>] results, e Cov(Tk (K,9),e) measurable is and hence E[A"|/i] ( + k2 ) Kl . with a marginal tax rate given by Tk (K, 9) = Tk Next, recall that Tk§ = -TkK and <j> also = K — K is orthogonal to any function of h, = Tk xVar(e), which is positive if and only if is + TkK K + Tk §9. (0, 0) a > a* = E [9\h] — E [9\h, =E E\E[9\uj,<t>]\<f>] is knowledge, the n-th order average expectation common knowledge and because 9 Tk x if m . common including [9\<t>] equal to <f>] , E l , for all n. Moreover, we have that = E [E [6\h,<f>] \<f>] =E[S\4>] , we have that oo § = Y, ((1 - a)""" En = E 1 ) [6\<£\ =E [S\u] . n=\ From Corollary 1 it then follows that the unique equilibrium =E k (w) in which case a is irrelevant. Similar is also irrelevant. = E[ K * Along with the given by , arguments imply that the k(uj) so that a* [k (9, 9) \u] is (0,5) \u] efficient allocation is , result in Proposition 4, strategy can always be implemented with a tax scheme for which Proof of Propositions 7 and Proof of Proposition first 8. period, that the equilibrium strategy at Proposition 2. Now consider t = 2. t t = — 1 is for t = 2 establishes the result. 41 efficient 0. is 3. exogenous in the unique and solves (15) follows directly from structure 1. is now endogenous but uniquely That the equilibrium strategy unique and solves (15) thus follows again from Proposition > Tk K = Because information 1. The information determined by the unique equilibrium strategy t we then have that the These are direct extensions of Propositions 2 and Start with 9. given by 2. at t Repeating the same argument = 2 is for all ,. Proof of Proposition = with Wij (xi t Start with 10. Xu = — k(8) Ko + x iA (ki = 1. In the period, information first exogenous is i,yi,Ai). Standard Gaussian updating then gives E[e\u iA where t , , + = wf cr" 2 we then have «2)^, i,1 ^ = Yi , ^X = ] + ^ Y 1 (48) , ! ^i Trf = that the unique solution to (15) is h (wi,i) = ko + + (asi + ^fz/i + ac 2 ) + (7i*i,i and (1 - a^" 2 + a" 2 + a"?. Using given by (49) 7i ) *i) with ^[(l-aK]/[(l-aK + <]. 7l To by guessing that the equilibrium strategy see this, start with Finally, use the latter along Next, consider signal is t = (15) and Ko + (k\ + some K2) (71 # coefficient 71. + (1 — 71) ii)'- (48) to derive the equilibrium 71. = In the second period, 0^2 2. = K\ Next, use this guess to compute aggregate activity as satisfies (49) for U u>i i (xi t 2,y2,A2,Ki,a\). The endogenous < given by K = The information about + «a) + («i # contained in K\ x k is + (71 ^ - (1 7i) *i) + V2 thus the same as that contained in * y -«o-(^+^)(i- 71 )y1 = + . J 1 («i where 772 = t/2/[(ki + K2)7i] is + K2J71 Gaussian noise with variance on the other hand, conveys no information about which is common knowledge. It 8, cr? 2 — °"n 2/ ( K i = (k\ The + follows that the period-2 public information about 8 can signal o\, K2) 7 2 2 o" ^ be summa- on (yi,Ai,Ki,ai,y2,A2) Gaussian with mean V ^2 = Cx^ -\y 4 -4*i + ^l and precision summarized ^ = n\ + o-" 2 + &~ \ + 7 2 , in the sufficient statistic 7 A + + -ir^2 ^2 2 *2 is ^2) 7i because (49) implies that o\ rized in a sufficient statistic Yi such that the posterior about 8 conditional is + («i + K2) 2 2 2 2 . (*1+«2)X—yi y *2 u~\- Similarly, the private information can be Xj^ such that the posterior about 8 conditional on Gaussian with mean — X-i.2 — ^i,l H 5" x i,2 IT, and precision Trf == 7rf + -2 o~ x 2 . The unique h (wi,2) = «o + with 72 = [(1 - a) Trf] / [(1 - a) Trf + tt^] solution to (15) («i + «2) (72^i,2 . 