MIT LIBRARIES DUPL 3 9080 02524 4523 Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium Member Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/inflationtargetiOOcaba ?^ Massachusetts Institute of Technology Department of Economics Working Paper Series INFLATION TARGETING AND SUDDEN STOPS Ricardo J. Caballero Arvind Krishnamurthy Working Paper 03-10 February 19, 2003 Room E52-251 50 Memorial Drive Cambridge, This MA 02142 paper can be downloaded without charge from the Network Paper Collection at Social Science Research http://ssm.com/abstract=383741 MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY MAY 3 2003 LIBRARIES Inflation Targeting Ricardo J. and Sudden Stops Arvind Krishnamurthy* Caballero This draft: February 19, 2003 Abstract Emerging economies experience sudden stops we have argued to in monetary policy during these sudden stops for in capital inflows. As Caballero and Krishnamurthy (2002), having access is useful, but mostly demand reasons. In this cannot commit to monetary policy "insurance" rather than for aggregate environment, a central bank tliat choices will ignore the insurance aspect and foUow a procychcal rather than the optimal countercychcal monetary pohcy. will also intervene excessively to inefficiencies are The support the exchange bank central rate. These exacerbated by the presence of an expansionary In order to solve these problems, bank's objective to (i) we propose modifying the bias. central include state-contingent inflation targets, (ii) target a measure of inflation that overweights non-tradable inflation, and (iii) weigh reserves holdings. JEL Codes: Keywords: EO, E4, E5, FO, F3, F4, Gl External shocks, domestic and international liquidity, inflation targeting, fear of floating, commitment, underinsurance. MIT and NBER; Northwestern University. This paper was prepared NBER's Conference on Inflation Targeting, January 2.3-26, 200.3, Bal Harbour, Florida. We are grateful to Ben Bernanke, Andrew Hertzberg and conference participants for their comments. We thank Donna Zerwitz for editorial assistance. Caballero 'Respectively: for the thanks the ity NSF for financial support. Krishnamurthy thanks the IMF for their hospital- while this paper was being written. All errors are our own. E-mails: caball@mit.edu, a-krishnamurthv@northwestern.edu. Introduction 1 Underlying weaknesses in the domestic financial sector and limited integra- make emerging market economies vulneraWithout much warning, the capital boom may come to a halt, exposing the country to an tion with world financial markets ble to "sudden stops" of capital inflows. flows that support a external crisis. Monetary policy in this context has often been seen as an additional source of problems rather than as a remedy. inflation problems have limited central bank Countries with a history of credibility. The currency pres- sures of the sudden stop test this credibility, so that either the loss of credibility or the attempt to regain it in the middle of the crisis exacerbates the contraction. However, there and unstable a group of countries for which the problem of high is inflation is no longer present but the problem of sudden stops These countries include persists. Chile, Mexico, and many of the Asian Moreover, looking towards the future, this group economies. is bound to grow, as hopefully Brazil, Turkey, and countries of Eastern Europe establish and discipline over seignorage Many fiscal policies. of these advanced emerging economies are now in the process of designing their monetary policy framework. Given the success of "inflation targeting" in a wide range of economies, framework be contemplated for it seems only natural that this these economies as well. In this paper, we study how inflation targeting should be adapted to countries whose primary macroeconomic concern The the presence of sudden stops in capital inflows. starting point of our anah'sis Krishnamurthy (2002) its is potency. resources. that, during a dubbed is the observation from Caballero and sudden stop, monetary policy loses The principal constraint on output is a shortage of external The main effect of domestic money, on the other hand, is on agents' domestic borrowing capacity. central is bank to the outflow "fear of floating" Thus, the knee-jerk reaction of the of capital, of raising domestic interest rates by Calvo and Reinhart (2002) the natural consequence of a central bank that and output. Raising with limited eff'ects However, while interest rates reduces the is — — within our model concerned with inflation exchange rate depreciation, on output beyond the impact of the external constraint. fear of floating may seem optimal from this contemporaneous perspective, it is The reason suboptimal ex-ante . suboptimality for this is that the anticipation of the central bank's tight monetary pohcy during the sudden-stop has important effects on the private sector's incentives to insure against sudden-stop events. In- suring against these events means taking prior actions that increase the total dollar assets of the country (decreeise the total dollar liabilities of the country) in the sudden-stop event. Since a contractionary monetary policy reduces the domestic scarcity value of dollars, it also lowers the returns to hoarding net dollar assets. Simply put, contracting dollar debt in an environment where the peso of a costly is less expected to be supported in the event Thus, the anticipation of a tight monetary policy leaves the crisis. economy is less insured against the sudden-stop. In this context, expectations shape policy, not in whether inflation ticipated or unanticipated, but in how the private sector views its is an- rewards to insuring against sudden-stops. For incentive reasons, the optimal monetary rule is to expand during external