Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium IVIember Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/quantileprobabilOOcher 5 -DEWEY IB31 M415 Massachusetts Institute of Technology Department of Economics Working Paper Series QUANTILE AND PROBABILITY CURVES WITHOUT CROSSING Victor Chemozhukov Ivan Fernandez- Val Alfred Galichon Working Paper 07-1 April 27, 2007 Room E52-251 50 Memorial Drive Cambridge, MA 021 42 This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network Paper Collection http://ssrn.com/abstract=9831 58 at QUANTILE AND PROBABILITY CURVES WITHOUT CROSSING VICTOR CHERNOZHUKOVt ALFRED GALICHON* IVAN FERNANDEZ- VAL§ Abstract. The most common approach to estimating conditional quantile curves is to fit a curve, typically linear, pointwise for each quantile. Linear functional forms, coupled with pointwise fitting, are used for a number of reasons including parsimony of the resulting approximations and good computa- tional properties. The resulting fits, however, may not respect a logical monotonicity requirement - that the quantile curve be increasing as a function of probability. This paper studies the natural monotonization of these empirical curves induced by sampling from the estimated non-monotone model, and then taking the resulting conditional quantile curves that by construction are monotone in the probability. This construction of monotone quantile curves arrangement of the original non-monotone to the true curves in finite samples, for conditional quantile curves have the Under may be function. seen as a bootstrap and also as a monotonic It is any sample shown that the monotonized curves are size. Under as the original misspecification, however, the asymptotics of the rearranged curves An the estimates of conditional distribution functions. (Hadamard) may analogous procedure The results are derived is non-monotone developed to monotonize by establishing the compact the monotonized quantile and probability curves with respect to the diflferentiability of the compact differentiability of the rearrangement-related operators Method, Hadamard 2000 subject Date: First version of this paper for is established. Rearrangement Operators. classification: Primary 62J02; Secondary 62E20, is of April (partially) 6, 2005. The last 62P20 modification was done April 27, 2007. borrowed from the work of Xuming He (1997), to the inspiration and formulation of the problem. Chesher, Phil Cross, is In doing so, regression, Monotonicity, Rearrangement, Approximation, Functional Delta Differentiability of AMS curves. partially differ from the original curves in discontinuous directions, tangentially to a set of continuous functions. Keywords: Quantile closer correct specification, the rearranged same asymptotic distribution asymptotics of the original non-monotone curves. re- Raymond Guiteras, Xuming We would like to He, Roger Koenker, whom we The title are grateful thank Josh Angrist, Andrew Vadim Marmer, Ilya Molchanov, Francesca Molinari, Whitney Newey, Steve Portnoy, Shinichi Sakata, Art Shneyerov, Alp Simsek, and seminar participants at BU, Columbia, Cornell, Georgetown, Harvard-MIT, MIT, Northwestern, and UCL for very useful comments that helped improve the paper. 1 UBC, Introduction and Discussion 1. The problem studied sion as the prime in this paper can be best described using Hnear quantile regres- example (Koenker, 2005). Suppose that x'(3{u) is a linear approxima- tion to the u-quantile Qo{u\x) of a real response variable Y, given a vector of regressors X = u G The X. (0, 1) typical estimation methods producing an estimate x fitting, are fit the conditional curve x'P{u) pointwise in Linear functional forms, coupled with pointwise (5{u). used for a number of reasons including parsimony of the resulting approxi- mations and good computational properties (Portnoy and Koenker, 1997). However, a problem that might occur that the is map u may not be increasing in u, manifestation of this issue, we X P{u) which violates the known the conditional quantile curves x In the analysis I—> logical monotonicity requirement. Another as the "quantile crossing f-^ x' (3[u) may problem" (He, 1997), is that cross for different values of u. shall distinguish the following two cases, each leading to the lack of monotonicity or the crossing problem: (1) Monotonically correct case: The population curve u and thus u (2) H^- satisfies the x'P{u) i—> x'P{u) is increasing in u, monotonicity requirement. However, the empirical curve may be non-monotone due to estimation error. Monotonically incorrect case: The population curve u <-^ x'P{u) is non-monotone due to imperfect approximation to the true conditional quantile function. Accordingly, the resulting empirical curve u i-^ x' (5{u) is also non-monotone due both non-monotonicity of the population curve and estimation to error. Consider the random variable Y^ := x%U) where U~ ?7(0, 1). This variable can be seen as a bootstrap draw from the estimated quantile regression model, as in Koenker (1994), and has the distribution function F{y\x)= I l{x'P{u)<y]du. JQ (1.1) 3 Moreover, inverting the distribution function, one obtains a proper quantile function F-\u\x) which is monotone in u. original curve x (3{u) = mi{y:F{y\x)>u}, The rearranged the original curve if (1.2) quantile function F~^{u\x) coincides with the is increasing in u, but differs from the original curve otherwise. Thus, starting with a possibly non-monotone original curve u the rearrangement (1.1)-(1.2) produces a monotone quantile curve u what follows, we focus our attention on the interval Indeed, any closed subinterval of (0, 1) tile this F^^{u\x). name have a direct erations research In loss of generality. in Section 2. regression bootstrap (Koenker, 1994), since the rearranged quantile curve its /3{u), rearrangement mechanism has a direct relation to the quan- by sampling from the estimated and x can also be considered isomorphically to the treatment of the unit interval case, as commented further As mentioned above, without (0, 1) t—» h-> original quantile model. Moreover, relation to rearrangement maps is produced both the mechanism in variational analysis and op- Hardy, Littlewood, and Polya, 1952, and Villani, 2003). Further (e.g.. important references on the rearrangement method are discussed below. The purpose of this paper is to establish the empirical properties of the rearranged quantile curves and their distribution counterparts: F u under scenarios (1) and (2). ^{u\x) The paper and y \-^ F{y\x), also characterizes certain analytical and approx- imation properties of the corresponding population curves: u 1-^ F~^{u\x) = inf{y : F{y\x) > u}, and y i-^ F{y\x) = / l{x'P{u) < y}du. Jo The first main result of the the rearranged curves. We paper establishes the improved estimation properties of show that the rearranged curve F~^{u\x) is closer to the true conditional quantile curve Qo{u\x) than the original curve. Formally, for each x, that for all p G [l,oo] / \Qo{u\x) - F-\u\x)\Pdu\ <( f \Qo{u\x) - x'p{u)\''du we have where the inequahty a subset of U := strict for is increasing. This property and is independent of the sample x P{u) <—> u i-^ is decreasing on Qo{u\x) is strictly and thus continues to hold size, whether the linear quantile estimator x P{u) also regardless of estimates Qo{u\x) consistently or not, x'P{u). whenever u (l,C)o) of positive Lebesgue measure, while (0, 1) in the population, p € i.e. = whether Qq{u\x) x'P{u) or Qo{u\x) ^ In other words, the rearranged quantile curves have smaller estimation error than the original curves whenever the latter are not monotone. This property that does not depend on the way the quantile model not rely on any other specifics of the current context and is is is a very important estimated. It also does therefore applicable quite generally. Towards describing the essence X to x. Suppose that P{u) is of the rest of results, let us fix the value of the regressor an estimator for P{u) that converges weakly to a Gaussian process G{u), so that Vnx'0{u) as a stochastic process indexed For sufficient conditions, (1991), by u Piu)) =4> x'G{u), in the metric space of (1.3) bounded functions example, Gutenbrunner and Jureckova (1992), Portnoy see, for and Angrist, Chernozhukov, and Fernandez- Val (2006). The second main result of the paper MF{y\x) - is that in the monotonically correct case F{y\x)) =^ F'{y\x)[x'G{F{y\x))], ' (1), (1.4) where as a stochastic process indexed by y in the metric space i°°{y), of K-; XI £°°(0, 1). 