MIT LIBRARIES DUPL 3 TDflO 1 00582627 T Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium IVIember Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/productiontheoreOOfish working paper department of economics PRODUCTION-THEORETIC INPUT PRICE INDICES AND THE MEASUREMENT OF REAL AGGREGATE INPUT USE Franklin M, Fisher Number 384 July 1985 massachusetts institute of technology 50 memorial drive Cambridge, mass. 021 39 PRODUCTION-THEORETIC INPUT PRICE INDICES AND THE MEASUREMENT OF REAL AGGREGATE INPUT USE Franklin M. Fisher Number 384 July 1985 I JAN 2 5 f^f^o PROD UCTION-THEORE TIC TN PIIT PRTCE INDICES AND THE MEASUREME NT OF REAL AGGREGATE INPUT USE Franklin M. Fisher Massachusetts Institute of Technology* * Paper prepared for the Fourth Karlsruhe Seminar on surement in Economics (Theory and Application of 1985. I Indices) MeaJuly , am indebted to Karl Shell for helpful conversations but retain responsibility for error. 1 Index number . theory, Introduction and the theory of price indices particular, tends to run in terms of arithmetic properties. questions as whether ty or a however, The particular index satisfies reversal test are well discussed and understood. are, a Important relatively well discussions they are only one side of the index number story. V7hat are I shall term the economic theory we trying to measure? if we had all the information possible? we Such chain proper- as such properties and such other side lies in what index numbers: a in V7hat of would we do if anything, are attempting to approximate with the index numbers computed in What, practice? In the case of the theory of the individual consumer, sure, the economic theory of index numbers is v/ell to be established. We are accustomed to regarding computed cost-of-living indices as to the ratio of expenditures required to attain a approximations unchanging indifference curve at base and current given Where the analytic questions are properly asked, be prices. the theory can extended to cast light on what to do in the presence of taste and quality change. (See, for example, Fisher and Shell 1972, While the aggregation problems accompanying an Essay I.) exten- sion to many consumers are formidable, they present no problem of principle. The situation is somewhat different when we turn the to production side of the economy and the measurement of real output and input. there is relatively little agreement Here analytic basis for index numbers. Indeed, the on the notion that what one means by aggregate real output is a Laspeyres output index is ^^irly widespread. meaning for words, own production light established knew theory can cast on the the usage, questions that index Putting aside the question of what index numbers would one compute if one prices and technology perfectly but had to summarize on the one hand or factor prices and inputs on the other outputs pair of aggregate measures. a what it is still appropriate to inquire are supposed to answer. numbers in Yet while anyone is free to choose his or her problem Only by thinking about in this way can one investigate the strengths and the weak- nesses of actually computable indices as approximations to analy- tically satisfactory constructs. More than along these lines a decade ago, Karl Shell and (Fisher and Shell 1972, I began Essay II) . thinking We consi- the production-theoretic foundation for dered presented and to which we still adhere) (and is that real output must to a given technology, relative fined deflation The position that we number of results. a output took de- be with points on the same production possibility frontier (PPF) considered as involving the same real output. This leads to a theory of output deflation that is isomorphic to the theory of the cost-of-living index. We developed that theory on the assumption that the money output be is that of an entire closed economy but have deflated since gone on to consider the more complex case in which inputs can purchased by the productive unit involved (Fisher to be Shell and 1981). shall not discuss that work in detail but shall follow I a closely related subject. Upon reading a the output-deflation section of our book, pointed of deflation use preliminary version of John Muellbauer (1972) case out that an isomorphic theory can be built for the input — up That topic deflation and proceeded to do so. — of inputs and the measurement of real aggregate Dealing is the subject of the present paper. with the input the conceptual problems involved casts light on the parallel problems of output deflation; further, there are some interesting new results to present. 2. I cing Ne .a5uring-Re.aI_Aggregi begin with the simplest case, that of one output from several inputs with a a single firm produ- well-behaved neo- classical production function. Any solution to the problem of measuring real aggregate . use must begin with an answer to the input following question: Since we shall be reducing input vectors to index-number scalars, and since we wish to obtain a complete ordering for the resulting and the input vectors to which they correspond, scalars choose a set of equivalence classes for input vectors such all vectors in the same equivalent class will be said to the same aggregate input. question this isoquants classes. immediately of the With a suggests itself production function given technology, involve to the answer to — use the define the In a Figure equivalence input we will say that two pure price phenomenon. 1, the base-period isoquant is drawn with w, represented by the solid line. input use is v, and total input costs C For aggre- then any change in money input costs will be period factor prices, 1. the If factor prices change and the firm remains on same isoquant, considered as this of vectors corresponding to the same output involve the same gate input use. that How is this to be done? the case of the single-output firm, In we must ease of notation, I baseOptimal In the current = wv. when omit transposition signs writing inner products, relying on the context to make clear what is intended. period, Actual Had factor prices, w, are dashed denoted by the factor usage is v* and actual money costs are C* factor prices been w instead of w in the base lines. = period, output corresponding to the base-period isoquant would have efficiently would v;v* the been produced with inputs v rather than v and money costs have been C rather than C. The view of inout-def lation Figure taken is that the change in costs from C to C* here should be thought of as: C*/C = {C*/C) (C/C) (2.1) with the first factor the increase in real aggregate input usage and the second reflecting price changes. [Figure general more In where C{w, x), base-period x x, input costs as C(w, money here] let the firm's cost terms, and calculates