contemporaneous It effect crises, even if the expansion has a limited on output. should be apparent that time inconsistency context. A central bank that cannot commit is a serious issue in this will ignore the insurance as- pect of monetary policy and follow a procyclical, rather than the optimal made worse by the presence of an expanBarro and Gordon (1983). The reason is that the central countercyclical policy. This bias sionary bias a la bank only it is sees a benefit from expanding during normal times. As a result, lowers interest rates during these times, leading to higher inflation (as in Barro and Gordon). When the sudden- stop occurs, the central even more reason to defend the exchange rate as it bank has inherits high inflation. In our framework, since crises are characterized by dollar shortages, there is scope for managing international reserves in order to ease these shortages. Our model reserves provides a natural motivation for both centralized holding of and holding reserves in the form of dollars. However, we show that a central bank that cannot commit will be too aggressive in injecting dollar reserves during a crisis. Moreover, this distortion interacts with the monetary policy problem. a more severe crisis, A more suboptimal monetary policy and a greater incentive for will lead to the central bank to inject reserves. Given the time inconsistency of the central bank, what should its man- date be? That that We is, how should the central bank's objectives be modified so internahzes the insurance dimension of the sudden-stop problem? it propose modifying inflation targeting so that the central bank follows state-contingent inflation targets, overweights nontradeable inflation in the measure of inflation that is targeted, and explicitly weighs reserves holdings in its objectives. Since the no-commitment central bank loosens during good times and we suggest that tightens during bad times, inflation target countercyclical (i.e. mandate should make the its low during good times, and high during In practice, the state contingency sudden stops). making inflation targets contingent prices, U.S. interest rates or U.S. may be implemented by on external factors such as commodity Corporate bond spreads, and the EMBI-I-. Tradables experience strong inflationary pressures during crises as the ex- change rate depreciates. is more limited. On other hand, the pass-through to non-tradables Thus targeting a measure of inflation that overweights non- tradables also will reduce the central bank's incentive to raise interest rates during crises. Finally, since the central crises, we suggest that its bank injects reserves too aggressively during objectives be modified to place weight on the stock of reserve holdings. Choosing an appropriate weight for reserves will help the central bank to internalize the effect of on the private Our paper icy in its exchange interventions sector's insurance incentives. is most directly related to the literature economies with financial frictions (e.g., on monetary pol- Bernanke and Blinder, 1988; Bernanke, Gertler and Gilchrist, 1999; Christiano, Roldos, and Gust, 2003; Diamond and Rajan, strom and 2001; Gertler, Gilchrist, and Natalucci, 2001; Tirole, 1998; Kiyotaki Unlike most of this literature, we Holm- and Moore, 2001; and Lorenzoni, 2001). are concerned with monetary policy in emerging markets, so we model the presence of two distinct financial constraints: one between domestic agents and one between domestic agents and foreign investors.' The recent emerging markets literature has identified sudden stops of international capital flows as an important part of external crises (see, for 'Of the preceding literature, Diamond and Rajan is the closest to our analysis in the sense that they also model two distinct constraints: a bank solvency constraint and an aggregate liquidity constraint, in their case. example, Calvo, 1998, and Calvo and Reinhart, 2002). We this feature. financial constraints. The importance for emerging markets was for example, Bulow and Rogoff, 1989). central bank that, since so will recognize to depreciate during a In one sense, the An open offer much the sovereign debt literature (see, another perspective on fear of floating. of debt in emerging too high, and mechanism dollar debt We as exogenous). market is in dollars, a that the output cost of allowing the exchange rate crisis is in our will therefore raise interest rates. model complements question in the Calvo and Reinhart model much so of international financial constraints first identified in Calvo and Reinhart (2002) They argue Our model shares model the sudden stop as a tightening of international is their explanation. why firms take on Calvo and Reinhart take stocks of foreign debt (i.e. show that stabilizing the exchange rate will reduce the private sector's incentive to insure against sudden stops, and naturally leads to increasing liability dollarization (see Caballero and Krishnamurthy, 2003). On the other hand, our central bank stabilizes the exchange rate because it focuses on inflation costs, as opposed to Calvo and Reinhart's output costs. The emphasis on insurance closely to is central to our analysis, Dooley (2000), who also emphasizes insurance Our monetary pohcy ing framework (e.g., analysis is conducted in and links us more effects. a standard inflation target- I^ing 1994, Svensson, 1999, or Woodford, 2002). Svens- son (2000) has extended the inflation targeting framework to open economies that fit the usual small-open-economy assumption, in which countries face no international tries financial constraint. His analysis such as Australia or Canada, but less so to is most applicable to coun- the emerging markets that are the focus of this paper. The next two sections develop a model of monetary policy in an en- vironment of sudden stops. this environment. it Section 4 studies optimal monetary policy in Section 5 focuses on the central bank's behavior cannot commit to its monetary policy choices. when Section 6 considers two modifications to the central bank's objectives that result in the optimal monetary policy being implemented. Section to the model. Section 8 concludes. 