3^ is the support and ^'(y|^) = d(3{u) 1 -T^TTT x'/3'(u) ,,.' ^ith p'{u):= du u=F{y\x) Moreover, we show that Vn{F-\u\x) - F-\u\x)) as a stochastic process indexed first by u, in i°°{0, 1); ^ x'G{u), (1.5) which, remarkably, coincides with the order asymptotics (1.3) of the original curve. This result has a convenient practical implication: if the population curve is monotone, then the empirical non-monotone curve can be re-arranged to be monotonic without affecting properties. To derive the above results we its (first find the functional order) asymptotic Hadamard derivatives 5 of F{y\x) and F~^{u\x) with respect to perturbations of the underlying curve x'P{u) continuous functions, and then in discontinuous directions, tangentially to the set of use the functional delta method. Establishing the rearranged distribution and quantile curves main in Hadamard differentiability of the discontinuous directions is the second theoretical result of the paper. The third main result that in the monotonically incorrect case is ^™.) -.(„.,). g'||M^. as a stochastic process indexed by y defined in the next section. = equation y E K, in i°°{K), < Here Ui{y\x) x'P{u), assuming that K{y\x) is ... < where K (1.) is an appropriate set UK{y\x){y\x) are solutions to the bounded. Similarly, for the rearranged quantile curve, (1.7) as a stochastic process indexed by u G A'', in i°°{K'), where K' is an appropriate set defined in the next section. Analogously to quantiles, most estimation methods tions for conditional distribution func- do not impose monotonicity, and therefore can give rise to non-monotonic empirical conditional distribution curves; see, for example. Hall, Wolff, and Yao (1999). A similar monotone rearrangement can be applied to these distribution curves by exchanging the roles plaj^ed by the quantile and the probability spaces. Thus, suppose that P{y\x) candidate estimate of a conditional distribution function, which is The rearranged monotone is quantile curve associated with P{y\x) /oo Q{u\x)= curve, not monotone in a y. ^0 l{P{y\x)<u]dyJo The rearranged is \{P {y\x) > u]dy. J-oo probability curve can then be obtained as the inverse of this quantile i.e., F{y\x) = inf ju : Q {u\x) > yj , which is monotone by construction. Section 3 shows in more detail that similar estimation properties and an asymptotic distribution theory goes through for The improved Q and F. distributional results in the paper do not rely on the sampling properties of the method particular estimation used, because they are expressed in terms of the differ- entiability of the operator with respect to the basic estimated process. Moreover, the results that follow are derived without imposing linearity of the functional forms. only conditions required are that The a central limit theorem like (1.3) applies to the (1) estimator of the curve, and (2) the population curves have some smoothness properties. The exact nature of these population curves does not affect the validity of the results. For example, the results hold regardless of whether the underlying model is an ordinary or an instrumental quantile regression model. There He exist other methods monotonic to obtain fits based on quantile regression. (1997), for example, proposes to impose a location-scale regression model, which naturally satisfies monotonicity. This approach is fruitful for location-scale situations, but in numerous cases data do not satisfy the location-scale model, as discussed, example, in Lehmann (1974), Doksum (2005) develop a computational (1974), method and Koenker (2005). Koenker and Ng for quantile regression that crossing constraints in simultaneous fitting of quantile curves. fruitful in Clearly, The delta many situations, but the statistical properties of the Koenker and Ng's proposal is different imposes the non- This approach may be method remain unknown. from the rearrangement method. distributional results obtained in the paper can also be viewed as a functional method for the rearrangement-related operators (1.1) inverse (quantile) operators as a special case. results for by Gill and Johansen (1990), Doss and is (1.2) that include the In this sense, they extend the previous Gill (1992), (1999) on compact differentiability of the quantile operator. here, as well as in the quantile case, and and Dudley and Norvaisa The main technical difficulty that differentiability needs to be established in discontinuous directions (that converge to continuous directions, i.e., tangentially to the set of continuous functions), because the empirical perturbations of the quantile processes are typically step functions. Both the work statistical of Dette, and mathematical Neumeyer, and results of this Pilz (2006), paper complement the important which applies the rearrangement operators to kernel mean in the regressors. •are mean regressions, in order to obtain Our results on Hadamard regression functions that are monotonic differentiability in discontinuous directions new. They complement the local expansions in smooth directions subsumed proofs in Dette et. for the case called here the al. monotonically correct case. addition, our results cover monotonically incorrect cases. The mathematical differs quite substantially. results on directional by Mossino and in the The results of this statistical In problem also paper also complement the differentiability of Li- functionals of rearranged functions like (1.2) Temam (1981). The results for Li -functionals results of this paper, such as (1.4)-(1.7), but the converse discussion after Proposition 4 in Section 2 for more do not imply the main shown is to be true. (See details.) There are many potential applications of the estimation and differentiability results of the paper to objects other than probability or quantile curves. For example, in a com- panion work we present applications to economic demand and production functions and to biometric growth curves, where monotonization is or logical restrictions (Chernozhukov, Fernandez- Val, We used to impose useful theoretical and Galichon, 2006a). organize the rest of the paper as follows. In Section 2.1 we describe analytical properties of the rearranged population curves. In Section 2.2 functional differentiability results. In Section 2.3 we present estimation the rearranged curves and establish their limit distributions. illustrate the main 2. In Section 5 basic derive the properties of we extend In Section 4.1 rearrangement procedure with an empirical application, and we provide a Monte-Carlo example. we In Section 3 the previous results to monotonize estimates of distribution curves. some we in Section 4.2 we conclude with a summary of the results. Rearranged Quantile Curves: Analytical and Empirical Properties In this section the treatment of the problem troduction. In particular, y^ := Q{U\x), where we U ~ somewhat more general than in the in- replace the linear functional form x'/3{u) by Q{u\x). Define Uniform(W) with y]du be the distribution function quantile function oiYx. is of Y^^ U = (0,1). Let F{y\x) := J^ l{Q{u\x) and F~^{u\x) := inf{y : F{y\x) > < u} be the Remark. We we consider the interval (0, 1) without loss of generality. + are interested in a particular subinterval {a, a Indeed, suppose we may For example, b) of (0,1). wish to focus estimation on a particular range of quantiles or to avoid estimation of we quantiles. For this purpose, = Q{a + Y^ := Q{U\x) F~^{u\x) := inf{y functions Q : > G {Q{u\x) : ii} for U~ u G u E {a,a = The (0, 1). U + (a, a+b): analysis of the paper applies to the u G for € < y}du, and F{y\x) := /^ l{Q{u\x) C/(0, 1), Q{{u — a)/b\x) we can use (a, a + b) and F{y\x) = a + bF{y\x) b)}. We Basic Analytical Properties. 