the deflator x)/C(w, be uses money for This deflator is divided into x). aggregate costs to give the measure of real input function The construction just given is output. output, 1 input usage relative to the base period. Obviously, this approach will lead to a largely theory isomorphic to that of the cost-of-living index (as well as to the Fisher-Shell theory of output deflation) In considering . therefore, sible objections to the theory being advanced, well consider to what those same objections imply Consideration it is about well-established theory of the cost-of-living relatively pos- the index. of such objections leads to insight as to what is involved in the present analysis. The first such objection is conceptual. The procedure just described treats input vectors as identical if they can the output same isoquant as and treats a an input increase. movement to of outputs higher-numbered But we are trying to theory of input aggregation and measurement. levels a become central to the produce build a Is it not odd that theory? Moreover, . firms with different technologies facing the same different of set input prices will have different factor price deflators con- structed for them. The answer lies in consideration of the object of the enter- We prise. are treating the firm as the object of interest with factor prices given from outside. 2 Any production-theoretic Cases of monopsony can also be treated but are irrelevant 2. to the present discussion. of input deflation must involve the production function view as the cost-of-living Just firm. the index describes of price changes from the point of view of the individual consumer, so the production-theoretic input price index describes factor changes from the point of view of the individual firm. that different firms have different points of view, is not a valid objection. price The fact so to speak, The aggregation problem to which it points cannot be solved by choosing a firm-independent measure of input prices. To do that is merely to impose on all firms a measure not relevant to any one of them." 3. interest To say this is not, in of course, to say that there is no the variation of the production-theoretic index the production function varies over firms (or as changes over time) Some results on such variation are presented below. D.QC[.££ieity.. and- Rela te d.. Pr o p^jtj. £s The second objection to the approach taken here is more troublesome, at least at first glance. somewhat Suppose that input V, Figure 2 prices change but that it just so happens that the usage of every changes in the same proportion, factor so that the actual input point in the current period is on the ray through v in Figure To that the usage of every does not lead to a exactly aggregate measure of increase in usage which doubles. input input It is evident that the production-theoretic view taken doubles. here suppose ideas, fix In terms of Figure usage will be said to increase by > input real 2, factor of C*/C a real 2, and it is easy to see that the sense of the inequality is no accident. Because 4. 2. duction-theoretic a Laspeyres price index must bound input-price deflator from above, aggregate C*/(C*/2), the The Paasche quantity input index from below. pro- the corre- production-theoretic Paasche quantity index bounds the sponding 4 index, is obviously 2, however. the production-theoretic index of aggregate input usage is Hence not homogeneous of degree one in the inputs being aggregated. [Figure 2 here] This objection was made by Diewert (1983, parallel glance, theory of the measurement of it seems a telling one. real pp. 16-26) output. to the At first Careful consideration, however, reveals that its force is far less than first appears. Suppose first that the technology is one of constant returns and that there has been no technological change between the and the current periods. must be however, Then the isoquant through the point 2v parallel along rays to that through v. the base situation pictured in Figure 2 In that cannot occur. case, In such circumstances, the only way that 2v can be the input point for the current period is if relative input prices do not change. But if relative input prices do not change, see that sensible then it is easy production-theoretic approach (like the every approach in such circumstances) will lead to an usage index of other input- 2. Now suppose (still with no technical change) that the nology does not exhibit constant returns. homothetic, the situation pictured tech- If the isoquant map is in Figure 2 in more general circumstances, however, occur; to cannot still Once one it can. leaves constant returns, however, it ceases to be obvious that it is desirable geneous of for an index of aggregate input use degree one in the individual homo- be to Inputs inputs. are The measure- important because they are employed in production. ment of aggregate input usage properly ought to be from the point of view of that employment. under- Without homotheticity in the lying technology it is not at all clear why movements along a ray should play any special role in aggregate input measurement. If this view that doubling does not mean doubling seems hard to swallow, consider the parallel issue that arises in the theory of the cost-of-living index. could that There is nothing about Figure not apply to that theory with isoquants being replaced by indifference curves and expenditures. in the little returns, case of the cost-of-living index, interest is in homothetic maps and none at all in so situations such as Figure the exception. there In such a context, 2 and 2 costs Indeed, relatively constant are the rule rather than one surely hesitates to insist that doubling of the consumption of every commodity musi mean a doubling of real income. Yet the apparent appeal of the homogen- property is every bit as strong in the consumer context eity — a as precisely because that appeal rests in the production one no consideration of the context involved or the question on being asked. This is, of course, not to say that the homogeneity property may not be an interesting one. an One can perfectly well construct input index by asking by what factor the current-period input must vector quant. 