?/ Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium IVIember Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/persistenceofvolOOpote working paper department of economics THE PEESISTEKCE OF VOLATILITI MI STOCK MAEKET rLUCTDATIOMS James M. Poterba and Lawrence H. Summers Number 553 September 1984 massachusetts institute of technology 50 memorial drive Cambridge, mass. 02139 THE PEESISTEKCE OF VOLATILITT AHD STOCI MAEKET FLUCTDATIOKS James K. Poterba and Lawrence H. Summers number 353 September 19B4 The Persistence of Volatility and Stock Market Fluctuations James M. Ppterba MIT and NBER and Lawrence H. Summers Harvard University and HBER Revised September I98U We are indebted to Carla Ponn and especially to Ignacio Mas for research assistance, to Fischer Black and Robert Me rt on for helpful discussions, and to the KBER and the HSF for financial support. This research is part of the NBER Program in Financial Markets and Monetary Economics. Seotember IQiS'- The Persistence of Volatility and Stock Market Fluctuations ABSTRAirr This paper examines the potential influence of changing volatility in stock market prices on the level of stock market prices. It demonstrates that vola- tility is only weakly serially correlated, implying that shocks to volatility do not persist. These shocks can therefore have only a small impact on stock market prices, since changes in volatility aJfect expected required rates of return for relatively short intervals. These findings lead us to be skeptical of recent claims that the stock market's poor performance during the 1970 's can he explained "by volatility-induced increases in risk premia. James M. Poterba Department of Economics Massachusetts Institute of Technology Cambridge, MA 02139 (617) 253-6673 Lawrence H. Summers Department of Economics harvard University Cambridge, MA 02138 (617) k9^-2kk-l ThiB paper examlncB the potential Influence of changing stock marKet vola- tility on the level of stock market prices. It QemonEtrates that volatility is only weakly serially correlated, implying that shocks to volatility do not persist. These shocks can therefore have only a small ingjact on stock market pri- ces, since changes in volatility affect expected required rates of return for only short intervals. These findings lead us to be skeptical of recent claims that the stock market's poor performance during the 1970 's can be explained by volatility-induced increases in risk premia, as suggested by MalXiel (1979) and Pindyck (l98'*)« They also lead us to doubt that fluctuations in risk premia associated vith changing return volatility can account for nuch of the observed variation in stock prices. The finding that volatility is not highly serially correlated is puzzling in light of Black's (1976) observation that stock market returns and changes in volatility are negatively correlated. The paper is divided into five sections. The first clarifies the theoreti- cal relationship betveen return volatility, the level of share prices, required rates of return. ajid The second section examines the time series proper- ties of stock market volatility as measured using both monthly and daily data. The results suggest that although volatility is serially correlated, changes in current volatility should have only a negligible impact on volatility forecasts over intervals as short as one or tvo years. The third and fourth sections use data on the iniplied volatilities in option premia to re-examine the persistence question, and again find evidence of only weeik serial correlation. The conclu- sion discusses the implications of our results for alternative explanations of recent stock market movements and for our understanding of the sources of asset price fluctuations more generally. 1, Volatility. Required Returns, and Stock Price Fluctuations This section discuBBes the relationship between changes in volatility and changes in the level of stock market prices. Por simplicity we assume that firms are not levered and that expected dividends grow at a constant rate. The former assumption allows us to ignore Black's (1976) important observation that the level of share prices, by affecting the degree of leverage, should have a direct impact on volatility. The latter assiimption is maintained for con- venience and could be relaxed easily. Because of the nature of the volatility estimates used in our empirical vork, ve use a discrete time formulation. We assiune that share E (P t ) - P t+1 D t ^ t ^ ^ /, is the risk-free interest rate, dividend paid in period t. = ^^ * ^.1 ^ t t where r prices satisfy the standard requirement that ^ * a is the risk premium, Equivalently, equation \K - \ * (l) and D. can be written as is the : ^2) \^t where = E (P t , t+1 J - E iP )/P t t+1 t (3) is a random disturbance assumed to be uncorrelated with any information avail- able at time t. It reflects the impact of revisions in expectations about future values of D, a, and r which take place between periods t and t+1. Equation (2) is a difference equation for P , and it can be solved forward subject to an appropriate transversality condition to yield P = t Ell t J { II j^Q \^Q T (1 + a t+i + r_)-^} t+i ]'. D t+J {k) -•^- ABBuming that the risk free rate Ib constant over time, this expression may be linearized around the mean value of a, a, to obtain: EjD - K - J, I - 1 + dP^ I 7r-^(E.ia_.] -a) • E (5) where dP ^ '^Vj Equation , » - (l*r^a)->l. I k=0 (6) . (l+r+a)^ Assuming that expected dividends grow at a constant rate future risk premia. Id. . , t+j dP ) -^^-^^^ expreBBes current stock prices as a linear function of expected (5) BO that E t (D ^ t 1 = (l+g) t -D^d+g)'' t _ ^Vj J^+t g, the derivative in (6) can be sinrplified as: » -D^d+g)'' ,^^ xk U+gJ -^^^^^ r I t = _,.. _ (l+r+a ) J ( rHQ-g ) . (l+r+a)J''^ k=0 (1+r+a)^ It is natural to postulate that a . depends on 2 , C7) . * the variance of e . We assiune for Eiirolicity that a^ = -ro; (B) vhere T is a constant of proportionality that depends on investors' levels of Merton (19T3,1980) derives a similar relationship between a^ risk aversion. and the variance of returns in a continuous -time model. .To stuify the effect of changes in volatility on P adopt some assumption about the evolution of 2 . it is necessary to We assume that o 2 follows an AR(1) process: +11. 