The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition David Roodman Center for Global Development April 2004 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition Contents Introduction................................................................................................................................................... 1 I. Scaling and weighting .......................................................................................................................... 2 II. The Seven Components........................................................................................................................ 7 Aid............................................................................................................................................... 7 Trade ......................................................................................................................................... 17 Investment................................................................................................................................. 28 Migration................................................................................................................................... 32 Environment.............................................................................................................................. 36 Security ..................................................................................................................................... 40 Technology ............................................................................................................................... 44 III. Overall results ................................................................................................................................ 46 Appendix. Aggregation of Protection Levels across Sectors...................................................................... 54 Bibliography ............................................................................................................................................... 57 Tables and figures Table 1. Computation of selectivity weights .............................................................................................. 12 Table 2. Quality-adjusted aid quantity by donor, bilateral or multilateral.................................................. 15 Table 3. Calculation of policy-induced charitable giving........................................................................... 16 Table 4. Quality-adjusted aid quantity with multilateral aid allocated back to bilaterals ........................... 17 Table 5. Calculation of uniform ad valorem tariff-equivalent of tariff regimes against agricultural commodities, 1997–98 (percent)........................................................................................................ 21 Table 6. Calculation of uniform ad valorem tariff-equivalent of tariff regimes against other agriculture, 1997–98 (percent) .............................................................................................................................. 22 Table 7. Calculations of production-distorting agricultural subsidies for CDI and of Total Support Estimate of OECD, 2000–02.............................................................................................................. 23 Table 8. Overview of estimation of ad valorem tariff-equivalent of subsidies........................................... 24 Table 9. Protection in ad valorem tariff equivalents, by sector (%) ........................................................... 25 Table 10. Computation of Aggregate Measure of Protection (AMP) ......................................................... 26 Table 11. Revealed openness, 2002 ............................................................................................................ 27 Table 12. Computation of overall trade score............................................................................................. 27 Table 13. Investment component scoring system ....................................................................................... 30 Table 14. Summary of Investment Component .......................................................................................... 31 Table 15. Comparison of 2003 and 2004 CDI investment ranks ................................................................ 32 Table 16. Summary of migration component ............................................................................................. 35 Table 17. Comparison of 2003 and 2004 CDI migration ranks.................................................................. 36 Table 18. Indicators used in environment component ................................................................................ 39 Table 19. Summary of environment component......................................................................................... 40 Table 20. Non–U.N.-run military operations counted in CDI security component. ................................... 42 Table 21. Summary of security component—contributions as a share of GDP (%) .................................. 43 Table 22. Comparison of 2003 and 2004 CDI security/peacekeeping ranks .............................................. 44 Table 23. Calculation of technology scores ................................................................................................ 46 Table 24. The Commitment to Development Index: Scores....................................................................... 49 Table 25. Detailed confrontation of 2003 and 2004 scores ........................................................................ 50 Table 26. Confrontation of 2003 and 2004 standings using 2004 methodology ........................................ 51 Figure 1. Correlation of standard CDI with versions with higher weight placed on one component......... 52 Figure 2. Average absolute change in CDI rank when higher weight placed on one component .............. 53 Figure 3. Supply and demand for an import from a developing country .................................................... 54 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition Introduction One year ago, the Center for Global Development and Foreign Policy magazine introduced the Commitment to Development Index (Birdsall and Roodman 2003; CGD and FP 2003).1 The superficial purpose was to rate rich countries based on how much their government policies hurt or help development in poorer countries. But “ranking the rich” was a means to more important ends: to draw media attention to the many ways that rich-country governments affect development, to provoke debate on which policies matter and how to measure them, to highlight gaps in current knowledge, to stimulate data collection and other research, to educate the public and policymakers, and, ultimately, to prod policy reform. By these standards, the initiative has been reasonably successful in its first year in the limelight. The index garnered coverage from the New York Times, the Economist, and the BBC, among many other outlets, and provoked commentary in the American National Review and the Australian Financial Review.2 Experts are writing papers on how to improve the CDI. (Picciotto 2003; Chowdhury and Squire 2003; Sawada et al. 2004) Professors are teaching with the Foreign Policy article. And the Dutch government has adopted the CDI as a performance indicator of its “policy coherence” for development. The first edition of the CDI embodied 12 months of rapid, creative work. As noted in Birdsall and Roodman (2003), the richest components of the first edition of CDI were those for policy areas with the best data sets and traditions of scholarly inquiry, namely foreign aid and trade. Other components were cruder for lack of such data and analysis, sometimes using measures of outcomes rather than rich-country policies—for example, the amount of foreign direct investment in developing countries, which is largely a function of developing-country policies, as well as private decisions. We nevertheless included the cruder components in 2003 in part to send the message that “helping is about more than aid” (investment, migration, etc., matter too), in part to invite commentary about how to better measure policy in those areas. Indeed, in the months after the release, CGD and FP were showered with constructive criticism of the CDI. Thus it was clear when the 2003 edition was released that the design work needed to continue. Improving the CDI would increase the meaningfulness of the index, boost its credibility, and help it serve its ultimate purposes more effectively. Guided by our own understanding of the shortcomings of the original edition and the helpful suggestions we received, CGD undertook or commissioned substantial data gathering and analysis in order to revise the CDI methodology. The collaborators for the 2004 edition were Theodore Moran of the Georgetown University School of Foreign Service (on investment), Elizabeth Grieco and Kimberly Hamilton of the Migration Policy Institute (migration), and Michael O’Hanlon and Adriana Lins de Albuquerque of the Brookings Institution (security). Together with CGD researchers, the team refined the aid, trade, and environment components, added a technology component, and overhauled the sections on investment, migration, and secu1 The Commitment to Development Index is a collective effort. I am grateful to the Rockefeller Foundation for its support; to the outside collaborators for technical work on components; to Alicia Bannon for excellent research assistance, and to CGD President Nancy Birdsall and the rest of the Advisory Board for guidance. The design of the 2004 CDI does not necessarily represent the views of any of the outside collaborators. 2 Jeff Madrick, “Looking beyond Free Trade,” New York Times, June 12, 2003; “Economics Focus: Gauging Generosity,” Economist, May 1, 2003; Jim Lacey, “We’re Number Twenty?!” National Review, June 30, 2003; Helen Hughes, “Faulty Index A Poor Guide to Real Benefits,” Australian Financial Review, May 20, 2003. 1 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition rity (formerly called peacekeeping). (The 2004 final design departs in places from the recommendations of non-CGD authors. Final responsibility rests solely with CGD.) One thing that did not change is the basic concept of the CDI. It still ranks 21 countries: all the members of the Development Assistance Committee (DAC) of the OECD save Luxembourg. Each country gets a separate score in each of a set of major policy areas that were selected because they affect development and have relevant data available for all 21 countries. This year policy domains are aid, trade, investment, migration environment, security, and (newly added) technology. A country’s overall score is the average of its seven component scores. The CDI rates countries in ways that allow normative comparisons, which usually means adjusting for size. Denmark cannot be expected to give as much foreign aid as Japan, which has an economy 26 times as big, but Japan could be asked to give as much as Denmark as a share of its gross domestic product, and that is how the index gauges aid quantity. Switzerland cannot be expect to import as much from developing countries as the Unite States, but it could have trade barriers as low, which is what the trade component looks for. And as in 2003, the CDI aims to assess policies today. In practice, because it takes time for official data to surface, most information used is for 2001 and 2002. The trade data are one major exception, being for 1997. Another is the data on contributions to internationally approved security operations, which cover the 1993–2002 decade. Since these troop levels committed can vary dramatically from year to year, a historical average is a better indicator of current policy stance than a single year of data. This paper describes the full CDI methodology as it stands now. Section I describes how we revised our handling of what is likely to become a perennial issue, how to scale and weight the components. Section II reviews the index component by component. It builds on background papers written for each of the seven policy areas (Roodman 2004a, 2004b; Cline 2004; Moran 2004; Grieco and Hamilton 2004; O’Hanlon and de Albuquerque 2003; Bannon and Roodman 2004), while making explicit where the final CDI departs from their recommendations. Section III presents the overall results, compares them to last year’s, and analyzes their sensitivity to changes in component weights. I. Scaling and weighting The CDI combines readings on dozens of indicators. Since the indicators are not perfectly correlated, countries’ standings on the final results are affected by the relative importance the CDI formulas give to the various indicators. In mathematical terms, the results are affected by choices of both functional form and choice of coefficients. Both the CDI designers and commentators have naturally asked whether the CDI makes the best choices. In some parts of the CDI, the way in which indicators are combined is grounded in a clear conceptual framework and calibrated to available evidence. For example, the aid component combines donors’ aid-giving totals with information on the extent to which they tie their aid (requiring recipients to spend it on donor-country goods and services) by referring to a finding that tying raises project costs 15–30%. Tied aid is discounted 20% (see below for the rationale), and the result is a figure, tying-discounted aid, that still has real-world meaning. Other examples are the theoretically-grounded method that is used to express agricultural subsidies in tariffequivalent terms, which allows them to be combined with actual tariffs; and the reasonable but 2 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition coarse assumption that the marginal cost of deploying personnel in international security operations is $10,000/month/person, which allows personnel and financial contributions to such operations to be combined in a bottom-line dollar figure. All these techniques use theory and evidence to reduce, though certainly not eliminate, arbitrariness in the CDI design. But where theory and evidence are thinner, we have not found such solid ways to reduce arbitrariness. When needed to combine indicators in a sort of conceptual vacuum, we restricted ourselves to taking linear combinations, as a first step toward managing the complexity. This happened in the trade, investment, migration, and environment components, and in each of these cases the CDI designers chose to weight some indicators more than others. The weights are of course open to challenge, but are backed by years of experience in the relevant fields. At the top level of the CDI hierarchy, however, where the seven CDI components merge into a single index, we equally weighted the components. Because of the prominence of this choice and its importance for the final results (section III examines how important it really is), and because we have weighted equally, this decision has provoked many challenges. I will focus on it for the rest of the section. Intuitively, taking linear combinations happens in two steps: mapping each variable to be combined onto a standard scale, which may involve scaling and translation (shifting up or down); then taking a weighted average. Both steps—standardizing and weighting—raise tough conceptual questions. Consider the challenges of standardizing first. To prepare the scores on the seven CDI components for being combined into an overall score, the standardizing system should arguably have the following properties: 1. Standardized scores should all fall within some intuitive scale, say 0–10. 2. For components that measure “goods” (in the 2004 CDI, they are aid, investment, migration, security, and technology), zero should map to zero. That is, if a country gives no aid (more precisely, if its aid program is deemed valueless after adjusting for quality), its final aid score should be 0—not, say, 3. For components that measure “bads” (environment and trade, which mainly assess environmental harm and trade barriers) a perfect absence of the thing assessed should translate into an intuitive maximum score, such as 10. All this is nearly equivalent to requiring that the coefficient of variation (standard deviation divided by the mean) be preserved. For the “good” components, it also means that the transformation should be a simple rescaling, with no translation. 3. The standardized averages on each component, at least in some base year, should be the same—say, 5. Then one can immediately tell by looking at a country’s aid, environment, or other score whether it is above or below the base-year average. And one can tell whether a country’s score in one component is better than its score in another, by the standards of the country’s peers. Last year’s scoring system (described below) did not have this property. The average trade score (6.4) was twice the average aid score (3.2). As a result, when Switzerland scored 4.0 on trade and 3.3 on aid, it appeared to a lay reader to be better on trade than aid when in fact it was below average on trade and above average on aid. 3 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition 4. The standard deviation of standardized scores should be the same for each component—as they would be if they were z scores (number of standard deviations from the mean). In other words, countries should be “graded on a curve” for each component. If they are not—if, instead, standardized scores on one component are relatively clustered—this effectively under-weights that component because differences between countries on the component will have relatively little effect on the overall results. Since we have restricted ourselves to linear transformations, two free parameters—slope and intercept—determine how the results from each component are standardized. With seven components, that yields 14 degrees of freedom. The above constraints together would consume far more than 14 degrees of freedom. The first imposes what we can call 14 inequalities3, and the other three impose 6 equalities each, for a total of 18. Thus only by luck could all four conditions be satisfied. If one drops the requirement that standard deviations are equal, there is more hope (12 equalities and 14 inequalities imposed on 14 parameters), but it still would take luck. In the first two years of the CDI, luck has not been with us. As a result, we have faced trade-offs, trade-offs that are tricky because they involve mathematical principles, our (limited) understanding of rich world-poor world linkages, and the imperatives of effective mass communication. For example, last year’s standardized investment scores had an average of 3.0. To force those scores to have an intuitive mean of 5, we would have had to add 2 to every country’s standardized investment score, which would have raised Portugal to 11 and given a “no investment” country 2 points out of 10. Or we would have had to multiply all the scores by 5/3, which would have raised Portugal to 15. Thus, enforcing condition 3 would have led to violations of condition 1 and perhaps 2. We made different choices in 2003 and 2004. In 2003, we did enforce conditions 1 and 2. Scores for the “good” components were scaled so that the best country got a 9 (and a country that gave no aid or made no contribution to peacekeeping would have gotten a 0). Nine was chosen to allow some room for improvement in future years within the 10-point scale.4 For the “bad” components, scores were scales so that the worst country got a –9 (and the country that did no harm to the global environment or erected no trade barriers would have gotten a 0); then 10 was added to bring the scores within the 0–10 frame. This system resulted in different components having different means. In 2004, we gave up on condition 1 in favor of condition 3. Scores on each component now average 5 by fiat; as a result, so do the overall CDI scores. But the boundaries of 0 and 10 are no longer inviolable. Countries whose aid programs, say, are deemed more than twice as good as average score above 10. And countries with trade barriers or rates of environmental harm more than twice the average score below 0. In fact, 6 of the 147 component scores this year exceed 10 and one is negative.5 These few transgression of the intuitive range seem worth the greater ease of comparison within and across components. For example, in a reversal from last 3 Technically the first condition imposes 21×7×2=294 inequalities: each country’s score on each component should be ≥0 and ≤10. The “14 inequalities” apply to the maximum and minimum scores on each component. 