5 be multiplied to place it on the base period iso- Such a construction guarantees the homogeneity property, Diewert (1983, approach. case of real output measurement this the In 5. He 18) p. terms the is what "Malmquist-Bergson-Moorsteen" gives an extensive bibliography and discussion of these matters in that context. but concentrates homothetic on movements along a isoquant maps, Once ray. it is not clear why leaves one such movements should be of special interest. One can different period way. input think of such a ray-centered Instead construction of asking by v/hat factor the point must be multiplied to place it on in a current the base period isoquant, ask the equivalent question: By what factor must the base period isoquant be expanded (or contracted) along rays to pass through the current-period input parallel point. Ob- viously, this amounts to the same thing. Thinking about matters in this way, however, points up the difference between such an approach and the one taken here. The Figure 3 real input index constructed in the theory here aggregate to By what factor must the base isoquant be expanded (or contracted) parallel along rays espoused period the question: answers become tangent to the isocost line at the new prices the new input point? unchanging) this construction gives the (and answer does the ray-centered one. as , lacking (or the isoquant map changes) [Figure 3 , Where here] ray-cen- The where ray through the current-period input point crosses the period isoquant. In effect, base it begins by asking the question: What would inputs have been in the base period had the firm restricted is the answers are different. construction takes as its reference point the point tered same homotheticity difference can be seen in another way. That through Where the isoquant map is (See Figure 3.) homothetic the being to the current period's input proportions? By been con- trast, the production-theoretic index takes as its base point the point on the base-period isoquant where that isoquant is to an prices. isocost line corresponding to the current period's In effect, it begins by asking the question: inputs have been in the base period had the firm period input interesting, prices? but I input What would faced current Both ways of looking at the problem believe the approach taken here is much of an economics-oriented one. (as tangent are more Certainly it lends itself readily the ray-centered approach does not) to an accompanying theory of input-price deflation. Having said all this, I should point out that much of 10 the comparative-static analysis given below is of interest primarily the case of homothetic technologies. in under homotheticity As already observed, if the technology does not change, both the , ray-centered approach and the one used here give the same answers and the real aggregate input use index here constructed does in fact have the homogeneity property. what if technology does change between the base But and the current period? tion-theoretic surprisingly, there is a approach despite Here the ray-centered and the will give different answers. period producPerhaps the failure of homogeneity of degree one, powerful case to be made that the answers the of production-theoretic approach are superior. The reason for every this lies in the fact that way of constructing a real input-usage index implies the construction of a corresponding input-price deflator and conversely. considering must the properties of any approach to the Hence, problem, in one consider the properties of both price and quantity indices, not merely the properties of only one of them. Implicit input vector in the idea that homogeneity of degree one in the is a desirable property for a real input index is the view that a weaker property is even more naturally desirable: The measure vector of aggregate input should not change if Parallel to this is itself does not change. statement about the input-price deflator: the a input similar The input price defla- tor should not change if input prices do not change (and, we may add, should be homogeneous of degree one in those prices). In addition, one wants the two indices natural consistency properties. In particular, 11 to have certain it is natural to the "circle property". require price the should have the property that the change in relative input index prices in In terms of prices, from situation A to situation B multiplied by the change relative prices from situation B to situation C should equal the change in relative prices from situation A to situation C. A similar property should hold for the index of real input usage. Unfortunately, one cannot have all these desirable properIn particular: ties at the same time. Theorem 3.1: A. The production-theoretic input-price deflator and its associated index . of real input use are the only indices having the circle property and also the following properties: 1. relative change in the index of factor The prices multiplied by the relative change in the index of real input usage equals the relative change in expenditures on inputs. 2. base With an unchanging technology, a movement along the period isoquant leaves the index of real usage input unchanged. 3. The index of factor prices does not change if factor prices remain constant. In addition, the production-theoretic input-price deflator is homogeneous of degree one in the input prices. B. There exists no way of constructing a pair of input- price and real input-usage indices that have properties 1-3 just given, the circle property, and also the following property: 4. inputs The index of real input usage does not remain constant. change which lead to those amounts chosen. 12 if being , Proof. It A. obvious that the indices resulting is production-theoretic the resulting input-price Figure 1 once again. isoquant, period property from C to C* is entirely shown (as property by 3 two points. from costs is Consi- Since v and v both lie on the base- implies that the movement in costs 2 price phenomenon. a pro- deflator obviously homogeneous of degree one in the input prices. der the approach have the circle property and Further, 1-3. perties from the dashed lines) Since input prices are the same at v as at implies that there is no price change between v* those Hence, by the circle property, the movement of money C to C* is entirely a change in real usage. input This division of the movement from C to C* into monetary and real changes, however, (See equation approach. B. that is In that just of the production-theoretic (2.1).) view of part A of the theorem, it suffices to the production-theoretic approach does not have property 4. Consider Figure 4. Here, the technology changes between the base and the current periods, and it just so happens that input usage remains at v despite the fact that relative input prices (Obviously, this requires a however, will The still the change in money costs from C to C a pure price phenome- non and the change from C to C* an increase in real input It change. change in the isoquant map.) production-theoretic input-price deflator, call show follows that real input usage will- be said to from V to V*, violating property [Figure 13 4. 