2.1. objects conditionally on the event In order to go back to the unconditional quantities, the transformations Q{u\x) for y all bU\x), where F{y\x) and F"^. define tail by developing some basic properties start for F{y\x) and F~^{u\x), the population counterparts of the rearranged distribution curve and We its inverse. need these properties to derive various empirical properties stated in the next section. Recall the following definitions from Milnor (1965): first A continuously differentiable function. derivative of g at this point does not vanish, regular point if is A called a critical point. ^"^ ({y}) contains only regular points, which is not a regular value Denote by y^ the support We assume throughout that compact subset x, or of R''. we might be be a singleton i.e., is if g~^ point u which X {x}. X of Y^, y^; C yX := {{y,x) y, which is : y R ({y}), compact subset the not a 9' (^) A 7^ 0. value y of R, UX =14 x X. and that x E X, a. of interest are not functions of X is taken to the following assumptions about Q{u\x): a continuously differentiable function in both arguments, Q{u\x) (b) For each x E X, the number of elements of {u E is is if called a regular value of g is Ey^^x E X}, and some applications the curves We make -^ he a M. called a critical value. (a) : A g' (u) 7^ 0. Vu G ^ U C R called a regular point of g value y E g {U) i.e., : interested in a particular value x. In this case, the set X= U In is eU point u Let g U Q'{u\x) \ = 0} is finite and uniformly bounded on x E X. Assumption U (b) implies that, for each x E X, Q'{u\x) and can only switch sign a bounded number values oiu>-^ Q{u\x) in 3^^, and yX* is not zero almost everywhere on of times. Let := {{y,x) : y y* be the subset Ey*,x E X}. of regular 9 Proposition (b), the 1 (Basic Properties of F{y\x) and F~^{u\x)). Under assumptions (a) - functions F{y\x) and F~^{u\x) satisfy the following properties: 1. The 2. For any y e y* set of critical values, yx \ yi, is finite, and Jyxy. dF{y\x) = 0. K{y\x) F{y\x) = Y^ sign{Q'{ukiy\x)\x)}uk{y\x) + < l{Q'{uK{y\x){y\x)\x) 0}, fc=i where {ufc(y|x), = fork l,...,K{y\x) < oo} are the roots of Q{u\x) = y in increasing order. 3. For any y E y*, = the ordinary derivative f{y\x) dF{y\x)/dy exists and takes the form ^^^1^^ = IJ which is continuous at each- y € absolutely continuous Nikodym 4- and For any y & 3^*. strictly increasing in \ y^, set f{y\x) := 0. y E yx- Moreover, f{y\x) is F{y\x) a is Radon- The quantile function F~^{u\x) partially coincides with Q{u\x); namely provided that Q{u\x) 5. y derivative of F{y\x) with respect to the Lebesgue measure. F-\u\x) for y \Q'{u,{y\x)\x)y = = Q{u\x), increasing at u, and the equation Q{u\x) is = y has unique solution F~^{u\x). The quantile function F~^{u\x) is equivariant to location and scale transformations ofQ{u\x). 6. The quantile function F~^{u\x) has an ordinary continuous derivative l/f{F-\u\x)\x), when F~^{u\x) G 3^*. This function is also a Radon-Nikodym derivative with respect to the the Lebesgue measure. 7. The map {y,x) continuous on lAX i—> F{y\x) is continuous on yX and the map {u,x) i-^ F''^{u\x) is 10 The some following simple example illustrates where the initial of these basic properties in a situation population pseudo-quantile curve is highly non-monotone. Consider the following pseudo-quantile function: Q{u) The left panel of Figure ticular, the slope of 1 = (u + - sm{2TTu)] 5 shows that this function Q{u) changes sign twice curve F~^{u), also plotted in this panel, The 1, results 1, 2, 4 is at 1/3 (2.1) . non-monotone is In par- and 2/3. The rearranged quantile illustrated in the right panel of Figure Here we can see that which plots the original and rearranged distribution curves. is [0, 1]. continuous and monotonically increasing. and 7 of the proposition are the rearranged distribution function in continuous, does not have mass points, and co- incide with the original curve for values of y where the original curve is one to one and increasing. Figure 2 illustrates the third and sixth results of the proposition by plotting the sparsity function for F~^{u) in the right panel is and the density function The of F{y). continuous at the regular values of Q{u). function for F~^{u) in the left panel is derivative of F{y) Similarly, the sparsity continuous at the corresponding image values (under F{y)). Functional Derivatives. Next, we 2.2. Hadamard differentiability of F{y\x) main results of the paper on and F~^{u\x) with respect to Q{u\x), tangentially to the space of continuous functions on for deriving the establish the UX. This differentiability property is important asymptotic distributions of the rearranged estimates. In particular, the property allows us to establish generic convergence results for rearranged curves based on any initial quantile estimator, provided the initial estimator satisfies a functional central limit theorem. The property also imphes that the bootstrap inference on the rearranged estimates, provided the bootstrap estimates. This result follows from the functional delta Theorem In > is valid for performing valid for the initial bootstrap for the (e.g., 13.9 in van der Vaart, 1998). what UX — method is R, follows, C{UX) £°°{UX) denotes the set of bounded and measurable functions h denotes the set of continuous functions mapping h : UX : -^ R, and 11 ^^^ Q'ly) ^^--'^''''^^ F(y) y/"T"""'^ I f \ / /\ / Figure 1. Left: The pseudo-quantile quantile function F^^{u). Right': The function Q{u) and the rearranged pseudo-distribution function Q~^{y) and the rearranged distribution function F{y). ,(y, ; - w Figure tile 2. Left: The density (sparsity) function of the rearranged quan- function F~^{u). Right: tribution function F{y). The density function of the rearranged dis- 12 i^{UX) denotes the < oo, ^ and measurable functions h set of UX -^ M such that /^ /^ \h{u\x)\dudx where du and dx denote the integration with respect to the Lebesgue measure on A", respectively. Proposition 2 (Hadamard Derivative := /q \{Q{u\x) + < tht{u\x) X), for every \ht - of F{y\x) with respect to Q{u\x)). Define F{y\x, ht) y}du. Under assumptions (a)-(h), as (2.3) ^ 0, - Y, I'r^r'r'li \Q'{uk{y\x)\x)\ := ^ in where ^ any compact subset G ht ^°° The convergence holds uniformly - hU \ht The convergence ^ 0, Moreover, := {(y,a:) : j/ of F~^{u\x) with respect to Q{u\x)). ^"''"l''''">,-^"''"l"' in G 3^*,x 6 Under in the ^i).M.). as- where ht E i°° = (2.5) {{u,x) : {F~^ {u\x) x) 6 , {UX), and h G C{UX). on regions that exclude the critical values, (2.4) ^P.(F-'M..)W. any compact subset ofUX* results hold uniformly mapping u h^ Q{u\x). At the to decreasing. ofyX* {UX), and h E C{UA:). P>W:=- ^(^_.'„|^)|^) every - 0, ^>,Mx.O:^ yX*}, for 0, DMr) Proposition 3 (Hadamard Derivative t ^^ (22) h\oo surnpitions (a)-(h), as t DM.,t)^!M^hLzim^O,(yM, The convergence holds uniformly the : critical values of Q{u\x) possibly changes from increasing monotonically correct case (1), the following result is worth emphasizing; Corollary 1 (Monotonically correct case). Suppose each {u,x) G UX, then yX* = yX and UX* = UX. Propositions 2 and 3 holds uniformly over the entire over, Dh{u\x) to the original = h, i.e., the curve is Hadamard u k^ Q{u\x) has Q'{u\x) > yX 0, for Therefore, the convergence in and UX, respectively. More- derivative of the rearranged quantile with respect the identity operator. 