42 is + then given by (1 - 72) Y2 ) (2:;, 1,2^,2) It is t > immediate that the construction of the equilibrium strategy for t — We 3 with the statistics X^t an Yt defined recursively as in the proposition. unique equilibrium strategy = 7i [(1 - a) J [(1 - a) Trf] Proof of Proposition conclude that the is ki,t (ui,t) with 2 applies also to any 11. = Ko + ir itf + y «2) (ltXitt + (1 - It) Y t) , m . t + («i ] We prove the result in two steps. Part (i) characterizes the efficient linear strategy in the absence of payoff externalities; this helps isolate the role of informational externalities. Part Part (i). (ii) then extends the result to general payoff structures. Suppose V (k,K,a,6) does not depend on (K,a) and, without any further loss of generality, let V (k, K, a,0) = Let ht — (k - 2 6) . {yi,A\,Ki,...,yt-\,At-i,Kt-i,yt,At} denote the public history in period agents follow a strategy k = and suppose t {k t }^=1 such that t kt {Ui,t) = Pi + Y^ Qt,rXi,r, ih) T=l where P t (ht) is a deterministic function of h t and Q tiT are deterministic coefficients. It follows that t = ki,t and hence Kt = Pt + 7t# + Vt+i, Pt where Pt + ltO + ^2, Qt,r€i,T, a shortcut for Pt (ht) and 74 is is defined as t = ^2Qt, T It - T=l Next consider welfare. Given any w =E[v t linear strategy, ex-ante utility (k hU A t+1 = )) E[v (h,u 0)} - < is Eu = *N J2t=i w t< where i+1 and where E[v(k ht ,9)} = E E = E Now consider a strategy {(p + (P + t 7t t, k = {kt}^ that pick an arbitrary function P t + Y!T=1 QtMr)~ey and any is t a variation of the and let ki iS (u>i tS ) coefficients Qt, T - Pt (ht) 43 + — initial strategy k ki tS (u>i iS ) for all s such that 5Z r =i Qt,r t h(ui,t) ,h t e-ef-J2 ,QlAr constructed as follows. First, pick an arbitrary period itO t *}2Qt, T Xi,T- < = = t. {kt}t=i Next, in 7*' an<^ ^ P . Finally, for all s > let t, s k s [Ui t = s) + / Ps [hs) Qs,r x i,r, y r=l A where the functions' are such that P By - ps (...,/?*,...) s ^ construction, at any period s - [...,kt implication the same per-period welfare level wt, as the t (h t strategy k. initial that, for all is +p k induces the same outcomes, and by the strategy t, condition for the strategy k to be efficient (h t ) t and t It follows that a necessary all ht, 2 (Pt ,(Qt,r)r=i) argmax=E -(P + lt e-e) -Y^t=1 QIA,t Pt.Qt.r e YX=\ s.t. This in turn is the case and only if Next note Kt+rjt that, because = Pt+ JtO + rj t for all if, = (l- lt )E[6\h Pt(h t ) ht t P t is t and t it all ht Q t<T = and } = Q't.r € T ' 7t _ 2 Vr. (50) public information, the observation in period t + 1 of K t = informationally equivalent to the observation of a signal is — = yt+i = - 9 + fj (51) t+ i It where r)t+\ = tt\, where Y t and posterior about 6 in period 7if 71? initial conditions Yi O [< n = <_! + = It^nt+v ^ Gaussian with mean t is iiq and ttj' a„ it + = c^ 2 a E 7Tt = 71"^ -f 71?, [6\uiit ] = ttit 2 with initial conditions X^i + 7j-i^,i ] Yt and > Similarly, the private posteriors are . -^-^x i>t + -^n, -2 = -^-Xht -i + -^-x = t 2 where x A"j, t E [0\h = 71? 71? 2 mean and precision given any follo"ws that, are defined recursively by 7Tf Ty with ~ Gaussian noise with precision &I t +i common linear strategy, the precision iS TJt+i/lt i^i and 7rf = ov iit j 44 and nf = *?_! + a-" 2 , Gaussian with Now note that a" 2 ax,j r=l 2-fj=l which together with We (50) gives conclude that a linear strategy k maximizes ex-ante Kt) = ki, t for some coefficient 7's, , t> Eu = 9). WFB - when note that, = «l)] and t all w^, (52) Tfe-Xi,t agents follow a strategy as in (52), -{^(7r?)-i ^ and hence is for all ( E[w(fc i Wfb + 7;) it if, 7 6R. To determine the optimal where - (1 only utility 1 /J*" + 2 (l-r>i) 2 1 (7r?)- } 1 + { 7i (tt?)- - (1 2 7i ) 1 (vrf)- } , the first-best level of welfare (the one obtained under complete information about Because the evolution of nf does not depend on the choice of the optimal linear strategy 74, reduces to the following problem: '"^li/l^wr'+^-^wr s.t. with = condition 7^ initial <t7 , =^ + A 7rf+1 where A4 = + a- i + a~ cr~t 2 7 is t 2 1 } V< the exogenous change in the precision of public information. Consider the value functions L4 L t (n?,n?) R+ — R+ mm = {7.}."=, s.t. For all t < N, L . t (7rf,7rf) must S=t y n s+1 74 is 2 7s «)- + 1 (l-7,) 2 ( rD- = tt« 1 7 l } J + A s + a- 2 7 2 Vs>i satisfy s.t. and hence the optimal ^ ^{ mm {7? (vrf)- L, (7rf.Tr?) defined by > : 7rf+1 1 = + (1 v 7r t - lt +A + t 1 f (Trf)" ^7 the solution to the following + /?L t+1 K 2 FOC: 1^5^4 + 1^+! ,K)--(.