4 The plan was to stay with the 2003 scaling factors, so that the best would no longer automatically get a 9 in future years. Note that this meant that scores might have some day transgressed outside the 0–10 range, so that compliance with condition 1 was not strictly guaranteed. 5 See section 3. Denmark, the Netherlands, Norway, and Sweden score over 10 on aid, as do Canada and the United States on migration; and Norway’s trade score is negative. 4 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition year, Switzerland now scores higher on aid than trade—5.8 versus 0.3—which makes more sense for a country that is above the average of its peers on aid and well below it on trade. An astute reader will have noticed in the discussion of condition 4, which demands equal standard deviations, that the question of weighting crept into the discussion of scaling. Using a linear transformation to double the range or standard deviation of a component has exactly the same effect on overall standings as doubling its weight. Nevertheless, for the lay reader, weighting is a distinct concept, and raises distinct concerns. Indeed, among the most oft-voiced criticisms of the CDI is that it is “equal weighted,” even though some policy domains, it is argued, clearly matter more than others. The accusation of equal weighting is true in a sense: in 2004, as in 2003, a country’s overall CDI score is the simple average of its component scores. Before examining the criticism, it is worth noting that “equal weighting” is a not a welldefined concept, for all it is voiced. Consider that allowing trade scores to range more widely in 2004 (Norway now has a negative score on trade) effectively happened to increase the effective weight on trade. Yet the CDI is still “equal weighted.” Which year was trade really “equal weighted”? Both, and neither. There are several reasonable ways to scale scores—characterized in part by which of the above conditions are enforced—thus several possible rankings resulting from “equal weighting.” Thus in choosing “equal weighting” for the CDI, we are not claiming to truly give aid, trade, etc., equal weight. That would be meaningless. Rather, both this year and last year, we have opted for what seems least arbitrary in the face of uncertainty. Still, I agree with the attacks on “equal weighting” in the sense that the CDI almost certainly does not have the following property: any two CDI-measured policy changes in a given country that have an equal effect on development have an equal effect on the CDI. We have not striven for that ideal yet, out of several considerations. First, achieving it does not seem essential for the CDI as a communications strategy and a goad to research, and it must be remembered that these are the ultimate goals of the project, not scientific measurement. The CDI broadcasts the basic message that many policy areas matter and that all countries have major room for improvement clearly as is. The success of the first edition in spotlighting issues despite being “equal-weighted” is reassuring. Second, a survey of expert opinion suggests that “equal weighting” is not unreasonable. Shyamal Chowdhury and Lyn Squire (2003) surveyed members of the Global Development Network, who are researchers in both rich and poor countries working on development issues. Of the 200 solicited respondents in the stratified random sample, 105 completed the questionnaire. They were asked to assign their own weights to each of the major issue areas then in the CDI.6 The authors computed the average chosen weight for each component. The results were statistically indistinguishable from equal weighting. The study corroborates my own experience. Of the 6 The survey was based on the first draft of the CDI, in which anti-corruption was a separate, seventh component rather than being folded in to investment as it eventually was. The 2004 CDI also has a seventh component, technology, which was absent from this survey. 5 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition seven CDI issue areas, all but one has been nominated to me for extra weight by someone with decades of experience in development.7 Of course, since “equal weighting” is not well defined, the precise meaning of this result is unclear. In addition, although the survey instrument specifically mentioned “policy stance,” it may not have highlighted the policy-flow distinction enough to avert misinterpretation. For example, a respondent might have given ample weight to investment because rich-country investment can indeed be a major factor in development—overlooking that rich-country policies that influence investment are a smaller factor. At any rate, there are more fundamental reasons to be cautious about departing from “equal weighting.” One phrase in the ideal property enunciated above, “equal effect on development,” is, like “equal weighting,” not well defined. Different policies have different effects on people in different times and places. Moral and philosophical conundrums arise about how one should compare effects on people with different levels of poverty and opportunities; about which discount rate to use; and about whether development is a something that happens to people or countries.8 Huge uncertainties also loom about the actual long-term effects of trade barriers, greenhouse gas policies, government R&D spending, humanitarian interventions, migration, etc. Finally, it cannot be assumed that the proper mathematical form for combining the components into an overall score is linear. Especially for large donor nations, the policy areas may interact significantly. For example, Thomas Hertel, head of the Global Trade Analysis Project, has called for simultaneous computable general equilibrium modeling of trade and migration.9 To the extent policy areas interact, there can be no right weights in a linear framework. None of this proves that it would be impossible in light of current knowledge, or especially with more research, to stick with the linear approach and yet find unequal weights that would command a broader consensus than equal weighting does. One starting point might be estimates of global dollar flows of aid, trade, investment, remittances, and so on. Greenhouse gases could be converted to the same dollar units via a fixed rate per ton, based on estimates of the harm climate change could do to developing country economies. Picciotto (2003) suggests such an approach along these lines.10 But from the point of view of the CDI, flows are merely intermediaries between richcountry policies on the one hand and poor-country development on the other, and it is the magnitude of the linkage between these latter variables that should determine ideal weights. In some areas, these relationships are reasonably well understood. For example, several studies have estimated the economic effects of rich-country trade policies on poor-country development. (World Bank 2001; Cline 2004) Cline estimates that complete rich-country liberalization would, after a 15-year adjustment, increase income in developing countries by $100 billion per year, which is 7 The exception is environment—and that is probably only because hardly any environmental experts have commented. Surely it can be argued that tinkering with the planet’s biogeochemical cycles is an issue of the first rank. 8 This last distinction is important for migration. If someone moves permanently from a poor to a rich country, quadruples her income, and sends back no remittances, is that development? 9 Private communication between Thomas Hertel and Michael Clemens, CGD, October 2002. 10 But for trade, Picciotto suggests using estimates of the benefits, in producer surpluses, of complete rich-country liberalization rather than current earnings on exports from developing to developed countries. This is not parallel to current total aid, remittance, or investment flows. 6 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition approximately twice current concessional aid flows. Similar work is now being done on migration liberalization. CGE modeling by Walmsley and Winters (2003) suggests that an if rich countries increased their temporary migrant worker stocks by an amount equal to just 3% of their labor forces, global income would increase $150 billion, with most of that accruing to the temporary workers themselves. Complete liberalization could generate vastly larger gains for temporary workers.11 The trouble with unequal weighting is that one cannot do it halfway. As soon as one, say, doubles trade’s weight relative to aid, one needs sound rationales for the choice of weights for every other component. The links between policy and development in other policy domains are much more uncertain or controversial. Most empirical evidence on the macro-level benefits of aid is fragile (Easterly, Levine, and Roodman 2004; Roodman 2003, revised draft forthcoming). There is little evidence on how investment-relevant policies in rich countries affect developing countries. And it is far from clear how to weigh in security interventions and rich-country public R&D investment. For the time being then, we have stood by the humble choice of “equal weights.” We hope that the CDI will increasingly spur research to speed the day when unequal weighting will be more defensible.12 In the meantime, we find “equal weighting” serviceable. II. The Seven Components Aid The aid component designed by Roodman (2004a) is a revised version of that used last year (Roodman 2003). As it did last year, it modifies the traditional quantity measure of aid programs (aid/donor GDP) to reflect several concerns, among them debt service received, tying, and selectivity.13 This year, it also incorporates a penalty for donors that raise the recipient administrative costs of aid by funding many small projects.14 And it factors in private charitable giving to developing countries to the extent this can be credited to government fiscal policy. The component is built largely on data from the Development Assistance Committee (DAC). 11 This does not automatically imply, however, that the migration component is currently underweighted relative to, say, trade. On the current scale, conceivably, a country that completely liberalized temporary migration might earn a score of 50 or 100—a score so high that it might actually exaggerate the benefits of migration. In other words, it is possible with the current scaling that a 1-point increase in trade score still corresponds to more benefit than a 1-point increase on migration. 12 In January 2003, in Cairo, at the annual Global Development Network conference, the Global Policy Project ran a two-day workshop on “The Development Impact of Rich Countries’ Policies,” which identified such research gaps. The summary is at http://www.gdnet.org/pdf/Fourth_Annual_Conference/Workshop3/Workshop4_global_policies_project.pdf. In October, in Washington, D.C., CGD and the GDN sponsored a conference on “Quantifying the Impact of Rich Countries’ Policies on Poor Countries,” at which new research was presented. A full list of papers is at http://www.cgdev.org/events/quantifying_impact.cfm. 13 Unlike in 2003, administrative costs are not subtracted from bilateral flows. Last year, Roodman (2003) argued that “large donor-to-donor variations in their share of gross ODA may indicate inefficiencies. At any rate, netting out administrative costs gives a truer picture of the amount of aid reaching recipients, which is a legitimate basis for comparison.” But low administrative costs may also reflect lack of monitoring and evaluation, which can reduce aid quality. I am indebted to Mark McGillivray for making this point. 14 I thank Robert Picciotto for suggesting this addition. 7 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition The calculations run broadly as follows. First all debt service received from developing countries on concessional (low-interest) loans is subtracted from donors’ gross aid totals. Then three aspects of quality are factored in as discounts or penalties: tying (requiring aid to be spent only on donor-country goods and services), selectivity (the degree to which aid goes to countries that are relatively rich or poorly governed), and proliferation (the tendency to fund many small projects. Finally, a portion of the private charitable giving to developing countries is credited to government tax policies. More precisely: • The starting point is gross disbursements of grants and concessional loans by donor (bilateral or multilateral) and recipient. The data are the latest available, for 2002. Included here is what DAC terms Official Development Assistance (ODA) and Official Assistance (OA).15 • Principal and interest payments are netted out, to more closely reflect net transfers to recipients. DAC’s standard “net ODA” statistic is net of principal payments only. The rationale for the DAC approach appears to be an analogy with net foreign direct investment.16 Only return of capital is netted out of net FDI, not repatriation of earnings. Similarly, only amortization is netted out of net ODA, not interest, which can be seen as the donors’ “earnings” on aid investment. I find the analogy inapt. In the case of FDI, return of capital can be expected to reduce the host country’s capital stock much more than repatriation of profits. Put otherwise, when foreign corporations locally reinvest profits, they generally increase the host country’s capital stock—and net FDI treats it that way. But when the government of Ghana writes a check to the government of Japan for $1 million, it hardly matters for either party whether it says “interest” or “principal” in the check’s memo field. It seems unlikely that interest and principal payments have different effects on Ghana’s development investments. For this reason, the CDI treats all debt service uniformly. • For bilaterals, tied aid is discounted 20%. The base for this discounting is gross disbursements. Studies suggest that tying raises aid project costs 15–30% (Jepma 1991), which translates into a reduction in aid value of 13–23%.17 20% is a round figure toward the top of this range. “Partially untied”18 aid is discounted 10%. The tying figures this year come directly from project-level data in DAC’s Creditor Reporting System database. But like last year, the available tying data are for aid commitments rather than disbursements. Rates of tying are assumed to be the same for commitments and disbursements. 15 OA is like ODA except that it goes to “Part II” countries, which include most European states that emerged out of the Soviet bloc and richer non-DAC members such as Israel and Singapore. DAC excludes OA from its most frequently cited statistic (net ODA), but we included it in our quality-adjusted aid measure because many Part II countries are in need and receiving aid. Some, such as Ukraine, are poorer than many Part I countries. Aid to relatively rich countries, such as Israel, will be heavily discounted in a subsequent step. 16 I base this on an excellent exchange with Simon Scott, Principal Administrator of the Statistics and Monitoring Division of the OECD’s Development Co-operation Directorate, who I cannot assume was representing institutional views, but only his own views. 17 A 15-percent cost increase lowers the purchasing power of aid by 1–1/1.15 = 13 percent. Similarly, a 30-percent costs increase cuts the value of aid 23 percent. 18 Aid that must be spent on goods and services from the donor nation or developing countries; or aid that must be spent on goods and services from developing countries only. 8 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition Unlike last year, technical assistance is not automatically assumed tied, and is only treated as tied if reported as tied in the CRS.19 • The resulting tying-discounted net transfers are split into two kinds of aid, project and program, based on the detailed classification by purpose in the CRS. “Project aid” is meant to include funding for activities over which donors try to exercise detailed, ongoing control. “Program aid” is meant to include budget support, adjustment loans, debt relief, and sector-wide action programs (SWAPs)—aid over which the recipient ideally has near-complete control.20 In the splitting, all debt service is treated as (negative) program aid since its opportunity cost should be a reduction in recipient governments’ discretionary spending. • For each triplet of donor, recipient, and aid type (project or program), the tyingdiscounted net transfer is multiplied by a “selectivity weight” that is meant to reflect the country’s appropriateness for aid. The selectivity weight is now the product of two factors.21 The first is linearly related to the country’s Kaufmann-Kraay composite governance score. (Kaufmann, Kraay, and Mastruzzi 2003) For project aid, the governance factor ranges between 0.25 and 0.75. The country with the lowest governance score, the Democratic Republic of Congo, defines the bottom of that range, getting a 0.25, while Chile anchors the top. For program aid, the scale is stretched to 0.0–1.0. As a result, program aid to the best-governed countries is rewarded more than project aid to them, while the reverse is true for countries with the weakest governance. This distinction is meant to capture the trade-offs between local and foreign “ownership” of aid-financed activities. In Chile, for example, detailed donor management of aid is deemed to be counterproductive, so project aid gets a 0.75 multiplier while program aid gets a 1.0. But in the DRC, governance is so weak that more donor control is treated as beneficial (weight of 0.25 instead of 0.0). Overall, though, both types of aid treated as more effective the better governed the recipient is. Of course because it is poor, the DRC cannot be expected to have very good governance. So the second selectivity multiplier reflects the country’s poverty. It is linearly related to the country’s log real 2002 GDP/capita, with Hong Kong (GDP/capita of $23,200), getting a 0 and Sierra Leone, the poorest country with data (real GDP/capita of $450), defining the upper end. Table 1 shows the resulting weights.22 Emergency aid is exempted from selectivity discounting, to acknowledge, in a way that is practical given the available data, that some forms of aid may be more valuable in countries with the worst governance. 