7 adds international reserves A 2 model of sudden stops we sketch a model In this section to the monetary is sudden stops. This serves as a preKide of pohcy analysis of the next section. The model we outline developed more rigorously in Caballero and Krishnamurthy (2002). Firms have assets at time t of These are domestic assets y4(. generate peso revenues), so that their peso value peso interest rate, and At We is duction. This is it they is the a decreasing function. ^'^ assume that firms need dollars in order to import where At{it) is (i.e. That dollars for investment. some investment goods that is, they need are inputs to pro- by noting that at the margin, firms in developing justified countries are borrowers in international markets. demand, so that firms always have to We are extrapolating this borrow from abroad. Moreover, we assume that firms are financially constrained so that the aggregate demand most models of demand. Firms for investment goods can be written as D{At,if). As in financial constraints, the net worth of firms influences their peso assets, worth At, along with any other peso sell their funds they are able to borrow, in order to raise dollars for investment goods. The dollars are borrowed at demand schedule. The supply of D is interest rate of if, decreasing in dollars if, which and increasing comes from two sources. Thus we assume that The rest are capital in equilibrium, ' A the price in the in At- First, domestic lenders have a supply of Rt dollars (small). inflows, CFt- is D{At{it),if) = Rt + CFt. (1) supplier of dollars earns a return of ^t+i\t ^In the next section we derive a more explicit sticky price mechanism that justifies using the nominal interest rate as an argument. 'Note that if domestic liabilities are extensively doUarized, then Ai also becomes a decreasing function of the exchange rate. In this case, monetary policy is less effective in influencing the peso value of domestic assets since the expansionary effect of lowering offset it is by the depreciation such policy causes. See Caballero and Krishnamurthy (2002) for a discussion of constrained monetary regimes in an environment with sudden stops. On the other hand, dollarization of external liabilities can be seen as an endogenous response to the mechanism we discuss Krishnamurthy (200.3). in this paper and is described in detail in Caballero and where Supplying one dollar yields the peso/dollar exchange rate. Et is pesos today. Invested at the peso interest rate of dollars tomorrow it £t and converting back into at £t+i\t yields the above expression. Supplying one dollar profitable as long as this return exceeds the in- is ternational interest rate (1 +Zj). Define, ^d For if > ij there _ St{l+it)/St+^t-l. an excess return on supplying dollars to domestic firms. is The spread zf — ij is a liquidity premium. The usual small-open-economy assumption is perfectly elastic at the price of if of investment = i^. is that the supply of dollars In this case, the equilibrium level simply D{At,it). Fixing the foreign interest is rate, the domestic net worth of firms (say through an increase in it) a fall in decreases investment. The sudden stop assumption is that there are times when the country quantity constrained in borrowing from international markets. That CFt < where Lt is the maximum quantity of funds that foreign investors will supply D{At,if) Note here that an increase is Defining in = Rt+Lt At has no if>il => eflPect is, is on + Rt- is because Instead the if. as the log exchange rate, et (2) on investment. This determined by the sudden stop supply of Lt only effect of At is, Lt, to this country. If this constraint binds, equilibrium investment is we can rewrite the domestic interest parity condition as, et+i\t = - et^it- When if Ct+i|t, a decrease in the peso interest rate of i^ this is (3) if- the usual interest parity condition. In that case, fixing rate. In the sudden stop case, where if > i^, it depreciates the exchange the current exchange rate is depreciated relative to the future exchange rate by the size of the liquidity premium. In this case, a decrease in it has the additional effect of causing the interest parity condition to shift upward, reinforcing the depreciation in the exchange rate. The model we have outhned embeds two principal ideas. First, there are times when an emerging economy is financially constrained in the inIn this instance, the supply of dollars ternational market. inelastic is The second the limited supply determines domestic investment and output. idea main that the is capacity of firms. of monetary policy effect The is has a potentially very large It on the exchange rate but limited contemporaneous last part of this effect on output. statement follows from the right hand side of The earlier part same expression and fixed. the on the domestic borrowing In particular, decreasing interest rates during a sudden stop does not attract more capital inflows. effect is and of the statement follows from the the fact that At rises as it Thus falls. (2), hand left i*^ which side of must rise to ensure equilibrium; by the interest parity condition, this implies that the exchange rate depreciates not only to offset the reduction in but also the it rise in if. Lt We denote the sudden-stop state as the V regime. In the V regime, + Rt fully determines investment. Let us imagine shifting to date — 1, t to a point in time where private and central