-,)(.r+^^=». ; 1 . -1 , 45 , +1)7r?+1 )} ^From the envelope theorem, dL t+i _ K 2 ,, -(l- 7f+1 ) +1 't+ from the low of motion Finally, for irf , 0*1+1 It follows that, for -v** N— < all i = t 2 + vrf - fi (1 - T^) Trfvrf (^+1 nff/ (nfj no more an informational Part (ii). («;*,,«*,«*,) as m (9) 74, information. with Ex Eu = where Waa < WFB must = and ^^ < 0j ' "? £ simply because this , a- 2+1 is + *? the last period and hence there V U (re, re, with V. = 0, 6) A similar re*,) (ytXit re*, let + (kj + argument re*.)# as in part (i) ensures that the = {u it ) + k*q (kJ + + (i - 7t) y*;» 4 is and public then given by ^ {& + 2 «5) /? V7 an d WKK/Waa = (re* (0) , 0,0) 1 1 (vrf)" {^f (7,) + ^ (1 - is the first-best level of welfare. — a*, we conclude 2 7,) W)- 1 } Using the mi £ £? s.t. ^K _1 2 , vrf+1 = Trf ("f ) + A, + + (re* (i + - <**) (1 2 re*.) (tt? .tt?) = min{ 7 2 s.t. The FOC 1 (Trf)" 7rf+1 = + (1 ttJVj - = a*) Trf (1 - 2 7i +A + t ) - it? KT 1 t, we have KT* + ^+1 (*?+i,*l+i)} (re* + 2 re*;) a" 2 ^2 for 74 gives 7, «,- - (1 -Od- W)- + 7,) 46 } a~ 2 7i2 V* Letting Lj (Trf,^) denote the associated value function in period t fact that that the optimal 7's must solve the following problem: L is satisfy £f=1 t_1 max V arg and Y* are the relevant sufficient statistics of available private ante utility Wfb + Wkk 0, .Xji = (^S) replacing h some ix Consider now the more general payoffs efficient linear strategy for v + N ) > "2 ) externality. re* with satisfies t 11 ^= N, j 7T = rrf Finally, for 2 .,.. the optimal 1, )- ^^=0. The envelope condition for nf+1 gives 8L d7T t+i while the law of motion for = -(l-^)(l-7t + ifW+1 )" +1 gives 7r^ = It follows 2 (kJ + k*2 ) 2 °J+1 7t- that the optimal 7's satisfy ** 7 (l-<**)*f =" tt? + (1 - a*) Trf - 0(1 - a*) (1 - t^) 2 Trf tt? 2 (tiJ^)" (/cf + k*2 ) 2 a~ 2t+l ' which completes the proof. Proof of Proposition 12. Let {ft*}u=i be the coefficients that characterize the efficient linear strategy as in Proposition 11 and let {7ff,7rJ'} _ f 1 and public information generated by the letting a£* The efficient linear strategy. result then follows from be the unique solution to (l-ar>f (l-arw+Tr? In fact, be the corresponding precisions of private it is 7i then and only then the unique solution to (20) coincides with the strategy obtained in Proposition 11. Proof of Corollary Gaussian signals studied 12, where it is shown 7. Consider the environments with both exogenous and endogenous in Section 6. The that, for all periods from the proof of Proposition result follows directly t, the present-value welfare losses the efficient linear strategy are decreasing functions of public information available in the beginning of period t. irf L t and n^ the precisions , obtained along of private and Putting aside informational externalities, the result can also be established for non-Gaussian signals using a Blackwell-like argument for the planner's problem that characterizes the efficient strategy. 47 References [1] Amador, Manuel, and Pierre-Olivier Weill (2007), "Learning from Private and Public obser- vations of Others' Actions," Stanford University /UCLA mimeo. [2] Amato, Jeffrey, and Hyun Song Shin (2006), "Imperfect mation Value of Prices," Economic Theory [3] Common Knowledge and the Infor- 27, 213-241. Angeletos, George-Marios, and Alessandro Pavan (2004), "Transparency of Information and Coordination in Economies with Investment Complementarities," American Economic Review 94, 91-98 [4] (AEA P&P). Angeletos, George-Marios, and Alessandro Pavan (2007), "Efficient Use of Information and Social Value of Information," Econometrica 75:4, 1103-1142. [5] Angeletos, George-Marios and Alessandro Pavan (2007b), "Socially Optimal Coordination: Characterization and Policy Implications," Journal of the European Economic Association, 5:2-3, 