4 here] have usage. changed soquant Figure 4 Lest violation of property the 4 just exemplified be considered particularly damaging, proof examine the situation in Figure property between corresponding 4 4 it is instructive to In Figure input usage at v is the same as at v. real approach (the ray-centered one, perty and 4 prices the 4, costs C and C* are the same. to contradiction again to see the and property 3. the in By property It follows that 2, any that satisfies pro- for example) has real input usage the same at v* as at must v the change in costs from C to C* as purely monetary describe property satisfy property. to such 1 and the circle approach will show a change in input prices between the situation corresponding C and that corresponding to C* even though to Hence any no input price changes. Thus, and 4 the presence of properties in are contradictory. 1 properties and 2, One cannot have both an price input that depends only on input prices and an input-usage index index depends that obvious way, only on input usage, have them multiply retain the natural circle property, in along an isoquant represent no change in input Something has indices, give. In the case of Paasche the missing property is property isoquant. either to property In 3 more the case of or property 2 — or usage. Laspeyres equivalence along sophisticated approaches, must be abandoned once we 4 the and still have movements an 3 leave homotheticity and an unchanging technology. Which property should be retained? is that one is trying to do. I That depends on v/hat it take the view that input price deflation means looking at input prices from the point of view of 14 the input-using unit prices — the firm in the simplest are among the givens of that unit's problem, quantities that should be retained. then, it is property 3 the fact that the corresponding usage index will depend both on prices and reflects we If The resulting input-price index should depend only on the input prices; merely Those whereas the of input used are functions of those prices. wish to form aggregates in this context, input case. on the fact that quantities themselves quantities depend on prices. I add two points in this connection that may serve to the argument more convincing. 14A make First, we have already seen that tension between properties the 3 and does not arise 4 until leave the case of an unchanging homothetic isoquant map. homotheticity behind, leave we When we the case in favor of an input-usage index homogeneous of degree one in the input vector stops being a convincing or without a homogeneous With one. isoquant map, however, the case in favor of an input-price index homogeneous of in the input prices remains one degree convincing. cost The function continues to have that property even when the underlying isoquant map is not homothetic. consider again the case of the cost-of-living index Second, interpret and property 4 Figure 4 in that context leads to a case in consumer prices (the dashed lines) living index. Insistence as an indifference map. which on unchanging imply a change in the cost-of- Retention of property 3, on the other hand, does not do this but does lead to the proposition that the change from C to C* involves an increase in real income despite the fact that V and V* appear to be on the same base-period indifference curve. indiffe- one realizes that v* must be on a higher-numbered Once rence curve than v according to the current period's indifference property does not seem so that miap, must apply to input argument (or odd. Plainly, same the measure- output) deflation and ment. while Thus, property and 2. 4, it might be nice to have both property this is impossible in the presence of properties Certainly, the implications proach that does so are well worth investigating; fatal 1 Given that, it seems sensible to me to retain property and abandon property 4. a and 3 o^f an ap- it is far from objection that such an approach fails to make the 15 3 mea- surement of real input usage depend only on the input vector be homogeneous of degree one in the elements to fails and that of vector. 4. continue now I Ge neralizati o n to Man y Outputs with the development input-price deflator. theoretic the case of generalize a of To do so, production- the it is necessary single firm producing a single output. While the generalization to many outputs is an easy one, shall see, the straightforward. is because of the either output or input prices. the present paper, unit This as we always so possibility that of firms involved is large enough to have an aggregation on generalization to many firms is not I the effect shall avoid this issue in however, and shall assume that the productive involved is small enough so that it takes prices as In view of this, to we may as well keep on thinking of the given. produc- tive unit as a competitive firm. 6. problems See Fisher and Shell, involved in 1981, for a discussion more general situations in the of case the of output deflation. Even the case of the competitive firm, however, requires generalization to allow several outputs, and that generalization, while not hard, has some interesting features. In particular, we must ask how the underlying isoquant map is to be constructed. In the isomorphic case of output deflation, this question is 16 . that of how to construct the production possibility frontier. case, that — inputs as fixed possibility is to take the obvious one vector at least up to scalar multiplication. the approach taken in Fisher and Shell, In of (This is 1972, Essay II. Such ) is natural when dealing with output price deflation in choice closed economy, however. but it is not inevitable, a a If the pro- ductive unit being studied purchases inputs at fixed prices, for example, then it becomes natural to draw the production possibility frontier constant as the locus of outputs that can input cost. (This produced be is studied in Fisher and at Shell, 1981.) In the present case of input deflation and measurement, the isomorphic choice to that of the closed economy with fixed inputs is to take the output vector of the firm as fixed to scalar multiplication. sumption given, is no interesting problem in which output there firm, makes sense to analyze matters from it Naturally, cular changes makes a same combinations input given value of output. this makes the isoquant map depend on the parti- output prices used. in the This means fixing output prices drawing an isoquant as the locus of all that can produce propor- Rather, given that we are dealing with a compe- point of view as does the firm. and Even apart from the as- that the productive unit being analyzed takes prices as tions are fixed. titive at least up This is the choice made in Muellbauer but it is not an appealing one. (1972), — Since v;e the isoquant map on the shall study the constructed effect indices, of this it important to study the effect of changing output prices in particular 7 17 Note that the case of unchanged output prices is no differ- 7. ent from that of a single output or of fixed output so that the only difference in terms of exposition of actual index construction) terms lies in whether proportions, (but not comparative exercises are done with changing prices or with static in changing output proportions. 