bank actions may influence this stock. Suppose that at date supply of funds it faces is i — 1 the economy horizontal at i(_j is {H not in a sudden stop. A regime). with some dollars at this date can either lend these funds investment or can save them an international bond. in the agent will be able to lend the dollar at if — il. That is, the fact that if > i*t will t The domestic agent By for domestic opting to save, and earn an excess return of induce domestic agents to "insure" against the sudden stop (raising Rt). We have shown elsewhere (see Caballero and Krishnamurthy, 2001) that when domestic financial markets are underdeveloped, there - akin to a free-rider problem zf — i*, is less than its social tor will underinsure against many is an externality whereby the market value of value. this benefit, In this circumstance, the private sec- sudden stops. This underinsurance may take forms: for example, borrowing too much; contracting foreign-currency denominated debt; choosing short-term debt maturities; or contracting too few credit lines (see Caballero and Krishnamurthy, 2003). Aside from direct (and costly) regulation of capital inflows and the pri- vate sector's insurance decisions, there are two instruments at the central bank's disposal to offset the externality. First, it can increase its f)wn holding Our model provides a natural holding of reserves and holding them in the We will return to this mechanism before of foreign reserves and thereby increase Rt- motivation for both centralized form of international liquidity. concluding the paper. -Second, and most important for the purpose of this paper, the central bank can sudden stop. Since lowering commit it monetary policy during the to expand during the sudden stop raises the private sector's incentive to self-insure. We this increases if, develop this idea fully in the next sections. Sudden stops and monetary 3 We now extend the preceding model to incorporate monetary policy and Our goal private-sector price setting. in — t to study optimal monetary policy we assume that the economy 1, the external supply of funds t, regime. The — q. the H regime. We t+ the I, demand is crisis H is in the H et and H regime, or transits to the V while that of entering V is episode passes, and the economy is in is g, f -I- 1 as is what happens at date t. At this date, ag- t* is (4) the constant foreign interest rate (only a normalization in this equation). Foreign inflation it is inflation On is equal to zero. real interest rate, rt, is defined by: = it- rt where and given by, the output gap, and The domestic e, et-i- y^=-b{n-z*). where yf That regime. elastic at the interest rate of i* events at the prior dates. At prior dates, all are mainly interested in gregate is denote the nominal exchange rate at date to be independent of the exchange rates are We faces probability of remaining in Finally, at date fix this it the economy either remains in the At date 1 is an environment of sudden stops. At date is, policy the (peso) nominal interest rate and between periods the supply side, t and ( -I- 1, (5) TTj+iit T^t+i\t is the expectation of conditional on information at date we assume that the economy is composed t. of two types of price setters. Slow price-setters set their prices to grow at a constant rate of over both periods fr this average from (i.e. t — 1 to and from t t to t + 1). They choose growth rate to be equal to the expected rate of depreciation of the exchange rate: - et et-i E;t-1 \ - ct+i ( et (6) Fast price-setters index their prices to the exchange rate. Putting these two groups together, and assigning positive weights of a and and t + an fast price setters, respectively, yields —a 1 inflation rate to the slow between t and loi, ait The expected change in + (1 - - a){et+i et). the exchange rate between any two dates satisfies the domestic interest parity condition we derived in - et+T.\t et = - it (3), if (7) Substituting the interest parity condition into the inflation expression yields, TTj+i We now tion = TTt+^t = rewrite the aggregate term we have derived + (1 - a){it - demand equation equation in n-i* avr (8). ^aiit-i'l-7r) Substituting this into the aggregate if). (8) to accoiuit for the infla- First note that, + demand {if-i*). expression yields, yf=-b{att+i1), (9) where, it = it — if — 7f, The aggregate demand equation, (9), aggregate demand in the prior section, botli the = if is fj — z*. a simple parameterization of the (1). Note that it is decreasing in domestic (peso) real interest rate and the domestic interest rate on dollar borrowing. Equilibrium and policy determine the domestic dollar rates. Beginning witli the former, in the H (if) and peso (/';) regime domestic dollar rates must be equal to international is perfectly elastic at ij. interest rates because the supply of dollars Thus: -d,H 0. In the V regime, the sudden stop implies that i'^'^ > i* (see (2)). We impose the sudden stop constraint directly as a constraint on output: vY The first term = -% + «rf*£|t-i term indicates that output reflects falls > "2/ 0- (10) below the natural stop. If the private sector anticipates a high value of stop, it will level. be inclined to take precautionary i^' steps. during the sudden We that in emerging markets the private value of precautioning small relative to for The second the private sector's incentives to insure against the sudden its social a model showing concerned with ways is typically too value (see Caballero and Krishnamurthy, 2002, Thus, this). our monetary policy analysis in which the central bank in argued earlier we are can increase the incentive to take precautions. Finally, we consider the average depreciation both periods setters. First in order to derive an expression - = et it = -it + i" Next, from the interest parity condition at