0=p+DO t t-1 ^0 ^1 t (o) ^^' Evidence to support the AR(l) assumption is presented in subsequent sections. From and (9), it immediately follows tnat a (8) \ vhere v ' ^'O * yw \ ^^°^ The mean value of a • t t * ^iVl also follovs an AR(l) process: t is therefore TP^/d-P^ u 1 ), and the deviat- and a obeys ion between a e - a a P - (a a) + v (ll) . Equation (ll) enables us to simplify (5) substantially, since E (a Substituting this relationship into p''(a -"a). " P . I K^K^.^ -1-^ J=0 (1+r+a)'' • - = / _ — (12) J=0 (l+r+a)'^(r+a-g) D (l+r+a) t and using (T) yields D^(l+g)'^p.^(a -a) ^ _^ _ I (5) - a) = - I r + a - g D l+r+a — r 1+r+a-p (l+g) , t J* I —t— j(a^ , , —V - a) r+a-g The last expression shows the effect of risk premia shocks on share prices; XX the second term is (dP /da ) • - a). (a This may be rewritten in terms of X volatility shocks, using (8), as t - Y (l+r+a") _ dcr X , ^^^^ 1—1—1 ll+r+'a-p (l+g)] r+"a-g X or ^^°S\ 2 dlogo^ where 2 TO X t = a -^°t\ ~ Z ' 1 Il+r+-^ 1+r+a-p^ (l+g)] 1 r+a-g] is the dividend yield, D /P . t t and X^ = r^+a^-g,. (ll») Z * The numerator simplifies since _ Evaluating both expressions at a yields >^. 2" dlogcT ~ ^^^^ • ll+r+a-p tl+g)] Hotice tbat the absolute value of the derivative of share prices vith respect to current volatility rises vith p^. This result is intuitively natural. If increases in volatility are expected to persist, they vill have a greater impact on the discount factors applied to future cash flows, and therefore on share prices. In order to examine possible relationships between volatility and the level of share prices, it is useful to insert some plausible parameter values into (15). The mean annual return on common, stocks for the period 19^*6-1983 was 11.6 percent. 1 The mean nominal return on Treasury bills was ^^.6 percent per year over the same period, iaiplying an average value of 7-0 percent for average real return on Treasury bills, which we use to estimate r, was cent. The a. ,k per- The estimated variance of the market return, expressed at annual rates, ranged from 26.83 in I96U to 638.57 in 197^, averaging 238.3. The last sta- tistic in conjunction with the mean estimate for a implies a value of .029 for Tf. Merton (19BO) estimated this parameter to be .032 for the period 1952-1978, The growth rate of nominal dividends on the S&P 500 during the 19^8-1983 period vas 5.2 percent annual-ly. Combining this with our inflation rate of k,2 percent yields an average growth rate for real dividends, g, of .01. The effect of changes in volatility on the level of share prices sensitive to the level of Pi, is very The derivative in (15 ) equals -.070 when P1=0, .131 when Pl=.5, and -.1*09 when Pl=.9. We have defined Pl as the serial corre- -t>- lation in annual volatility; an annual value of Pi = .90 iurplies a monthly auto- correlation of more thaji .99. Stated another way, a 50 percent increase in market volatility from itB average level would reduce the value of the market by 3.5 percent if Pi = 0, by 6.5 percent of Pi «= .5, and by 20 percent if Pi=.9. It is clear that if fluctuationB in volatility are to play a significant role in explaining market fluctuations, then Pi must be quite large. The next two sec- tions examine the serial correlation properties of several measures of volatility. 2. Serial Correlation in Market Volatility Ab enrphaBized in Merton (ipBO), a great deal of variance estimation. vork, remains to be done on In this section, we use crude estimators for the variance of market returns to study the serial correlation properties of volatility. ^ "2 "2 use tvo estimators of market variance, c and o , computed respectively from monthly and daily returns data. We While daily data are preferable for variance estimation, they were available to us only for the 195B-8^ period. Monthly returns data were available from 1926 to 1983. Volatility Estimation Using Monthly Data 2.1 Our first variance estimator, based on monthly data, vas calculated as: ^2 ^2 % vhere = J^^^it 2 - ^it) /12 (16) denotes the annualized return on common stocks in month i of year t, s it and r IbbotBon is the Treasury bill rate. 3 Our monthly returns data were obtained from (I981t). ~2 In Table 1, ve report summary statistics on and 19^8-83. o for two periods, I926-I9B3 It is immediately clear from the autocorrelogram and partial auto- correlogram that there is no substantial positive serial correlation in market volatility. For the 19^*8-1983 period, the first order autocorrelation coef- ficient is only .lli<; for the longer 1926-83 period, it is .675. The high autocorrelation coefficient for the whole period is sensitive to the inclusion of the Depression years in the data sample. The first order autocorrelation for the sample period 1935-1983 is .50, and for the 19^0-1983 period, the estimate declines to .05. Besults similar to those for the postwar period were obtained - 8 - Table 1: Autocorrelation in Annual Stoel: Market VolatllltieB I9UB-I983 Sample 