5. I Thg Inpjjt-Price Deflator; Foxipal Stateipgflt now give a formal description of the The givens of the problem are: the vector input-price deflator. of base-period factor prices, factor prices, output prices, w; p, production-theoretic the vector of current w; period total base-period costs, C; and the vector of the same in both periods. Production takes place according to the production function: F(x, V) (5.1) where x vector = is the vector of outputs produced by the firm and v of inputs it uses. Hats will be used to describe period values. Consider the solution to the following problem: (5.2) Maximize y h px subject to F(x, v) = and wv = C Call the resulting value of y, y. Next, solve the following problem: 18 the base- , Minimize C (5.3) = wv subject to F(x, v) = and px = y production-theoretic The input-price deflator is then the ratio, J = C/C. comments are in order. Some First, the solution the to problem in (5.2) amounts to finding the isoquant (for the production value, of base-period in (5.3) tangent to the plane input prices and cost. corresponding period's factor prices, w. This construction readily seen to be equivalent to that in Figure 1 at is above. for beginning with the maximization problem in instead of directly with the base period's isoquant has to reason The (5.2) to The solution to the problem then takes that isoquant and minimizes cost along it current the y = px) do with the analysis of comparative statics given below. Since we shall wish to ask how the deflator index of real input usage) would differ if the isoquant map were ferent, picks it out structed. is necessary to have a (and its associated method which the con- isoquant map is the actual base-period one, then this will be the actual base-period isoquant. will the isoquant tangent to the be unambiguously be the isoquant with which the deflator is If dif- period factor prices and costs. plane to Otherwise, it representing base- This approach is consonant with the general view that the givens of the problem are factor prices and base-period costs (current-period costs are to be deflated) not actual base-period inputs. Next, tions. the deflator can be defined in terms of cost func- Remem.bering that "output" here is really y, we can think 19 of the firms cost function as C(w, y) revenue, period C(w, y)/C(w, y) deflator the This . static analysis, is readily be to comparative as is the more extensive description above because it presupposes that the given seen base is not so helpful for form however, Letting y be actual . "output", will y, remain the same when the isoquant map changes. It is obvious that, as in the case of the index, the input-price deflator here defined the Laspeyres price index, by both J and L are the same (C) L = wv/wv. is the cost of doing so by using glance at Figure line 1 index The denominators of however, is while the numerator of base-period inputs, v. (A will confirm that the cost of v at the dashedIt follows that the production- prices is greater than C.) theoretic is bounded above The numerator of J, . the minimum cost of producing "output" y, L (J) cost-of-living of real input usage is bounded below the by Paasche quantity index, wv/wv. Now, the whole exposition so far has used the isoquant to make comparisons. made to Equally valid comparisons can using the current-period isoquant. that base-period just given shows that the be An analysis isomorphic production-theoretic input price deflator formed using the current-period isoquant is bounded below by the Paasche input-price index, P = wv/wv, while the corresponding production-theoretic index of input usage is bounded above by the Laspeyres quantity index, wv/wv. If the isoquant map is homothetic and unchanging, production-theoretic and indices that use the base-period then the isoquant those that use the current-period isoquant will be the same. 20 the production-theoretic input-price deflator will In that case, be bounded below by L and above by P, with a similar statement holding for the index of input usage. While the assumption of homotheticity is however, interest, the assumption of an unchanging isoquant map Merely a change in relative output prices will alter the is not. isoquant map and may destroy the relation between index and the deflator constructed using price considerable of isoquant (and similarly for other inequalities) Paasche the base-period the One important . way of looking at the comparative static analysis given below is thus as an analysis of the ways in which the production-theoretic indices using the current-period isoquant differ from those using the be base-period isoquant and of the changes that must therefore made in the Paasche input-price index to restore the bounding inequality. 8. should course, the same analysis gives the changes be made in a Laspeyres input-price index to relation the Of restore to the production-theoretic deflator constructed current-period isoquant. things like this, and Notice, I It is tedious to keep that its using repeating shall not do so henceforth. however, that such an interpretation of comparative statics requires that the inequalities in question apply if there is no change in the isoquant map. This means that either the homothe- base period or the current-period isoquant map must be tic. Since such homotheticity is the interesting leading case, I shall assume it for the rest of this paper, pointing out where it is needed explicitly for purposes other than the 21 interpretation of results just discussed. 9. ty 9 The assumption involved is weaker than that of homogeneiof the production function (of any degree) little point in going into details here, however. Shell (1981, 80-81) pp. There seems (5.1). See Fisher and for a discussion of the parallel issues in the case of output price deflation. the comparative static analysis given below Of course, be viewed as interesting in itself. deflator can It shows the ways in which constructed from the point of view of one firm differs from that constructed from the the (and the input-usage index) point of view of another. For this purpose, homotheticity is not required except where stated explicitly below. Comparative Statics: Changing Output Prices 6. now turn to I leading case of comparative static analysis a to exemplify what is involved therein. exhibit the Lagrrangians for and (5.2) It will be convenient to (5.3), respectively. They are: A px + 7f{x, V) L = (6.1) - (1/V) (wv - C) and L (6.2) = wv + (^F(x, V) - kipx - y) A Here, one (\ ' being K ' M- ' written ^^^ {1/lc ) are Lagrange multipliers, the last as a reciprocal for reasons of interpretation. 