date ^t\t-\ t — the n set by the slow price for note that, et+i\t We of the exchange rate over - Cf-i = it-\ - t 7ir. — \, i* need to make an assumption about the central bank's behavior at date I. We make the simplest one, and assume that it sets the real domestic interest rate equal to the international interest rate (recall that foreign inflation is normalized to zero): it-\ — t^ = i* consistent with attaining a zero output gap in (9) also applied at date t — . if Note that this policy choice the aggregate demand is relation 1. Substituting the exchange rates back into the expression for n from (6) gives, f 7f = 2 H Eiif] ^-^ 2 10 + n , which implies that, = Eiir] Relation (11) what central to is o. (11) The follows. between the average domestic real interest rate adjusted international interest rate rate z" (i^ — the deviation Constraint (11) arises from ra- («{''^)- by the private sector. tional expectations price setting is n) and the liquidity- It tells us that if the central bank chooses a low real interest rate in one of the states, in equilibrium, the real interest rate in the other state We can rewrite the expression must be high. more concisely using the for nt+i tilde notation as, TTt By symmetry and date with inflation at et+i = i + - a)2^ (12) the inflation rate between date 1, -I- {1 t — 1 t is TTf = Since, Cj == Tf +l e) e — and + (i'^ e — tt et-i = QTT -f (1 - a){et - et-^i). (from interest parity condition and the assumption ) = 27r (see = Trj the definition of 7f - (1 tt), we find that, - Q)i^ (13) Optimal policy 4 Maximizing social welfare for this economy is achieved by minimizing the t — I, of the loss function, L: expected value, given information at L=Xyf + where < 5 < 1 is a discount These terms are first term is fairly Trf + {I- S)nl,, (14) rate. standard in the inflation targeting literature. The the cost of output fluctuations around potential output, while the other terms reflect the cost of inflation. The parameter A determines the relative weight on output gap stabilization. We now commit to derive the optimal monetary policy its choices of The output equation {i(^ ,i} in H ) when the central bank can in advance. follows directly from (9), with if set to zero: 11 we In V, regime, solve for the equilibrium must be such that Zj' yt if' from external financial constraint (10). That — —bif Since = i^' between (9) is consistent = —ay + baif is Z(' we see that the relation is: (15) + ad ' Note that the external constraint with yY from the ^=7-^. r/ = ^(ay-hai^), \ V 0^2^,' changes in the latter for anticipated the in (2), is, i^i^i under rational expectations, and i( i^ Analogous to . (10) has yt increasing in Zj' Since . decreasing in i^ this means that lowering lY has a beneficial effect on output , in V The . effect is By through an "insurance" channel. a lower iY during the sudden stop, the expectation of i^ anticipating rises. ' That is, the return to insuring against the sudden stop increases, and this relaxes On the aggregate financial constraint. demand on y - the other hand, the usual aggregate effect of lowering interest rates - the is absent in the V regime. positive effect on aggregate demand is rise in i^ state-contingent monetary policy is effect of fixed at date of a reduction in i\ the negative effect of the corresponding When contemporaneous Ex-post, since lY is t, iY the fully offset by output V . ' fully anticipated, in is, vY = -^i>(ay + We assume throughout that yl < ocaaiY)- so that increasing yl lowers the objec- 0, tive in (14).^ The objective for the central bank min is, gL^ + (l-g)L^ where, L^' = X{b<i>f{ay + aa^Yf + ^This means assuming that possible to (Jr —^> — i, (1 . - a)iYf + Although, i,' is (1 - S){Tt + - a)iYf an endogenous variable, show that the assumption can always be met by choosing Oy 12 {I it is large enough. and, L" = X{hc^i^f + (tt - - a)l^f + (1 - (1 5)(7f + - 0)1^ f (1 subject to the rational expectations constraint that, = E^t] Let us start with the 0. order condition with respect to first tt, which is straightforward: = - 2(1 + 2(7(7r - 2tx- 2(1 - = 2(2 -(5)^ commitment c - no + a)i^) + 2(1 - 2(1 - 2(1 ^ = - <5)(1 - q){n + (1 - <5)g(7f - (5)(^ = 77^^ (1 - + (1 - ajz^) a)i^) cv)E(i^]) 0, stands for the commitment solution. Thus, in the case, the central inflation, there is + a)lY) q)£'[z^] Since average rate of inflation. positive average (1 - (1 = where the superscript full - g)(7r bank chooses policy so as to achieve a zero price setters take into account average all benefit, only costs, for the central bank to choose a inflation. This does not mean that monetary policy the marginal benefit of increasing /}', is we compute rates and we impotent. at neutral interest If fr'^, find ril. -on = 2(1 - \-.H_-V |.H_-v'_^_o which implies that the central bank nWrxn ,n l'^\I(^2 > q)\aaiay{h^Y will choose i} < (since we are mini- mizing the objective). The exact solution is, '' °^A(6Q)Mg('I'a<i)2+l-'7) The central bank sets i^ below i, sector's incentives to insure against the is ' in order to increase on average so that policy is inflation, the central tighter in the H stop. regime, and output 13 ^^^ the private The cost of this policy V regime. To offset the eff'ect of bank chooses if^ > (see (11)), sudden that the exchange rate depreciates in the this policy + (2-5)(l-a)2- is lower. Note that as a V result of its attempt to increase precautioning against the regime and hence increase y^, the central bank tolerates some instabihty and exchange in inflation The 5 rates. bank without commitment central Let us now study a central bank that cannot commit to the interest rate choices of date commitment. it will t, Two prior to this date. First, if biases arise from the lack of the central bank's preferences are as stated in (14) choose interest rates to completely