19 Technical assistance may deserve a discount far higher than 20% since foreign experts are often an order of magnitude more expensive than local ones. Most studies of the costs of tying have looked at tied goods rather than services. 20 In practice, the CRS purpose classification was not designed to make this distinction, so the splitting is imperfect. See Roodman (2004a) for details. 21 In 2003, the selectivity weight was a linear function of two factors, which were added rather than multiplied: log real GDP/capita and KK governance controlling for GDP/capita. The new system seems more intuitive and allows the new distinction between program and project aid. 22 The maximum of this scale, Sierra Leone’s value, is 2.27. The intention in choosing this number was to arrange for the maximum combined selectivity factor (poverty factor × governance factor) for any country for either program or project aid would be 1.00. However, because of a programming error discovered after the 2004 numbers were frozen, it turns out that the maximum combined factor is 1.16, for program aid to Madagascar. 9 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition • For each bilateral and multilateral donor, the resulting selectivity-weighted aid figures are summed across recipients to obtain a single figure for each donor, whether bilateral or multilateral. • Each donor is assessed a penalty for “project proliferation,” the phenomenon of funding many small aid projects. Project proliferation is thought to overburden recipient governments with administrative and reporting responsibilities, and lure the most talented workers out of government and into the employ of the donors, thus undermining the effectiveness of aid projects, and government administration in general. (Cassen 1994; Brown et al., 2001; Knack and Rahman 2004). The penalty is calculated as the fraction of aid dollar commitments made in quanta of $100,000 or less, times 4, times gross disbursements.23 The factor of 4 was derived from a more sophisticated model of proliferation costs in Roodman (2004c).24 Thus a country that committed 1% of its aid in 2002 in amounts less than $100,000, would be assessed a penalty of 4% of its gross disbursements. The penalty is treated as already having been weighted for selectivity, as if proliferation cost is already appropriately discounted for countries where aid is predicted to be less productive anyway. • The result is a “quality-adjusted aid quantity” for each bilateral or multilateral donor. (See Table 2.) The quality-adjusted aid totals of multilaterals are then allocated back to bilaterals in proportion to the bilaterals’ contributions to the multilaterals during 2002. For example, since France accounted for 5.96 percent of 2002 contributions to the World Bank’s concessional lending arm, the International Development Association (IDA), it receives credit for 5.5 percent of the IDA’s quality-adjusted aid of $2.8 billion, or $166 million. • The final performance measure for government aid is bilaterals’ total quality-adjusted aid as a share of GDP. (See Table 3.) This year, the aid component also rewards policies that encourage private charitable giving to development organizations. Private giving is encouraged by specific tax incentives that lower the “price” of giving. And it is encouraged by a low tax/GDP ratio, which leaves citizens and corporations with more after-tax income to spend on charitable giving. The approach taken in the CDI is to estimate the proportional increase in giving caused by each country’s fiscal policies, compare that to actual giving, then work backwards to estimate how much actual giving is a credit to policy. (See Table 3.) Specifically: • An estimate is made of the increase in charitable giving brought about by tax incentives. All but three CDI countries—Austria, Finland, and Sweden—offer income tax deductions 23 With two exceptions. New Zealand did not report to the CRS database. Lacking commitments data, the full model’s estimate, based on a large set of interpolations of underlying variables, was used. For multilaterals without CRS data, the extrapolations seemed too tenuous because multilaterals are more diverse in purpose and giving patterns, and so multilaterals without CRS data were assigned a zero proliferation penalty. 24 Because of the complexity of the model in Roodman (2004c) and the minimal empirical evidence to test and calibrate it, it seemed best to use something much simpler into the CDI. So the results from the full approach for the selectivity-weighted proliferation costs by donor were regressed on a set of simple indicators of proliferation. The share of aid commitment dollars made in amounts below $100,000 turned out to have a correlation of 0.78 with the full model’s results, and other indicators could explain little additional variation. See Roodman (2004a). 10 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition or credits for charitable giving. We treat all such provisions as deductions; that is, we treat them as reducing the price of giving by “the” marginal income tax rate. Because tax codes are complex and varied, different taxpayers within countries pay different marginal rates, and the codes are extremely difficult to summarize and compare internationally. We therefore use a crude but available proxy for the marginal income tax rate, namely the share of gross wage earnings going to income tax for workers at 167% of the income level of the average production worker (OECD 200x). Thus, for example, this statistic is 22.6% for the United States, so incentives in the U.S. tax code are treated as reducing the price of charitable giving by 22.6%. In other words, thanks to the deduction, a U.S. citizen can effectively spend 77.4¢ to get $1 worth of charity, on average. Based on a survey of the literature, we set the price elasticity of charitable giving at –0.5. In the United States, this implies that income tax incentives increase charitable giving by 13.7%.25 • An estimate is also made of how much having lower taxes increases giving. The benchmark against which “lowness” is measured is Sweden’s 2001 tax revenue/GDP ratio of 51.4%, the highest among the 21 countries. The United States, to continue the example, is treated as having reduced its total tax burden from Sweden’s 51.4% to the actual 28.9%. This raises the privately claimed share of GDP from 48.6% to 71.1%, an increase of 46.3% over the base.26 Again drawing on the literature, we take the income elasticity of giving to be 1.1: charitable giving increases somewhat more than proportionally with private income. As a result, the lower U.S. tax burden is estimated to raise charity 52.0%.27 • The price and income effects are then combined. For the United States, the 13.7% and 52.0% increases compound for a 72.7% increase. • DAC data on actual private giving to developing countries is then used to estimate what giving would have been in the absence of these policies, and what credit should be given to policy. This statistic counts all giving by individuals and foundations, but leaves out official aid that is channeled through foreign NGOs. In the U.S. case, charitable giving is reported at $5.66 billion for 2002. The CDI estimates this would have been $3.27 billion before the policy-induced 72.7% increase, and attributes the difference, $2.38 billion to favorable fiscal policies. • The policy-induced increases in charitable giving are then discounted for quality and added to the official quality-adjusted aid quantities. Private giving too can go to countries that are more or less appropriate for aid, and can contribute to the problems of project proliferation, for example by siphoning off talented administrators from government service. As a rough adjustment, the CDI discounts policy-induced private giving by the simple average of the quality discounts for bilaterals’ own aid programs, which is 37%. To complete the U.S. example, we credit the country for $2.38 billion × (1–37%) = $1.50 billion in quality adjusted aid. Added to its $7.295 billion in official quality-adjusted aid, 25 The precise calculation is (1–0.226)–0.5–1=0.137. Some share of the revenue funds transfer payments, which the recipients may use as they please, including for charitable giving. The precise effect of this redistribution on giving is difficult to know because it depends on such factors as the difference in income between the typical taxpayer and typical transfer recipient. This seems like too complicated an issue to address. 27 The precise calculation is ((1–0.289)/(1–0.514))1.1–1=0.52. 26 11 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition this raises its CDI aid score to 1.9, from what would have been 1.6 had charitable contributions not been considered in the CDI in 2004. The treatment of charitable giving involves a number of coarse assumptions. It models taxpayers with a single representative agent, simplifies complex tax provisions, uses rough but ready approximations for the appropriate tax rates, assumes certain fixed elasticities, and assumes that the elasticities are the same for charitable giving to developing countries as they are for charitable giving in general. Its methodological sophistication, such as it is, should not be confused with precision. But given the modest impact the adjustment has for the United States— the country most known for private generosity and public stinginess when it comes to aid—it seems unlikely that refinements in methodology, though desirable, would affect results much. Overall, despite the quality adjustments and the incorporation of private giving, what most distinguishes donors from each other in the CDI is still the raw quantity of official aid they disburse. Denmark, the Netherlands, Norway, Sweden are large donors by DAC’s quantity measure (net ODA), and they score highest on the CDI aid measure too—as they did last year. The nearly 8-fold variation between the most generous donor by DAC’s measure (Denmark, at 0.96% of GDP) and the least generous (the United States, at 0.13%) dominates differences in quality, which probably does not vary across donors so much. They also dominate private giving. That said, the new proliferation penalty does have a noticeable effect at the bottom of standings, pulling down Greece, Ireland, and New Zealand. These small donors appear to spread their aid thinly. As a result, the United States and Japan no longer occupy the bottom two slots of the aid ranking, despite being lowest in net concessional transfers to developing countries. The final column of Table 4 compares the CDI index of official aid performance to the standard DAC measure. This summarizes all of the “adjustments” in quality-adjusted aid. New Zealand suffers most from the adjustments because of a very high project proliferation penalty28. Greece, Ireland, and Spain also experience heavy discounts because of project proliferation. And Japan is pulled low because of its high debt service receipts on ODA loans. Of course, aid quality as defined here leaves out many factors that influence aid effectiveness, such as appropriateness of project designs, appropriateness and enforcement of loan conditions, and so on. The CDI aid component is hardly the final word on measuring aid performance. Table 1. Computation of selectivity weights Country name Formula: Madagascar Malawi Tanzania Mali Benin Burkina Faso Mongolia Zambia Niger 28 A. Real GDP/capita, B. Log real 2002 ($) GDP/capita 650 519 493 777 913 896 1,462 713 685 Log A 6.48 6.25 6.20 6.66 6.82 6.80 7.29 6.57 6.53 D. KaufE. Governmann-Kraay ance selecC. GDP composite tivity multiselectivity governance plier, project multiplier score, 2002 aid (linear map (linear map of B to 0– of D to 0.25– 2.27 range) 0.75 range) 2.06 –0.07 0.53 2.19 –0.42 0.47 2.22 –0.54 0.46 1.96 –0.35 0.49 1.86 –0.26 0.50 1.88 –0.31 0.49 1.59 0.21 0.58 2.01 –0.57 0.45 2.03 –0.64 0.44 F. Governance selectivity multiplier, program aid (linear map of D to 0–1 range) 0.56 0.45 0.41 0.47 0.50 0.49 0.65 0.40 0.38 H. ComG. Com- bined sebined se- lectivity lectivity multiplier, multiplier, program project aid aid C×E 1.09 1.04 1.01 0.95 0.93 0.92 0.92 0.90 0.89 C×F 1.16 0.98 0.92 0.92 0.94 0.91 1.04 0.80 0.77 This penalty had to be extrapolated because the country no longer reports the requisite data to DAC. 12 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition Country name Mauritania Mozambique Senegal Ethiopia Guinea-Bissau Eritrea Sierra Leone Moldova Yemen, Rep. Kenya Ghana Nepal Uganda Gambia, The Lesotho Cambodia Togo Nigeria Comoros Chad Burundi India Tajikistan Bolivia Rwanda Congo, Rep. Vietnam Kyrgyz Republic Bangladesh Central African Republic Papua New Guinea Djibouti Honduras Cameroon Sri Lanka Cote d’Ivoire Pakistan Armenia Jamaica Dominica Morocco Lao PDR Jordan Cape Verde Guinea Uzbekistan Philippines Georgia Egypt, Arab Rep. Congo, Dem. Rep. Guyana Syrian Arab Republic Haiti Ecuador El Salvador Guatemala Albania China Indonesia Belize A. Real GDP/capita, B. Log real 2002 ($) GDP/capita 1,337 7.20 1,009 6.92 1,359 7.21 641 6.46 689 6.54 848 6.74 451 6.11 1,267 7.14 693 6.54 878 6.78 1,815 7.50 1,171 7.07 1,199 7.09 1,525 7.33 2,011 7.61 1,459 7.29 1,291 7.16 753 6.62 1,452 7.28 892 6.79 543 6.30 2,276 7.73 811 6.70 2,089 7.64 1,081 6.99 856 6.75 1,982 7.59 1,391 7.24 1,537 7.34 1,061 6.97 1,895 7.55 1,795 7.49 2,231 7.71 1,515 7.32 3,052 8.02 1,328 7.19 1,783 7.49 2,618 7.87 3,341 8.11 4,660 8.45 3,335 8.11 1,485 7.30 3,634 8.20 4,238 8.35 1,793 7.49 1,426 7.26 3,560 8.18 1,939 7.57 3,276 8.09 537 6.29 3,617 8.19 2,996 8.01 1,397 7.24 3,050 8.02 4,138 8.33 3,476 8.15 3,517 8.17 3,961 8.28 2,778 7.93 5,229 8.56 D. Kaufmann-Kraay C. GDP composite selectivity governance multiplier score, 2002 1.64 –0.08 1.81 –0.40 1.64 –0.16 2.07 –0.84 2.03 –0.84 1.91 –0.73 2.27 –1.16 1.68 –0.43 2.02 –0.94 1.89 –0.81 1.47 –0.15 1.72 –0.66 1.71 –0.73 1.57 –0.53 1.41 –0.21 1.59 –0.59 1.66 –0.72 1.98 –1.20 1.60 –0.69 1.88 –1.09 2.16 –1.40 1.34 –0.19 1.93 –1.17 1.39 –0.38 1.77 –1.02 1.90 –1.19 1.42 –0.48 1.62 –0.85 1.56 –0.78 1.78 –1.13 1.44 –0.64 1.47 –0.71 1.35 –0.49 1.57 –0.91 1.17 –0.12 1.65 –1.10 1.48 –0.84 1.26 –0.40 1.12 –0.03 0.93 0.65 1.12 –0.05 1.58 –1.03 1.07 –0.01 0.98 0.22 1.48 –0.98 1.61 –1.22 1.08 –0.22 1.43 –1.00 1.13 –0.36 2.17 –1.82 1.07 –0.24 1.18 –0.66 1.62 –1.40 1.17 –0.66 0.99 –0.18 1.09 –0.53 1.09 –0.52 1.02 –0.34 1.22 –0.84 0.86 0.22 E. Govern- F. Governance selec- ance selectivity multi- tivity multiplier, project plier, proaid gram aid 0.53 0.56 0.48 0.46 0.52 0.53 0.41 0.32 0.41 0.32 0.43 0.35 0.36 0.21 0.47 0.45 0.39 0.28 0.41 0.32 0.52 0.54 0.44 0.37 0.42 0.35 0.46 0.42 0.51 0.52 0.45 0.39 0.43 0.35 0.35 0.20 0.43 0.36 0.37 0.23 0.32 0.14 0.51 0.53 0.35 0.21 0.48 0.46 0.38 0.26 0.35 0.20 0.46 0.43 0.41 0.31 0.42 0.34 0.36 0.22 0.44 0.38 0.43 0.36 0.46 0.43 0.40 0.29 0.52 0.55 0.37 0.23 0.41 0.31 0.48 0.46 0.54 0.58 0.65 0.80 0.54 0.57 0.38 0.25 0.54 0.58 0.58 0.66 0.38 0.27 0.35 0.19 0.51 0.52 0.38 0.26 0.48 0.47 0.25 0.00 0.50 0.51 0.44 0.37 0.32 0.13 0.44 0.37 0.51 0.53 0.46 0.42 0.46 0.42 0.49 0.48 0.41 0.31 0.58 0.66 H. ComG. Com- bined sebined se- lectivity lectivity multiplier, multiplier, program project aid aid 0.87 0.92 0.86 0.82 0.84 0.87 0.84 0.65 0.83 0.64 0.81 0.67 0.81 0.48 0.79 0.75 0.79 0.57 0.78 0.61 0.76 0.79 0.75 0.64 0.72 0.60 0.72 0.65 0.72 0.73 0.71 0.63 0.71 0.59 0.69 0.39 0.69 0.58 0.69 0.44 0.69 0.29 0.69 0.70 0.69 0.40 0.67 0.64 0.67 0.45 0.67 0.38 0.66 0.61 0.66 0.50 0.65 0.52 0.64 0.40 0.63 0.55 0.63 0.53 0.63 0.58 0.62 0.46 0.61 0.64 0.60 0.38 0.60 0.46 0.60 0.57 0.60 0.64 0.60 0.74 0.60 0.64 0.60 0.40 0.58 0.62 0.57 0.64 0.57 0.40 0.56 0.31 0.55 0.56 0.55 0.38 0.55 0.53 0.54 0.00 0.54 0.54 0.52 0.44 0.51 0.22 0.51 0.44 0.51 0.52 0.50 0.45 0.50 0.45 0.50 0.49 0.50 0.38 0.50 0.57 13 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition Country name Lebanon Fiji Peru Panama Namibia Swaziland Azerbaijan Grenada Angola Sudan Zimbabwe Thailand Bulgaria Tunisia Romania Botswana Ukraine Costa Rica Chile Dominican Republic Gabon Latvia Brazil Paraguay Macedonia, FYR Malaysia Bosnia and Herzegovina Kazakhstan Venezuela, RB Algeria Colombia Trinidad and Tobago Lithuania Mexico Belarus Iran, Islamic Rep. Mauritius Antigua and Barbuda Turkmenistan South Africa Croatia Estonia Russian Federation Uruguay Malta Hungary Argentina Barbados Saudi Arabia Bahrain Slovenia Kuwait Israel Cyprus Macao, China Hong Kong, China A. Real GDP/capita, B. Log real 2002 ($) GDP/capita 3,756 8.23 4,733 8.46 4,358 8.38 5,286 8.57 5,674 8.64 3,986 8.29 2,757 7.92 6,186 8.73 1,817 7.50 1,741 7.46 2,018 7.61 6,009 8.70 6,115 8.72 5,824 8.67 5,600 8.63 7,298 8.90 4,173 8.34 7,497 8.92 8,463 9.04 5,486 8.61 5,621 8.63 7,935 8.98 6,653 8.80 3,912 8.27 5,543 8.62 7,897 8.97 4,902 8.50 5,106 8.54 4,626 8.44 4,901 8.50 5,371 8.59 8,067 9.00 8,865 9.09 7,707 8.95 4,730 8.46 5,611 8.63 9,321 9.14 9,379 9.15 4,091 8.32 8,969 9.10 8,823 9.09 10,367 9.25 7,016 8.86 10,727 9.28 11,649 9.36 11,621 9.36 9,378 9.15 13,774 9.53 11,800 9.38 14,216 9.56 15,711 9.66 16,553 9.71 17,518 9.77 18,757 9.84 19,147 9.86 23,223 10.05 D. Kaufmann-Kraay C. GDP composite selectivity governance multiplier score, 2002 1.05 –0.44 0.92 –0.03 0.96 –0.22 0.85 0.16 0.81 0.31 1.02 –0.43 1.23 –0.96 0.76 0.50 1.47 –1.36 1.49 –1.40 1.41 –1.34 0.78 0.25 0.77 0.26 0.80 0.11 0.82 0.01 0.67 0.77 0.99 –0.59 0.65 0.81 0.58 1.28 0.83 –0.17 0.82 –0.28 0.62 0.64 0.72 0.02 1.03 –1.01 0.83 –0.47 0.62 0.45 0.90 –0.73 0.87 –0.67 0.93 –0.88 0.90 –0.81 0.84 –0.66 0.61 0.34 0.55 0.69 0.64 0.13 0.92 –0.98 0.82 –0.73 0.53 0.70 0.52 0.68 1.00 –1.30 0.55 0.38 0.56 0.29 0.46 0.94 0.69 –0.55 0.44 0.70 0.40 1.16 0.40 0.96 0.52 –0.58 0.30 1.24 0.39 –0.05 0.28 0.53 0.23 0.99 0.20 0.36 0.16 0.56 0.12 0.88 0.11 0.53 0.00 1.16 E. Govern- F. Governance selec- ance selectivity multi- tivity multiplier, project plier, proaid gram aid 0.47 0.44 0.54 0.58 0.51 0.51 0.57 0.64 0.59 0.69 0.47 0.45 0.39 0.28 0.62 0.75 0.32 0.15 0.32 0.14 0.33 0.15 0.58 0.67 0.58 0.67 0.56 0.62 0.54 0.59 0.67 0.84 0.45 