22 symmetry of already remarked, As the obvious first case to examine that of a change in one of the output prices, p. lO.c.l, pp. 82-83) . A. '^ Thsozsm-^^lj- c/^ Pj^ = y^i\ ~ We prove the . following theorem (isomorphic to Fisher and Shell unchanged), prices would Theorem 1981, ^k^ If a rise in the price of the ith factor, w. B. is (with output increase (reduce) output of the kth good, given the base-period isoquant, then a rise in the price of the good will reduce (increase) the importance of kth the ith factor price in the production-theoretic input-price deflator. Proof: (6.1) A. Apply the Envelope Theorem first to (6.2) and then to obtaining: , 9 (6.3) C/3 p^ = 9 L/9 P;^ =7^(^k = --/4x^ B. - V L/9 Pj^) = Pk^ y<^x^ - Xj^) . Suppose a rise in w. would increase production of the kth given the base-period isoquant. good, ^^/^ ~ Consider such rise from a the base to the current period, with all other factor prices held constant. Then the input-price deflator must be greater than one the comparison is made using the isoquant map before the whether output price change or using the isoquant map after that production of the kth good goes up, Since isoquant, tive x. > x, (It is the theorem . given the base-period Since the Lagrange multiplier, marginal cost of "output", change. y.)^ /<^ , is posi- part A of the lower if map after the output price change is used than if implies that the input-price deflator must be the isoquant the isoquant map before the output price change is. 23 Since the only factor price that changes is w., of increase in an p. input-price deflator. which a it follows that the effect is to reduce the importance of w. (A in the similar analysis applies to the case in rise in w. decreases production of the kth given good, the base-period isoquant.) way It is illuminating to relate these results directly to in which the weights in Paasche input-price a shift with changes in output prices. (isomorphic, lemmas two Proof ; would index To do this, we first prove respectively, Lemmas to lO.c.l and 84-85 of Fisher and Shell, 1981). 10. c. 2, pp. I,emma 6.1: the Under homotheticity '^/p , w^ i^(v^/C). = ~ Differentiating (6.2) yields 7)L/'3^i=v. (6.4) pL/'Py =/^ ; . Hence (6.5) ?/</9wi = '>V9y'3w. Now, we can evaluate () O ^ i/ u^'i that is, consider ^ / c) Y v/hat = ii^ 5v./pJ . two steps. First, consider happens to employment of the ith factor as costs increase with factor prices constant. theticity, it suffices this is just v./C. to evaluate To evaluate ^C/a y. (6.6) ^v./?y= //{, (^ v./pC) (^C/^y) and the lemma now follows from (6.4) 24 and homo- (yv./t)y, therefore, From the applied to (6.2), however, this is just By Envelope Hence . = /^(w./C), (6.5). Theorem , : Under homotheticity fi.2: r.pTnTTia Proof; , Differentiate (6.2) with respect to treating C as a constant) ^ L/3w. (6.7) w. and p, (this time to obtain: = V. 9l,/Pp^ ; -/^x^ = Hence (o . b) ^Pk^^i Pk ^ 9 ^k 9 ^i _ jA^\Ci. where the last step follows from Lemma 6.1. We can now prove (isomorphic to Theorem 10. c. 2 of Fisher and Shell 1981, p. 86) Theorem 6.2 : Under homotheticity 9 (V /C) ^ - Q ^ (^/C)(^x^/^w.) - Proof: 9(v./C) (6.9) ^ C(Pv./^p.) k 1 '' ?Pk C -^/^(?x^/^ w.) - - V 1 (Pc/Pp,) K 2 (/^x^v./C) /^^i>^i C2 25 . = - U^/C) {')'i^^/? w.) using Lemma 6.2 and applying the Envelope Theorem to (6.2). Combining this with Theorem 6.1, p, we see that an increase in will increase the importance of w. in the input-price deflator if and only if the "weight", in naturally associated with w. of total costs is also increased. index an v./C, This sort of duality is typical of comparative static results in this area. Although 10. restricted it seems unlikely that such relationships are to the case of homothetic technologies, unable to find a I have been proof of Theorem 6.2 that does not make explicit use of homotheticity A great many other comparative results can be particular, case given the In results just given can be adapted to cover the of a Hicks-neutral technical change in the production of The presentation of such particular results output. have to await the proved. a different occasion, however, for I will want to remaining space to return to ,ore general problems — a use those of aggregation. 7. There considered. are Aggregation over Input Prices two types of aggregation problem can be These are aggregation over input prices and aggrega- tion over firms (or industries or sectors) . with the question of output-price deflation, aggregation that When one is dealing these two types of tend to coincide because it is natural to associate 26 particular kinds of output with particular firms. with input-price deflation, on the other hand, When dealing the two types of aggregation problem are less naturally associated, and it is best to take them up separately. begin by considering aggregation I over input prices. The production-theoretic input-price index can be written as a function of current-period factor prices, holding base-period factor prices fixed: J = J(w^, (7.1) . . w^) , that we wish to form an aggregate of the first Suppose prices, . 1 t < r, < so that J can be written as J = H(A(w^, (7.2) where A(.) . . ., w^) , w^_^^, theorem (Leontief, . . ., Wj.) , By Leontief's well-known is a scalar-valued function. aggregation factor t this can be done if 1947), and only if Q(J./J.) ^_^ (7.3) ^ where J. = ^ k Wj^ /)j/Qw.. l,...,t; = (i,j = = t+1, . . . ,r) , This means that the J-constant rate of substitution between any pair of prices in the marginal aggregate must be independent of any price not in the aggregate. Now, application of the Envelope Theorem to (6.2) above shows that (7.4) J./Jj = v./v^ (i,j Hence (7.3) requires that changes in in which v. and v. are emploved. 