stabilize the exchange rate ("fear Second, of floating"). the central bank's preferences are distorted so as if to always prefer to increase output, as in Barro and the fear of floating problem the H state, and tightens rate of inflation. This commitment in is made the V The worse. central (1983), then bank loosens in state, while inducing a positive average exactly the opposite of the policy dictated in the is solution. Fear of floating 5.1 Suppose that the central bank chooses interest rates in each state to minimize the loss function in (14). Then in H, - a)i^)^ + (1 minL^ = while in V, it Compared + (if - L^' is (1 = {k-{1- a)lYf + to the loss function in that there that there X{baii^f it - {H or V) solves, <5)(7f + (1 - a)i^f solves, min is Gordon is V {I - 5)(n + {I - a)iYf. of the previous section, the main change no output term. This follows from our assumption in (10), no aggregate demand channel whereby lowering interest rates increases output. The loss function in H is the same as in the previous section. It is easy to verify that the solution to these two problems (that sistent with the rational expectations requirement that E|«|^] i¥ = iY = 0, with 7f = 0. Note that at 14 tt = 0, inflation = is con- 0) is to set and the exchange rate are fully stabilized gap H in is While the policy cost that output is bank central by choosing = it — it In addition, the output 0. equal to zero. both stabilizes is drops too inflation much and the exchange in the rate, the sudden-stop state, essentially ignores the insurance channel of and focuses purely on maintaining a stable exchange V monetary . The policy, rate. Exacerbating the problem: Barro-Gordon 5.2 We now modify the central bank's objective function to introduce an expan- sionary bias a la Barro-Gordon (1983): L=-Ayt+7r2-f(l-5)7r2^i. The We yt term now reflects the central bank's preference to always raise output. drop the squared-output term since The H choice problem in minL^ = A6Qzf + This gives the Note that a first (tt - larger value of choice problem in - n)i^f + - h)(iT + (1 - a)i^f. t, order condition A Since in equilibrium, for increasing higher value of V remains the same as is fixed: a)l^'f + (1 - offsets this tendency. ff <5)(7r output) leads in + the fear of floating case (1 - a)iYf. is, 2 and (1 A (greater preference minL^ = {n-{lfirst (1 order condition; since output, as of date The does not change our message. it is, to a lower interest rate choice. The (17) — we must have 1 — Q that E[z^'] (19) that, Qba ^^^2(r3^>«15 = 0, it follows from (18) Replacing this expression back into (18) and ir > ^" = we z^ < find that and -^^-^)^2(r^<«' -y '* The central = bank preference qba ^2(l-a)2<5 > for increasing bank sets rate in > 0. H < i^ As 0. in increases output, the central raises the private sector's inflation expectations, is bank predetermined by the sudden stop supply. However, is now positive, the central with an exchange rate that depreciates at date raises the interest rate in tighter and leads to sees no output benefit to changing interest since the average rate of inflation and an even V^. t. To counter bank this, is crisis is faced the central In equilibrium, this leads to a lower sudden stop supply. The Zj' , thereby exacerbated. Implementing optimal policy through 6 eiTect in Barro-Gordon, the anticipation of the low interest In V, the central rates since output bank " output has a perverse H our model. Since lowering interest rates in Tf (19), 0: inflation targets Given the time inconsistency of the central bank, what should be? That it how should the is, its mandate central bank's objectives be modified so that internahzes the insurance dimension of the sudden stop problem? this section made we highlight two possibilities. state dependent: stringent (low) in H First, inflation targets and loose (high) in In can be V. Second, the central bank's mandate can overweight the inflation of non-tradables in the measure of inflation that regime, there bank is offsets this it targets. Since output contracts in the deflation in non-tradables. The V inflation-targeting central by lowering interest rates and causing the exchange rate to depreciate (leading to inflation in tradables). This incentive increases by placing a larger weight on non-tradables. 6.1 We State contingent inflation targets continue with the linear-output specification but modify the central bank's objective function to introduce a state- contingent inflation penalty 16 term of k", for w e {H,V}: L = -Xyt + A positive k means that (TTf - K-)2 inflation + (1 - 6)(TTt + i k'^)2. (20) the central bank, while a less costly for is - negative k penalizes inflation further. The choice problem in minL^^ = Xbai^ + This gives the first {ft H is, - k" - {I - a)i^f + The L^' = (tt - K^' - order condition first V V (1 (1 is - a)iYf + a)l^)-. - a)(5 As 6 " k^'' + - (1 a)tl'f. —K 1 - Q we must have that H_ ~ it is E[z^] = 0, we obtain: equal to zero. Imposing k'^: ^^Q __ 2{l _ -a)S 1 q v g " a strong Barro-Gordon inflation bias (high A), then is made low - (5)(7r note that in the commitment solution yields a constraint across there - it ~ 2-5 before, since in equihbrium We (1 now, -y If - is: ^' it (1 H choice problem in min — - k" + 5){tt that, everything else constant, a larger value of k^' leads to a lower interest rate in The - order condition: 2-51 -a Note (1 k^ can be in order to offset this bias. Similarly, to the extent that the central bank has a loose the net result is inflation target in a ir V of zero. 17 (if k^ is high), k^ can be set low so Substituting this k expression back into the order conditions for first interest rate choices allows us to solve for the optimal interest rate choices: -H If — * 1 ^ 1 - g K r 2-b\-a- V q and -v By kY > choosing _ ^ Q (and hence 1 n^ < V the