M.I.T. LIBRARIES - DEWEY Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium Member Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/noteonenvironmenOOIaff HB31 .M415 Dewey 9r- working paper department of economics A NOTE ON ENVIRONMENTAL INNOVATION Jean-Jacques Laffont Jean Tirole 95-10 June, 1994 massachusetts institute of technology 50 memorial drive Cambridge, mass. 02139 \ A NOTE ON ENVIRONMENTAL INNOVATION Jean-Jacques Laffont Jean Tirole June, 1994 95-10 MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY MAR 2 9 1995 LIBRARIES 95-10 A Note on Environmental Innovation* and Jean- Jacques Laffont^ June 16, Jean Tirole* 1994 Abstract The purpose of this exploratory note to alert the reader is, first, to the negative impact of allowance markets on environmental inno- some improvements. Stand-alone spot markets enable the government to expropriate an innovation by offervations and, second, to suggest ing a competing "technology" (pollution permits) and putting an arbitrary downward pressure on the licensing price. reduce expropriation but still Advance allowances create very suboptimal incentives for They have the further drawback that permits are ineffiused when the innovation occurs. In this respect, options to innovations. ciently pollute at a given striking price fare better than allowances because they create private incentives to phase out pollution in case of innovation. The note then studies government procurement. Surprisingly ex- post licensing by the innovator to the government may yield a higher licensing fee than an ex-ante contract. "The authors are grateful to Carlo Carraro and Paul Joskow for helpful discussions to Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei for financial support. tIDEI and GREMAQ, Toulouse, France *IDEI, Toulouse, France; CERAS, Paris; and M.I.T., Cambridge, 1 MA USA and Introduction 1 companion paper (1994) we analyze the impact In a of spot and futures markets tradeable pollution permits on the potential polluters' compliance decisions. there on the individual incentives is to adopt pollution abatement devices. The for focus In contrast, this exploratory note considers technological innovation, namely the invention of substitutes or pollution abatement devices that can be used by The all polluters. innovation therefore is a public good, while the investments considered in the companion paper are purely private. The model 2 There are two dates, tional simplicity, t = 1,2, and a continuum of agents/potential we assume no consider first-period pollution. rights N(-) given by n is = Without The demand curve agents' N(p), where p decreasing. Unlike in our is discounting. is polluters. loss of generality, we For nota- also do not for second-period pollution The the (second-period) spot price. companion paper, we do not allow agents to function make indi- vidual investments in pollution abatement (although this could be incorporated into the analysis). So, the demand function Let D(n) denote the social ment faces a + society $(1 shadow is fixed. damage where D' of pollution, cost of public funds A > 0; that is, > 0, D" > The 0. govern- money raising $1 of public costs A) because of distortionary taxation. We model innovation in a simple way. There is one potential innovator, who at private cost C(x) incurred at date 1 (C(0) = 0, C'(0) = 0, C'(l) = +oo,C > 0, and C" > for x > 0) innovates with probability x at the beginning of date 2. The a pollution-free perfect substitute for the existing polluting good, or else abatement device that can be all installed at is is a pollution no cost on any existing equipment and eliminates We will consider two cases depending potential innovator before she performs R pollution (we will use this second interpretation.) on whether a contract can be signed with the & innovation D. If such an ex ante contract can be signed (as in section the innovator is protected by limited liability (or, equivalently, income It will of the zero). R&D innovator is become process. clear that When we could consider no ex ante contract is simply granted a patent on her innovation. 1 5), is we will assume that very risk averse under more sophisticated descriptions signed (sections 3, 4 and 6), the Spot market 3 This section assumes that the government issues pollution permits in period 2 after observing whether the innovation occurs. innovator invents or not; (iii) The second-period timing is as follows: (i) the government sets a price p for pollution permits (ii) 2 ; the and the innovator sets a price i on licenses. Let us first analyze the pricing game. In the absence of innovation, the regulator chooses price p so as to solve: r N(x)dx + roo max'{ (1 + X)pN(p) Jo Letting = — J.J T)(p) the standard Ramsey denote the elasticity of demand for pollution permits, we obtain formula: p where D'/(l + A), - D(N( P ))}. i damage expressed the marginal Ki + AiHp)* in monetary units, is the marginal cost of "producing the 'good pollution'". In case of innovation, the inventor, who has a lower cost (namely 0) of enabling agents produce than the regulator (who has marginal cost D'/(l to slightly the price for pollution permits. Welfare is + A)), always undercuts therefore equal to / °° N(x)dx. 3 p The regulator therefore chooses: p Because the innovator does not make a chooses not to perform R&D (x = = 0. (2) profit in either state of nature, she rationally 0). Advance allowances 4 This section shows that, while spot markets destroy incentives for innovation (see section 3), futures markets bring limited improvement, even issue permits in order to exert rights to pollute if the regulator can commit not to downward pressure on the license fee. both substantially discourages innovation and may Granting advance induce a suboptimal adoption. In case of innovation, the spot price adjusts downward so as to allow permits to compete with the innovation. 