27 w, = l,...,t). leave unchanged the ratio It follov/s that such ratios can . depend only on the first t factor prices, the ones to be included Under homotheticity in the aggregate. that dependence will be , on the t-1 ratios of the factor prices to be aggregated. Now such price ratios, substitution of rates in production among the in the aggregate. included of course, will also be the marginal factors be to Since the employment of any factor not so included certainly depends on that factor's own price, the aggregation condition just described is equivalent to the the marginal rates of substituion among that tion cluded aggregate be independent of the in A second application not Theorem now shows that aggregation over the first is so included. factors in- employment the factors condi- of Leontief's of input prices t possible if and only if the efficient production surface can be written as: = F(x, (7.5) where v) = G(x, B(v^, . . ., v^) is scalar-valued and homothetic B(.) , v^_^^ , . v^) ., . , property (the latter being guaranteed if the underlying technology is homothetic) In other words, theoretic input-price corresponding factor factor-price aggregation in the productiondeflator is possible if and only aggregation is possible in the if the production function itself. If simply to say. the productive unit under study is a firm given as its efficient technology, If, and F(., .) there is nothing more however, the productive unit is an aggregate and its efficient technology built up from the technologies of underlying firms by allocating a total stock of factors and assigning 28 out- by allocating a total stock of factors and assigning firms puts to achieve efficient production, more that can be said. the literature, and the conditions that permit such See, for example, Fisher Schworm (198^) great deal a That case has been extensively studied in 12 shown to be extremely restrictive. 11. then there is out- aggregation It follows that aggregation (1969, 1982) and Blackorby and . of factor prices in the production-theoretic input-price deflator is unlikely to be possible. 8. Vertical Aagreaation over Productive Units The other type of aggregation problem is that of aggregation over productive units. over units that do not buy or sell from each other or Here there are two Horizontal or one units that ("vertical" aggregation). conglomerate aggregation that are beyond the scope of the present paper. easy ("horizontal" "conglomerate" aggregation) and aggregation over trade directly with each other as aggregation cases: problems presents That is because includes more and more productive units it becomes less indepen- to maintain the assumption that output prices are dent of the activities of the aggregate productive unit. General shall not for a discussion of the isomorphic problem of output deflation when input prices are not equilibrium considerations come to the fore, and I discuss such considerations here. 12 12. See Fisher and Shell, 1981, independent of the activities of the productive unit. 29 on the other hand, Vertical aggregation, raises some inte- resting questions that can be discussed here. suppose first that there are only two fix ideas, To further that the first of these Suppose involved. the Seller, suppose that the Buyer buys Finally, the "Buyer". from firms, the buys only primary factors and sells only to the second "Seller", firm, firms using no primary factors, only and sells only to consumers. Obviously, prices of the Buyer — output the prices the — the Seller. the prices of the Seller — which in — are turn in- the input prices of A sensible set of questions to ask is how to measure relative contributions of the Seller and of primary the output are influenced by the Buyer's input prices by the prices of primary factors fluenced — consumers faced by factors to inflation as seen by the Buyer and how to measure the relative contributions of primary factors, and the Buyer to it is convenient to begin with an the Seller, inflation as seen by consumers. To study such questions, even simpler case, factors stage that in which a single firm buys only primary and sells only to consumers, of production. Here, so that there is only ons an obvious thought is to calculate the single firm's production-theoretic output-price index and its production-theoretic these It input-price index and to take the ratio two indices as the contribution of the firm to is important to understand that this "obvious of inflation. thought" is totally mistaken. There relatively is more than one way to see this. formal way. The I production-theoretic 30 begin with a output-price is constructed by assuming output prices to be given index the firm by demand conditions and having the firm side in out- optimize various ways given those prices and the conditions of factor The construction of the production-theoretic input-price supply. assumes input prices to be given from on the other hand, index, the outside firm and performs certain optimization those prices and the conditions of demand as taking compare the production-theoretic output-price problems given. To input-price and indices is to take as simultaneously valid two sets of conditions can hold simultaneously only if £JA prices that outside the firm, determined are in which case the question of the firm's own contribution to inflation is vacuous. There is more to this than the fact that we have been assumthe productive unit analyzed too small to influence ing The extension of the theory to relax that assumption (whether monopoly elements are involved) still constructs the not prices. or input- price deflator by assuming input prices fixed outside the productive unit and the output-price deflator by assuming output prices so Comparison fixed. fixed outside the unit, of the two assumes both sets and this is not a of prices useful assumption in the present context. The The underlying reason for this problem is not hard to find. method suggested by the "obvious thought" cannot provide appropriate has to do answer to the question being asked. (in this example) with contributions to question inflation as Inflation as seen by consumers, however, is by the cost-of-living index and not by the production- seen by consumers measured That an . 31 theoretic output-price The latter index index. output takes prices as demand determined, as reflective of the prices at which firms can sell It is the cost-of-living index that takes output . as production determined, prices which consumers can buy as reflective of the prices at but if Each measure has its uses, . we seek to evaluate contributions to inflation as seen by consumers, it is the cost-of-living index that must be used. Once this is realized, it is possible to see how to proceed. As observed in Fisher and Shell the pp. 7-8) , as to where we take the interface between opportunity set. its activities in discussing between taste and quality changes, difference choice and (1972, there the Consumers buy goods and use them inside the household to maximize utility. side the household Some preparation, consumption rather than directly as for example) . a household activities can be considered as production activities those is in of in(food Now suppose that the productive sys- tem were organized differently with the activities now carried on in the productive unit under analysis being carried on inside the household. 