central bank will follow a 0), state contingent policy as dictated in the social iY < In equilibrium, this leads to a higher 0. supply. The crisis is Zj ' optimum, with i^ , > and and a looser sudden stop thereby lessened. Before concluding this section, note that both the state-contingent tion target infla- and the nontradeable-infiation overweight solutions act through the inflation terms of the central bank objective. If we were to introduce a contemporaneous output effect of a change in i^ these recommendations , We could by raising the weight of output in the would remain but there would be an additional channel open: now also achieve the desirable eiTect central bank's objective during V-regimes. Non-tradable inflation target 6.2 now introduce an infinitesimal (in the sense that it does not feedback aggregate demand) non-tradable good, whose inflation is determined Let us into by a simple Phillips curve: - TV We - modify the measure of inflation that the central bank targets to be a weighted average of using so far. The n^ and the tradable inflation of central bank's objective function ttj that we have been is, L=-Xyt + if3n^ + {l-P)nt-K'^f + {l-6){P7r^^, + {l-p)nt+,-Kn^. P is the weight on non-tradable inflation. inflation rate on non-tradables k" ^ 0). The choice problem min L'' = {n + pyY - in (1 - V to be We zero. normalize the Finally we set (21) + 1 (non-crisis) (leaving k^' = t is: /3)(1 - a)i]y + 18 {1 ~ 6){1 - 0f{n + (1 - a)V(f. The order condition first zT is, = n{l-{l-l3){l-S))+PyY (1 The choice problem in H - a){l - 0){2 - 5) is, ,H i i» This gives a sohition and decreasing As is, for k^ in z^ that hnearly increasing in n, decreasing in A, . the previous section in is we can always choose k^ when we impose the equilibrium condition that relation for Given ment < i^ which is By n in terms of this k^ i] , -P is k^ We . proportional to f3yY by choosing /? achieved by setting > 0. Since k^ < 0. £'[j^] E[i'^] k^ simply choose = 0, so that Since yY = so that 0, this < we tt 0, n = 0. That arrive at a equals zero. we can imple- means that i^ > 0, increasing the weight on nontradables in the measure of inflation that the central bank targets, the central bank follows a state contingent policy as dictated in the social optimum. Again, in equilibrium, this leads to a Since crises are characterized by dollar shortages (see equation (2)), there is higher 7 Zj , ' and a looser sudden-stop supply. Reserves management for managing international reserves in order to ease these Our model provides a natural motivation for both centralized holding of reserves and for holding them in the form of dollars. We assume that the central bank has a small amount of international scope in the model shortages. reserves at date beyond date t + t. These reserves can be injected at date 1, latter represents the when they yield 7 > utils t, or saved for use per unit of reserves. opportunity cost of using the reserves early, The and should be interpreted more broadly as the value of precautioning. We contrast how the results of section 4 the introduction of international reserves. modified and section The 5.1 loss function in change upon both cases is to: L^Xy^ + 7Tf + (l-5)nf^,+jRt, 19 (22) with Rt the amount of reserves injected. Recall that in section 4, central we 5.1, bank commits to in we solve for the interest rate choices that the minimizing the loss function. While, in section solve for the sequentially optimal interest rate choices given this loss function. There is no value in injecting reserves in H Since there . is no dollar shortage, the action has no effect on either prices or output. Reserves will be hoarded because do so has an opportunity cost failing to 7. In the V regime, the action increases dollar supply and relaxes the vertical constraint: (10) to: Vt One can = Rt -ay + adi^iy (23) t\t see from this expression, that B}[ enters exactly as —ay in all the expressions. In particular, g = *6(< - % - aarf^HAs we discussed on earlier, (24) the optimal policy considers the dependence of yY (which enters through expectations), while the no-commitment case ij' does not. The introduction of international reserves management considerations does not change any of the main qualitative conclusions with respect to monetary pohcy commitment in either the tions 4 and 5.1, respectively. In particular, both and i cases; that < = i''^ in the -i = in commitment or no-commitment case of sec- = in equation (16), To i]' the no-commitment case; and that i^ decreasing in ay. Since sions, the reserve injection increases the The most > for (countercyclical) mon- commitment solution for iY in RY —ay see this, note that in the is tt case.^ However, reserve injections are a substitute etary policy. the case that it is still enters as in all expres- optimal iY new result comes from the first order condition From equations (22) and (24), the solution for RJ in interesting with respect to /?]' . the commitment case is: Rt'^ = - ^TTTI^TT^ + 2A(6*)2 ^These statements assume that Rt < a.y, reserves to eliminate the sudden stop shock. 