13 The convergence uniform over the entire domain is in the monotonically correct case. This result raises naturally the question of whether uniform convergence can be achieved by some operation of smoothing either over y (or over u). The in the The answer monotonically incorrect case - namely integrating is indeed yes. Hadamard following proposition calculates the tionals obtained {y',x)^ by derivative of the following func- integration; / l{y <y'}g{y\x)F{y\x)dy, {u',x)^ Jy / \{u <u']g{u\x)F~\u\x)du, JU with the restrictions on g specified below. These elementary functionals are useful building blocks for various statistics, as briefly mentioned in the next section. Proposition specified 4. results are true with the limits being continuous uniformly in f Jy \{y < y'}g{y\x)Dh,{y\^,t)dy-^_ [ l{y < y'}g{y\x)Dh{y\x)dy Jy (y', x) / l{u € yX, for any g G i°°{yPt!) such that x i—> g{y\x) is continuous for y. 2. < u'}g{u\x)Dfn{u\x,t)du -^ Ju / l{u < u'}g{u\x)Dh{u\x)du JU uniformly in {u',x) 6 UA!, for any g E d-^iJAX) such that x a.e. on the domains: 1. a.e. The following (-+ g[u\x) is continuous for u. This proposition essentially (l)-(2) follow from the is a corollary of Propositions 2 and fact that the pointwise coupled with the uniform integrability shown in interchange of limits and integrals. An 3. Indeed, the results convergence of Propositions 2 and Lemma alternative way 3 in the 3, Appendix, permits the of proving result (2), but not any other result in the paper, can be based on exploiting the convexity of the functional in (2) with respect to the underlying curve, following the approach of Mossino and (1981), and Alvino, Lions, and Trombetti (1989). pursue this approach in in this paper. Due to this limitation, Temam we do not However, details of this approach are described Chernozhukov, Fernandez- Val, and Galichon (2006b) with an application to some nonparametric estimation problems. 14 It is also worth emphasizing the properties of the following smoothed functionals. For a measurable function / : R h->- R smoothing operator as define the Sf{y):= jh{y-y')f{y')dy\ where ks{v) = < l{\v\ 5}/25 and 5 > is (2.6) a fixed bandwidth. Accordingly, the smoothed curves SF{y\x) and 5F~^(u|x) are given by SF{y\x) := f ks{y - y')F{y'\x)dy\ SF-\u\x) := - i^)F-\u'\x)dv! j ks{u Since these curves are merely formed as differences of the elementary functionals in Proposition 4, Corollary 2. followed by a division by We 5, have that SDhi{y\x,t) the following corollary — > is immediate. SDh{y\x) uniformly in {y,x) G SDht{u\x,t) -^ SDh{u\x) uniformly in {u,x) e J^^Y, and UX. Note that smoothing accomplishes uniform convergence over the entire domain, which is a good property to have from the perspective of data analysis. 2.3. Empirical Properties of F{y\x) and F~^{u\x). main We are now ready to state the results for this section. Proposition 5 (Improvement Suppose that curve Qo{-\-). Q{'\-) is in Estimation Property Provided by Rearrangement). an estimator (not necessarily consistent) for some true quantile Then, the rearranged curve F^^{u\x) Q{u\x) in the sense \Qo{u\x) that, for each x ^ - F-\u\x)\Pduj where the inequality is strict the curve is obtained, is closer to the true curve than X <U\QQ{u\x)-Q{u\x)\Pdu] for p G (l,oo) whenever Q{u\x) oflA of positive Lebesgue measure, while Qo{u\x) The above property is is is ,pe[l,oo], decreasing on a subset increasing on U . independent of the sample size and of the way the estimate of and thus continues to hold in the population. This proposition establishes that the rearranged quantile curves have smaller estimation error than the original curves whenever the latter are not monotone. This is a very 15 important property that does not depend on the way the quantile model It also does not rely The on any other and specifics is estimated. thus applicable quite generally. is following proposition investigates the asymptotic distributions of the rearranged curves. Proposition 6 (Empirical Properties Suppose that Q{-\-) is UX, and — ^/n{Q[u\x) and (b). Then Assume in i°°{K), where K is that, in Q{u\x)) UX, G as a stochastic process indexed by {u,x) process with continuous paths. F{y\x) and {u,x) i-^ F"^(u|x)). Q{-\-) that takes its values in the space of an estimator for measurable functions defined on ^ of {y,x) ^°°{UX), ^ G{u\x), where {u,x) Q{u\x) also that bounded i-^ G{u\x) is a Gaussian satisfies the basic conditions (a) any compact subset ofyX*, ^{F{y\x) - F{y\x)) G as a stochastic process indexed by (y, x) yX* ; ^ DG{y\x) and in 1°°1JAX k), with UXk = {(^i x) : {F-\u\x),x)^K], ^/n{F-\u\x)- F-^{u\x))^Dg{u\x), as a stochastic process indexed by {u,x) Corollary 3 (Monotonically correct G for each (u,x) UX, then G UXk- case). yX* = yX Suppose u and \-^ UX* = UX. vergence in Proposition 5 holds uniformly over the entire Dg{u\x) = G{u\x), i.e., Q{u\x) has Q'{u\x) Accordingly, yX the rearranged quantile curves have the and UX. same > the con- Moreover, order as- first ymptotic distribution as the original quantile curves. Thus, and in the initial monotonically correct case, the quantile estimates coincide. first Hence, all order properties of the rearranged the inference tools that apply to original quantile estimates also apply to the rearranged quantile estimates. In particular, if the bootstrap is valid for the original estimate, estimate, by the functional delta of Section 4, we method it is also valid for the rearranged for the bootstrap. In the empirical exploit this useful property to construct uniform confidence example bands for the conditional quantile functions based on the rearranged quantile function estimates. 16 In addition to tlie results on quantile function estimates, Proposition 6 provides the asymptotic properties of the distribution function estimates. The preceding remark about the vahdity of bootstrap applies also to these estimates. In the monotonically incorrect case, the large sample properties of the rearranged quantile estimates differ from those of the initial quantile estimates. Proposition 6 enables us to perform inferences for rearranged curves in this case, including by the bootstrap, but only after excluding certain nonregular neighborhoods (for the distribution estimates, the neighborhood of the critical values of the map u t—> Q{u\x), and, for the rearranged quantile estimates, the image of the latter neighborhood under F{y\x)). However, we consider if the following linear functionals of the rearranged quantile and distribution estimates: {y',x)^ / l{y < y'}g{y\x)F{y\x)dy, {u,x)^ Jy < u'}g{u\x)F~\u\x)du, l{u / Ju then we no longer need to exclude the nonregular neighborhoods. The following proposition describes the empirical properties of these functionals in large samples. Proposition 7 (Empirical Properties Proposition specified l{y < y'}g{y\x){F{y\x) - as a stochastic process indexed by {y',x) l{u ^/n F{y\x))dy ^ on the < u'}g{u\x){F-'^{u\x) G yX, I \{y < y']g{y\x)DG{y\x)dy, Jy in i°°{yX). - F-\u\x))du =» l{u < u'}g{u\x)DG{u\x)du, Ju Ju as stochastic process indexed by {u',x) G The restrictions on The the conditions of domains: Jy 2. Under the following results are true with the limits being continuous 6, V^ [ I. of Integrated Curves). UX, the function g are the linear functionals defined in i°°{UX). same as in Proposition above are useful building blocks 4- for various statistics, such as partial means, various moments, and Lorenz curves. For example, the conditional Lorenz curve is L{u\x) = ( / l{f < u}F-\t\x)dt'^/(^ I F-\t x)dt 17 which is statistics a ratio of a partial to the Hadamard mean. differentiability of these with respect to the underlying Q{u\x) immediately follows from the Hadamard differentiability of the rule. mean elementary functionals of Proposition 7 by means of the chain Therefore, the asymptotic distribution of these statistics can be determined from the asymptotic distribution of the linear functionals, by the functional delta method. In particular, the validity of the bootstrap for these functionals functional delta method is preserved by the for the bootstrap. We next consider the empirical properties of the smoothed curves obtained by applying the hnear smoothing operator SF{y\x) := The Jh{y - S defined in (2.6) to F{y'\x) and F~^{u\x): SF-\u\x) := y')F{y'\x)dy', J ks{u following corollary immediately follows from Corollary 2 - u')F-\u'\x)du'. and the functional delta method. Corollary 4 (Large Sample Properties Proposition 6, of Smoothed Curves). Under the conditions of in ^°°{yM), MSF{y\x) - SF{y\x)) as a stochastic process indexed by {y,x) ^/7^{SF-\u\x) ^ S[Dc{y\x)], E yX, and - SF-\u\x)) as a stochastic process indexed by {u,x) E in ^°°{UX), ^ S[bG{u\x)l UX. Thus, inference on the smoothed rearranged estimates can be performed without excluding nonregular neighborhoods, which validity of the bootstrap for the is convenient for practice. Furthermore, smoothed curves follows by the functional delta method for the bootstrap. 