1926-1983 Sample Autocorrelation Partial Autocorrelation 0.6T5 (.131) 0.675 (.131) Lag Length (Years ) 0.269 (.131) -0.31*5 (.131) Autocorrelation 0.1ll» (.167) Partial Au t ocorrelat ion O.lll* (.167) -0.115 (.167) -0.129 (.166) -0.221* (.167) -0.200 (.167) 3 0.110 (.131) 0.206 (.131) k 0.077 (.131) -0.058 (.131) 0.233 (.166) 0.287 (.167) 5 0.11»5 (.131) 0.217 (.131) o.ooB (.160) -0.122 (.167) 6 0.215 (.131) 0.002 (.125) 0,197 (.167) 0.255 (.167) Source: Annual volatility estimates vere calculated as the average of twelve squared monthly values of the return on common stocks minus the return Treasury "bills. These data were dravn from Ibbotson (198I1) for the period I926-I983, a total of 696 observations. The second sample, for the I9I+B-I983 period, contains 1*32 observations. Standard errors are shown in parentheses. See text for further details. - 9 - using data for only the I96O-I983 period, vhen the estimated first order serial correlation coefficient was .131. Tne hypothesis that annual volatility was a vhite noise process -could be rejected at standard levels in the 19'<B-19B3 or I96O-I9BI4 periods.^ As a further check on the autocorrelation properties of our volatility "2 cBtimates, we estimated some sinrple autoregressive nodels for o^. The results, which are presented in Table 2, corroborate the conclusions reached above. They suggest no great persistence in volatility, and indicate that the simple first order autoregressive model used in the preceding section's theoretical development fits the data quite well. 5 Higher order models did not yield appreciably smaller sums of squared residuals for either sample period under consideration. The point estimates of Pi for each sample period are substantially less than unity. They imply that volatility shocks do not persist for long periods. For the I926-I9B3 sample perod, where we find the greatest amount of persistence, ninety percent of a volatility shock will have dissipated after the shock. required. tsf six years In the AR(2) case for this period, only four years are The half life of the shock, the time required to move half way back to the long-run equilibrium, is two years for both processes. period, the in5>lied haJ.f life is much shorter — In the postwar less than one year. 6 These results confirm Schmalensee and Trippi's (19T8) findings of relatively little persistence in volatility for individual firms. The estimated autocorrelations all suggest little persistence in volatility, and conventional t-tests reject the hypothesis that volatility is a random walk vPi c 1). However, recent work on the estimation of time series models with unit roots, such as Dickey and Fuller (198I), has shown that the actual - 10 - 4-' 4^ ^m^ c tl H 4J C^ >X> VJ3 CVJ • ir\ • m OJ .-( • ir\.3- t-^• ITN • m w^ m J- cy ^-^ t 1 *^s. ^>v ^-v VC J^ .3 a\ VX> 0\ CD CD CVJ CD «-l 4-> .H CVJ ITN OJ ir\ ir\ fH f- 1-( f-l m • • • • • • • • • U^ CVJ <^^^ CVJ «l-^ ITS fn 1 ^"^ ^-^ ^*fc CKVD ^— ^i"^ O • iTN 1 m ^-^ ft 1 ^ 1 ='^ 1 i i^ 4J «-l k. or ,-1 CAco ITkCO cu-a- no • • • CO a\ J- t— f-H cy\ ^.^ i.,-- • t-t«— .H CT\eo rr> OJCO m ^— ITS fncD OO CD f-( -3 • • • *— t- • • On \r\ • ^.^ -1 CVJ VD-3- • • ^^^ *m^ CT\ w^ .3 00 3 «5 C tf ^x' —1 b, t f c vol 4J 0) O" • >3 O; ii g- ^U • VD t— o c ^ ^ H CD CQ o »— J3• O cy CVJ CD • • ro o \D VD iH • .H CO CV) •H m o m o f— VD 3 • C 10 C O VD • iH O • fH • • \t\ O 4^ m-< 0) kl 43 COVD CMr\ • • O*-' •o 0) c ts ei ki m 1 1 H (P _,_ _ t— ro • ir\ CTv ir\ m • ^ *-- 1 „^ _, 1 ro CVJ • • Ow. 1 irvvD js- CVI • • o tt^^ 0) •o «M p C - • 1 •H m ^ m ,H o— 10 CVJ Q. • 1 S> 4J C5 • -3• 1 m .H • O'-' ^-•^ ^^ •H t— r— t— r-l t-< Ow • • i i 43 4> ID o bo V k> 0) (B ' ^^ ^"^ 4> - -H C m 3 1 K) 0) as OJ U k. O O 43 3 O gg ,.^ I <-i r-l • • o ^««> 1 1 -H EH CD 0) ki (d » • ID c 3 U O* 3 O 4J 0) 43 U u + fH o! HO > >s»«, «-< b o Q. CO VD •H • o (m O ^-•b o^ 0\ • \£> i-( • m O*-' O^-^ • ta-^ • ^"'^ rfM*^ ^m tH -3- m CO 9-^ • • o*— <(«"«« ii«-i«k !-H »-l • o *^ fH • »«<* t— CVJ f-t iH • • -a- O• O" ^•K ^^k t- in r— iH fH • ^.^ o• o • >!»>« HV l4 0) + B CVJ •H •O •O Q) 43 C a) *3 m c o h- O (H tH • o> • h.^ ^^ ^— >a-«fc PO o CVJ i-t Ow o^ vh' ir\ fOVD CVI t— CVI CVJ CVJ • • • • • O'-' o^- O' o• ta*,^ • o • O*-' ^^ ^-^ «*-«• l>»S. J- 0\<H • • 4>n>h t- O• o tH • O^ CO o• o> u o •O 0) iH 0) • 4J H - •r\ g 0) k. •H H " V t-i m CO 1 m CO m CO m CO 1 1 i \o VD BJ (M CV CO 0\ 0\ iOx pH rH r^ PO CO m CO m CO 1 1 VD CD CO CVI •3- JS- 0\ c^ CD .3 Os .H »M iH C3\ H PO ^ 43 CJv 0) a 3 H CL CVI O m 0) -3- ir\ VD I- CO 43 O 01 ""H .e -H -43 C 10 ^ 3 S.^ ;? e* *-gi! B fH 43 CO ft) JC 43 -iH B • C B k. B B td 43 O, B X 43 U cr c 0) 0) J2 •O U 43 o! O 43 P. U H O C H ft) ft) ft) 1 II 43 t> n ,D 0) S 0) B •O 43 43 43 CL SJ B l> fH 0) 0) • B ^ O n rH U 0) tf ki .-1 + 0) O B .H 43 43 i-l < *3 C O 0) D ft) Q.f^ 0) •H fc. ft) ". s o 0) B .-1 rH -' 43 «M CV4L U O CO 0] B U c u o > °f OO JS C 3 O »^ t* •rt t> + 43 Q) 43 ^ 43 CL > s! v e > O O ft- tf t-l 0) .H CV 4^ CVI 43 O J3 • 43 B ki B 0) Wl O 3 O U 1-H ki g B OJ 3 -O •O iH ki O p) BJ ft) ^s- CD * CO. U O e) 3 D B c r ^ 49 >H f-l a> v so OS 43 H M ID •H *> B) ft) 43 <H o! 4J T3 ^ « ^ fti c o 9-i CD 03 es s 0) i. 0} c a O 43 bH o c o Ed U •« •p 0) 43 03 te C I £D OJ k. tm,^ *3 cu 3 t— .