2 By exerting price pressure on the licenses of the innovation, We could alternatively allow the government to choose the number of permits instead of their treatment of this case would follow the lines of the analysis in section 4. The 3 This expression holds as long as the price does not exceed the inventor's monopoly clearly inefficient to set a price above the monopoly price. price. price. But it is allowances substantially devalue the innovator's property right and reduce the incentive to innovate. To illustrate this simple point, consider the following potential polluters and n advance permits sold in period price falls to zero and so does the price of rationally chooses not to perform the n units of pollution and is R k, D 1. extreme example: There are n In case of innovation, the spot licenses sold to the = (i 0), n polluters. The innovator even though the innovation eliminates awarded a patent. Advance permits have a second perverse example, but does occur more generally. that need not occur in this extreme effect, Let us assume that the innovator first is not allowed to trade on the permits market. Unless the equilibrium price for pollution control (through either a license from the innovator or a permit) equal to zero (in which case is the innovation does not take place anyway), the existing n permits are used ex post even though the innovation could completely eradicate pollution. Let N(p) denote the secondperiod demand curve, with inverse the innovation occurs: > P(n) and no Either p innovator); or p < P(n) and the same as more allows Let us The number consider the following timing after innovator sets a license price p, (b) then the market for a) the permits clears. for permits. demand P{n). And license sold (which is is not optimal for the the innovator de facto picks the price on the spot market of licenses sold in the absence of innovation. is then [N(p) The only — n]. So, the level of pollution positive effect of innovation is that is it potential polluters to produce. now analyze the innovator's choice of pricing and R&D intensity. Let pm denote the constrained monopoly price for the innovator: p m \p is m maximizes actually a slight misnomer. {p[N(p) The permits — n] } (3) . play the role of a competitive fringe, and, by a standard revealed preference argument, force the innovator to charge a lower license price p m that she would charge in their absence.] Let The innovator chooses m denote the resulting maximand. R&D level x so as to solve: i To summarize, the II sale of maximizes {xll m — C(x)} (4) . advance permits has two perverse effects here: First, the permits partially prevent the adoption of a superior, pollution-free technology. Second, they further reduce the innovator's incentive to innovate (this incentive is already subop- timal in the absence of permits because the innovator does not internalize the increase in "consumer surplus" brought about by the innovation.) Let us now allow the innovator to trade on the permits market. of licensing costs, the innovator's profit is In the absence independent of the number of permits she purchases. purchasing n np and has n), pays still When quite low. But, n = n, the permits, she faces residual — h]. The p[N(p) profit if < h demand curve N(p) — in — innovator's incentives are unchanged and are n units of pollution are eradicated, and welfare than when the innovator does not trade in is higher the permits market. Unfortunately, the innovator's (weak) willingness to buy permits on the market in case of innovation disappears The innovator's profit, (p of the number has then no The crux when she — an arbitrarily small marginal cost faces e)[N(p) — — n)] —pn, (n is now a strictly decreasing function of repurchased permits n. Allowing the innovator to trade on the market effect. of the matter is that none of the market participants (polluters, innovator) internalizes the social cost of pollution of the leftover permits. To induce market pants to phase out the wasteful permits in case of innovation, one possibility these permits to pollute by options with a striking price ing cost t of licensing. e of the innovator. is partici- to replace exceeding the marginal licens- tj In contrast with final sales of permits, sales of options have the desirable property that they provide incentives to therefore to retire previous rights to pollute. make full use of the They furthermore have a innovation and beneficial impact on the incentive to innovate as they restore some of the innovator's monopoly power lost with the issuance of permits. Alternatively the government, which internalizes the social cost of pollution of the over permits, could respond to innovation by buying back some permits. could also purchase the innovation from the innovator (see section The government 6). Procurement 5 By left- opposition with the market-oriented approach of the previous section, this section con- siders the ideal planning solution. We make the strong assumption that the government can ex ante identify the potential innovation and designs an incentive contract for the innovator so as to maximize social welfare. The government optimally issues no advance permits at date purchase the innovation at some price property rights on the innovation, free technology, namely the Once the government q. it sells the license at the 1. Rather it promises to acquires the (exclusive) Ramsey price for the pollution- price that solves: -— \ r-^-rh- (5) p Let W R denote the associated social welfare. there is no innovation and the government Similarly sells let WR denote social welfare when the corresponding optimal number of permits in period — {xq 2. 