3. Theory of Rearranged Distribution Curves The rearrangement method can also be applied to rearrange cumulative distribution curves monotonically by exchanging the roles of the quantile and probability spaces. There are several situations where one might be faced with the problem of nonincreasing empirical distribution curves. In an option pricing context, for example, 18 Ait-Sahalia and Duarte (2003) use market data to estimate a risk-neutral distribution. Estimation error may cause the resulting distribution function to be non-monotonic. In other cases the distribution curve obtained by some inverse transformation and local is non-monotonicity comes as an artefact of the regularization technique. In other situa- may tions the particular estimation technique and Yao, 1999). Wolff, We not respect monotonicity (see, e.g., Hall, present an alternative solution to this problem that uses the rearrangement method. Here we do not present the conditional case however, are exactly parallel to those presented in this for conditional distributions, Suppose we have y h^ P{y) section. for notational convenience. All derivations as a candidate empirical probability distribution curve, which does not necessarily satisfy monotonicity, with population counterpart P{y). Define the following quantile curve rQ /•oo Q[u) l{P{y)< u}dy - = which yC is The In what tities inverse of the quantile curve is Q The u}dy, further assume that the support of P{y) it is can be treated analogously first). F{y) which we follows, +oo), so that the second term drops out (otherwise [0, to the monotone. l{P{y)> J -oo JQ also and the rearranged probabihty curve = M{y:Q{u)>y}, construction. It should be clear at this point that the quan- are exactly symmetric to F and monotone by F is Q following improved approximation property distribution function, then for (J |Fo(y) where the inequality and y h^ P{y) is strictly increasing. is - all p G is true for F: Let Fo{y) be the true [l,oo], F{y)\Pdy^ strict for in the quantile case. ' < \Fo{y) - P{y)\''dy^ , (j^ p E (l,cx)) whenever the integral on the right is finite decreasing on a subset of positive Lebesgue measure,, while Fo(u) This property to hold in the population. is independent of the sample size, is and thus continues 19 In the monotonically correct case, that is when P' {Q{u)) > for all u G [0, 1], if the empirical distribution curve P{y) satisfies V^[Piy)~P{y))^G{y) where in i°°{y), G is a Gaussian process, then in£°°([0,l]),and, in e^{y), V^(F(y)-F(y))^G(y). (3.1) Results paralleling those of the previous section also follow for the monotonically incorrect case. In particular, we have - Q{u)) ^/^ {q{u) ^^"^G(y,(.)) =^ E^ fc=i in £°°([0, 1]), and ' '* K(u) \ ^(^<"'-'^')-(1f(^) in ^°°{y), is where {yk{u), bounded uniformly for A; = 1, ..., K{u)] K(u) twmk^ are the roots of P{y) = u, (3.2) u=P[y) assuming K{u) in u. 4. 4.1. {ykH)\ Empirical Example. To Illustrative Examples illustrate the practical applicability of the method, we consider the estimation of expenditure curves. We rearrangement use the original Engel (1857) data, from 235 budget surveys of 19th century working-class Belgium households, to estimate the relationship between food expenditure and annual household income (see Koenker, 2005). Ernst Engel originally presented these data to support the hypothesis that food expenditure constitutes a declining share of household income (Engel's Law). In Figure 3, we show a scatterplot of the Engel data on food expenditure versus house- hold income, along with quantile regression curves with the qua.ntile indices {05,0.1, 0.95}. We see that the quantile regression lines become closer and cross ..., at low values of 20 income. This crossing problem of the Engel curves we also evident in Figure 4, in is which plot the quantile regression process of food expenditure as a function of the quantile index. For low values of income, the quantile regression process The rearrangement procedure is clearly non-monotone. non-monotonicity producing increasing quantile fixes the functions. Moreover, the rearranged curves coincide with their quantile regression coun- terparts for the middle values of income where there In Figure 5, we plot simultaneous 90% no quantile-crossing problem. is confidence intervals for the conditional quantile function of food expenditure for different values of income (at the sample median, and the 5% percentile of income). We construct the bands using both original quantile regression curves and rearranged quantile curves based on 500 bootstrap repetitions and a grid of quantile indices {0.10, 0.11, .... 0.90}. We obtain the bands for the rearranged curves assuming that the population quantile regression curves are monotonically that the first order behavior of the rearranged curves coincides with the behavior of the original curves. bands lie correct, so The shows that even figure for the within the quantile regression bands. low value of income the rearranged This observation points towards the maintained assumption of the monotonically correct case. The lack of monotonicity of the estimated quantile regression process in this case is likely to by caused by sampling error. We find more evidence consistent with the monotonically which we plot the simultaneous confidence bands and rearranged curves. We (with bandwidth equal to ranged curves even in the for the correct case in Figure smoothed quantile regression construct the band by bootstrapping the smoothed curves The bootstrap bands .05). are valid for the smoothed rear- monotonically incorrect case. The almost perfect overlapping between the confidence bands points towards the monotonically correct ingly, 6, in case. Interest- smoothing reduces the width of the confidence bands, but does not completely monotonize the quantile regression curves. 4.2. Monte Carlo. We use the following Monte Carlo experiment, matching closely the previous empirical apphcation, to illustrate the estimation properties of the rearranged curves in finite samples. In particular, scale shift model: Y= Z{X)'a + we consider two designs based on the {Z{X)'')')e, where e is location- independent of X, with the true 21 Figure The 3. scatterplot and quantile regression food expenditure data. The on food expenditure household income vs. plot fits of the Engel shows a scatterplot of the Engel data for a sample of 235 19th cen- tury working-class Belgium households. Superimposed on the plot are the {0.05, 0.10, ...,0.95} quantile regression curves. The range displayed corre- sponds to values of income lower than 1500 and values of food expenditure lower than 800. conditional quantile function Qo{u\X) Design 1 = Z{xya + {Z{Xy^)Q,{u). includes a constant and a regressor, namely has an additional nonlinear regressor, namely, a = median(X). We select the parameters empirical example, employing the estimation design 1 we set a = (624,15,0.55) and 7 = Z{X) = Z{X) = (1,.Y, for designs 1 method of and {1,X); and design 2 1{X > 2 to a} X), where match the Engel Koenker and Xiao (2002). For (1,0.0013); and for design 2 we set a = 22 Income = 394 (1% A. quantile) B. Income = 452 (5% quantile) 0.0 Income = 884 (Median) C. Figure D. 0.2 0.6 0.4 Income = 2533 (99% quantile) Quantile regression processes and rearranged quantile pro- 4. cesses for the Engel food expenditure data. Quantile regression estimates are plotted with a thick gray line, whereas the rearranged estimates are plotted in black. (624.15,0.55,-0.003) and 7 Monte Carlo samples of size = (1,0.0017,-0.0003). n = 235. To generate the we draw observations from a normal the residuals X e = (V - Z(A')'a')/(Z(X)'7) use designs 1 and values of the dependent variable, distribution with the of the in all the replications to the observations of We For each design, we draw 1,000 Engel data income same mean and variance set; in the and we fix Engel data as the regressor set. 2 to assess the estimation properties of the original and rear- ranged quantile regressions under the correct and incorrect specification of the functional 23 A. Figure 5. Income = 452 (5% quantile) Simultaneous Income = 884 (Median) B. 90% confidence bands for quantile regression processes and rearranged quantile processes for the Engel food expenditure data. Two bands for quantile regression are plotted in light gray, for different values of the income regressor are considered. The rearranged quantile regression are plotted in dark gray. form. Thus, in each replication, Q{u\X) we estimate the model = Z{Xyp{u), Z{X) = This gives the correct functional form incorrect functional form for design 2, for that design is 1, that Q{u\X) a nonlinear regressor). Accordingly, estimation error sampling and whereas the bands ^ {l,X). is, Q{u\X) = Qo{u\X), and an Qo{u\X) (due to the omission for design error, while the estimation error for design 2 arises 1 arises entirely of due to due to both sampling error specification error. Regardless of the nature of the estimation error, Proposition 5 establishes that the rearranged quantile curves should be closer to the true conditional quantiles than the original curves. 24 A. Figure tile Income = 452 (5% 6. Simultaneous regression processes for the quantile) 90% B. Income = 884 (Median) confidence bands for the smoothed quan- and the smoothed rearranged quantile processes Engel food expenditure data. The bands for the smoothed original curves are plotted in light gray, whereas the bands for the smoothed rear- ranged curves are plotted in dark gray. The smoothed curves are obtained using a bandwidth equal to 0.05. In each replication, monotonize we fit this curve to get a linear quantile regression curve Q{u\X) = X (3{u) F~^{u\X) using the rearrangement method. Table 1 and reports measures of the estimation error of the original and rearranged estimated conditional quantile curves using different a value, We X = norms {p = xq, that corresponds to the select this value 1,2, 3,4, 5% and oo), with the regressor fixed at quantile of the regressor X {X = 452). motivated by the empirical example. Each entry of the table gives a Monte Carlo average of i/p U':={ / \QQ{u\xo)-Q{u\xoWdu 25 for Q{u\xo) indices Both u = XqP{u) and Q{u\xo) = F~^{u\xq). We evaluate the integral using a net of of size .01. and in the correctly specified case in the misspecified case, we find that the rearranged curves estimate the true quantile curves Qo{u\X) more accurately than the original curves, providing a 4% to 15% reduction in the estimation/approximation error, depending on the norm. Table Estimation Error of Original and Rearranged Curves. 1. Correct Specification Design 2 Incorrect Specification Original Rearranged Ratio Original Rearranged Ratio L' 6.79 6.61 0.96 7.33 7.02 0.95 L2 7.99 7.69 0.95 8.72 8.20 0.93 L3 8.93 8,51 0.95 9.85 9.12 0.92 L' 9.70 9.17 0.94 10.78 9.86 0.91 L°° 17.14 15.32 0.90 19.44 16.44 0.85 Design 1 5. Conclusion This paper analyzes a simple regularization procedure for estimation of conditional quantile and distribution functions based on rearrangement operators. Starting from a possibly non-monotone empirical curve, the procedure produces a rearranged curve that not only satisfies the natural monotonicity requirement, but also has smaller mation error than the original curve. Asymptotic distribution theory rearranged curves, and the usefulness of the approach is is esti- derived for the illustrated with an empirical example and a simulation experiment. ^ Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Department of Economics and Operations Research Center, University College London, CEMMAP, and The University of Chicago. E-mail: vchern@mit.edu. Research support from the Castle Krob Chair, National Science Foundation, the Sloan Foundation, and § CEMMAP is gratefully acknowledged. Boston University, Department of Economics. E-mail: ivanf@hu.edu. 26 I Harvard University, Department of Economics. E-mail: galichon@fas.harvard.edu. Research support from the Conseil General des Mines and the National Science Foundation is gratefully acknowledged. 27 Appendix A.l. Proof of Proposition Proofs note that the distribution of Y^ has no atoms, First, 1. A. i.e., Pr[y^ since the = = y] number Fv[Q{U\x) = = y] Pr[[/ e = of roots of Q{u\x) y {ueU is finite Next, by assumptions (a)-(b) the number of & root of Q{u\x) -.u is under (a) - (b), critical values of and = U~ Q{u\x) is y}] = 0, Uniform(W). hence finite, claim (1) follows. Next, for any regular l{Q{u\x) / <y]du= where Uo{y\x) := we can write F{y\x) y, and {uk{y\x), in increasing order. first term 0}{uk+i{y\x) '^K{y\x){y\->-))- for /c = 1, <y]du+ ...,K{y\x) < l{Q{u\x) oo} are the roots oiQ{u\x) < y} = 1 = l{Q'{ui:+i{y\x)\x) Uk{y\x)); while the last term simplifies to 1{Q' {uK{y\x){y\x)\x) An y]du, y Hence on the interval [uk^i{y\x),Uk{y\x)]. in the previous expression simplifies to Y^i^Iq — < I Note that the sign of Q'{u\x) alternates over consecutive Uk{y\x), determining whether l{Q(y|a:) the \{Q{u\x) / J^ as < 0}(1 > - additional simplification yields the expression given in claim (2) of the proposition. The proof of claim (3) follows that at any regular value y the by taking the derivative number of solutions of expression in claim (2), noting K{y\x) and sign{Q' {uk{y\x)\x)) are locally constant; moreover, >( x_ sign{Q'{uk{y\x)\x)) '''^^^^^~ I \Q'iu,{y\x)\x)\ Combining these To show derivative, Theorem facts we get the expression for the derivative given in claim (3), the absolute continuity of F{y\x) with /(y|x) being the Radon-Nykodym = J^^dF{y\x), cf it suffices to show that for 31.8 in Billingsley (1995). centered on the critical points yl}f{y\x)dy = /^^ y^^ each y' G 3^x, Jl^f{y\^)dy Let V^^ be the union of closed balls of radius \y*, and define y^ l{y e yl}dF{y\x). Since the set of = Then, J^ points 3^^, \ y* l{y G yx\V{^. critical t is finite 28 and has mass zero under F{y\x), J^^l{y G yl}dF{y\x) Therefore, Claim l{y € yi}f{y\x)dy /_^;^ we have that F{y\x) = = F [F~'^ [u\x)\x) = the equation u Claim We (5). function of a -t- have Y^ (3Q{U\x) = = !Q^s\x)<y^^ Q~'^ s — Q{s\x) > ^s<Q-Hy\x)^^ = is {F~^ [u\x)\x) yields F~^{u\x) (3Y^, for > /3 therefore inf{y 0, is t ^ 0. increasing and Q~\y\^)- Inverting = Q{u\x). Q{U\x) has quantile function F~^{u\x). = a+ as J^;^ dF{y\x). by noting that at the regions where (4) follows one-to-one, = fiy\x)dy ] r_'^ J^^dF{y\x) t : Pr(a The + quantile PV^ < y) > = a + (3F~^{u\x). u} Claim (6) is Claim (7). immediate from claim The proof (3). of continuity of F{y\x) subsumed is Proposition 3 (see below). Therefore, for any sequence F{y\x) uniformly in F{y\x) = y, and F{y\x) u has a unique root y is = continuous. Xt A. 2. of the proof of —^ x we have that F{y\xt) F~^{u\x), the root of F{y\xt) e.g., = Ut, x. i.e., — Since yt = van der Vaart and Wellner D Proof of Propositions Lemma 1 Let Ut —^ u and Xt -^ F'^{ut\xt), converges to y by a standard argument, see, (1997). in the step 1, 2-7. In the proofs that follow we repeatedly use will which establishes the equivalence of continuous convergence and uniform convergence: Lemma 1. Let D and D' be complete separable metric spaces, with D compact. Suppose f D ^> D' is continuous. Then a sequence of functions fn'-D^D' converges to f uniformly on D if and only if for any convergent sequence x^ ^> x in D we have that : fni^n) -^ f{x). Proof of Lemma See, for example, Resnick (1987), page 1: Proof of Proposition for u e B^{uk{y\x)) and l{Qiu\x) for all k e I, ..., + 2. We for small tht{u\x) have that enough <y}< + any tht{u\x) ^ > 0, D there exists e > > l{Q{u\x) K{y\x); whereas for ah u l{Q{u\x) t for 2. + t{h{uk{y\x)\x) - [JkB^{ui,{y\x)), as <y} = l{Q{u\x) < i ^ y}. 