0.39 0.67 0.85 0.75 1.00 0.52 0.53 0.50 0.50 0.65 0.79 0.55 0.59 0.38 0.26 0.47 0.43 0.62 0.73 0.42 0.35 0.43 0.37 0.40 0.30 0.41 0.32 0.44 0.37 0.60 0.69 0.65 0.81 0.56 0.63 0.39 0.27 0.43 0.35 0.66 0.81 0.65 0.81 0.33 0.17 0.61 0.71 0.59 0.68 0.69 0.89 0.45 0.41 0.66 0.81 0.73 0.96 0.70 0.89 0.45 0.40 0.74 0.98 0.53 0.57 0.63 0.76 0.70 0.90 0.60 0.70 0.63 0.77 0.68 0.87 0.63 0.76 0.73 0.96 H. ComG. Com- bined sebined se- lectivity lectivity multiplier, multiplier, program project aid aid 0.50 0.47 0.49 0.53 0.49 0.50 0.49 0.54 0.48 0.56 0.48 0.45 0.48 0.34 0.48 0.57 0.47 0.22 0.47 0.20 0.46 0.22 0.45 0.52 0.45 0.51 0.45 0.50 0.45 0.48 0.45 0.56 0.44 0.39 0.44 0.55 0.44 0.58 0.43 0.44 0.41 0.40 0.40 0.49 0.39 0.43 0.39 0.27 0.38 0.36 0.38 0.45 0.38 0.31 0.38 0.32 0.37 0.28 0.37 0.29 0.37 0.31 0.36 0.42 0.36 0.45 0.36 0.40 0.35 0.25 0.35 0.29 0.34 0.43 0.34 0.42 0.33 0.17 0.33 0.39 0.33 0.38 0.32 0.41 0.31 0.28 0.29 0.36 0.29 0.38 0.28 0.36 0.24 0.21 0.22 0.30 0.21 0.22 0.18 0.21 0.16 0.20 0.12 0.14 0.10 0.12 0.08 0.11 0.07 0.08 0.00 0.00 14 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition Table 2. Quality-adjusted aid quantity by donor, bilateral or multilateral A Gross aid B Amortization C D E Proliferation cost F Tying cost G SelectivQualityInterest Net aid ity adjusted aid 1 Formula: A–B–C (D–F)×G–E Australia 777 0 0 777 113 70 0.63 332 Austria 509 3 2 504 83 31 0.59 198 Belgium 758 35 3 721 112 7 0.66 360 Canada 1,633 26 1 1,606 96 118 0.59 778 Denmark 1,178 45 9 1,124 181 35 0.70 580 Finland 291 7 0 283 31 17 0.66 145 France 5,624 947 0 4,678 309 348 0.51 1,886 Germany 4,538 945 356 3,237 150 119 0.63 1,826 Greece 123 0 0 123 46 22 0.47 1 Ireland 268 0 0 268 150 0 0.74 48 Italy 1,208 200 0 1,007 1 266 0.80 595 Japan 9,811 3,062 1,735 5,014 2 197 0.56 2,673 Netherlands 2,677 97 50 2,531 68 25 0.62 1,485 New Zealand 92 0 0 92 60 0 0.64 -1 Norway 1,193 5 0 1,188 365 2 0.71 482 Portugal 187 0 1 186 84 13 0.58 16 Spain 1,164 154 1 1,009 407 178 0.53 31 Sweden 1,351 1 0 1,350 143 12 0.72 817 Switzerland 826 4 0 822 27 2 0.70 549 United Kingdom 3,696 102 2 3,592 43 26 0.68 2,386 United States 13,847 1,033 443 12,371 140 1,997 0.55 5,597 AfDF 741 125 97 519 0 0 0.73 379 AsDF 1,168 262 156 750 0 0 0.67 506 CarDB 119 56 36 27 0 0 0.48 13 EBRD 72 0 0 72 0 0 0.44 32 EC 10,145 786 494 8,865 25 0 0.53 4,645 GEF 137 0 0 137 0 0 0.50 69 IDA 6,667 1,263 745 4,658 0 0 0.65 3,027 IDB Sp F 425 259 119 48 0 0 1.28 61 IFAD 250 102 34 114 0 0 0.75 85 Montreal Protocol 60 0 0 60 0 0 0.52 31 Nordic Dev.Fund 35 2 0 33 0 0 0.79 26 Other UN 630 0 0 630 0 0 0.50 318 SAF+ESAF(IMF) 2,936 1,984 0 951 0 0 0.91 868 UNDP 278 0 0 278 0 0 0.69 192 UNFPA 312 0 0 312 0 0 0.65 203 UNHCR 655 0 0 655 0 0 0.61 402 UNICEF 571 0 0 571 114 0 0.64 251 UNTA 478 0 0 478 0 0 0.60 287 WFP 352 0 0 352 0 0 0.68 240 1 The estimated proliferation cost already factors in selectivity, and so is not multiplied by the selectivity factor in this formula. 15 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition Table 3. Calculation of policy-induced charitable giving Country Formula: Australia Austria Belgium Canada Denmark Finland France Germany Greece Ireland Italy Japan Netherlands N. Zealand Norway Portugal Spain Sweden Switzerland U.K. U.S. E. Giving increase B. Mar- C. Increase D. Tax ginal in- in giving reve- because of come tax with incen- nue/GDP, smaller 1 rate (%) tive (%) 2001 (%) gov’t (%) ((1–D)/(1– (1– 51.4%))^ income A×B)^price 3 4 elasticity–1 elasticity–1 1 32.0 21.3 30.1 49.2 0 17.3 0.0 45.4 13.7 1 34.4 23.5 45.8 12.7 1 24.8 15.3 35.1 37.5 1 41.5 30.7 49.8 3.6 0 32.8 0.0 46.1 12.1 1 17.9 10.4 45.0 14.6 1 29.5 19.1 36.8 33.5 1 7.6 4.0 36.9 33.3 1 22.2 13.4 29.9 49.6 1 24.2 14.9 42.0 21.5 1 9.4 5.1 27.3 55.7 1 21.2 12.7 39.5 27.2 1 25.7 16.0 33.8 40.5 1 28.4 18.2 43.3 18.5 1 12.2 6.7 33.5 41.2 1 17.8 10.3 35.2 37.2 0 30.8 0.0 51.4 0.0 1 14.6 8.2 30.6 48.0 1 18.2 10.6 37.3 32.3 1 22.6 13.7 28.9 52.0 A. Tax incentive? G. Grants F. Com- by NGOs bined in- (million $, 2001 crease 2 prices) (%) (1+C)× (1+E)–1 80.9 13.7 39.2 58.5 35.5 12.1 26.5 59.0 38.6 69.6 39.5 63.6 43.3 63.0 40.0 50.7 51.4 0.0 60.1 46.3 72.7 229 54 69 277 17 10 203 770 5 78 32 165 236 21 404 5 118 18 186 328 5,656 H. Giving in Giving absence of attributed to tax favorable tax policies policies F/(1+G) 127 47 49 175 12 9 160 484 4 46 23 101 165 13 288 3 78 18 116 224 3,274 G–H 103 6 19 102 4 1 42 286 1 32 9 64 71 8 115 2 40 0 70 104 2,381 1 Income tax as % of gross wage earnings (2002)—single individual at 167% income level of the average 2 3 4 production worker. Data for latest available year. Price elasticity of giving taken to be –0.5. Income elasticity of giving taken to be 1.1. 16 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition Table 4. Quality-adjusted aid quantity with multilateral aid allocated back to bilaterals Bilateral qualityadjusted 1 aid Country Australia 332 Austria 198 Belgium 360 Canada 778 Denmark 580 Finland 145 France 1,886 Germany 1,826 Greece 1 Ireland 48 Italy 595 Japan 2,673 Netherlands 1,485 New Zealand -1 Norway 482 Portugal 16 Spain 31 Sweden 817 Switzerland 549 United Kingdom 2,386 United States 5,597 1 From Table 2. QualityQualityMemo: OfTotal adadjusted ficial aid qualityjusted Adjusted quality (Adaid allochari- (aid+chari justed cated from adjusted multilater- official Charita- table table giv- aid/Net aid ble giving giving ing)/GDP als ODA) 136 468 103 64 0.13% 44% 136 334 6 4 0.17% 44% 298 657 19 12 0.27% 52% 314 1,092 102 64 0.16% 48% 387 967 4 3 0.55% 59% 150 295 1 1 0.23% 53% 1,872 3,758 42 27 0.27% 52% 1,489 3,315 286 179 0.18% 51% 104 105 1 1 0.08% 35% 94 142 32 20 0.14% 29% 888 1,483 9 6 0.13% 60% 1,648 4,321 64 40 0.11% 45% 550 2,035 71 45 0.50% 54% 16 15 8 5 0.03% 59% 346 828 115 72 0.48% 45% 106 123 2 1 0.10% 32% 519 549 40 25 0.09% 31% 466 1,283 0 0 0.56% 58% 104 654 70 44 0.26% 61% 928 3,315 104 65 0.22% 57% 1,697 7,295 2,381 1,494 0.08% 45% Trade The focus of the trade component developed by William Cline (2002) is a measure of barriers in rich-counties to goods exports from poorer ones. Cline’s index has two major parts. The first, getting 75% weight, is an aggregate measure of protection (AMP), which estimates the combined effect of tariffs, non-tariff measures, and domestic production subsidies on an ad valorem tariffequivalent basis. Out of concern that unmeasured (tacit) barriers may be an important factor in reducing access of developing countries to rich country markets, especially in Japan, the remaining 25% weight goes to an indicator of “revealed openness,” which is essentially imports from developing countries as a share of importer’s GDP. Cline has revised the index (Cline 2004, ch. 3), and I have made small changes in adapting it for the CDI.29 The CDI version of the AMP divides goods into six categories: agricultural commodities, other agriculture (processed agricultural goods and fish), textiles, apparel, fuels, and other goods (mainly manufactures). For all categories, estimates are gathered of the average ad valorem tariff-equivalent of tariffs (some tariffs are expressed in specific units such as tons). Subsidies (for agricultural commodities only) and of quotas (textiles and apparel only) are also expressed in 29 One change cut the AMP for the European Union, Japan, and the United States by about half, but had relatively little effect on relative standings on the component. In computing the average tariff within agriculture using world production weights, 21 product categories were used, as described in text here, instead of the original 5. 17 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition tariff-equivalent terms. These are then combined into an overall estimate of protection in tariffequivalent terms. The EU is often treated as a single unit in trade data, so in some places, the 14 EU members that are scored in the CDI get identical numbers. But where the data permit, EU members are differentiated. The methodology computes the following variables in turn: Agricultural tariffs on an ad valorem basis. For agricultural commodities and other agriculture, the simple tariff-equivalent of tariff regimes is computed as the weighted average of the protection levels in major product categories such as wheat, rice, and cattle and sheep meat. The weights are based on levels of world production. It may be theoretically preferable to derive the weights from imports from developing countries rather than world production, but rich-country protection in agriculture is so high that even a sophisticated model incorporating various estimated elasticities could be quite inaccurate in predicting imports in the absence of protection, which is a necessary ingredient in calculating the harm that current protection does. Production figures, in contrast, are not as endogenous to protection and give clear sense of which crops are the major ones at the global level. All data are from the GTAP 5.0 database (Dimaranan and McDougall 2002). (See Table 5 and Table 6.) Dollar value of agricultural subsidies. It is often said that OECD governments spend more than $300 billion a year subsidizing agricultural production. Although aid to rich-country farmers is in fact copious, the $300 billion “fact,” so phrased, is wrong. Rather, OECD farmers and food buyers receive support by virtue of government policy that is equivalent to more than $300 billion in subsidies, as measured by the OECD’s Total Support Estimate (TSE). Much of this benefit is actually delivered in the form of tariffs, which the OECD converts to subsidy equivalents. Much of the rest includes “general services” such as agricultural education and R&D, transfers to consumers rather than producers, and transfers to producers in ways that create little incentive for additional production, thus little trade distortion. Since the CDI aims to measure trade distortions, and handles tariffs separately, it uses a narrower definition of subsidy, while still drawing on the OECD subsidy data. Table 7 shows the full OECD agricultural subsidy typology, and how both the TSE and the CDI subsidy totals are arrived at. The OECD lists three major kinds of support: support to producers, general services such as agricultural extension and inspection services, and support to consumers. The first major subcategory of producer support is Market Price Support (MPS, row B of the table), which is the additional income accruing to producers because their farmgate prices are higher than world prices. Governments maintain these price differentials with two kinds of border measures: barriers to imports (tariffs) and subsidies for exports. Import barriers account for the lion’s share of MPS in OECD countries and, because they generate transfers from domestic consumers to domestic producers, they also show up as negative entries under consumer support (row T). Spending on export subsidies can be inferred by taking the algebraic sum of MPS and transfers from consumers to producers, which carry a negative sign (see row X). The other subcategories of OECD producer support are in fact subsidies in the sense of government expenditure. The OECD’s TSE counts all producer support, including MPS, as well as general services and taxpayers subsidies to consumers—$300 billion/year average in 2000–02 for the 21 rated countries (row W). In contrast, the subsidy measure in the CDI consists purely of certain subcategories of producer support, those that are true government expenditures that distort pro18 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition duction (rows X and Y). From the MPS it takes only export subsidies. It excludes payments based on overall farming income since these should not distort production decisions. It also discounts payments based on historical entitlements by half. In theory, these subsidies too are decoupled from present production and shouldn’t distort it, but they are often administered in ways that stimulate production. For example, the U.S. formally decoupled most support payments in 1996—but then disbursed an extra $8.6 billion/year in “emergency assistance” during 1998– 2001, and in 2002 allowed farmers to update the base figures for their “decoupled” subsidies. And some EU payments are decoupled only at the national or regional level—allocation within regions is still based on actual production. (de Gorter, Ingco, and Ignacio 2003) Throughout, averages for 2000–02 are used because subsidy levels are sensitive to volatile world prices. For the 21 scored countries, total trade-distorting subsidies are estimated at $79 billion/year for 2000–02. EU subsidies disaggregated by member. Although agricultural subsidies are largely unified in the EU under the Common Agricultural Policy, the Policy itself can be thought of as the outcome of a political process in which each country can be expected to have maximized its receipts by lobbying for subsidies on the products it is most able to produce. Moreover, EU members do offer additional subsidies to their farmers outside the CAP. Thus the amount of subsidy a country’s farmers receive is in no small part a reflection of the country’s policy stance. For the sake of differentiating EU members, the CDI therefore estimates subsidy levels for individual EU members, following the method developed in Cline (2002). The CAP subsidy total is allocated to individual members based on the size of their contributions to the main Common Agricultural Policy fund, the European Agricultural Guidance and Guarantee Fund, and nationallevel, non-CAP subsidies are added in. Ad valorem tariff equivalent of agricultural commodity subsidies. The methodology for expressing agricultural subsidies in tariff-equivalent terms is too complex to summarize here. Table 8 lays out the data and calculations as performed for the CDI. See Cline (2004, ch. 3). Ad valorem tariff equivalent of protection in textiles, apparel, fuels, and other goods (mainly manufactures). The CDI uses the values that Cline culls from the literature for each of these categories. For textiles and apparel, the tariff-equivalents of tariffs and non-tariff measures (quotas) are combined to give overall levels of protection in the sectors. See Table 9. Aggregate Measure of Protection. For each rich country, the ad valorem tariff equivalents of protection in the six sectors are combined based on the value of imports in those categories from the non-DAC world. The precise formula used is different from Cline’s and arguably more direct. (See Appendix.) Both approaches attempt to correct for the potential endogeneity of imports to protection, which can bias straight import weighting (high protection reducing imports, thus underweighting the very categories where protection is highest). And both yield results that differ only modestly from straight import weighting. Revealed openness is a weighted sum of imports from non-DAC countries over importer’s GDP for 2002. Imports from the least developed countries (LDCs) are double-weighted to reflect the extra potential for trade to reduce poverty in countries where it is highest. Imports of manufactures too are double-weighted because they seem more likely than, say, oil imports, to be subject to the tacit barriers this component tries to detect (Cline 2004). As a result, manufac- 19 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition tures imports from LDCs are quadruple-weighted.30 All EU members are assigned the same revealed openness score.31 See Table 11. Combining the AMP and revealed openness. The two main indicators have opposite senses: lower AMP and higher openness should be rewarded. Because they are in effect separate estimates of the same underlying variable, level of protection (they are correlated -0.77), they are combined in a way that is unique within the 2004 CDI. The revealed openness scores are linearly transformed to have the same mean, standard deviation, and sense as the AMP. Once they are on the same scales, they are combined in a 75/25 ratio. (See Table 12.) Not surprisingly given that most of the underlying data is the same as for last year, the pattern of results has not changed much. Agricultural tariffs are still the dominant source of intercountry variation, giving Norway in particular a very low score, and Japan and Switzerland low scores as well. Agricultural commodity subsidies, though harmful, only rival agricultural commodity tariffs where those tariffs are low, namely Australia, New Zealand, and the United States. The source of the very high numbers for the EU, Norway, Switzerland, and Japan are tariff-rate quotas (TRQs) enacted under the Uruguay Round agreement of the World Trade Organization. Under this system, countries replaced import quotas with pairs of tariffs—lower tariffs on within-quota imports higher ones on above-quota imports, in order to cap imports at the old quota level, at least in theory. These estimates of protection inherited several shortcomings from the GTAP tariff data that dominate the results. Rather than using tariff rates actually applied, they use upper bound rates committed to in the Uruguay Round of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade. The estimates do not factor in the preferences (lower tariffs) that many rich countries grant developing countries, such as through the U.S. Africa Growth and Opportunity Act and the European Everything But Arms initiative. They leave out contingent protection such as anti-dumping duties. And they are for 1997. In 2004, the World Bank (Kee, Nicita, and Olarreaga 2004) and the Centre d’Etudes Prospectives et d’Informations Internationales (see Bouët et al. 2001) released new sets of estimates which theoretically correct all these problems in the GTAP numbers. But the results are already controversial among researchers. Kee, Nicita, and Olarreaga, for instance, estimate Japan’s protection at just 3.9% tariff-equivalent with respect to all countries and 1.5% with respect to low-income countries only—lower than their estimates for the EU, United States, and Canada (World Bank 2004, ch. 10), and far less than the 13.0% figure with respect to low and middle-income countries that is found here. Since the field was in ferment in early 2004, it seemed best to stay with the GTAP 5 dataset which, whatever its theoretical limitations, has undergone peer review for use in a widely respected academic database. I hope that in 12 months we will understand the key differences in assumptions and methods are that generating such differences in results. And by 2005, GTAP 6 should reach its own influential verdict.32 30 This is a small change from the 2003 CDI, in which they were triple-weighted. The new approach is more consistent and makes only a tiny difference since manufacturers imports from LDCs are low. 31 We experimented with computing revealed openness separately for each EU member, but found that it gave the Netherlands and Belgium outsized scores, probably because they have small economies and are ports of entry for the continent. The two probably ship a good share of their reported imports from developing countries on to other nations. 