-• irvoD f^ 0) c CJ - f— CD •— J- OJ l« ^ 4J to A) - atlo in e x: 43 B ^ < k. e ft) 5 0} H *D B ~li~ Blze of these testB nay be substantially different from their nominal size. Dickey and Fuller (198I) present tables of adjusted critical t-values for The last column in various saniple sizes to test the hypothesis of a unit root. Table 2 showB that t-statistic against the hypothesis Pi = 1 along vith the appropriate critical t-value for the 95% confidence interval. T in each case we are able to reject the null hypothesis of a unit root. Our analysis so far has assumed that market volatility can be modelled as a Btationaiy time series. may trend over time. Some research, however, has suggested that volatility If so, this would in^jly that our estimated autocorrela- tions are biased upwards. The equations in rows 3,^,7, and 8 of Table 2 present simple tests for the existence of trends over various sample periods. They suggest a positive trend for the time period 19^8-1983, and a negative trend for 1926-1983. However, the findings also show that the null hJTOthesis of no trend cannot be rejected in the 19^8-1983 period cannot be rejected. These results contradict Pindyck's (l9Bli) claim that there has been a clear upward trend in market volatility over the last thirty years. monthly volatility estimates "ty He pre-smooths computing twelve-month moving averages before looking for trends, and this makes his conclusions difficult to evaluate. Even if there were trends, however, it is important to recognize that only unexpected deviations from trend should affect asset returns. If the trend rate of volati- lity growth rises abruptly, that should lead to a one-time adjustment in share prices, bat it cannot account for a low rate of return over an extended period. 2.2 Volatility Estimates Based on Daily Data Our second volatility estimator was based on daily data; it follows closely on Merton's (198O) estimator. 8 Using daily returns on the Standard and Poor's -12- 500 Stock Index, we conrputed ^2 o; ^ vhere b. xt 2^ -2 = r 1=1 B " /21 (IT) adjusted for non-trading days. 1b the daily return In daily data, measuring the returns around the risk-free rate would have virtually no effect on the estimated volatilities. The twenty-one trading day intervals which we use correspond roughly to months of calendar time. The autocorrelogram and partial autocorrelogram for this volatility esti- mator are shown in Table 3. In this case, the data clearly exhibit positive serial correlation. Again, the persistence of volatility is relatively unim- portant from an economic perspective. The first order autocorrelation coef- ficient obtained using monthly data is .59^, which is equivalent to an autocorrelation coefficient of only (.596)12, or .002, in annual data. This is not inconsistent with the estimates obtained using the post-war monthly volati- lity data in the last section, since we could not reject the null hypothesis that there was no serial correlation in volatility. Table k shows estimated auto regressive models for the volatility series calculated from daily data. Once again, the first or second order autore- gressive process provides an adequate description of the data. The hypothesis that the coefficients on all variables lagged more than two periods equalled zero could never be rejected. Higher lagged terms have small, as well as sta- tistically insignificant, coefficients. exceeded .10 in absolute value. Kone of the estimates of P3 or pit The tests against the null hypothesis of again clearly reject the hypothesis that volatility follows a random walk. half life for a shock in the AR(l) model is less than three nxanths. ever P.,=l The -a. -13- Table 3: Autocorrelation In Monthly Stock Market Partial Autocorrelation Lag Length (Months) • Autocorrelation 0.596 0.1U2 0.027 -0.025 0.059 0.056 0.596 (.071) 1 2 3 k 0.1*U6 0.330 0.225 0.196 0.1B6 0.169 5 6 7 8 0.15i* 0.172 0.192 O.16B 0.050 0.021 0.009 0.021 -0.003 0.013 -0.036 -0.097 -0.113 -0.107 -0.115 -0.085 -0.062 9 10 11 12 13 Ik 15 16 17 IB 19 20 21 22 23 2k Source; . (.071) [.071) (.071) (.071) (.071) ..071) (.071) (.071) ..071) (.071) :.07l) ..072) ..071) .071) .075) .069) .070) .071) .071) .071) { .071) .071) ( .071) Volatility (.071) (.071) (.072) (.072) (.071) (.072) (.071) (.072) ..071) (.071) 0.021* ( 0.016 0.067 0.069 -0.009 ..071*) -0.161 ..071) -0.009 .069) 0.023 .070) 0.031+ .072) -0.063 .071) 0.020 .073) -0.070 .071) -0.097 .072) ( -0.01*7 ( ( ( 1 ( ( - ( ( 1 ( ( ( 0.017 -0.003 ( ( ( 0.01*5 ( 0.002 ( .071) .072) .070) .072) .091) The table shows the estimated autocorrelogram for monthly estimates of market volatility. Each month's estimate is based on the average of squared daily returns on the S&P 500 Index for the period 1968:001 to 19Bl*:l80, A total of 197 monthly observations, based on 1*137 daily observations, are \ised. Standard errors are shown in parentheses. — ^ -u*> 1 cc *"^ a> H *J ^H .s- m C m m cn PO VD • • • • • • • l/N CO ^-^ -=r rvj -3- • 1 *"^ 1 ir\ ir\ ^-^ 1 *-^ ^-*. «•—.. cn CD »^ OJ *5 =3 **-^ c\) .= ir\ ITS 1 «— CD D C\J • ^•~ ^-^ » ir\ -3 .-1 » .-1 • m ^.^ irs • m ^-^ 1 I cc ft' 4J ••-1 #-^ CM ^ "^ f— »— VD VD • D .-( • cr\ \X) M • • ir\ • t— CD t— VD t— ITS .H f-H CVi'^H VD ri .H ITv • • ^ On • i-t m t^ rovD • VD 3^ n • • OS t— CD •H • On rH tH »-< •^ *> s. f-l >• 4J ^^ u 1 J9- •a • ^i^ir a\ m IS CO CO ir\ cr\ m ^ • OD ro 00 • tn .:» t-t VC i-l On rH • • • OD ro CO CD m ft) g ^ m ft) XI JJ ' C a! ft) iH ft) oa Q e o CD 10 t*' ft) O -^1 tH •H £ a m u 0} 3 'Ojo- c \D t— 0\ CD ITi m lf\ I 1 0) ll H ^K JS- CVI iH ** OJ b! V *i *» tH O ::: £ ID U a> iTN *j S3 c o e "H •o IB 3 0) to ft) "*-' u •H .» CD c O o* 0) c 3 ft) •H X2 4J *i OO n XH O" 0) 4» I CM ic 4J to c u u 0) 3 3 43 O* B) b t) ft' 43 V m CM CD oo O• O I O o 3 3 ^^ I ID <6 >? iH ^^ ^ O CVJ O t— •-10 CM • O. • iH t— «-i • CVI r— ^O O • ft) O (H «-' -^ •o b o u o c iH tfl tfl -P o 4> -H b CO CM T3 ID > D ft) 4J tH ft) CM J> ft) S^ B) c; ft) ID •• JJ 0) >«, .