585-593. [6] Angeletos, George-Marios, Guido Lorenzoni, and Alessandro Pavan (2007), "Wall Street and Silicon Valley: [7] A Delicate Interaction," MIT and Northwestern mimeo. Baeriswyl, Romain, and Camille Cornand (2007), "Monetary Policy and its Informative Value," University of Munich/Universite Louis Pasteur mimeo. [8] Bacchetta, Philippe, and Eric van Wincoop (2005), "Can Information Heterogeneity Explain the Exchange Rate Determination Puzzle?," Ameri.can [9] Barro, Robert (1979), omy [10] "On the Determination of the Public Debt," Journal of Political Econ- Chari, V.V., Lawrence Christiano, and Patrick Kehoe Economy (1994), " NBER "Optimal Fiscal Policy in a 102, 617-652. Golosov, Michael, Aleh Tsyvinski and Ivan Werning (2006), Guide, [12] 95. 87, 940-71. Business Cycle Model," Journal of Political [11] Economic Review "New Public Finance: A User's Macroeconomics Annual 2006. Hayek, Friedreich A. (1945), "The Use of Knowledge in Society," American Economic Review 35. [13] Hellwig, Christian (2005), UCLA "Heterogeneous Information and the Benefits of Transparency," mimeo. 48 [14] Heinemann, Prank, and Camille Cornand (2006), "Optimal Degree of Public Information Dis- semination," Economic Journal, forthcoming. [15] Kocherlakota, Narayana "Advances (2005), in Dynamic Optimal Taxation," 9th World Congress of the Econometric Society. Demand MIT [16] Lorenzoni, Guido (2006), "A Theory of [17] Lorenzoni, Guido (2007), "News Shocks and Optimal Monetary Policy," [18] Lucas, Robert E., Jr. (1972), "Expectations and the Neutrality of Money," Journal of Economic Theory [19] 4, Shocks," Lucas, Robert E., mimeo. and Nancy Jr., L. Stokey (1983), "Optimal Fiscal and Monetary Policy in 12, 55-93. Mackowiak, Bartosz, and Mirko Wiederholt (2007) "Optimal Sticky Prices under Rational Inattention," [21] MIT 103-124. an Economy without Capital," Journal of Monetary Economics [20] mimeo. Humboldt University/Northwestern University mimeo. Hyun Song Shin Morris, Stephen, and (2005), "Central Bank Transparency and the Signal Value of Prices," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity. [22] Hyun Song Shin Morris, Stephen, and American Economic Review [23] Phelps, Edmund (2002), The New Microeconomics tion Theory," in A. A. Alchian, C.C. Holt et [24] Raith, Michael (1996), Economic Theory [25] al., in Employment and Infla- Microeconomic Foundations of Employment York: Norton. "A General Model of Information Sharing in Oligopoly," Journal of 71, 260-288. Roca, Mauro (2006), "Transparency and Monetary Policy with Imperfect edge," [26] New of Public Information," 92, 1521-1534. (1970), "Introduction: and Inflation Theory, "The Social Value Common Knowl- Columbia University mimeo. Svensson, Lars (2005), "The Social Value of Public Information: Morris and Shin (2002) is Actually Pro Transparency, Not Con," forthcoming in American Economic Review. [27] Townsend, Robert M. (1983), "Forecasting the Forecasts of Others," Journal of Political Econ- omy [28] 91, 546-588. Vives, Xavier (1984), "Duopoly Information Equilibrium: Cournot and Bertrand," Journal of Economic Theory 34(1), 71-94. 49 [29] Vives, Xavier (1988), "Aggregation of Information in Large Cournot Markets, " Econometrica 56, 851-876. [30] Vives, Xavier (1993), "How Fast Do Rational Agents Learn?" Review of Economic Studies 60, 329-347. [31] Vives, Xavier (1997), Behavior [32] "Learning from Others: Games and Economic 20, 177-200. Woodford, Michael (2002), "Imperfect icy," in P. a Welfare Analysis," Aghion, R. Frydman, and Expectations in Common Knowledge and J. Stiglitz, and M. Woodford, Modern Macroeconomics: In Honor of the Effects of Monetary Pol- eds., Edmund Knowledge, Information, S. Phelps, Princeton Uni- versity Press. [33] Woodford, Michael (2005), "Central Bank Communication and Policy Effectiveness," paper given at the 2005 Symposium of the Federal The Greenspan Era: Lessons for the Future. 50 Reserve Bank of Kansas City at Jacksons Hole,