32 We seriously considered using the CEPII results in the 2004 CDI. I thank Lionel Fontagné and Yvan Decreux of CEPII for their generous and responsive manner in which they provided us with their latest results, and Peter 20 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition Table 5. Calculation of uniform ad valorem tariff-equivalent of tariff regimes against agricultural commodities, 1997–98 (percent) Greece Germany France Finland Denmark Canada Belgium Austria Australia 64.9 64.9 64.9 64.9 64.9 64.9 0.0 64.9 64.9 1.0 61.4 61.4 61.4 61.4 61.4 61.4 61.4 62.7 61.4 61.4 0.0 38.6 38.6 38.6 38.6 38.6 38.6 38.6 8.9 38.6 38.6 0.8 14.5 14.5 14.5 14.5 14.5 14.5 14.5 1.9 14.5 14.5 2.0 0.0 251.4 0.0 251.4 0.0 251.4 0.0 251.4 0.0 251.4 0.0 251.4 0.0 251.4 0.0 0.0 251.4 0.0 251.4 1.5 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.7 36.6 36.6 36.6 36.6 36.6 36.6 36.6 0.2 36.6 36.6 0.8 6.7 6.7 6.7 6.7 6.7 6.7 6.7 19.8 6.7 6.7 0.5 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 88.9 88.9 88.9 88.9 88.9 88.9 88.9 16.3 88.9 88.9 0.1 30.9 30.9 30.9 30.9 30.9 30.9 30.9 30.9 4.1 87.7 87.7 87.7 87.7 87.7 87.7 72.4 214.8 30.9 87.7 87.7 87.7 7.3 87.4 87.4 87.4 87.4 87.4 87.4 87.4 0.7 87.4 87.4 1.0 76.4 76.4 76.4 76.4 76.4 76.4 76.4 4.9 76.4 76.4 13.9 45.3 45.3 45.3 45.3 45.3 45.3 45.3 36.0 45.3 45.3 2.3 VegePlantAnimal Cattle, Dairy ProcOverall Paddy Other tables, Oil Sugar based Cattle, prod- Raw sheep Other prod- essed weighted rice Wheat grains fruit seeds cane fibers sheep ucts milk meat meat ucts rice Sugar average Ireland 64.9 5.0 0.0 36.4 30.9 87.7 87.4 76.4 58.2 287.0 409.0 116.1 3.1 45.3 118.8 0.0 Italy 0.0 149.1 88.9 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 76.4 6.7 11.2 44.9 36.6 11.1 20.2 0.0 3.9 198.1 Switzerland Sweden Spain Portugal 4.9 64.9 64.9 64.9 2.6 61.4 35.8 120.0 64.9 102 61.4 61.4 61.4 141 0.6 38.6 38.6 38.6 4.7 14.5 98.9 101.2 38.6 439 14.5 94 17.7 48 0.7 0.0 251.4 97.4 152.8 47 9.7 0.0 205 1.1 36.6 291 0.6 6.7 202 0.0 0.0 246 5.3 88.9 275 3.6 30.9 285 42.5 87.7 155 5.3 87.4 98 53.4 76.4 2,776 9.4 45.3 137.3 155.4 333.9 195.3 109.4 129.9 205.3 409.0 249.2 Japan 0.0 251.4 0.0 53.1 45.3 14.5 0.4 351.3 368.2 316.8 107.2 76.4 45.3 38.6 0.9 87.4 76.4 45.3 61.4 0.0 87.7 87.4 76.4 64.9 0.0 30.9 87.7 87.4 Netherlands 0.0 88.9 30.9 87.7 0.0 0.0 319.3 103.1 0.0 88.9 30.9 2.5 6.7 0.0 88.9 1.2 36.6 6.7 0.0 0.0 0.0 36.6 6.7 0.0 0.0 251.4 0.0 36.6 33.0 131.0 New Zealand 14.5 0.0 251.4 0.0 0.4 197.7 296.3 223.9 United Kingdom 149 Norway 14.5 0.0 251.4 0.1 161.6 150.3 United States Weight (World production, billion $) Timmer, Thomas Hertel, Bita Dimaranan, William Martin, Bernard Hoekman, and Paul Gibson for consultations on the difficult decision not to use them in 2004. 21 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition Table 6. Calculation of uniform ad valorem tariff-equivalent of tariff regimes against other agriculture, 1997–98 (percent) Sweden Spain Portugal Norway New Zealand Netherlands Japan Italy Ireland Greece Germany France Finland Denmark Canada Belgium Austria Australia 35.7 3.1 3.1 3.1 74.3 3.8 3.1 22.1 3.1 3.1 3.1 3.1 3.1 3.1 3.1 2.4 3.1 3.1 2.7 Other crops 0.0 1.6 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.0 54.7 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 2.3 0.0 0.0 3.2 Wool 6.9 0.2 6.8 11.0 11.4 0.0 0.3 7.5 4.9 9.6 2.6 10.8 6.8 9.0 3.0 7.8 0.4 7.8 4.7 0.3 Fishing 11.4 114.5 11.4 11.4 11.4 94.4 2.2 11.4 6.6 11.4 11.4 11.4 11.4 11.4 11.4 11.4 8.6 11.4 11.4 2.8 Vegetable oils 28.8 111.2 28.8 28.8 28.8 157.2 12.5 28.8 38.3 28.8 28.8 28.8 28.8 28.8 28.8 28.8 14.1 28.8 28.8 5.6 Other food 8.3 129.6 8.3 8.3 8.3 50.1 8.5 8.3 16.2 8.3 8.3 8.3 8.3 8.3 8.3 8.3 62.5 8.3 8.3 9.2 Beverages, tobacco 18.4 102.5 18.4 18.6 18.7 105.6 9.1 18.4 26.8 18.5 18.1 18.6 18.4 18.5 18.1 18.4 24.9 18.4 18.2 5.8 Overall weighted average Switzerland 3.1 United Kingdom 2,181 8.5 590 3.0 1,106 11.4 ,341 4.3 142 0.6 23 0.9 160 21.5 United States Weight (World production, billion $) 22 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition Table 7. Calculations of production-distorting agricultural subsidies for CDI and of Total Support Estimate of OECD, 2000–02 Australia Canada National currency figures A. Producer Support Estimate (PSE) 1,681 B. Market Price Support (MPS) 43 C. Payments based on output 50 D. Payments based on area 37 planted/animal numbers E. “Counter cyclical payments” 0 F. Payments based on historical 152 entitlements G. Payments based on input use 1,130 H. Payments based on input 0 constraints I. Payments based on overall 269 farming income J. Miscellaneous payments 0 K. General Services Support Estimate (GSSE) L. Research and development M. Agricultural schools N. Inspection services O. Infrastructure P. Marketing and promotion Q. Public stockholding R. Miscellaneous 1,032 678 0 88 236 10 0 21 EU Japan 6,533 100,266 3,098 56,820 358 4,016 766 27,364 5,619 5,068 175 0 N. ZeaSwitzer- United land Norway land States Total ($) 147 20,065 101 8,464 0 2,852 0 3,241 7,666 46,972 4,510 16,630 355 7,345 882 2,461 0 845 0 606 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1,269 584 8,527 506 0 7,998 3,812 259 117 44 0 4,350 670 336 115 7,264 1,917 903 0 0 2 488 0 2,244 57 –349 0 0 0 199 0 2,070 411 224 518 493 424 0 0 8,722 956 1,028 251 2,028 3,208 1,016 235 1,448 55 49 11 1105 26 46 155 212 121 6 59 25 0 0 1 1332 649 0 248 162 125 15 132 536 24,297 93 2,453 23 13 706 89 2,988 60 15,938 59 76 199 2137 S. Consumer Support Estimate –194 –3,218 –49,127 –6,930 –112 –8,455 –5,302 3,800 (CSE) T. Transfers to producers from –19 –3,097 –53,525 –5,067 –98 –9,575 –4,610 –16,627 consumers Other transfers from consumers 0 –120 –251 –1,872 –13 –342 –1,079 –1,808 U. Transfers to consumers from –175 0 3,835 6 0 595 237 22,235 taxpayers V. Excess feed cost 0 0 815 3 0 867 150 0 W. OECD Total Support Estimate (A+K+U) 2,538 8,603 112,823 X. Export subsidies (B+T) Y. Other direct trade-distorting subsidies (C+D+E+F/2+G+H) 24 1,293 1 2,053 1.83 1.53 Z. Exchange rate/$ Dollar figures AA. OECD Total Support Estimate (W/Z) AB. Export subsidies (X/Z) AC. Other trade-distorting subsidies (Y/Z) Total trade-distorting subsidies (AB+AC) 1,387 7,073 359 21,992 8,439 93,504 3,295 43,493 1 551 3 –1,111 44 11,113 –100 3 2,323 23,835 1.09 0.08 2.25 8.59 5,623 103,507 88,413 160 2,560 5,146 93,504 300,300 1.64 1.00 13 705 1 1,338 3,029 39,987 13 7,205 1 20 –129 1,293 –61 3 1,413 23,835 3,060 75,796 718 1,338 43,017 7,218 21 1,164 1,352 23,838 78,666 23 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition Table 8. Overview of estimation of ad valorem tariff-equivalent of subsidies Tariff Imports/ Imports/ Subsidy equiva- (produc- consumpTariff tion at tion at Import Agricultural Estimated rate (sub- lent of border farmgate world commodity trade-dis- sidies/ price equivalent prices) prices elastic- of subsiproduction torting sub- produc- meas3 1 1 1 2 dies (%) sidies ($) tion,%) ures (%) (%) (%) ($) ity 12.4 Australia 19,866 718 3.6 2.3 3.5 5.2 3.4 17.5 Austria 4,021 1,496 37.0 45.3 10.0 13.6 3.1 15.6 Belgium 4,156 992 24.0 45.3 10.0 13.6 3.1 7.7 Canada 20,516 1,338 6.5 36.0 27.8 51.3 1.8 14.4 Denmark 6,132 1,127 18.0 45.3 10.0 13.6 3.1 20.1 Finland 1,796 1,649 92.0 45.3 10.0 13.6 3.1 15.1 France 47,260 10,000 21.0 45.3 10.0 13.6 3.1 15.7 Germany 27,149 6,575 24.0 45.3 10.0 13.6 3.1 13.8 Greece 13,576 2,226 16.0 45.3 10.0 13.6 3.1 17.1 Ireland 4,571 1,528 33.0 45.3 10.0 13.6 3.1 12.2 Italy 43,146 5,278 12.0 45.3 10.0 13.6 3.1 5.2 Japan 116,443 7,218 6.2 118.8 15.9 25.8 2.7 12.0 Netherlands 13,876 1,646 12.0 45.3 10.0 13.6 3.1 2.1 New Zealand 6,331 21 0.3 3.1 4.7 15.5 3.0 16.5 Norway 2,062 1,164 56.4 198.1 38.4 60.9 1.4 13.9 Portugal 4,793 799 17.0 45.3 10.0 13.6 3.1 13.1 Spain 35,650 5,133 14.0 45.3 10.0 13.6 3.1 18.1 Sweden 2,102 919 44.0 45.3 10.0 13.6 3.1 11.8 Switzerland 4,460 1,352 30.3 137.3 43.6 58.1 1.5 15.2 United Kingdom 16,676 3,650 22.0 45.3 10.0 13.6 3.1 13.8 United States 195,753 23,8938 12.2 9.4 9.3 10.7 3.2 1 Assumed the same for all European Union members. 2 Computed as β = σD(1–φM), where β is the import price elasticity,σD is the elasticity of substitution in demand between domestic goods and imports, assumed to be 3.6, and φM is imports/consumption at world prices. See Cline (2004, ch. 3). 3 Computed as 1 τ = 1 + 1 + ϕ M (1 + t ) 1 + 1 s ( 1 ) β − 1, where ϕM is imports/(production at farmgate prices), t is the ad valorem tariff equivalent of border measures, and s is the subsidy rate. This is nearly equivalent to equation A10 of Cline (2004, ch. 3, appendix 3A–2), differing only in that the elasticity β enters here in a more theoretically correct way. Cline’s formula is equivalent to τ= 1 1 ( β 1 + ϕ M (1 + t ) 1 + 1 s ), which is the first term in a Taylor expansion of the above formula. 24 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition Table 9. Protection in ad valorem tariff equivalents, by sector (%) Agricultural commodities SubsiTariffs dies Total Australia 2.3 12.4 14.7 Austria 45.3 17.5 62.9 Belgium 45.3 15.6 61.0 Canada 36.0 7.7 43.8 Denmark 45.3 14.4 59.7 Finland 45.3 20.1 65.5 France 45.3 15.1 60.4 Germany 45.3 15.7 61.1 Greece 45.3 13.8 59.1 Ireland 45.3 17.1 62.5 Italy 45.3 12.2 57.5 Japan 118.8 5.2 124.1 Netherlands 45.3 12.0 57.3 New Zealand 3.1 2.1 5.2 Norway 198.1 16.5 214.9 Portugal 45.3 13.9 59.2 Spain 45.3 13.1 58.4 Sweden 45.3 18.1 63.5 Switzerland 137.3 11.8 149.3 United Kingdom 45.3 15.2 60.6 United States 9.4 13.8 23.2 Other Textiles Apparel agriculture Tariffs Quotas Total Tariffs Quotas Total Fuels Other 5.8 17.0 7.1 25.3 29.3 8.3 40.0 0.0 13.4 18.2 9.7 5.1 15.3 12.1 5.2 17.9 0.0 5.0 18.4 9.7 5.1 15.3 12.1 5.2 17.9 0.0 5.0 24.9 15.7 9.1 26.2 21.2 11.4 35.0 0.0 5.4 18.4 9.7 5.1 15.3 12.1 5.2 17.9 0.0 5.0 18.1 9.7 5.1 15.3 12.1 5.2 17.9 0.0 5.0 18.5 9.7 5.1 15.3 12.1 5.2 17.9 0.0 5.0 18.4 9.7 5.1 15.3 12.1 5.2 17.9 0.0 5.0 18.6 9.7 5.1 15.3 12.1 5.2 17.9 0.0 5.0 18.1 9.7 5.1 15.3 12.1 5.2 17.9 0.0 5.0 18.5 9.7 5.1 15.3 12.1 5.2 17.9 0.0 5.0 26.8 8.5 0.0 8.5 12.5 0.0 12.5 0.0 3.6 18.4 9.7 5.1 15.3 12.1 5.2 17.9 0.0 5.0 9.1 8.6 7.1 16.3 25.0 8.3 35.4 0.0 12.3 105.6 13.8 7.1 21.9 17.5 8.3 27.3 0.0 3.6 18.7 9.7 5.1 15.3 12.1 5.2 17.9 0.0 5.0 18.6 9.7 5.1 15.3 12.1 5.2 17.9 0.0 5.0 18.4 9.7 5.1 15.3 12.1 5.2 17.9 0.0 5.0 102.5 0.7 7.1 7.8 17.5 8.3 27.3 0.0 1.9 18.4 9.7 5.1 15.3 12.1 5.2 17.9 0.0 5.0 8.5 11.2 9.1 21.3 13.3 11.4 26.2 0.0 4.6 25 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition Table 10. Computation of Aggregate Measure of Protection (AMP) Portugal Norway New Zealand Netherlands Japan Italy Ireland Greece Germany France Finland Denmark Canada Belgium Austria Australia 58.4 59.2 214.9 5.2 57.3 124.1 57.5 62.5 59.1 61.1 60.4 65.5 59.7 43.8 61.0 62.9 14.7 18.4 18.6 18.7 105.6 9.1 18.4 26.8 18.5 18.1 18.6 18.4 18.5 18.1 18.4 24.9 18.4 18.2 5.8 7.8 15.3 15.3 15.3 21.9 16.3 15.3 8.5 15.3 15.3 15.3 15.3 15.3 15.3 15.3 26.2 15.3 15.3 25.3 17.9 27.3 17.9 17.9 17.9 27.3 35.4 17.9 12.5 17.9 17.9 17.9 17.9 17.9 17.9 17.9 35.0 17.9 17.9 40.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 5.0 1.9 5.0 5.0 5.0 3.6 12.3 5.0 3.6 5.0 5.0 5.0 5.0 5.0 5.0 5.0 5.4 5.0 5.0 13.4 5.1 5.3 5.1 5.1 5.1 4.8 3.5 5.1 5.0 5.1 5.1 5.1 5.1 5.1 5.1 5.1 3.7 5.1 5.1 1.5 5.4 6.3 5.4 5.4 5.4 8.9 4.7 5.4 8.0 5.4 5.4 5.4 5.4 5.4 5.4 5.4 4.5 5.4 5.4 4.0 2.7 1.7 2.7 2.7 2.7 1.2 3.5 2.7 1.5 2.7 2.7 2.7 2.7 2.7 2.7 2.7 2.4 2.7 2.7 3.3 10.3 9.9 10.3 10.3 10.3 13.8 9.0 10.3 8.8 10.3 10.3 10.3 10.3 10.3 10.3 10.3 7.2 10.3 10.3 6.4 14.7 7.6 14.7 14.7 14.7 4.4 17.5 14.7 28.1 14.7 14.7 14.7 14.7 14.7 14.7 14.7 8.4 14.7 14.7 14.9 AgriculAgriculOther Other tural tural com- agriculcom- agricul- Textiles Apparel Fuels modities ture Textiles Apparel Fuels Other modities ture 61.8 69.1 61.8 61.8 61.8 66.8 61.9 61.8 48.7 61.8 61.8 61.8 61.8 61.8 61.8 61.8 73.8 61.8 61.8 69.9 Other 9.8 22.2 10.0 9.7 9.8 32.0 12.1 9.6 13.0 9.7 9.9 9.8 9.9 9.8 10.1 9.8 10.2 9.9 10.0 13.4 Aggregate Measure of Protection (%) Shares of imports, 2000 (%)1 Spain 63.5 102.5 15.3 Protection (tariff-equivalents, %) Sweden 149.3 18.4 U.K. 4.6 2.2 3.5 1.2 11.1 11.7 70.3 7.4 Switzerland 60.6 United States 23.2 8.5 21.3 26.2 0.0 Assumed the same for all European Union members. 1 26 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition Table 11. Revealed openness, 2002 Australia Canada European Union Japan New Zealand Norway Switzerland United States Imports (billion $) A B C D Least developed All low and middle Weighted countries only income Total Total total Manufactures imports Manufactures imports (A+B+C+D) 0.05 0.09 12.69 17.99 30.82 0.16 0.40 24.68 32.11 57.35 6.85 11.72 263.11 401.28 682.95 0.29 1.55 86.46 144.40 232.70 0.01 0.02 2.22 3.13 5.37 0.10 0.12 4.51 5.99 10.71 0.06 0.10 6.38 8.38 14.92 4.82 9.37 371.66 468.31 854.15 GDP 411 716 8,545 3,980 58 189 268 10,400 Weighted imports/GDP (%) 7.5 8.0 8.0 5.8 9.2 5.7 5.6 8.2 Table 12. Computation of overall trade score Australia Austria Belgium Canada Denmark Finland France Germany Greece Ireland Italy Japan Netherlands New Zealand Norway Portugal Spain Sweden Switzerland United Kingdom United States Average Standard deviation Measured Revealed openness (25% of score) protection (75% of Transformed to Compos- Standardized score score) ite Raw value protection scale ----------------------- (%)----------------------4.4 13.4 7.5 13.1 13.3 5.8 10.0 8.0 10.1 10.0 5.8 9.9 8.0 10.1 9.9 5.7 10.2 8.0 10.0 10.1 5.8 9.8 8.0 10.1 9.9 5.7 10.1 8.0 10.1 10.1 5.8 9.8 8.0 10.1 9.9 5.8 9.9 8.0 10.1 9.9 5.8 9.8 8.0 10.1 9.8 5.8 9.9 8.0 10.1 10.0 5.9 9.7 8.0 10.1 9.8 3.4 13.0 5.8 23.2 15.5 5.9 9.6 8.0 10.1 9.7 5.9 12.1 9.2 2.5 9.7 –2.7 32.0 5.7 24.3 30.1 5.8 9.8 8.0 10.1 9.8 5.8 9.7 8.0 10.1 9.8 5.8 10.0 8.0 10.1 10.0 0.3 22.2 5.6 24.9 22.9 5.8 9.8 8.0 10.1 9.9 6.7 7.4 8.2 8.7 7.7 11.8 5.3 7.7 0.9 11.8 5.3 11.8 5.1 5.0 2.2 27 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition Investment Investment flows from abroad have long played a major role in economic development—from the 19th century in the United States to the 21st century in China. Source-country policies can affect capital flows, and given the magnitude of the capital flows—net foreign direct investment from DAC to non-DAC countries was $104 billion in 2002 (DAC 2004)—relatively small policy changes on the source side could make a significant difference for countries on the receiving side. But incorporating investment into the CDI is difficult for two reasons. First, not all investment is good for development, or at least is as good as should be. Prime examples include oil industry ventures in Nigeria and Angola, and foreign-financed factories with inhumane working conditions. Second, the role of rich-country policies in stimulating and guiding investment is subtle. In 2003, a major CDI investment indicator was net FDI in non-DAC countries as a share of source-country GDP. FDI, of course, is not a policy, but an outcome, and an outcome in which poor-country policies and private decisions figure much more than rich-country polices. FDI was nevertheless used for a lack of more direct measures of policy, and out of a belief that it was better to include an imperfect component than no component at all. It would still raise public awareness about the policy-investment-development link, and highlight gaps in current knowledge. For 2004, Theodore Moran (2004) has completely overhauled the investment component. Moran’s approach, adopted without modification into the CDI, dispenses with FDI and puts in its place a more qualitative survey of government policies—a checklist approach. Countries can gain or lose points based on the answers to 18 distinct questions. A perfect score would be 100. For example, countries get 20 points for having programs to insure nationals against political risks for investment in developing countries. But they lose 4 if they do not screen for and monitor environmental, labor, and human rights problems. Paraphrasing Moran (2004), the 18 questions fit into five categories, covering: 1) provision of quasi-official political risk insurance (with careful screening mechanisms regarding impact); 2) procedures to prevent double taxation of profits earned abroad—taxation, that is, in both source and receiving countries; 3) actions to prevent bribery and other corrupt practices abroad; 4) measures to support foreign investors moving to developing countries, including help for developing countries creating investment promotion agencies, assistance with identifying investment opportunities, and appropriate mediation to resolve investment disputes; but also factoring in whether countries advocate against receiving countries applying labor, environmental, or human rights standards to FDI; 28 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition 5) policies that affect portfolio flows, namely, restrictions on pension fund investment in developing countries and—working in the opposite direction—support developing countries designing securities institutions and regulations. The first four categories, worth a total of 80 points, pertain to foreign direct investment. The last, with 20 points, obviously relates to portfolio flows. (See Table 13 for the scoring system and Table 14 for the results.) The shift since 2003 in focus from outcome to policy transformed the results. It lifted Australia 18 spots, Germany 11, the United Kingdom 10, the United States and Italy 9, and Canada 8. On the inevitable flipside are Austria, Belgium, Spain, Sweden, and Switzerland. Spain, for instance, has been a major investor in its former colonies in the Americas, and so scored extremely high last year. Moran’s data suggest that Spain’s policy support for such investment is a bit below average (it scores 60, while the 2004 average is 66), with the historical linkage playing a much bigger role. (See Table 15, which shows investment ranks for 2003 and 2004. Because of the change in scaling system, it is not meaningful to directly compare scores from the two years.) Ireland stands out at the bottom end of the standings, coming in last place with only 36 points. Perhaps because until recently it had viewed itself as lagging economically, its policies are strongly oriented toward keeping capital at home. 29 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition Table 13. Investment component scoring system Factor Official provision of political risk insurance Member of multilateral insurance agencies? Official national insurance agency? Deduct if agency does not monitor environment/ labor/ human rights standards. Deduct if investors in some sectors are ineligible. Deduct if agency has inappropriate national economic interest tests. Deduct if agency extends coverage to inefficient import substitution projects. Deduct if agency restricts eligibility to firms majority-owned by nationals. Prevention of double taxation Avoids double taxation with a tax sparing agreement or foreign tax credit or bilateral investment treaties? Deduct if does not allow investors to enjoy developing country tax incentives o, rates, or exemptions. Prevention of corrupt practices OECD anti-bribery convention -- Phase 1 completion/Phase 1 implementation/Phase 2 completion? Participation in Extractive Industries Transparency Iinitiative workshop? Bribe Payers Index score quintile Other FDI facilitation measures Official assistance in resolving investment disputes with host countries? Official assistance in identifying investment opportunities? Official assistance to developing country export promotion agencies? Deduct if country advocated against labor, environmental or human rights standards Facilitating portfolio investment Official support for design of developing country securities institutions and regulations? No restrictions on pension fund investment in emerging markets? Maximum possible points Maximum addition or deduction 10 20 –4 –3 –3 –2 –2 20 –6 14 2 4 4 4 2 –5 6 14 100 30 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition Table 14. Summary of Investment Component Doesn't let investors enjoy developing country tax incentives? OECD convention -- participation level? Extractive Industries Transparency Initiative Conference participation? Bribe Payers Index Score Quintile Official assistance in resolving investment disputes? Help businesses identify investment opportunities? Help developing countries set up investment promotion agencies? Negative advocacy Official support for design of securities institutions and regulations? No restrictions on pension fund investment in emerging markets? Total 14 86 0 0 0 4 4 4 2 12 0 0 58 0 2 0 4 4 4 0 10 –6 0 57 0 0 0 4 0 3 2 12 –6 14 84 0 0 0 0 4 4 2 14 0 0 64 0 2 0 4 4 2 0 12 –6 0 68 0 2 0 4 0 2 0 14 0 0 62 0 0 0 0 4 2 2 14 –6 14 89 0 2 0 4 4 3 2 14 0 0 54 0 0 0 4 4 2 0 12 –6 14 36 0 0 0 0 0 2 0 10 0 14 71 0 0 0 4 0 1 2 12 0 0 61 0 0 –5 4 4 2 2 12 0 14 89 6 2 0 4 4 3 2 12 0 14 38 0 2 0 0 0 2 0 10 0 14 70 0 2 0 2 0 2 2 14 –6 14 75 0 2 0 4 0 2 0 12 0 0 60 0 2 0 4 4 2 0 10 –6 0 50 0 0 0 0 4 4 0 10 –6 14 62 0 0 0 4 4 4 0 10 –6 14 85 0 0 0 4 4 3 2 12 0 7 75 6 2 0 0 4 2 2 14 0 GerNeth New SwitJa- er- Zea- Nor- Port- Spai Swe- zerAus- Aus- Bel- Can- Den- Fin- Fran man Gree IreFactor tralia tria gium ada mark land ce ce land Italy pan lands land way ugal n den land U.K. U.S. y 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 5 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 Multilateral Insurance? Official national agency? 