-I BJ CM J3 ft) as "O ft) C + 8] o< a; "O tfl > 43 3 CO u I D CI t •a C • t" CM i-< >» Si ft) e! O to ft) 4J ft) • 0^ IUi c Q. ft) BS CS -H O CD X X9 • C CT" •o z O ^X> O I o«-- o\eo CJ\eo VD e> o> -a- O *-- o -a- On VD O IfN O*— o*-» O O -^ IfN o O ^^ I ft) 4:> C i s 4J CM * > D 1" I a. ID V e ft) o ft) to (m 43 0) + c I o > o. to (0 B) to BS 43 1 c: to c o CM • • ITN • CM O t— CM • VO CM tH VD • lf\ CM • .a- o m CD o CM CM ft) B) ft) > ^c= O C ft) fc< e o ft) "O iH 01 to £ 5.2 fr< m Oj ft) CM fO IfN VO P o B 0) j= 43 O t '^^ CM u ft) c b tfl pn o\ A £ 43 u TS cr II 0) ^ B> ft) U V E -H -H 4> •H 0) CO 03 t) ft) ,H c 5 B £ m m ft) -1S- Substantlve economic concluBlons about the importance of volatility Bhocks are unaffected by the choices between the different autoregresBive modelB. All of our resultB suggest very little perslEtence.^ Moreover, the results again question the iE53ortance of trends in volatility. None of the estimated time trend coefficients is statist ically significant. In both the AR(l) and AR{2) cases, the estimate trend coefficients have t-Etatistics of less than unity and the addition of trend variables has little effect on the other coefficients in these equations. -J6- 3. Market Volatilities Implied "by Option Prenla The estimates presented in the last section suggest that volatility shockB are short-lived. However, the estinated aerial correlation parameters might be biased downward by measurement error, and they may also fall to reflect market participants' beliefs about volatility persistence. To address these problems, we analyzed the persistence in volatilities inferred from option premia. Unfortunately, options on stock market indices such as the SiP 500 have been traded for too short a period to make analyzing them informative. However, the Chicago Board Options Exchange (CBOE) has computed an index of the price of a standardized stock option on every Thursday since January 8, 1976.10 ...the CBOE Call Option Index is an average of percent option premiums; for each CBOE ;inderlying stock, a narket premimn is estimated for a hypothetical six-month, at the money option using the market premiums of existing option series. This estimated market premium is expressed as a percentage of the stock price. The CBOE Call Option Index for a given day is the arithmetic average of all such percent premiums on CBOE underlying stocks on that day. CBOE (1979) , p. l) 1 These data are now available for a period of eight and one half years and it is possible to analyze the persistence of volatility expectations using them. The CBOE Index does not correspond to the option premium of any traded security. for trtiich It is a measure of this option premiiim on the "representative share" options are traded on the CBOE. As such, the implied volatility should be substantially higher than the volatility of the market, since the market is a weighted average of many imperfectly correlated shares. While our estimates of the implied volatility on a representative share are not directly comparable to the volatilities estimated in the last section, our assumption is that their serial correlation properties should be reasonably similar. 11 11- To estimate the volatility of the "representative Btock" linplied by the CBOE index, ve assumed that the dividend yield on this share equalled that on the SiP 500.^^ We followed Black's (1976) suggestion for -dividend adjustment and subtracted the present value of dividend payments over the life of the option from the price of the stock. Vie assumed that the option on the representative stock vas priced according" to the Black-Scholes (19T3) formula, and applied a numerical search algorithm to determine the variance of returns vhich was consistent vith the observed option price, risk free rate, and market dividend yield. The CBOE Index is standardized to apply to an option on a stock vith a current price of $U0.O0, and since the index applies to at the money options the strike price is $U0.00 as veil. The veekly data on the CBOE Index, as veil as our estimates of the injjlied volatilities, are shown in the Data Appendix. The movements our infilled volatilities vere compared vith those of sixmonth ex post volatilities estimated from dally returns on the StP 500; the tvo series cohere reasonably veil. Figure 1 shows the movments in these tvo series, each divided by its mean, for the 19T6-19Bi+ period. A positive association bet- Both series rise throughout the late veen the series is readily apparent. 1970s, and decline during the 1982-1981* period. The CBOE implied volatility does not rise as dramatically as the ex poste volatility series during the I9BI stock market rally, although it does increase. Table 5 shovs the estimated autocorrelogram and partial autocorrelogram for the implied volatility series. These are veekly data, and so the estimated autocorrelations are higher than those in the earlier sections. autocorrelation, for exanple, is .971. The first order Hovever, these results confirm the -18- CD OD rN OD m 0) •rH CD CD •H •8 O OD CD CD rCD •H CD o rs- CD H m rs- CD I CD 0) R- O O in &4 Ir •H •-I 5 u ^^ ^ 43 ^ r-l Tii •H iH > r-l 1 1 NU3W 01 3AIIU13y AIIIIIUIOA IN- LU T- CD ;i; -19- "Pable 5: Autocorrelation in Volatility Forecasts IciDlled by Option Premia Lag Len^rth (veeks) 1 2 3 U 5 6 7 B 9 10 11 12 13 Ik 15 16 U.. 17 IB 19 20 21 22 23 2k 25 26 Autocorrelation 0.971 0.939 0.903 0.869 0.835 0.802 0.767 [.OI47) O.73I* [.IBI4) 0.703 0.673 0.650 0.629 0.612 0.589 0.566 ..195) ..195) ..195) .195) >.195) .195) .195) .195) .195) .195) .195) ( .195) .195) ( .195) ( .195) ( .195) ( .195) ( .195) 0.5i«5 0.525 0.507 0.k93 0.ii82 0.1*73 O.I466 0.1;58 0.1;50 0.H3 0.1;39 [.082) [.106) 