13 factors Then the household would buy primary and aggregation over them in its productive activities to maximize utility. The As 13. usual, I ignore difficulties of households in the cost-of-living index. use prices it would face would be those of primary factors. cost-of-living index would be computed using those prices. parison of such living a cost-of-living index with the actual index computed using the output prices of the Its Com- cost-of- productive unit being studied thus measures the extent to v/hich that produc- 32 tive unit contributes to inflation as seen by the household. an approach seems somewhat such If Buyer and Seller. — the Consider inflation from the point of view of The relative contributions of the Seller and factor primary asking its this is measured by the Buyer's production-theoretic Buyer; input-price index. of consider to the case of two firms described earlier generalization the forced, prices can be analyzed quite naturally how different the production-theoretic input-price by index would be if the Seller did not exist and the Buyer were vertically integrated from purchase of primary factors to sale to mers. in that the Seller's output-price index plays no role (Note This is the same procedure as that this.) consu- house- involving holds but in a more familiar context. It easy to see that the same procedure applies to is restrictive cases. there is nothing in For example, requires the Buyer to use no primary inputs. it less that Whether or not such inputs are used, the comparison to be made is that of the produc- input-price index with and without vertical inte- tion-theoretic gration. Note Buyer's that and a similar procedure can be used to consumers' relative contributions inflation as seen by the Seller. to measure the output -price This might be of some interest when considering demand-pull rather than cost-push inflation. I leave the details to the reader. Now, indices it is interesting to ask hov? such vertically aggregated particular, can unaggregated indices. In the same comparison of Seller-contribution and relate to the corresponding 33 e primary-f actor-contribution to inflation as seen by the Buyer be made using the input-price index of the Buyer and the Inpiii -p r i c case the from which the Buyer buys only in Returning to One would hope that it could. index of the Seller? Seller, the input-price index reflects inflation as the Buyer's it, while the Seller Buyer sees the Seller's input-price index reflects inflation sees it — inflation as reflected in changes in prices of primary factors. the It seems natural to compare the as the two to evaluate the Seller's contribution to inflation as seen by the Buyer. Perhaps construction of an input-price index for a verti- cally integrated firm is not required. Unfortunately, given those for reasons similar this will not v/ork, earlier for the failure of the to thought." "obvious Seller's input-price index is calculated taking as given the The Seller's output prices the the the prices at which the Seller sells to But it is the change in those prices that Buyer. changes — in the Buyer's input-price index. lead to The contribution of Seller to inflation as seen by the Buyer cannot be assessed using a construct that assumes there is no such inflation. So long as we remain in the theoretical world in which there is sufficient information to construct all theoretic indices, this presents no great problem. ty of constructing a vertically aggregated production- these The difficul- production-theoretic price index is not analytically greater than that of input structing such an index without vertical integration. ference merely lies in what production processes are The con- dif- considered to be under control of the productive unit being analyzed. When we come to the question of 34 approximations used in . practice, the other hand, on the difficulties are considerably Consider in particular the use of Laspeyres input-price greater. indices above already seen that (in the simple have We 14 a ) Laspeyres input-price index for the Seller will bound Where 14. prices input productive unit is large enough the (1981, 59-68) pp. for La- firms) See Fisher and discussion of the parallel a affect to (even if it is made up of competitive and Paasche bounds do not apply. speyres considered case Shell case of output-price deflation. the production-theoretic input-price index above from Further, Seller. it for the Laspeyres is not hard to see that such a index will also bound from above the production-theoretic input- price index that would apply under vertical integration. So far so good. Unfortunately, the reason for constructing such aggregated vertically input-price index was to compare it with the tion-theoretic In practice, however, all are likely to have for the Buyer is another Laspeyres price index, this merely provides an upper and production-theoretic index we need. input-price indices merely provides produc- input-price index of the Buyer and thus to assess relative contributions to inflation. we a a bound on the Comparison of the Laspeyres for the Seller and the Buyer, comparison of two upper bounds, therefore, That compari- close approximation to the compari- son may or may not provide son of the production-theoretic input-price indices a input- 35 themselves. . and it is obviously not possible to say anything general as to the sign of the approximation error. This is, for the of course, a problem, but regard it as a problem use of Laspeyres indices and not for the theory of production-theoretic input-price index. of I As is true in the index numbers and aggregation generally, I regard it as the area im- portant to ask the right questions and examine the defects of the answers that can be given in practice. able That seems to me prefer- to tailoring the questions to suit the currently answers 36 available . Blackorby, and W. Schworm C. (1989") "Consistent Aggregation in University of Economies." Competitive f British Columbia, Department of Economics (unpublished) Diewert, W. E. "The Theory of the Output Price Index and (1983), the Measurement of Real Output Change." University of Bri- tish Columbia, Department of Economics, Discussion Paper No. 83-10. Fisher, F. M. Production "The Existence of Aggregate (1969), Functions." Econometrica 37, pp. 553-577. Fisher, F. "Aggregate Production Functions Revisited: (1982), M. The Mobility of Capital and the Rigidity of Thought." Review 615-625. of Economic Studies 49, pp. Fisher, F. M. Indices Fisher, (1972), The Econ omic The ory of Price New York: Academic Press. , F. and K. Shell M. and Shell (1981), K. Indices." Center for Analytic Research in University of Pennsylvania, Economics "Output Price CARESS Working Paper and the Social Sciences, # 81-05. Leontief , W. W. (1947) , "Introduction to a Theory of the Internal Structure of Functional Relationships." Econometrica 15, pp. 361-373. Muellbauer, J. Indices." N. J. "The Theory of True Input Price (1972), University of Warwick, Research Paper 17. 5 8 5 ii u 6 7 37 Revision of Economic g^s^'-'f^ Date Due MIT LIBRARIES 3 TOfiD DDsaeaE? t