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 0 20 20 20 0 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 Agency monitor environment/ labor/ human rights? 0 –2 0 0 –4 0 0 –2 –2 0 0 0 0 0 –2 –2 0 0 –4 0 0 Investors in all sectors eligible? 0 –3 0 0 0 0 0 0 –3 0 –3 –3 0 0 0 –3 0 –3 –3 0 –3 No inappropriate national eco0 –3 0 0 0 0 0 0 –3 0 –3 –3 0 0 0 0 0 –3 –3 0 –3 nomic interest tests? Restrict extending coverage to inefficient import-substituting –2 –2 –2 –2 –2 0 –2 –2 –2 0 –2 –2 –2 0 –2 –2 –2 –2 –2 –2 –2 projects? International companies with a 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 –2 0 –2 0 0 0 0 –2 –2 –2 –2 –2 significant presence in this Avoids double taxation? 18 18 18 18 18 18 20 18 18 0 18 20 16 5 14 18 18 18 16 20 18 Political risk insurance Corrupt practices Double taxation Other FDI Portfolio 31 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition Table 15. Comparison of 2003 and 2004 CDI investment ranks Germany Netherlands Australia United Kingdom Canada Portugal United States Italy Norway Finland Denmark France Switzerland Japan Spain Austria Belgium Greece Sweden New Zealand Ireland 2003 rank 2004 rank 12 1 4 1 21 3 14 4 13 5 3 6 15 6 17 8 7 9 10 10 9 11 11 12 1 12 16 14 2 15 5 16 8 17 18 18 6 19 20 20 19 21 Migration Migration is one of the thornier topics covered in the index. Though it is widely agreed that the effects of migration and migration policy on development are great and could become much greater, they have not been as extensively studied as those of aid and trade polices. There is no widely accepted analytical framework from the perspective of development, and little empirical evidence. In addition, there are data problems, including lack of comprehensive information on remittances and illegal immigration, and a paucity of internationally comparable information on rich countries’ migration policies. The CDI migration component is built on the conviction that migration advances development in source countries because it “provides immigrants with access to labor markets and higher wages which, in turn, increase the potential for individual immigrants to remit money or goods to the sending country…and enables migrants to establish migrant networks, which encourage continuous and expanding economic relations between sending and receiving countries.” (Hamilton and Grieco, 2002) In addition, freer flows of people, like freer flows of goods, should contribute to global convergence in factor markets. The easier it is for a Vietnamese woman to get a job in Japan, the more Nike will have to pay her to keep her sewing clothes in its Vietnam factories. And emigration of workers that are unskilled (by rich-world standards) should increase the wages of those who do not leave by reducing labor supply. It should be said that while freer migration may directly benefit rich countries too, it can lower pay for nationals facing more intense competition 32 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition for their jobs. This is not a major consideration for the CDI, however, not because it doesn’t worry us, but because the purpose of the CDI is to focus on effects on developing countries. What happens when professionals leave—the so-called “brain drain”—is more complex. The exodus of doctors and nurses from Ghana and South Africa has cost those countries. However, sometimes professionals gain skills abroad and then return home: Returned Indian expatriates are playing a big role in the software and services boom in Bangalore. Even when professionals remain abroad, they often retain links with industry and research at home. All this argues at least for exploring how much rich countries discriminate in their immigration policies against lower-skill workers. For the 2004 CDI, the Elizabeth Grieco and Kimberly A. Hamilton of the Migration Policy Institution attempted to collect data from the 21 national governments on admissions by visa type, which might have allowed the CDI to make skills distinctions. (They also hoped to gather data on whether entrants have legal access to the labor market, and for how long.) But the task proved impossible. We hope that an international agency such as the OECD will eventually step in to collect such information and make it internationally comparable.33 Grieco and Hamilton’s substantial data collection effort still led to major improvements to the CDI migration component. In their paper (Grieco and Hamilton 2004), they proposed taking a weighted average of six indicators: 1) gross non-DAC immigrant inflow/receiving-country population; 2) gross non-DAC immigrant inflow/total immigrant inflow; 3) net migrant inflow over five years/receiving-country population—this includes inflows from DAC countries too for lack of resolution in the data; 4) the difference between the unemployment rates for natives and immigrants, which is supposed to reflect barriers to immigrants entering the work force; 5) the share of foreign students that are from non-DAC countries; and 6) an index from the United Nations High Commissioner for Refugees (UNHCR) measuring countries’ contributions to aiding refugees and asylum seekers. The CDI adopts these recommendations, but with some substantial changes. Out of concern about conceptual overlap between the first three, it drops one—the first. The remaining two it combines multiplicatively rather than additively. This seems to better capture the relationship between them. As a thought experiment, if a country with a population of one million had a net and gross immigration of 10 people, nine of whom were from developing countries, it would score extremely well on indicator 2 because of the high non-DAC ratio (0.9) and extremely poorly on 3 because its total flow/population would be essentially zero (0.00001). If the two indicators were put on a standard scale and averaged, the country itself would appear about average as far these two indicators went. If they were multiplied, then the resulting score would be 33 The IMF’s Balance of Payments Statistics Yearbook reports inflows and outflows of worker remittances by country and quarter. But the data are missing for many countries. And the inflow numbers are not disaggregated by source, while the outflow numbers are not disaggregated by destination, making it hard to measure flows from individual rich counties to developing countries as a group. 33 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition essentially zero too—as seems appropriate given that only nine non-DAC immigrants entered a country of a million people. The product of indicators 2 and 3—net inflow of migrants × DAC share of gross inflow—can be seen as a rough estimate of the net inflow of non-DAC migrants. The CDI also leaves out indicator 4, the unemployment rate difference. Higher unemployment among immigrants might actually reflect the greater attractiveness of a country’s labor market to foreign workers. “Unemployment,” after all, is the state of not having a job, yet being in the job market. If there are many immigrants “in the market for a job,” this could reflect policy barriers to employment, which the CDI ought to penalize, or policies that facilitate entrance to the market, which the CDI ought to reward. Because of this ambiguity in sign, it seems appropriate to leave this indicator aside until there is more evidence to validate it one way or the other. The CDI adopts Grieco and Hamilton’s indicator 5, the share of the foreign student population that is non-DAC, without change. This deserves comment. Indicator 5 could mislead in precisely the same way as 2: a country could admit almost no non-DAC students, yet have a high non-DAC ratio if it admits even fewer DAC students. Japan is a case in point. Its 2001 non-DAC student body was 60,687, which was 95% percent of its total foreign student body, the highest in the sample. But that was only 0.05% of Japan’s population, which is barely above the 0.03% of Italy and Portugal, which are lowest on this measure, and far behind Australia’s 0.47%. The essential question is, which indicator is more likely to capture differences in policy—non-DAC students/total foreign students or non-DAC students/total population? For students much more than unskilled workers, language is likely to be a major non-policy barrier, and probably does much to explain Japan’s low foreign student numbers across the board. It seems more meaningful, then, to abstract from the predominantly non-policy factors that reduce the foreign student body altogether, by taking foreign student population as the denominator. Finally, as in 2003, the CDI uses a simplified version of the UNHCR index. The CGD version is computed as total of three quantities, all taken over receiving-country GDP: the number of refugees hosted domestically; the number of other people “of concern” to UNHCR, such as those internally displaced; and the number of asylum applications taken.34 Accepting the considered judgment of Grieco and Hamilton (2004), the student population measure gets 15% weight and the modified UNHCR index gets 20%. The remaining 65% goes to the product of indicators 2 and 3. Before combining these three measures, each is rescaled to have a sample average of 5.0. Table 16 shows the calculations. As with investment, overhauling the migration component rearranged the standings. Canada, the United States, and Australia, all historically nations of immigrants, have shot into the top three spots, displacing New Zealand, Switzerland, and Germany. Switzerland in particular admits many people from developing countries—but almost as many are leaving. (Geneva diplomats and their nannies?) So it did well in 2003 when 90% of the migration score was based on gross immigration from developing countries, but loses from the shift to net migration in 2004. 34 The UNHCR ranks all countries—not just rich countries—on the three indicators, averages the ranks, then reorders the countries and assigns final ranks. 34 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition Table 16. Summary of migration component Refugee popu1 lation + asylum applications Approximate net inflow of non-DAC Non-DAC stuimmigrants dents As % of Net migrant foreign StanNon-DAC inflow/1000 Per Stanshare of population, studard- billion $ dardStangross inized PPP ized 1995– Prod dardized dents, 2 3 flow (%) uct score 2001 score GDP score Overall 2000 8.8 Australia 66 25.64 16.9 11.3 79 6.3 135.5 2.7 2.9 Austria 75 2.85 2.1 1.4 48 3.9 356.1 7.1 2.6 Belgium 48 6.08 2.9 1.9 47 3.8 199.0 3.9 11.2 Canada 92 23.86 22.0 14.6 58 4.7 246.4 4.9 6.1 Denmark 61 12.68 7.7 5.1 67 5.4 494.8 9.8 2.6 Finland 78 3.70 2.9 1.9 69 5.6 118.0 2.3 2.7 France 83 3.31 2.8 1.8 78 6.3 142.7 2.8 6.1 Germany 66 11.29 7.4 4.9 73 5.9 516.8 10.2 6.2 Greece 69 16.28 11.3 7.5 94 7.6 52.8 1.0 5.8 Ireland 44 24.27 10.6 7.1 26 2.1 228.7 4.5 3.6 Italy 93 7.03 6.5 4.3 59 4.8 10.7 0.2 1.9 Japan 81 2.22 1.8 1.2 95 7.7 1.1 0.0 5.9 Netherlands 74 10.25 7.6 5.0 49 4.0 511.8 10.1 5.0 New Zealand 78 10.61 8.3 5.5 81 6.6 109.4 2.2 4.9 Norway 58 10.21 5.9 3.9 57 4.6 414.1 8.2 2.8 Portugal 66 6.50 4.3 2.8 77 6.2 3.9 0.1 2.3 Spain 86 4.59 4.0 2.6 41 3.3 15.4 0.3 5.1 Sweden 67 5.06 3.4 2.3 47 3.8 775.3 15.4 3.6 Switzerland 50 3.06 1.5 1.0 34 2.7 644.7 12.8 4.4 United Kingdom 88 7.81 6.9 4.6 45 3.6 221.0 4.4 10.5 United States 93 22.89 21.3 14.1 77 6.2 99.9 2.0 5.0 Average 7.5 5.0 0.6 5.0 252.3 5.0 Weight 65% 15% 20% 1 2 ”People of concern” to the U.N. High Commissioner for Refugees. Data for most recent 3 year available. Includes immigrants from other DAC countries. 35 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition Table 17. Comparison of 2003 and 2004 CDI migration ranks Canada United States Australia Greece Germany Denmark Netherlands Ireland Sweden New Zealand Norway United Kingdom Switzerland Italy Austria Portugal France Belgium Finland Spain Japan 2003 rank 2004 rank 5 1 14 2 12 3 16 4 3 5 10 6 8 7 9 8 11 9 2 10 6 11 13 12 1 13 19 14 4 15 20 16 21 17 7 18 18 19 15 20 17 21 Environment The environmental realm offers a wealth of potential indicators, but ones that are expressed in various units. Considerations run from treaty ratifications to dollar amounts of subsidies to rates of pollution. The approach I take in the environment component is therefore to organize indicators hierarchically—with groups and subgroups and sub-subgroups—put each indicator on a standard mean-5 scale, and take weighted averages for input into the next level up. For example, the climate stability subcomponent is a weighted average of greenhouse gas emissions per capita and taxes as a share of gasoline prices. That in turn feeds into the depletion of share commons component. In this component, as in the investment and migration components, weighting is often unequal. At top level, the 2004 environment component is based on two components: depletion of shared commons (67% weight) and contributions to international efforts—governmental cooperation (33%). Thus, it is divided between environmental impacts of rich-countries’ own activities on poorer countries, and rich countries’ efforts to help poorer achieve sustainable development. It takes the position that rich countries’ chief responsibility in this domain is to put their own houses in order, as it were, because their use of shared environmental resources is vastly out of proportion to their populations, and because they can set an example for the developing world of clean, efficient commerce. Following is an outline of the component’s construction, with some commentary. Roodman (2004b) contains more detail. Percentages indicate each variable’s weight at the next level up: 36 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition 1) Depletion of shared commons (67%) a) Climate stability (67%) i) Greenhouse gas emissions per capita (75%). The risks of climate change bear particularly on developing countries in part because they have less capacity to adapt. Climate change could affect agriculture and aid in the spread of diseases such as malaria and cholera. (Gross 2002) Population rather than GDP is the denominator in order to avoid sending the odd message that the richer a country is, the more acceptable it is for it to harm shared resources. Emissions, of course, are not a policy but an outcome. But policies ranging from land use planning to utility regulation do affect emissions. Unfortunately, at this point, we lack good, comprehensive measures of greenhouse gas–relevant policies. The one exception—an indicator with available data and great relevance—appears next. ii) Taxes as a share of gasoline prices (25%). This is new for 2004. Gasoline taxes are indicative of motor fuel taxes in general (the other major fuel being diesel). And there is a strong negative correlation across the sample of 21 countries between motor fuel taxes and motor fuel use. (Roodman 2004b) Road transportation accounted for 23% of OECD carbon emissions from fossil fuel burning in 2001 (OECD 2003, p. II.93), thus about 20% of total greenhouse gas emissions. Considering that this measure has the virtue of capturing policy rather than outcome, a 25% weight seems appropriate. b) Ozone layer—consumption per capita of ozone-depleting substances (17%). The Montreal Protocol is phasing down consumption of many chemicals, but ozone-depleting chemicals are still being used in rich countries. c) Marine fisheries—fishing subsidies per capita (17%). Rich country-fleets are contributing to overfishing in many international fisheries reducing the available resource for developing countries. 2) Contributions to international efforts—governmental cooperation (33%) a) Participation in multilateral environmental institutions (50%). One point each for ratification of: i) Kyoto Protocol on climate change. Finalized in 1997, this is the most important international effort to date to prevent climate change. It set important precedents by setting emissions targets for industrial countries, and opening the way for international trading in emissions rights. ii) Beijing Amendment to the Montreal Protocol on ozone-depleting substances. The international community has adopted a series of amendments strengthening the Montreal Protocol on Substances that Deplete the Ozone Layer. The Beijing Amendment is the latest. Countries that have ratified it ratified all earlier amendments. 