1.125) l.ikz) [.157) [.171) ( < ( Partial Autocorrelation 0.971 -0.056 -0.087 0.029 -0.028 -0.003 (.0147) -0.0143 [.OI47) (.OI47) (.0I47) (.OI47) (.OI47) [.0I4B) -0.003 [.OI43) 0.032 [.OI47) -0.003 [.056) 0.092 [.OI47) -0.002 ..0l;l4) 0.062 [.0147) -0.130 >.Ol47) -0.026 ..OI47) ( 0.0614 ( ( -O.Oll* ( ( ( ( 0.012 0.059 0.053 0.025 0.028 -0.032 -O.OOB ( ( .OI47) .0146) .OI46) .0147) .OI47) ( .OI47) ( .OI48) ( .Oli7) O.OOl; ( .OI48) .0I46) 0.027 { .01*8) ( Source ; Estimates of volatility forecasts were determined try inverting the Black-Scholes option valuation formula to obtain the volatility implied tjy CBOE option premia indices. These data were available for the period 1976:1 to 19814:26, for a total of l*l47 weekly observations. See appendix for further details and data description. Standard errors are shown in parentheses. -20- earlier contluBions that volatility changes are not perslBtent. One year after a shock to volatility, expected volatility vill exceed its mean by only (.9Tl)52 »,22 or twenty two percect, of the i-nitial shock. The partial autocorrelogram again suggests that a first order autoregressive representation is appropriate for this series. The statistical insignificance of partial autocorrelations at lags of more than one week is indicative of an AR(l) structure in these data. Table 6 reports estimates of several time series models for these data. Equations for our entire data period, comprising hWj weeks, are reported in the first four rows of the tahle. The hypothesis that the residuals from the AR(1) model are white noise is nearly rejected at standard levels, as shown ty the reported Q-statistics. ficulty. The AR(2) results do not suffer from this dif- The higher order (third and fourth order) autocorrelation parameters are never statistically significant. The implied responses to a volatility shock are similar in all of the estimated models. They suggest that the hEilf life for a volatility shock is about six months. 13 Although the estimated weekly autocorrelation is near unity, the last column of the table shows that the hypothesis of a unit root is still rejected in each case. Because each weekly observation on the CBOE Index depends on forecasts of volatility for each of the next twenty six weeks, two consecutive observations on the iJ35)lied volatility vill have twenty five weeks of forecast volatilities in common. This may bias our estimated autocorrelations. Ve therefore esti- mated autoregressive models using non-overlapping data periods, corresponding to every twenty-sixth observation in our data set. The estimated AR(l) ani AR(2) models are reported in the last two rows of the table. The estimated six-month -^i- c O * w4 tf 1 >^ r' ^J c- —1 ft) ft) ft) ^S o ir t- ^^ *"-^ H pn CM *J ir\ • J- CM t— ir\ 01 *> ^-( C 3 O O • \D CM at a u s o 1te.O C* *-^ CM CD 4J ftl ir\ • • cr\ ir\ C^VC ft) "O • >e jy CM c fc< tH • • CM CM CM CM CM CM ^-^ *'"«^ *^^ O <^^ a) ^-H POVD CfWD ^-^ 1 1 1 1 ._^ j-_ ft ir\ -3- NX> • PO tH • • • VD f— r-l\D CO ir\ CD PO cu ro CM no ir\j3• po PO PO PO *-^ ^-^ ^..^ ,_^ CV f— »H PO CM C\J o\ cr\ • • • • J- CM 1 • ^-^ } ft) -H 1 1 1 O o •o «b-<« • • CM i-( CD CC CO o3 Cfl -a- CD PO fH O C^ vo en 0\ CD ey\ c^^ CO • • fi »-i c^^ CD CD \D • • ID j: ft) 43 .HVD 4J 1 1 • • 1 J- •H 1 3 0) H * H 0) \S>\D CAJ- o• o 4:> ^ ^ JJ m a 1-1 • 1 1 o*-1 cr\ t— r— vD o• o• Ow t 1 1 CD 0) rH 3 l- cr o ID (M 43 C O 03 CC o! .H ft) O rH > ^^ ^-^ ro c- t— «»-^ VD\£> Lr\ J- (4 o (M OO O— CM Q. • 1 ID r^ • -3- \D o o• o— • CJ\ ^— rovD oo • • 03 ft) PO CM C rH • 1 • O '-' O"-- O 0) •o a V a •H u tH JVD 0\ • ,,^ ._^ t— t— ,_» ^CM SD J- ^ O .-1 • ._ t— \X) o o• r-l J- VD 1^ rH J- oo CM 0\ «H CM CM ^-^ r-l ^^ rH *-^ O • O'-' ,^ 1-1 O• O• • • JS- • • -^ CM ft) • • 43 O'-' tf •O i •H CD 43 D 0) fl H 0) _ 43 1 CO 43 D u 43 1 ^"^ O rH m C X o — V J- PO CO 0\ CM • ro h- ^-^ ^-^ ^m^ lf\ rH rH t— PO VD 0\ O ^ t— CO o r— CO • o• o• r-l CM rH PO rH "-^ "*-' '-' • • ^m^ ^•m^ ir\ rH OO CM O \D t— CM CM f^ Os CM • • PO fi VD VO • • "^ O U CM ro -a- irv > 43 ID b^ X) ft) 43 1 CM 43 o t> £ 43 rH U W C + aO ^X Tl II ft) ft) 03 t) ki 0) T) 03 ft) O! ft ft) -H • -H 43 03 CD 03 "H • CD 0) 43 ft) J= 43 C C 43 tS > U 43 ft) ft ft) 03 x: 1 43 43 T3 k- ft) rt 43 U 03 Ih C J= JC [H to ft) D X3 jff- J» rH H < C ft) oJ tI4 Oj- u ft ft-H X> ft) £ 43 c O 0) fc. m c CD »H ft) cr 03 o ^ 43 eS ft) t) D* ft> ^ 43 > e ^ 43 03 rH -H B iH I. s C ft) "o ri V o 1 s» 43 0) ft) 43 OJ o; t-^ -O 43 VD »H •<-{ S •• CO > K •>43 >^ C -3 CM Oj ft) ft) ft) ft) rH •H 43 • CO jii 03 03 ft) < s« "H ft) It! e o ft) ft> 43 rH rH ft) J= 43 H ft) 03 H n •H rH flj \D \D D* 3 a rH CJ\ ft) C 3 O U + > m c -H C o -H O •H -rK 43 • • 3 T) CD eS CJ3«} «B ,n -H CM TJ 43 43 £tV — B) T! ft! ^H * t- "H 43 ^, Bi ir» C tf 43 ftj .^•S o CM 0) E 43 1 ^^ ft tC 43 1 •H O •o j: I- C O 1 43 ft O O rH CM 1 i ft> rH ft) -H b03 W, O k. 1 ft) -O ft) r u 43 ft) 03 o! 1 ^ U eS CD 1 flj J= •43 £ 43 ID 03 U Im HO «- O t) O >ItJ- O 43 OD CM e! 43 3 D O 3 "O 03 43 rH W C a K a! o! o »H » -D »H + 03 C 43 <H 03 B) >> CO 43 3 PO 43 t) ID cy* CM D -H 43 JJ O > -r^ ki O 43 43 k< 03 > 43 I) O. C ID 43 HO bo a< (^ c rH J- oo O^' • B O O m O -H rH ft) ^•^ Im ft) •H ft) 1 B) 43 43 C O C O C ft) -H ID 43 T3 ft) V£> 43 ... ««H ID a CO 83 t) k. 15 (D n rH C O O 43 t- 03 g »03 •H 1 •H 4J f ft) o rH K CD ft) »H «M CJ c o u ft) rH 43 -^g J3- ft) 03 J3 -H OD BCd «-^ el »H rH U C CB ^ O O, f-i i Ci. f— rH C^ l- 8J g n o 1 •• C . *^^ *— ^-^ . K ""«* CM CM pn CM e *3 • • • OJ ON tf ^ T Ck.v£) ^"* ITN ^ .. tP rH 4J CM x: CO 4J CT\ 6C C rH C -H 01 t U <H Ci. r-t rH e* vr^ *J ftH • 03 -o rH ID 43 B) U «J ft) 43 ft -22- autocorrelation coelTicient