20 «y + "«d^'r so that there is (25) insufficient international From equations case (22) and (23), the solution for is: ^r'"' Note that mitment b'^ case. have that Rf only = jq^ < will '"'^ 1, -^ + = > Rf use too little (26) more negative is any equilibrium That the no-commitment in + aa,z^ so the first term Also, since for ''^. a, RY level of R] in the < ''^ , z^ com- '"''^, i^ we the central bank with no commitment not is, monetary policy, but it also will inject reserves too aggressively. There are two factors behind this increases output and decreases i^' output benefit, but ignores the accounts for the second result. both Ex-post, the central bank considers the . on effect the lower effect: First, injecting reserves Zj' i^' . Ex-ante, the central bank decreases the private sector's incentives to insure against the sudden stop shock. the commitment-central-bank inject less The latter effect reserves than the makes no-commitment one. The second policy. In the factor has to do with the time inconsistency no-commitment solution, the central larger crisis caused by the inadequate monetary bank has policy. As a monetary of to offset a result, it over- injects its reserves. The latter factor is remedied indirectly by solving the monetary policy time inconsistency problem as we have discussed. The former factor, the other hand, requires further modification to the central bank's so that it increases the value it on mandate assigns to hoarding reserves during the V- regime. 8 We Final remarks have analyzed monetary policy den stops are times when a country in an environment of sudden stops. Sud- is financially constrained in the interna- tional financial market. In this context, lowering or raising domestic interest rates has only small effects on the tightness of this financial constraint, but does have significant effects on the domestic borrowing capacity of agents. Moreover, the anticipation of such actions are important in determining precautionary actions that agents take against sudden stops. From this viewpoint, we have derived positive and normative results for 21 monetary policy and reserves management. inconsistency problem and bias. Finally, its We have highlighted a new time interaction with the conventional stabilization we have suggested how an inflation targeting framework can restore incentives, so that central banks behave optimally. Our model is clearly very stylized. In particular, our assumption that the country faces a vertical supply of funds during sudden stops But is extreme. important to realize that our main conclusions do not depend on it is this extreme. We could consider a more general model in which the supply of funds was not completely inelastic in the V regime. In this case, the V regime would have both an aggregate demand channel and the insurance channel we have highlighted (i.e. lowering iY leads to a contemporaneous increase in yY). Importantly, relative to the H-iegiuie, the output-inflation tradeoff will still turn steeper (although not vertical) during the V-regime and hence the central bank targets channel more than is in the H will be prone to favor inflation over output regime. Moreover, as long as the insurance present, this reaction will remain suboptimal. Insurance against sudden stops affects many policy decisions in emerging markets, from reserve management to liquidity ratio requirements. It only natural that optimal monetary policy be analyzed in the same as in this paper. Moreover, it is We light, important to understand the interaction of monetary policy with other insurance policies (as policies). seems we have with hope that our framework provides a starting point integrated approach. 22 reserve for such an References [1] Barro, Robert, and David Gordon, "A Positive Theory of Monetary Policy in a Natural Rate Model," Journal of Political Economy, August 1983, Pi (4), pp. 589-610. [2] mand," American Economic Review, [3] Money and Aggregate De- Bernanke, Ben and Alan Blinder, "Credit, Bernanke, in B., M. Gertler, and May 1988, 75(2), pp. 435-439. S. Gilchrist, "The Financial Accelerator a Quantitative Business Cycle Framework," Handbook of Macroeco- nomics, Taylor and Woodford, eds., 1999. [4] Bulow, Jeremy and Rogoff, Kenneth, "A Constant Recontracting Model Journal of Political Economy, February 1989, of Sovereign Debt", 97{1), pp. 155-178. [5] Caballero, Ricardo and Arvind Krishnamurthy. "International and Do- mestic Collateral Constraints in a Model of Emerging Market Crises," Journal of Monetary Economics, December 2001, ^<S(3), pp- 513-548. [6] Caballero, Ricardo and Arvind Krishnamurthy. of [7] Monetary Policy Caballero, Debt: in "A Vertical Analysis of Emerging Markets." Mimeo, MIT, 2002. Ricardo and Arvind Krishnamurthy, "Excessive Dollar Financial Development and Underinsurance," Journal of Fi- nance, forthcoming, 2003. [8] Calvo, Guillerhio, "Capital Flows and Capital-Market Crises: ple [9] Economics of Sudden Stops," Mimeo, University of Maryland, 1998. Calvo, Guillermo, and Journal of Economics. [10] Christian©, cial Crisis," [11] The Sim- L..I., Carmen May C. Gust, Reinhart. "Fear of Floating." Quarterly 2002, 117{2), pp. 379-408 and .]. Roldos, "Monetary Policy in a Finan- Journal of Economic Theory, forthcoming, 2003. Diamond, Douglas and Raghuram Rajan. "Liquidity Shortages and Banking Crises." Mimeo, University of Chicago, 2001. [12] Dooley, Michael, "A model of crises in emerging markets," nomic Journal, January 2000, 110{460), pp. 256-272. 23 The Eco- [13] Gertler, M., S. Gilchrist and F.M.Natalucci, "External Constraints on Monetary Policy and the Financial Accelerator," NYU working paper, 2001. [14] Holmstrom, Bengt and Jean uidity." [15] King, Tirole. "Private and Public Supply of Liq- JowTial of Political Economy, February 1998, 106{l), pp. 1-40. Mervyn A., "Monetary Policy in the UK," Fiscal Studies 1994, 15(3), pp. 109-128. [16] Kiyotaki, Nobuhiro and John Moore. "Liquidity, Business Cycles, and Monetary [17] Mimeo, LSE, 2001. Lorenzoni, Guido. "Interest Rate Stabilization and Monetary Control: A [18] Policy." Reconciliation." Mimeo, Princeton University, 2001. Svensson, Lars E. O., "Inflation Targeting as a Monetary Policy Rule," Journal of Monetary Economics, 1999, 43, pp. 607-654. [19] Svensson, Lars E. 0., "Open-Economy Inflation Targeting," Journal of International Economics, 2000, 50, pp. 155-183. [20] Woodford, Michael, "Inflation Stabihzation and Welfare," Princeton University, 2002. 24 32M Ub Mimeo, ^mi%e Lib-26-67 MIT LIBRARIES 3 9080 02524 4523 K!?@?;i!ii