0, 5) < y}, such that 29 Therefore, f^ l{Q{u\x) ^ ""y + tht{u\x) l{Q{u\x) f ~- < y]du - + t{h{u,{y\x)\x) - < 5) - y} < l{Q{u\x) y} ^^ i JB,{uk(y\x)) k=l < y}du J^ l{Q{u\x) which by the change of variables y' — Q{u\x) equal to is K{y\x) ^ dy\ \Y. fc=l where Jk the image of B^{uk{y\x)) under u is possible because for Fixing > e for 0, - t{h{uk{y\x)\x) small enough, Q{-\x) e i — > we have that 0, Y^ ES'^^ lQ'"u[l£')t^^ is Jk fl [y,y + 5 — 5)] = ^ [y,y — Uk{y\x). ^ ^ Lemma result holds uniformly in {y,x) Take a sequence of 1. uniformly continuous on K, and tinuous on K. To {yt,Xt) in pact sets [Ki, K{y\x) (1) follows = ..., ^ Since 5 > can be K that converges to (y,x) G ..., some Km) of Uk{y\x) (implied (1) the function {y,x) the function (y,x) K i-^- K{y\x) integer kj > K, then the i-^ \o'(u''( \x)\x)\ uniformly con- is excludes a neighborhood of critical points such that the function K{y\x) by noting that the the sets {Ki, E K, a compact subset of yP^*, we 0, for all (y, x) is number of com- constant over each of these sets, therefore can be expressed as the union of a finite Km) kj for (2) see (2), note that {y\yx,x € ^), and i.e., t{h{uk{y\x)\x) ^(1) bounds (A.l) from below. preceding argument applies to this sequence, since is — than ^lO greater \Q'{uk{y\x)\x)\ + is arbitrarily small, the result follows. To show that the use of variables one-to-one between B^{uf.{y\x)) and J^. -h{uk{y\x)\x) ^ made The change Q{-\x). i-^ 5)1 and \Q'{Q-\y'\x)\x)\ -^ \Q' {uk{y\x)\x)\ as Q-\y'\x) Therefore, the right hand term in (A.l) Similarly is ^{y'\x)\x \Q' [Q J Jkn\y,v-t{Huk(y\x)\x)^6)] i E Kj and j limit expression for the derivative by the assumed continuity of h{u\x) in G is {1, ..., M}. Likewise, continuous on each of both arguments, continuity by the Implicit Function Theorem), and the assumed continuity of Q'{u\x) in both arguments. D 30 Proof of Proposition quantile operator For a fixed x the result follows by Proposition and by an application of the Hadamard of the proof below, 1 3. shown by Doss and Gill (1992). 2, by step differentiability of the Step 2 establishes uniformity over xeX. Step 1. Let /C be a compact subset of 3^^*. Let to a point, say (y, x). Then, for every such sequence, \yt - -^ y| be a sequence (y^, Xt) Ct := ^||/!-t||oo in K, convergent + ||<?(-kt) — <5('k)||oo + and 0, \F{yt\xu ht) - < F{y\x)\ f [l{Q(n|x,) + tht{u\x) < yj - l{Q{u\x) < y}]du Jo < f l{\Q{u\x)-y\<et}du -^0, (A.2) Jo where the last step follows By function of Q{U\x). continuous in {y,x). is which in turn implies from the absolute continuity of y setting ht Lemma 1 = 2. We F{y\x), the distribution the above argument also verifies that F{y\x) implies uniform convergence of F{y\x,ht) to F{y\x), by a standard argument^ the uniform convergence F~^{u\x,ht) -^ F~^{u\x), uniformly over Step i—> have that uniformly over K* where K* is , of quantiles any compact subset oiUX*. A'*, F[F-\u\xM\:cM)-F[F-M-M)\x) ^ ^^(^-:(,|,^ ,^)|,) ^ ^^,^^ (A.3) t = Dh{F-\u\x)\x) + using Step over 1, K* by , Proposition 2, o{\), and the continuity properties of Dh{y\x). Further, uniformly Taylor expansion and Proposition F{F-\u\xM)\x) - F{F-\u\x)\x) ^ 1, as i ^(j.-i(-^|^)|^) — >• 0, -^'^H^> M - i^-HH^) ^ ^^^^^ (A.4) and (as -will be shown below) F{F-\u\x,ht)\x,ht) as i -* (A.3). 0. The ^See, e.g., Observe that the left hand - F{F-\u\x)\x) 1 in ^^_^^ side of (A. 5) equals that of (A.4) plus that of result then follows. Lemma _^^^^ Chernozhukov and Fernandez- Val (2005). 31 only remains to show that equation (A. 5) holds uniformly in K*. Note that for any It right-continuous cdf F, where F{ — ) we have denotes the strictly increasing cdf that u of F, left limit F{xo—) = i.e., F, we have that F{F~^{u)) F{F-\u\x,ht)\x,ht) 0< < F{F~^{u)) < = u + — F(F~^(n) — ), F{F~^{u)) lim3;f3;o F{x). For any continuous, Therefore, write u. - F{F-\u\x)\x) t u < + F{F~^{u\x, — F{F~^{u\x, ht) - ht)\x, ht) — |x, ht) u t F{F-\u\x, < - F{F-\u\x, ht) - ht)\x, ht) \x, ht) t (^) [F{F-\u\x,ht)\x,ht) - F{F-\u\x,ht)\x)] t [F{F-\u\x, ht) - - F{F-\u\x, ht) - \x, ht) \x)] t '=^ — where DH{F-\u\x,ht)\x) - DhiF-\u\x, we use that F{F~^{u\x, as i is continuous and strictly increasing in V The 0, following Lemma then if in (1) J Gn Proof of Lemma sition 2 —^ and y, lemma, due to Pratt (1960), < Gn and 2. Let \fn\ JG finite, Lemma 2. then ht)\x) in (2) will suppose that fn J fn —* ht) = - \x) + o(l) F{F~^{u\x, = ht) o(l), — we use Proposition \x) since 2. F{y\x) D be very useful to prove Proposition ^ f o,nd Gn —> G 4. almost everywhere, Jf D See Pratt (1960). 3 (Boundedness and Integrabihty Properties). Under the hypotheses of Propo- and 3, we have that for all {y,x) E yX \DhMx,t)\<\\ht\U, (A.6) and Jo f where for any Xt^>-xEPi,ast—^Q, A{y\xt,t) -^ 2\\h\\^f{y\x) for a.ey ey and / A{y\xt,t)dy -^ / Jy Jy 2\\h\\o^f{y\x)dy. 32 . Lemma Proof of To show 3. (A. 6) note that sup < |5ft,(y|x,t)| immediately follows from the equivariance property noted The inequality (A. 7) for a.e y ||/).t||oo E and y = Xf ^> y any Proposition 2 the case yt ^y, when > 0; Claim in x G X, > (5) of lS.{y\xt,t) Proposition -^ > f{y\x) 0; and 1. 2||/i||oo/(y|a;) 2 respectively with functions h[{u\x) = trivially otherwise). -^ 2||/i||oo/(y|a;) for a.e and trivially otherwise) /S.{yt\x, t) f{y\x) — when —\\ht\\oo (for the case Similarly, that for (for any for by applying Proposition follows h'f{u,x) That is trivial. (A.8) ||/ii||oo x ^ follows A! by . Further, by Fubini's Theorem, = Note that ft{u) .<_.2||/it||oo. enough i, 2||^||oo. By Lemma A. 3. and 2||/i4||(x) converges to any y[ — > y' < and for y'}g{y\x)Dh{y\x). x^ is t — > continuous -^ m{y\x,y'). We 3. ^ y'}g{y\x)Dht{y\x,t) and to demostrate that / m{y\x,y')dy, We we need (A.IO) have that \mt{y\xt,yt)\ a.e. and the Moreover, by Proposition to show that m{y\xt,yt)dy -^ dominated by — Jy in {x,y'). for integral of 2, for y[ bounded, for which converges almost every y we have Lemma any is — » y' 2. and Xt — > x (A.ll) m{y\x,y')dy. Jy Jy have that m{y\xt,y[) ||/ii||ooo!w J^ 2||/i||tx)- we need (1), conclude that (A.IO) holds by In order to check continuity, We trivially, 2 < for small 2||/!.t||oo x number by Lemma Tnt{y\xt.,y[) = ft{u) Then, 0. To show claim some constant C, by CA(y|xt, t) which converges to a finite -^ u, Define mt{y\x,y') := l{y 4. / mt{y\xt,y't)dy limit as 2||/i||oo Jy and that the almost every the right hand side of (A. 9) converges to Proof of Proposition m{y\x,y') := l{y for 2 Moreover, /t(") : ^ m(y|x,y') for almost every \\g\\oo\\h\\oof{y\xt), which converges to y. Moreover, m{y\xt,yt) ||5||oo||^||oo/(y|3;) for is almost every 33 y, and, moreover, /^ \\g\\o^\\h\\^f{y\x)dy converges to Lemma holds by 2. To show claim l{u < (2), define m^t{'<^\x,u') = < l{u mt{u\xt,u[)du —^ / and that the limit ^(ulxj)!!/?,^!!^), which converges to We We g'('u|a:)||/i||oo theorem. Moreover, by Proposition u. — 2, we have that m{u\xt,u[)du ^^ m{u\xt,u[) integral of The of R, 2. we need to show that as t -^ for any u[ — > u' and lemma 0. an approximation is to [1, is a function mapping a non- decreasing function Qq{u). Let FQ[y) ~ (7(0,1). = Moreover, U We conclude that (A. 13) U := 5: (0, 1) to mupping = Fq\u) = \Qoiu)~Q*{u)fdu r U K, to K inf{y G r < 1 \Q,{u) uu a bounded subset Think of Q{u) . the distribution M : Fqiy) > u}. i/p - Q{u)f du provided (1) p G (l,oo), (2) Q{u) that has positive Lebesgue measure, increasing on U. converges to the |5(ti|xt)|||/!.