from these data than the Bix-month autocorrelation iniplied is toy .UZ, vhicb is only slightly lower cur weekly estimateB. The resultB agai^ suggest that over half of a volatility shock vanishes within six months. -23- U. The Term Structure of Icrplled Volatilities The CBOE CeJ.1 Option Index data provide strong support for the transient character of volatility shocks. However, they do not permit us to directly investigate how long-term expectations of volatility respond to changing short- A second source of option data can illuminate term volatility expectations. this issue. Since 1979* Valueline has computed indices of option premia at We inverted these option premia indices using three and six month maturities. the sane procedure vhich ve applied to the CBOE data.l^ The availability of two different maturity option indices provides an opportunity for additional tests of the persistence hypothesis. The implied volatility for the six month options was assumed to equal the average of the expected three month volatilities for the next three months as well as the three months following them: In this notation, , & ,i^ o 2 t is the volatility expected to prevail, as of time t, over the k months beginning in week s. The assumption in (iB) allows us to solve for an estimate of the inplied forward volatility vhich is expected to prevail for the three month period beginning three months from the current week: *p ^P t+13,3^t '^ - •^p 2t,6°t " t,3°t (19) We can use the estimated forward volatilities to study the change in the implied forward volatility vhich occurs when the current three-month "spot" Implied volatility changes. The results of this estimation are shown below: -2i- ^^t -t+l? **T. -^"Ll t-1 t+12.3 t+13.3 = -°233 (.0769) L 7°. ^ - t^"'»^ 1 ^^ ^^T (.050) ^»^ ^ + 0.511 1 ^20) These resultB indicate that when current volatility expectations change, expected volatility in future periods also changes. However, they also consti- tute further evidence for our contention that volatility shocks are not persistent. One year after a volatility shock, these estimates imply that only seven percent of a shock vill still persist. " The half life of a volatility shock according to these data is Just over three months. One year after a ten percent shock to volatility, the three-month forecast of volatility vould only be 1.3 percent greater than in the initial period. ' -25- 5. ConcluBJonp and InrplicationB Our findings suggest that Bhocks to stock market volatility are not perThis is illuBtTated in Figure 2, vhich showB the impulse response sistent. functions corresponding to several of the estimated time series models for vola•tllity. These functions, vhich show the moving average representation of each process, depict the evolution of volatility following a "shock" equal to ten percent of the steady-state value of volatility. shocl: dissipates varies two years. While the speed with which the across modeD^, the half life of the shock never exceeds For the equations corresponding to the CBOE and daily volatility estimators, the half-life of a volatility shock is less than half a year. Our engiirical results suggest that changes in volatility should affect expected required returns for periods not substantially greater than two years. This means that they can only have a very limited impact on the level of share prices. A doubling of volatility would reduce the level of the market by only Since actual volatility fluctuations ere usually smaller about nine percent, 15 than this, we doubt that changing volatility accounts for any large fraction of market fluctuations. This observation applies both to the problem of explaining recent events and to the deeper problem of explaining the sources of stock price fluctuations. Our work deepens the puzzle of explaining the strong negative correlation, observed "ty Black (1976) and Schmalensee and Trippi {19TB), between stock market returns and volatility. Black (1976) showed that the inverse correlation between volatility and returns was so strong that a positive one percent return on a stock in5)lied more than a one percent reduction in volatility; this -26- m CD I vo rM ^ -H m CO S iH 1 CO •S" cr> iH AinilUlOA ' ^ •H ^ 1 -^' 1 Q) 1 Q) 0) 'P Aj ^ *— iJ 00 2 •^ 1 0^ .-< 1 rH 00 w (^ tx nv O 00 «^ I , 1 -27- inplies that raising the share price actually reduces the dollar volatility of the stock. The finding that volatility is not highly perBistent Buggests that autonomous changes In ^volatility should have only a relatively small effect on share prices. If Black's (1976) "leverage effect" explanation of the rela- tionship between returns and volatility were correct, then one would expect to observe that volatility, like prices, would follow a random walk. One possible explanation for the observed data is that the same events which make the returns to capital more uncertain also reduce their expected value. This coincidence in the arrival of stochastic shocks would lead to on apparent relationship between volatility changes and share prices, although in ^"' :_: , fact no such causal link exists. Another possibility is that when adversity strikes, firms are expected to respond with new strategies. Between the time the market anticipates that some new policy will be chosen and the time this ,™ policy is actually announced, uncertainty and therefore volatility may increase. -26- Endnotes 1. These data are based on Ibbotson (198I4). 2. To the extent that there is measurement error in our estimates of volatility, the estimated serial correlation coefficients nay be biased downward. In the next section we use estimates of volatility expectations which are less susceptible to these difficulties. 