4 The innovator reacts to incentive q by choosing x so as to maximize C(x)} or C'(x) The optimal procurement = q. (6) policy consists in choosing q, or equivalently x, so as to maxi- mize: xW R + (1 We - x)W R - + (1 + \)xq - [xq C{x)) = xW R + (1 - x)W R - - C(x) \xC'{x). obtain: W R - WR = + (1 A)C'(x') + Xx*C"(x For instance, in the case of a quadratic cost function (C"(x) q Because it is Ex 6 computed xC"(x)), one has ' 1+2A costly to leave rents to the innovator, the prize q' social value of the innovation (7) ). WR-W R _ m = m at the shadow = C'(x') is lower than the cost of public funds tv ( 1 7J^ )• post licensing to the government Suppose now that no contract between the potential innovator and the government can be signed at date in but that the government can purchase the innovation at date 2 and, as 1, the previous subsection, license move bargaining between date The government 2. agreed with the innovator following period 1). The it to the agents. We assume frequent-offer, alternating- the government and the innovator starting at the beginning of issues short-term pollution permits as long as (so, we are now it has not yet treating "period 9" as an infinite-horizon reader will check that the licensing- fee by the Nash bargaining solution with reservation value W R is game equal to the one given for the government (as in Binmore- Rubinstein- Wolinski (1986)): 5 W R -WR q A £>() 5 WR and WR are equal to the = and £>{•) = Let u^ = (1 —2A— = (8) maximal values of {-D(N(p)) + (I + A)pAT(p) + /" N(x)dx} for £>(•), respectively. R R denote the discount factor corresponding to the bargaining periods, w = (\ — 0)W and — /3)W R denote the per-period welfares, and qt and g,- denote the equilibrium offers when the P government and the innovator make the offer. Then: qt w R -Xqi = fa, and = w R -0\qa . Note that (as may seem surprising in view of the asset specificity literature, which emphasizes the role is for instance the case for quadratic cost functions) q of long-term contracts in reducing expropriation by the buyer by the supplier through the promise of a high transfer price. may exceed q'. This and encouraging investment There are two differences with the asset specificity literature. First, the buyer (the government) here partly internalizes more importantly, the the seller's welfare. Second, and seller faces limited liability. are then not quite transferable, and a long-term procurement contract does not utilities maximize The total surplus of the two parties. innovator's rent. 6 The public funds. licensing fee is reduced so as to limit the possibility that ex post bargaining yield than (ex ante) procurement is The government nicely illustrated is a higher licensing price by the case of a very low shadow cost But would never agree ex it ante to such a price because this would give excessive incentives for case in which q > of then willing ex post to accept almost an infinite licensing price in order not to delay the adoption of the innovation. The The q* actually raises several issues. First, it is R&D. not in the interest of the innovator to sign ex ante a contract with the government. Second, as in Hart-Moore (1992), an innovator to force it who has to raise the price signed an ex ante contract might blackmail the government from q* to q to complete the research, if she is indispensable for its completion. Last, we have assumed that the innovator does not while bargaining with the government. parties more The sell short-term licenses to the agents possibility of short-term licenses patient in the bargaining process. We makes both have not yet studied the net effect. Summary 7 The purpose of this exploratory note has been, first, to alert the reader to the negative impact of allowance markets on environmental innovations and, second, to suggest some improvements. Stand-alone spot markets enable the government to expropriate an innovation by offering a competing "technology" (pollution permits) and putting an arbitrary downward pressure on the still licensing price. Advance allowances reduce expropriation but create very suboptimal incentives for innovation. that permits are inefficiently used when the innovation They have the further drawback occurs. In this respect, options to pollute at a given striking price fare better than allowances because they create private incentives to phase out pollution in case of innovation. The note then studied government procurement. Surprisingly ex post licensing by the innovator to the government 6 cost may yield a higher licensing fee than In a private context, the licensing fee C is concave (convex). is an ex ante contract. higher (lower) under a long-term contract if the marginal MIT LIBRARIES Ml III 3 9080 00922 5183 The Limited scope of this note has of a futures market as a guide left many issues unexplored. For for the agents' individual example, the role investments in pollution-abating technologies and the issues of agent rent extraction (that are the focus of our companion paper) were more left here out of the analysis. Another desirable extension would describe in detail the microstructure of the innovation process (see Aghion-Tirole (1993)) examine how financing, control rights on the process, property and return from licensing would be optimally split among government, users of the innovation and financiers.) consider more complex incentive futures markets, procurement, rights and on the innovation the several actors (innovator, Last, it would be very useful to mechanisms than the simple ones (stand-alone markets, and ex post licensing to the government) analyzed here. References Aghion, P. and J. Tirole [1993] "On the Management of Innovation" , forthcoming, Quar- terly Journal of Economics. Binmore, K., Rubinstein, A. and A. Wolinsky [1986] "The Nash Bargaining Solution Economic Modeling", The Rand Journal of Economics, 17:176-188. Hart, 0. and J. Moore [1992] Capital", mimeo. "A Theory of Debt Based on the Inalienability of in Human and J. Tirole [1994] "Pollution Permits and Compliance Strategies", Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei Discussion Paper. Laffont, J.- J. !i906