||oo oo], this inequality is strict a subset of almost every value of for J^l{Q{u) < y}du denote Let Q*{u) i/p uu which converges be used to prove Proposition Q{u) Q{U) when U Then, for any p G |g(u|3;j)|||/i||oo, Moreover, for smaU enough u. Furthermore, the integral of will that that Qo{u) function of (A. 13) ^, D 2. Assume 4. - by dominated convergence theorem. |g'(u|a;)|||/i||oo Lemma m{u\x,u')du. / m{u\x,u') for almost every > dominated by following Lemma as is |5(u|a;)|||/i||oo holds by m{u\x,u') for almost > Ju — have that m{u\xt,u[) u to — X > / t, bounded by by the dominated convergence mt{u\xt.,u[) Lemma conclude that (A. 12) holds by is Furthermore, the integral of u. 5^(u|a;)||/i||oo Ju We x (A. 12) have that mt{u\xt,u[) for a.e. In order to check the continuity of the limit, Xf Xt —^ and m{u\x,u')du, / continuous in {u',x). is u' = Ju converges to the integral of 5(u|a:t)||/it||oo and u'}g{u\x)Dht{u\x) and m{u\x,u') u'}g{u\x)Dh{u\x). Here we need to show that for any u[ -^ Ju every Conclude that (A.ll) ||g||oo||/i||cx:>- and is decreasing on (3) the true function Qo{u) is 34 Proof of Lemma A 4. lemma direct proof of this Chernozhukov, Fernandez- Val, Galichon (2006a). Q to Lorentz (1953): Let G and 1 of helpful to give a quick indirect It is lemma proof of the weak inequality contained in the given in Proposition is using the following inequality due U be two functions mapping K, a bounded subset to Let Q* and G* denote their corresponding increasing rearrangements. Then, we of R. have L{Q*{u),G*{u))du< / any submodular discrepancy function L for G*{u) = = \w — inequality, please refer to For p 4. = submodular v\^ is i— >• E+ In our case, p e for is its G{u) = Qq{u) = own rearrangement. For the proof of the strict [l,oo). Chernozhukov, Fernandez- Val, Galichon (2006a), Proposition oo, the inequalities follows Proof of Proposition A. 4. R^ : Qoiu) almost everywhere. Thus, the true function Moreover, L{v,w) 1. L{Q{u),G{u))du, / by taking limit as This proposition 5. is — p > oo. D an immediate consequence of Lemma D A. 5. Proof of Proposition method less (e.g. This Proposition simply follows by the functional delta 6. van der Vaart, 1998). Instead of restating what this method it takes space to simply recall the proof in the current context. To show the The sequence hn' -^ first of part, consider the maps map satisfies gn'iy,x\hr,') h in (.°°{UX*), where h is continuous. gn{y,x\h) — > It ^{Q{u\x) - process indexed by (y,x), since Conclude similarly for the Proof of Proposition to the proof of Proposition 6. second part. — y/n{F{y\x,n'^^'^h) Dh{y\x) in £'^{K) follows by the ping Theorem that, in £°°{K), gn{y, x\y/n{Q{u\x) A. 6. is, - Q{u\x))) for - F{y\x)). every subsequence Extended Continuous Map=» Ddylx) as a stochastic Qiu\x)) => G{u\x) in £°°{K). D This follows by the functional delta method, similarly 7. D References [1] Ait-Sahalia, Y. and Duarte, J. (2003),"Nonparametric option pricing under shape restrictions," Journal of Econometrics 116, pp. 9-47. 35 [2] Alvino, A., Lions, P. L. and Trombetti, G. (1989), Rearrangements," Nonlinear Analysis 13 [3] Angrist, ification, [4] Chernozhukov, V., and J., P. Mathematical [5] " A Statistics. Chernozhukov, V., and Processes. [6] (1995), Probability Sankhya I. pp. 185-220. Fernandez- Val (2006): "Quantile Regression under Misspec- I. with an Application to the U.S. Billingsley, (2), "On Optimization Problems with Prescribed Wage Structure," Econometrica 74, pp. 539-563. and measure. Third edition. Wiley Series Wiley-Interscience Publication. John Wiley Fernandez- Val (2005): & in Probability Sons, Inc., New and York. "Subsampling Inference on Quantile Regression 67, pp. 253-276. Chernozhukov, V., Fernandez- Val, and A. Galichon (2006a): "Improving Estimates of Monotone I., Functions by Rearrangement," Preprint, available at arxiv.org and ssrn.com. [7] Chernozhukov, V., Fernandez- Val, I., and A. Galichon (2006b): "An Addendum for Quantile and Probability Curves Without Crossing (Alternative Proof Directions and Explorations) [8] Dette, H., Neumeyer, N., and K. Pilz (2006): Monotone Regression Function," [9] Doksum, K. in the [10] Gill, Preprint. "A simple Nonparametric Estimator of a Bernoulli, 12, no. 3, Strictly pp 469-490. "Empirical Probability Plots and Statistical Inference for Nonlinear Models Two-Sample Case," Annals Doss, Hani; tile (1974); " of Statistics 2, pp. 267-277. Richard D. (1992), "An elementary approach to weak convergence processes, with applications to censored survival data." Journal of the American for quan- Statistical Association 87, no. 419, 869-877. [11] Dudley, R. M., and R. Norvaisa (1999), Differentiability of six operators on nonsmooth functions and p-variation. With the collaboration of Jinghua Qian. Lecture Notes in Mathematics, 1703. Springer- Verlag, Berlin. [12] Engel, E. (1857), "Die Produktions und Konsumptionsverhaltnisse des Konigreichs Sachsen," Zeitschrift des Statistischen Bureaus des Koniglich Sachsischen Misisteriums des Innerm, 8, pp. 1-54. [13] Gill, R. D., and S. Johansen (1990), "A survey of product-integration with a view toward apphca- tion in survival analysis." [14] Gutenbrunner, C, and Process [15] Statistics 18, no. 4, 1501-1555. Jureckova (1992): "Regression Quantile and Regression Rank Score the Linear Model and Derived Statistics," Annals of Statistics 20, pp. 305-330. Hall, P., Wolff, R., tion," [16] in J. Annals of and Yao, Q. (1999), "Methods for estimating a conditional distribution func- Journal of the American Statistical Association 94, pp. 154-163. Hardy, G., Littlewood, J., and G. Polya (1952), Inequalities. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. [17] He, X. (1997), "Quantile Curves Without Crossing," Am^erican Statistician, 51, pp. 186-192. 36 [18] Koenker, R. (1994): (eds.), Asymptotic "Confidence Intervals Statistics: for Regression Quantiles," in M.P. and M. Huskova Proceeding of the 5th Prague Symposium on Asymptotic Statistics. Physica-Verlag. [19] Koenker, R. (2005), Quantile Regression. Econometric Society Monograph Series 38, Cambridge University Press. [20] Koenker, R., P. Ng (2005), "Inequality constrained quantile regression." Sankhyd 67, no. 2, 418- 440. [21] Koenker, R., and Xiao (2002): "Inference on the Quantile Regression Process," Econometrica Z. 70, no. 4, pp. 1583-1612. [22] Lehmann, [23] Lorentz, G. G. (1953): Methods Based on Ranks, E. (1974): Nonparam.etrics: Statistical Sa.n Francisco: Holden- Day. "An Inequality for Rearrangements," The American Mathematical Monthly 60, pp. 176-179. [24] Milnor, [25] Mossino (1965), Topology J. J. and R. and application [26] Portnoy, Temam the differential viewpoint, Princeton University Press. (1981), "Directional derivative of the increasing rearrangement to a queer differential equation in cases," Journal of Multivariate Analysis 38 [27] Portnoy, S. , plasma physics," Duke Math. "Asymptotic behayioj of regression quantiles (1991), S. from , no. 1, in J. 48 (3), mapping 475-495. nonstationary, dependent 100-113. and R. Koenker (1997), "The Gaussian hare and the Laplacian tortoise: computability of squared-error versus absolute-error estimators," Statist. Sci. 12, no. 4, 279-300. [28] Pratt, J.W. (1960), "On interchanging limits and integrals." Annals of Mathematical Statistics 31, 74-77. [29] Resnick, A [30] S. I. values, regular variation, Vaart, A. van der (1998). Asymptotic 4. and point processes, Applied Probability. Springer- Verlag, statistics. Cambridge New York. Series in Statistical and Probabilistic 3. Vaart, A. van der, and cations to statistics, [32] Extreme Series of the Applied Probability Trust, Mathematics, [31] (1987), J. New Wellner (1996), Weak convergence and empirical processes: with appliYork: Springer. Villani, C. (2003), Topics in Optimal Transportation, Providence: American Mathematical Society. 3521 5?D