3. Merton (I98O) observes that although estimators of the variance vhich center the estimated returns around a point vhich is not their Ban53le mean will be biased, these biases are trivial. He estimates variances using uncentered returns; Pincfy'ck (19S^) estimates variances for twelve month periods hy computing second moments centered around the overall mean return in his sample. li. We used Box-Jenkins (19T0) Q-statistics to test the null hypothesis of no serial correlation of up to fifth order. The values of the test statistics were 32.9 for the I926-19B3 period, i+.70 for 19l*B-1983, and k.kl for I96O-I983. The sriticELl v&lue for rejecting the null hypothesis of at the .05 level is 12.59. 5. The finding that lew-order autoregressive processes provide an adequate description of the variance of market returns suggest that it may be possible to apply the econometric techniques for time- varying heteroscedasticity, suggested by Engle{l9B2}, vhen studying the behavior of security returns. 6. The same conclusion emerged vhen we examined changes in volatility. is showE by *be folloving equation, estimated for the 19^B-19B3 period: This i^ ' cl . = 1083.3 - .i*3B lof . - of -1 ^"^ (3079.1) ^^ ^^ (.155) The coefficient on the lagged volatility change is negative and has a t-value of 2. 83, clearly different from zero. T. Critical values of the unit root tests are drawn from Dickey and Fuller (1981). Tables I and II. 8. Merton (198O, Appendix A) discusses tvo adjustments to estimated volatility series. The first, for nontrading days, is implemented in our study. The second, vhich corrects for nontrading shares in the stock index, multiplies the estimated volatility by a constant. Since our stuc^ is concerned vith the autocovariance and not the level of the volatility series, and the former is unaffected 'by multiplication by a constant, we did not make the correction. 9« The results of estimating a model in changes were: \ ' Vl = ^-^^^10"^ - -315 • I Vi - ^-2^ • (3.1*2x10-^) (.068) Again, this suggests negative serial correlation. 10, A further description of this series may be found in CBOE(l979). -29- 11. Latane and Rendelnan (19T6) coiaputed implied standard deviations for a series of pptions over a thirty nine week period and discovered tnat these lumlied standard deviations tended to move together. Schmalensee and Trippi (1978) found Bimilar results. Tnese coincident movements in volatility are the .market-vide volatility shifts we hope to capture. 12. We assumed that dividends were paid as a continuing flow at rate X per year, where A is the current yield on the StP 500. 13. We also considered the serial correlation of changes for the non- overlapping differences «2 -I,t "2 I.t-2b "2 -^'^^^ (.OliU) (0.00013) where the subscript I denotes an implied volatility. "2 ^'^^^ Ik, The Value Line data were available for the period 19BO:l6 to 19Bl4:26; this constitutes a total of 220 weeks. However, there were 17 weeks of missing dAta. This precluded calculating the long autocorrelograms which are reported for the other volatility series. However, the first order autocorrelations for these series, .88 for the three month implied volatility and .87 for the six month, were roughly consistent with earlier findings. 15. This calculation is based on Pi = .21, the estimate from the CBOE inrolied volatilities, and the other parameter values described in Section 1. i3n. -30- Ref rrences Black, Fischer, 19T5, Fact and fantasy in the use of options, Financial Analysts Journal 31, 36-1^1, 6l-72. • Black, Fischer, 1976, Studies of stock price volatility changes, Proceedinps of the 19T6 Meetings of the American Statistical ABSOCiation, business and Economic Statistics Section . 177-ltSl. Black, Fischer and ftyron Scholes, 1973, The pricing of options and corporate liabillticE, Journal of Political Econony 8l, 637-659. Box, G.E.P. and G, Jenkins, 1970, Time Series Analysis: Forecasting and Control (Bolden Day: San Francisco). Chicago Board Options Exchange, 1979, The CBOE call option index; Methodology and technical considerations (Research I>epartment of the CBOE, Chicago, XL). Dickey, David A. and Wayne A. Fuller, 19Bl, Likelihood ratio statistics for autoregressive time series vith a unit root, Econometrica ^9, 1057-1072. Engle, Robert F., 1982, Autoregressive conditional heteroscedasticlty vith estimates of the variance of United Kingdom inflations, Econometrica 50, 987-lOOB. Ibbotson, Roger G., 1981*, Stocks, bonds, bills, and inflation; (R.G. Ibbotson Associates, Chicago, IL;. 19B1< yearbook , Latane, E. and R. Rendleman, 1976, Standard deviations of stock price ratios ingjlied in option prices. Journal of Finance 31, 369-381. Malkiel, Burton G,, 1979, The capital formation problem in the United States, Journal of Finance 3^*, 291-306. Merton, Robert C, 1973, An intertemporal capital asset pricing model, Econonietrica ^1, 867-887. Merton, Robert C, 1980, On estimating the expected return on the market. Journal of Financial Economics 8, 323-361. Pindyck, Robert S. , 198U, Risk, inflation, and the stock market, American Economic Review 7^, 335-351- Roll, Richard, 1977, An analytical valuation formula for unprotected American call options on stocks with known dividends. Journal of Financial Economies 5, 251-258. Schmalensee, Richard and R. Trippi, 1978, Common stock volatility expectations implied by option premia. Journal of Finance 33, 129-^7. ^50^1^ 035 MIT LIBRARIES 3 SDflD DD3 Dbl 3TM K. "> ki^ ^J« J ^ 5.* i^:r^*r?.f5 .?'"*<.;«*' #^*/ J •^ J .« v^im>#. Jg;^^^;;.;* Date Due 1 1 Lib-26-67 b^ur Qj^d^ '^ ""^ ^"^ t^^e^