37 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition iii) Convention on Biological Diversity. This is one of the major contributions to international law of the 1992 “Earth Summit” in Rio de Janeiro, and a first step toward international cooperation to protect biodiversity. b) Financial contributions to such international environmental institutions (50%) i) Contributions to GEF’s third replenishment (50%). The Global Environment Facility, housed at the World Bank, is a conduit for grant funding for projects in developing countries with global environmental benefits, in areas relating to biodiversity loss, climate change, degradation of international waters, ozone depletion, land degradation, and persistent organic pollutants. The measure used is countries’ contributions to its third funding cycle, or “replenishment,” which began in 2002. This is divided by donor GDP. ii) Contributions to the multilateral fund under the Montreal Protocol, as a share of GDP (50%). The multilateral fund is meant to help developing countries phase out consumption of ozone-depleting substances. The measure is total 2001 and 2002 contributions as a share of GDP. It is worth noting that 44% of the component’s weight goes to outcomes measures. However, consumption of ozone-depleting substances accounts for 11% of this share, and it is now strongly determined by policy. On balance, it is fair to say that one-third of the component is based on an outcome measure (greenhouse gas emissions) with clear non-policy elements. Table 18 shows the values of all indicators in the environment component. All of these indicators are eventually transformed onto the standard mean-5 scale as they are combined with each other, but for clarity standardized scores are not shown. Table 19 does show the full calculations at the top level of the hierarchy. The pattern of results is similar to last year’s. Three large and relatively sparsely populated countries, Australia, Canada and the United States do poorly overall, largely because of their high greenhouse gas emissions, the most heavily weighted indicator. Switzerland retains its top spot because of low emissions. 38 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition Table 18. Indicators used in environment component Greenhouse gas emissions/capita, 2002 (tons of CO2 equivalent) Ozone-depleting substances Share of consumptaxes in tion/capita, premium 1999 Fishing subunleaded (ozonegasoline depleting- sides/ GEF conprice, potential– person, tributions/ 1 2002 (%) grams) 1997 ($) GDP (%) Montreal Protocol contributions/GDP Kyoto (%) Protocol Australia 28.3 51.9 44.1 1.8 0.0031 0.0012 Austria 10.7 64.1 53.3 0.0 0.0037 0.0017 Belgium Canada 14.7 23.8 69.2 40.0 53.3 29.4 0.3 25.6 0.0053 0.0043 0.0016 0.0007 Denmark Finland 12.9 15.5 69.7 70.0 53.3 53.3 11.5 4.8 0.0061 0.0000 0.0014 0.0015 France Germany 9.5 12.1 73.7 73.4 53.3 53.3 1.9 0.6 0.0036 0.0039 0.0000 0.0011 Greece Ireland 13.3 18.3 55.5 64.2 53.3 53.3 3.7 25.3 0.0014 0.0016 0.0005 0.0007 Italy Japan 9.6 10.9 68.4 53.7 53.3 54.0 1.1 23.3 0.0000 0.0026 0.0013 0.0016 Netherlands New Zealand 14.1 21.0 70.9 46.3 53.3 18.6 1.9 10.7 0.0000 0.0037 0.0015 0.0015 Norway Portugal 12.4 9.3 70.0 68.9 27.4 53.3 36.4 3.8 0.0049 0.0015 0.0012 0.0010 Spain Sweden 10.2 8.0 62.4 69.6 53.3 53.3 4.3 4.9 0.0000 0.0000 0.0015 0.0014 Switzerland U.K. 7.5 11.0 64.3 77.5 4.9 53.3 0.0 1.7 0.0074 0.0035 0.0016 0.0002 United States 25.1 24.8 92.2 1 For 95 RON (Research Octane Number) unleaded. 3.2 0.0011 0.0006 Ratifications Beijing Amend- Convention on ment to Montreal Biological Protocol Diversity 39 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition Table 19. Summary of environment component Depletion of Contributions to shared commons international efforts Australia 3.1 3.8 Austria 6.4 5.5 Belgium 5.7 6.2 Canada 1.5 5.7 Denmark 4.9 7.3 Finland 5.1 4.6 France 6.5 4.6 Germany 6.2 5.9 Greece 5.4 3.1 Ireland 2.4 3.5 Italy 6.5 3.4 Japan 3.8 5.9 Netherlands 5.7 4.6 New Zealand 3.8 6.4 Norway 2.8 6.6 Portugal 6.3 3.7 Spain 6.0 4.6 Sweden 6.4 4.5 Switzerland 7.8 8.1 United Kingdom 6.3 4.8 United States 2.3 2.1 Average Weight 5.0 5.0 67% 33% Overall score 3.3 6.1 5.9 2.9 5.7 5.0 5.9 6.1 4.7 2.8 5.5 4.5 5.3 4.7 4.0 5.4 5.5 5.8 7.9 5.8 2.3 5.0 Security Security—internal stability and freedom from fear of external attack—is a prerequisite for development. Sometimes a nation’s security is enhanced by the actions of other nations. So security should be in the CDI. But as recent events have made obvious, one person’s liberation is another’s destructive intervention, so choosing what to count and what to reward is inherently controversial. The 2003 CDI restricted itself to contributions to international peacekeeping, in part for reasons of data availability. The 2004 version, done again under the guidance of Michael O’Hanlon, and with substantial new data collection (O’Hanlon and de Albuquerque 2003), expands the scope to forcible humanitarian inventions. Examples include the Australian-led intervention in East Timor in 1999 to halt Indonesian repression after the territory had voted for independence. The component also expands the time frame considered, from two years to ten.35 The rationale for this long period is that total government contributions to such operations is a particularly volatile variable—Kosovo’s and East Timor’s and Rwanda’s do not come along that often. A decade of history gives more insight than two years into a government’s current capacity and willingness to intervene. 35 After O’Hanlon and de Albuquerque’s wrote their report, which covers five years, we expanded the data set to ten. 40 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition Because of the inherent controversy in choosing which rich-country interventions to reward, it seems essential for validity, in considering the universe of interventions over the last decade, to apply either a weighting system in counting interventions—analogous to the aid component’s weighting based on recipient poverty and governance—or a filter, which is actually an extreme form of weighting. The CDI follows O’Hanlon’s advice for a filter: it only counts operations that have been endorsed by an international body such as the U.N. Security Council, NATO, or the African Union.36 To be precise, the 2004 edition security component, counts five costs, all taken as a share of rich-country GDP: 1) Dollar contributions to the U.N. peacekeeping budget. These are averaged over 1997– 2002. Data were not available for 1992–96. 2) The cost of maintaining capacity for contributing personnel to U.N.-run peacekeeping operations. To estimate this, a country’s peak personnel contribution to such operations during 1993–2002 as a share of its standing military forces is computed. This percentage is then applied to its military budget for the year. 3) The cost of deploying personnel in U.N.-run peacekeeping operations. This is estimated at $9,000/person/month. (The full cost is estimated at $10,000, but the U.N. reimburses contributing countries at the rate of about $1,000/person/month.) This too is averaged over 1993–2002. 4) The cost of maintaining capacity for contributing personnel to peacekeeping and forcible humanitarian operations that are not U.N.-run but receive international approval. This is calculated in the same way as item 2. (Table 20 lists operations counted.) 5) The cost of deploying personnel in such non-U.N. operations—calculated the same way as item 3, except using $10,000/person/month. Two more aspects of the methodology need to be explained. First, in a departure from O’Hanlon and de Albuquerque, all the tabulations incorporate a discount rate of 7%/annum, equivalent to 50%/decade, on the grounds that a recent contribution is substantially more indicative of present policy stance than an old one. Thus the averages described above are weighted averages, with each year getting 7% less weight than the next. And the peaks are discounted too. Absent a time discount, we would be faced next year with the choice of either dropping 1993 data as we shifted the time frame to 1994–2003, which could introduce unrealistic discontinuities; or expanding the time frame, to 1993–2003, a choice that, if perpetuated for many years, would create absurdities as ancient events received as much weight as current. The discounting will allow us to formally expand the time frame while smoothly phasing out old data. Second, 2003 data are incomplete and so excluded—a fact of huge importance in light of the U.S.-led invasion of Iraq. That intervention will probably never be rewarded in the CDI pre36 The component excludes a pair of operations that technically make it through the filter: the U.S. and French peacekeeping interventions in Rwanda immediately after the genocide and revolution in 1994. These interventions were approved by the U.N. Security Council, but the overall behavior of rich countries with respect to Rwanda during the genocide was totally contrary to the spirit of this component. 41 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition cisely because it lacked an international imprimatur. However, on October 16, 2003, the U.N. Security Council did give its mandate to the postwar multinational military presence in Iraq. Unless there are major changes in methodology, or some exception is made, this will dramatically increase the U.S. score in future years.37,38 Table 21 has the 2004 security results. Once again, major changes in method caused major changes in scoring. (See Table 22.) Australia and the United Kingdom shot up to nearly tie Norway for first place—Australia on the strength of its intervention in East Timor, the U.K. because of interventions in the former Yugoslavia and Sierra Leone, among others. The United States climbed from 18th to 11th—perhaps still a surprisingly low ranking given its major interventions in Kosovo, Haiti, and Somalia in the last decade. But perhaps for the simple reason that Yugoslavia was at their doorstep, many European nations contributed troops at levels that, adjusting for size, rivaled the United States. There is some continuity with last year’s results. Norway took the top spot this year thanks to high contributions to both U.N.- and non–U.N.-run operations; it held second place last year. Switzerland and Japan continued to occupy the bottom spots. Japan has a strong constitutional and cultural commitment to peaceful conflict resolution. And Switzerland has an ancient tradition of neutrality. It only joined the United Nations in 2002. Table 20. Non–U.N.-run military operations counted in CDI security component. Where Afghanistan (postwar) Albania (aid for Kosovo refugees) 1 Bosnia When 2001–present 1999 1996–present Major participants France, Germany, Spain, U.K. Italy Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Italy, Netherlands, Norway, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, U.K., U.S. Bougainville, Papua New Guinea 1998–present Australia, New Zealand Côte d’Ivoire 2002–present France East Timor 1999–2000 Australia Egypt and Israel 1982–present Spain, U.S. Haiti 1994–95 U.S. Kosovo (air war) 1999 Belgium, France, Germany, Italy, Netherlands, U.K., U.S. 2 Kosovo (postwar) 1999–present Germany, Italy, Netherlands, Norway, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, U.K. Iraq (Northern no-fly zone) 1997–2003 U.K., U.S. Sierra Leone 2000 U.K. Somalia 1992–93 U.S. 1 Includes implementation force (IFOR), stabilization force (SFOR), and operation Deliberate Forge. 2 Includes operation Joint Guardian and Kosovo Force (KFOR). 37 O’Hanlon has argued for excluding all military and security operations in Iraq on the grounds that they are motivated primarily by national security rather than development interests. 38 The full impact would be felt in 2006, when 2004 data were included. 2004 will be the first year during which the U.S. troop presence will be under U.N. mandate for a full 12 months. 42 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition Table 21. Summary of security component—contributions as a share of GDP (%) U.N.-run peacekeeping operations and Non–U.N.-run PKO and humanitarian interventions humanitarian interventions Cost of Cost of Contributions maintaining maintaining to U.N. personnel peacekeeping personnel Cost of using Cost of using capacity personnel capacity personnel budget Australia 0.008 0.054 0.019 0.012 0.174 Austria 0.009 0.014 0.039 0.017 0.014 Belgium 0.009 0.013 0.018 0.038 0.040 Canada 0.007 0.030 0.017 0.023 0.049 Denmark 0.008 0.048 0.025 0.051 0.076 Finland 0.008 0.033 0.067 0.044 0.046 France 0.011 0.027 0.014 0.041 0.071 Germany 0.010 0.002 0.002 0.027 0.044 Greece 0.007 0.001 0.003 0.075 0.031 Ireland 0.005 0.045 0.094 0.008 0.012 Italy 0.009 0.002 0.001 0.038 0.056 Japan 0.009 0.003 0.000 0.000 0.000 Netherlands 0.008 0.030 0.015 0.051 0.084 New Zealand 0.008 0.096 0.058 0.013 0.022 Norway 0.007 0.080 0.046 0.054 0.086 Portugal 0.007 0.035 0.053 0.040 0.020 Spain 0.008 0.001 0.002 0.027 0.021 Sweden 0.009 0.029 0.020 0.027 0.048 Switzerland 0.000 0.003 0.001 0.003 0.013 U.K. 0.009 0.035 0.012 0.049 0.165 United States 0.006 0.004 0.001 0.018 0.114 Total 0.266 0.093 0.119 0.127 0.209 0.198 0.165 0.085 0.118 0.164 0.106 0.012 0.189 0.198 0.274 0.155 0.059 0.132 0.020 0.270 0.144 43 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition Table 22. Comparison of 2003 and 2004 CDI security/peacekeeping ranks Norway United Kingdom Australia Denmark Finland New Zealand Netherlands France Ireland Portugal United States Sweden Canada Belgium Greece Italy Austria Germany Spain Switzerland Japan 2003 rank 2 10 15 3 13 4 11 7 9 5 18 19 17 11 1 6 16 8 13 21 20 2004 rank 1 2 3 4 5 5 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 14 16 17 18 19 20 21 Technology Technology is an essential factor in development. Innovations in medicine, communications, agriculture, and energy meet societal needs, improve quality of life, increase productivity, and facilitate industrialization in poorer countries. Taking the very long view, a fundamental reason that China’s economy can grow at rates of 7% or more for many years is because the country is taking up innovations developed elsewhere over the last century.39 Vaccines and antibiotics led to major gains in life expectancy in Latin America and East Asia in the 20th century, achieving in four decades improvements that took Europe almost 150 years. Cell phones have revolutionized communications in poor countries such as Nigeria. The Internet also helps developing countries access and disseminate information, form civil society movements, and do commerce with rich-world economies. Thus people in developing countries benefit from technological advances as both producers and consumers. Recognizing the link between technology and development, the second edition of the index introduces a new technology component, developed by Bannon and Roodman (2004). Technology policy can be compartmentalized into two areas: technology generation and technology diffusion. We found it much more difficult to measure policies relating to diffusion, and so the inaugural edition of the CDI technology component focuses on technology generation. In particular, the index does not measure how rich countries limit the diffusion of technology, 39 I thank Steven Knack for making the this point forcefully. 44 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition such as through intellectual property rights (IPR) protection. The current system of IPR protection, governed primarily by the WTO’s TRIPS agreement, restricts generic imitations of patented products in even the poorest countries. This keeps prices of new products high, reducing access for poor countries and limiting their ability to imitate (and learn through imitation). The CDI doesn’t score rich countries on their IPR approach because rich countries’ policies seem largely indistinguishable from each other—all have signed on to TRIPS. Moreover, it is quite possible that the TRIPS regime helps some developing countries on balance while hurting others. The very poorest countries, which could consume technological products such as HIV drugs, but are not in a position to produce them, are probably hurt by strong IPR. But more industrialized developing countries may benefit from strong IPR, since it attracts FDI and creates incentives for innovation—innovation that could be particularly suited for developing countries needs. As a result, the 2004 technology component simply tabulates government financial support for research and development, counting both direct government funding of R&D, and the value of tax incentives for it. The component discounts government funding for defense R&D by 50%. While some military innovations have useful civilian spin-offs (including the Internet), much military R&D does more to improve the destructive capacity of rich countries than the productive capacity of poor ones. The component does not reward countries for supporting research that targets the immediate needs of the poorest countries, such as the development of a malaria vaccine. This is primarily due to data constraints: detailed breakdowns of R&D expenditure are simply not available for the 21 CDI countries. More broadly, it can often be difficult to assess a priori which innovations will be adaptable and most advantageous to the poor in the long term. The calculations are therefore straightforward. The OECD publishes a variant of the standard “B-index” that measures the rate of tax subsidization for business expenditure on R&D. We use the simple average of the rates for small and large companies. On the OECD variant, 1 indicates full subsidization, 0 indicates no subsidization or taxation, and negative values indicate taxation. The benchmark is full expensing. That is, a 0 means that the tax code treats R&D as an ordinary expense, allowing it to be fully deducted from taxable corporate income in the year the expenditure is made. If governments do not allow immediate full deduction, this is considered taxation. Tax treatment more favorable than simple expensing is a subsidy. This tax or subsidy rate is multiplied by a country’s total business enterprise expenditure on R&D (BERD) to generate an estimate of government tax expenditures on R&D. To this is added direct government spending on R&D, whether performed by public agencies or by private parties on contract, with military R&D discounted by half. The total is taken over GDP. (See Table 23.) Overall, Austria scores tops because of high direct expenditure on R&D. The United States would score first but much of its R&D is defense-related; the defense R&D discount pulls it down to ninth. 45 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition Table 23. Calculation of technology scores A B C D E Tax subsidy Direct rate for R&D, manufacturers Business Total Of Tax government R&D (average expenditure expenditure which: government on R&D/ on R&D/ GDP expenditure/ military support/GDP small/large 1 1 (%) (%) (%) GDP (%) companies) GDP (%) A×B Formula: C+D×(1–E/2) Australia 19.9 0.78 0.16 0.71 7.3 0.84 Austria 11.7 1.13 0.13 0.78 0.0 0.91 Belgium –0.8 1.60 -0.01 0.46 0.4 0.45 Canada 24.8 1.10 0.27 0.61 4.8 0.87 Denmark –0.9 1.33 -0.01 0.67 1.2 0.65 Finland –1.0 2.43 -0.02 0.87 2.9 0.83 France 6.1 1.41 0.09 0.82 24.3 0.81 Germany –2.5 1.75 -0.04 0.80 6.7 0.73 Greece –1.5 0.20 0.00 0.33 0.9 0.33 Ireland 0.0 0.80 0.00 0.26 0.0 0.26 Italy 20.9 0.56 0.12 0.51 4.0 0.62 Japan 6.5 2.26 0.15 0.57 4.1 0.71 Netherlands 5.0 1.10 0.05 0.68 1.9 0.73 New Zealand –2.3 0.43 -0.01 0.55 0.7 0.54 Norway 10.7 0.96 0.10 0.64 6.9 0.72 Portugal 33.5 0.27 0.09 0.51 2.0 0.60 Spain 44.1 0.50 0.22 0.38 37.3 0.53 Sweden –1.5 3.31 -0.05 0.90 22.2 0.75 Switzerland –1.0 1.95 -0.02 0.61 0.7 0.59 United Kingdom 10.1 1.28 0.13 0.57 30.5 0.61 United States 6.6 2.00 0.13 0.82 55.1 0.73 1 A 0 indicates that R&D spending can be fully deducted like other business expenditures. Positive values indicate active subsidization relative to this benchmark. Negative values indicate businesses cannot fully deduct in the year of expenditure. III. Overall results As explained in section I, the overall scores from each of the seven components are rescaled to have a sample average of five—and then averaged across components to yield final scores. Table 24 shows the final results. On the overall 2004 Commitment to Development Index, most of the Nordics and the Netherlands do well, buoyed by large aid flows, high contributions to security, and lower pollution rates. The exception is Norway, pulled down by huge agricultural tariffs. Japan comes in last because of barriers to exports and workers from developing countries, relatively low net concessional aid transfers, and low contributions to internationally approved security interventions. The final column of Table 24 shows some continuity with 2003, but also some major changes in standing. The Netherlands continues to hold first place (now in a tie with former number-two Denmark) and Japan remains in 21st. Meanwhile, Australia, Canada, and the United States have shot up about a dozen places, while New Zealand, Portugal, Spain, and Switzerland have sunk about as much. 46 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition Since one purpose of the CDI is to track policy change over time, it is important to investigate the extent to which changes in measurement, as opposed to changes in what is measured, are responsible for the substantial rearrangement since 2003. The revisions since last year can be thought of in four steps: switching to a new scaling system for the final scores on each component (so scores have a mean of 5 rather than a maximum of 9)40; making numerous changes to the methodology of the six original components, but still applying it to the 2003 database41,42; adding the technology component (applying it to the 2003 database); and, finally, updating to the 2004 dataset. Table 25 shows how the scores changed during each step, on each component and overall. At the bottom of Table 25 are two measures of how different the scores after each step are from the final 2004 scores. The first measure is the root-mean-square difference, taken over the 21 countries. The second is the correlation. Because of the change in scaling system, it is not meaningful to expect the final scores for the two years to match. The 2004 scores have an average of 5, by decree, where the 2003 scores do not. But one could expect them to covary, making correlation the better comparison across that methodological divide. But once scores are scaled the same way, starting with step B, the RMS difference becomes more meaningful. The bottom right of Table 25 makes clear that revisions to the original six components largely explain the changes in standing since 2003. The correlation with the final 2004 scores rises slightly after rescaling, from 0.27 to 0.29, then jumps to 0.96 after incorporating the revisions in methodology. Adding in technology raises the correlation to 0.99. Switching to 2004 data completes the journey. The RMS numbers tell the same story. To be more concrete, Australia, Canada, and the United States clearly benefited from the shift in the migration component from gross to net, as well as the shift from monitoring investment flows to investment policies. Australia especially was helped by the expansion of the security component, which now takes cognizance of the country’s 1999 intervention in East Timor. The same reasons lie behind the declines of New Zealand, Portugal, Spain, and Switzerland. Portugal and Spain, for instance, have been major direct investors in their former colonies in the Americas. They scored high on the 2003 investment component that emphasized FDI. But Moran’s data suggest that their policy support for such investment is about average. Table 26 distills a few numbers from the foregoing, showing what policy change the new methodology detects between 2003 and 2004. It shows the standings for 2004, and what they would have been had the new methodology been applied last year—steps C and D in Table 25. The main source of change is the aid component, specifically the raw quantity of aid given. Most donors increased concessional disbursements as a share of GDP between 2001 and 2002, the years on which the 2003 and 2004 aid components are based. France, the country that climbs the most in this table, increased its DAC-measured net ODA from 0.32% to 0.38% of GDP, a 19% 40 For the “bad” components trade and environment, scores were first scaled between –9 and 0; then 10 was added to them. 41 In transforming indicators onto the standard “mean-5” scale, 2004 scale factors were still used in order to allow valid comparisons between 2003 and 2004 results. Thus standardized scores often do not average precisely 5.0. 42 Not all of the underlying data could be “downdated” to 2003 in doing this back-calculation. For example, the most important data for the trade component, from the GTAP database, was for 1996–97 in both editions of the CDI. The investment component was taken to be identical both years. The net migration rate was still estimated for 1995– 2000, not 1995–1999. Security scores were computed for the nine years in 1993–2001 rather than the more ideal 1992–2001. 47 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition rise. The broad rise in aid giving may reflect some combination of pledges made at the Monterrey Financing for Development conference in the spring of 2001, and the altered geopolitics after the attacks of September 11. Another important question about the results is how sensitive they are to changes in those controversial component weights. To investigate the effect of raising weights on individual components, I generated 63 non-standard versions of the CDI: first with the weight on aid raised to 2, then 3, and so on up to 10 (while weights on the other components were held at 1), then the same for trade, and then the other components. For each version I calculated the correlation of overall scores with the standard CDI, and the average absolute change in rank.43 Figure 1 and Figure 2 show the results. For most of the components, the CDI proves reasonably stable despite large overweighting. Except for trade and environment, even tenfold overweighting yields a score correlation of 0.66–0.82. The index proves more sensitive to the weighting on trade and environment because those components’ scores are more idiosyncratic. On trade, the United States ranks first, and the 14 scored EU members are tightly bunched; the correlation after overweighting trade tenfold is 0.45. In the case of environment, the divergence appears driven in substantial part by Switzerland’s strong number-one performance on the component—its 7.8 puts it well above the next finishers, Austria and Germany at 6.1—which clashes for its tie for 18th on the overall CDI. Rank turns out to be as sensitive to increasing weights on aid, migration, and security as it is to higher weights on trade and environment. This is because aid, migration, and security all have wider ranges. As one of those components gains weight, its high outliers climb rapidly in overall rank while its low outliers fall. 43 I am indebted to Michael Clemens for this technique. 48 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition Table 24. The Commitment to Development Index: Scores Aid Trade Country Australia Austria Belgium Canada Denmark Finland France Germany Greece Ireland Italy Japan Netherlands New Zealand Norway Portugal Spain Sweden Switzerland U.K. United States 2.9 3.7 6.0 3.6 12.3 5.0 6.0 3.9 1.8 3.0 2.8 2.4 11.2 0.8 10.6 2.3 2.0 12.4 5.8 4.8 1.9 4.4 5.8 5.8 5.7 5.8 5.7 5.8 5.8 5.8 5.8 5.9 3.4 5.9 5.9 –2.7 5.8 5.8 5.8 0.3 5.8 6.7 Average Standard dev. 5.0 3.5 5.0 2.2 Invest- Migration Environ- Security Technol- Average 2004 2003 rank rank ment ment ogy 5.9 6.5 8.8 3.3 9.0 6.4 4 19 4.7 4.4 2.9 6.1 3.1 6.9 12 9 4.6 4.3 2.6 5.9 4.0 3.4 13 12 5.8 6.3 11.2 2.9 4.3 6.6 6 18 6.7 4.8 6.1 5.7 7.1 5.0 1 2 5.2 5.1 2.6 5.0 6.7 6.3 11 17 5.3 4.7 2.7 5.9 5.6 6.1 7 14 5.3 6.7 6.1 6.1 2.9 5.6 7 6 4.1 4.1 6.2 4.7 4.0 2.5 17 13 3.9 2.7 5.8 2.8 5.5 2.0 18 15 4.5 5.3 3.6 5.5 3.6 4.7 14 15 3.2 4.6 1.9 4.5 0.4 5.4 21 21 6.7 6.7 5.9 5.3 6.4 5.5 1 1 4.3 2.9 5.0 4.7 6.7 4.1 16 4 5.3 5.3 4.9 4.0 9.3 5.5 7 10 4.5 5.6 2.8 5.4 5.2 4.5 14 3 3.7 4.5 2.3 5.5 2.0 4.0 20 6 6.1 3.8 5.1 5.8 4.5 5.7 3 8 3.9 4.7 3.6 7.9 0.7 4.5 18 5 5.9 6.4 4.4 5.8 9.1 4.7 4 11 5.3 5.6 10.5 2.3 4.9 5.5 7 20 5.0 1.1 5.0 2.5 5.0 1.3 5.0 2.4 5.0 1.3 5.0 0.9 49 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition Table 25. Detailed confrontation of 2003 and 2004 scores Denmark Canada Belgium Austria Australia 3.1 3.0 3.5 2.8 1.7 A 3.3 4.9 4.6 2.6 5.4 4.4 2.7 B 1.5 1.4 3.5 3.8 4.1 2.8 4.0 2.8 2.7 3.0 6.6 5.4 5.4 5.8 2.3 3.9 2.7 2.7 4.5 1.8 6.7 5.4 5.5 5.8 0.0 0.0 4.1 4.1 1.6 6.0 6.8 5.6 5.5 5.8 1.7 2.9 4.7 4.7 0.8 5.0 6.8 5.6 5.4 5.7 1.7 2.9 5.1 5.1 1.3 3.6 6.6 5.3 6.0 5.7 2.1 3.6 6.3 6.3 6.1 6.0 6.7 5.5 5.4 5.8 1.4 2.4 4.3 4.3 4.5 3.7 6.8 5.6 5.4 5.8 2.6 4.3 4.4 4.4 6.5 2.9 7.2 6.1 4.7 4.4 1.6 2.6 6.5 6.5 3.7 5.6 6.7 2.0 6.6 3.9 6.8 5.6 5.4 5.8 1.4 2.3 6.7 6.7 8.1 10.3 6.3 9.0 14.0 14.8 12.3 6.8 5.6 5.5 5.8 1.0 1.7 4.8 4.8 4.4 1.7 2.3 1.0 2.5 1.6 2.6 5.6 6.1 8.2 2.3 4.7 8.3 5.8 1.6 2.5 2.6 2.8 3.7 6.1 6.0 6.4 5.8 6.1 3.8 2.7 4.9 5.4 5.4 5.9 5.2 2.6 5.4 5.9 5.6 5.0 2.9 6.1 5.0 5.5 5.0 5.7 7.1 2.6 4.5 5.1 5.6 5.9 3.5 2.9 5.4 5.9 5.9 6.1 2.6 8.8 1.8 2.7 3.2 3.3 2.8 6.7 3.0 3.6 4.7 4.7 3.6 4.1 4.1 4.2 4.5 4.7 5.9 5.5 2.0 2.0 3.6 4.3 4.1 3.8 3.9 6.2 4.6 5.1 4.7 4.7 9.0 11.4 3.5 4.0 2.5 2.5 3.9 4.4 4.3 4.0 4.1 7.7 11.0 11.2 1.7 2.6 3.0 2.9 2.4 5.6 3.2 3.6 5.3 5.8 5.6 5.5 5.3 4.8 2.9 2.9 5.5 5.6 4.7 5.4 5.1 5.2 5.3 6.6 5.0 5.6 6.2 6.1 3.8 4.4 4.5 4.7 5.3 3.7 7.0 6.7 6.4 6.3 3.5 4.0 5.0 5.2 5.2 9.0 7.4 7.1 5.0 5.0 5.5 6.9 7.3 6.9 6.7 3.0 4.0 4.3 6.5 6.6 3.4 4.1 5.5 5.7 5.8 4.4 3.8 4.0 3.4 3.4 4.0 4.7 4.4 4.3 4.6 3.2 3.1 3.1 7.0 6.9 4.4 5.3 4.0 4.4 4.7 3.6 9.6 9.0 6.4 6.4 3.2 3.7 5.8 5.9 5.9 Overall B C' C D Finland 2.1 4.0 1.3 3.4 TechEnvironment Security nology A B C D A B C D C D A France 1.5 2.8 7.0 5.8 5.5 5.9 1.5 2.5 5.3 5.3 1.1 Investment Migration A B C D A B C D Germany 2.6 1.8 Trade A B C D Greece 2.2 D Ireland 1.4 Aid C Italy Sweden Spain Portugal Norway N. Zealand 3.3 2.2 3.7 3.4 6.6 10.3 1.7 5.1 7.0 10.8 2.4 4.7 5.0 5.7 1.7 2.3 6.9 5.8 5.5 5.8 9.0 15.0 5.6 5.6 1.0 9.7 10.6 1.0 –2.4 –2.3 –2.7 3.5 5.9 5.3 5.3 4.6 0.4 2.0 6.8 5.6 5.5 5.8 8.2 13.7 4.5 4.5 1.8 3.9 2.9 5.8 4.0 1.7 1.9 0.3 6.3 10.5 4.7 4.7 9.0 11.3 3.3 9.7 12.4 6.9 5.8 5.4 5.8 1.8 3.0 3.8 3.8 3.9 2.3 4.8 6.9 5.7 5.5 5.8 3.4 5.7 6.4 6.4 3.1 5.0 5.2 2.2 1.8 1.3 2.8 5.8 3.8 0.8 7.2 6.1 7.0 5.9 2.3 3.9 2.9 2.9 9.0 11.3 3.8 4.4 5.0 5.5 5.7 5.8 3.6 3.6 7.2 7.2 7.2 7.2 0.1 5.1 6.1 6.5 6.7 5.8 1.3 2.3 6.0 6.5 5.7 5.5 2.9 2.8 5.1 5.7 5.3 5.4 6.8 4.9 2.8 3.6 3.9 4.0 7.4 5.0 3.4 4.1 4.5 4.7 6.9 1.9 5.2 4.9 5.3 5.5 2.6 3.0 5.3 5.3 5.3 4.6 9.7 9.1 4.7 4.7 4.2 5.0 3.9 4.0 3.9 0.1 0.6 0.7 4.5 4.5 5.0 6.0 3.4 3.5 3.3 1.7 4.4 4.5 6.0 5.7 4.5 5.5 5.9 5.9 6.1 3.7 1.8 2.0 4.0 4.0 4.7 5.9 3.6 3.7 3.7 8.7 5.1 5.2 4.5 4.5 5.2 6.6 4.3 4.4 4.5 9.4 9.4 9.3 5.5 5.5 4.3 5.4 5.0 5.0 5.3 8.7 6.7 6.7 4.1 4.1 5.1 6.1 4.2 4.2 4.3 2.6 Switzerland 3.0 2.9 10.5 10.5 1.0 2.0 1.9 2.3 1.5 Japan 1.2 1.9 2.3 2.4 4.6 2.6 4.1 3.4 2.8 4.6 4.6 4.6 1.5 2.0 2.0 1.9 4.0 4.6 4.4 4.5 0.5 0.6 0.3 0.4 5.4 5.4 2.4 2.7 3.0 3.3 3.2 Netherlands 6.9 10.8 10.8 11.2 7.0 5.9 5.5 5.9 6.1 10.2 6.7 6.7 4.5 5.6 6.0 5.9 5.7 6.1 6.0 5.3 3.5 4.4 6.4 6.4 5.5 5.5 5.6 7.2 6.9 6.7 6.7 U.K. 1.9 7.7 6.8 7.2 6.7 2.0 3.4 5.6 5.6 2.3 1.4 1.3 0.3 0.2 .27 .29 .96 .99 1.6 0.1 1.00 1.3 2.7 2.9 0.3 .45 .45 .99 0.8 0.9 0.5 0.4 .94 .94 .95 U.S. Comparisons with 2004 scores Difference (rms) 2.4 1.0 1.2 1.6 0.6 0.6 3.1 3.9 0.0 3.3 3.6 0.6 .96 .96 .96 .97 .97 .97 .15 .15 1.0 .23 .23 .98 Corr. Key A: Original 2003 B: Switch to new scaling: mean=5 C: Switch to new methology C': Switch to new method, but exclude new component, technology 50 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition Table 26. Confrontation of 2003 and 2004 standings using 2004 methodology 1 2 3 3 5 5 7 8 8 10 11 12 12 14 15 15 17 18 19 20 21 2003 data Denmark Netherlands Australia Sweden United Kingdom Canada United States Finland Germany Norway France Austria Portugal Belgium New Zealand Italy Greece Ireland Spain Switzerland Japan 6.9 6.7 5.9 5.9 5.7 5.7 5.3 5.2 5.2 5.0 4.7 4.4 4.4 4.3 4.2 4.2 4.0 3.8 3.7 3.5 3.3 1 1 3 4 4 6 7 7 7 7 11 12 13 14 14 16 17 18 18 20 21 2004 data Netherlands Denmark Sweden Australia United Kingdom Canada United States Germany Norway France Finland Austria Belgium Portugal Italy New Zealand Greece Ireland Switzerland Spain Japan 6.7 6.7 6.1 5.9 5.9 5.8 5.3 5.3 5.3 5.3 5.2 4.7 4.6 4.5 4.5 4.3 4.1 3.9 3.9 3.7 3.2 51 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition Figure 1. Correlation of standard CDI with versions with higher weight placed on one component 1.0 Correlation of scores 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 Tec Secu hnolo gy Envir rity Migra onment Inve s tion tmen Tra d t e A id 0.0 1 2 3 4 Highe 5 6 r w ei g ht 7 8 9 10 52 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition Figure 2. Average absolute change in CDI rank when higher weight placed on one component Average absolute rank change 5.0 4.5 4.0 3.5 3.0 2.5 2.0 1.5 1.0 0.5 Tec Envir hnolo gy Secu onment Migra rity Inve s tion tmen Tra d t e A id 0.0 1 2 3 4 Highe 5 r w ei g 6 ht 7 8 9 10 53 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition Appendix. Aggregation of Protection Levels across Sectors In his proposal for an Aggregate Measure of Protection (AMP), Cline (2002) first estimates levels of protection in each of four major sectors, then aggregates the levels into a single measure of protection. The CDI trade component draws heavily on Cline’s proposals, but departs in some respects, including the method of aggregating across sectors. The method used in the CDI is arguably more direct. The starting point for our approach is Annex II of Cline (2002). There, Cline derives a formula for the reduction in exporter’s producer surplus caused by a tariff. (See Figure A–1.) Figure 3. Supply and demand for an import from a developing country D S D’ e t b f g c d a D D’ M Q S In this diagram, line DD is the demand curve in the absence of protection, line D’D’ is the demand curve in its presence, and SS is the supply curve. t is the ad valorem tariff and M is the observed level of imports under protection. The increase in producer surplus, S, caused by removal of protection is the sum of areas b, c, and d. Letting α and β be the absolute values of the elasticities of demand and supply, Cline shows that this area can be estimated as: S=M (1) tα β tα [1 + ]. β +α 2 β +α This expression is quadratic in t, at base because high tariffs hurt exporters doubly, reducing both the price and quantity of their output. Cline notes that unless t is high, the quadratic term 54 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition is small. However, it turns out that for agriculture, levels of protection are quite high (reaching 215% for Norway in agricultural commodities), so this quadratic term can matter. We generalize the above picture to multiple sectors. For simplicity, we assume that the absolute elasticities of supply and demand, α and β, are the same for all sectors. In the generalization, there are protection levels ti, observed import levels Mi, and protection-induced losses in producer surplus Si. In this partial equilibrium context, we estimate the total harm done by protection as the sum of the harms in each sector: S = ∑ Si = ∑ M i t iα β t iα [1 + ]. 2 β +α β +α We then define the aggregate measure of protection to be the uniform tariff t that would reduce exporters’ surplus by just as much as the observed set of protection levels. Our task then is to solve for t in: ∑M i tα tα β tα β t iα [1 + ] = ∑ M i i [1 + ]. β +α β +α 2 β +α 2 β +α (The two sides of the equation differ only in that t is indexed on the right side.) Let M φi = i M = ∑Mi M . Dividing the above equation by M, canceling terms, and rearranging and gives: t[1 + 1 tαβ 1 t iαβ ] = ∑ φ i t i [1 + ], 2 β +α 2 β +α Now let Q = αβ/(α+ β), an expression that occurs on both sides of the equation.44 Substituting this in yields: 1 1 t[1 + tQ ] = ∑ φ i t i [1 + t i Q], 2 2 Using the quadratic equation to solve this for t, it works out that: 44 Q can also be written: 1 1 α + 1 . β It is the reciprocal of the difference in slope between the demand and supply curves. (Recall that α is the absolute value of the elasticity of demand, which is negative.) It represents the proportionate equilibrium change in exports actually supplied with respect to the tariff level, as Cline shows: ∆M/M = tαβ/(α+β). 55 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition t= 1 Qt 1 + 2Q ∑ φ i t i 1 + i 2 Q −1 . Using the Taylor expansion for 1 + x , it can be shown that at low tariff levels (as the φt ti→0), this formula converges to the simple weighted average of the tariffs, ∑ i i . Now the ϕi and ti are observed variables. So to estimate t using this equation, we make one more assumption, about the value of Q. We take it to be 0.5, which it is under the simple assumption that α = β = 1. Thus we calculate: t t = 2 1 + ∑ φ i t i 1 + i − 1. 4 This is the formula for the last column of Table 10. 56 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition Bibliography Bannon, Alicia, and David Roodman (2004), “Technology and the Commitment to Development Index,” Center for Global Development, Washington, DC, April. Birdsall, Nancy, and David Roodman (2003), “The Commitment to Development Index: A Scorecard of Rich-Country Policies,” Center for Global Development, Washington, DC, April. Center for Global Development and Foreign Policy (CGD and FP) (2003), “Ranking the Rich,” Foreign Policy, May/June. Bouët, Antoine, Lionel Fontagné, Mondher Mimouni, and Xavier Pichot (2001), “Market Access Maps: A Bilateral and Disaggregated Measure of Market Access,” Working Paper 18, Centre d’Etudes Prospectives et d’Informations Internationales, Paris, December. Brown, Adrienne, Mick Foster, Andy Norton, and Felix Naschold, The Status of Sector Wide Approaches. Overseas Development Institute. London. July 2001. Cassen, Robert (1994), Does Aid Work? Report to an Intergovernmental Task Force, 2nd ed, Clarendon Press, Oxford, U.K. Chowdhury, Shyamal, and Lyn Squire (2003), “Setting Weights for Aggregate Indices: An Application to the Commitment to Development Index and Human Development Index,” draft, Global Development Network, Washington, DC. Cline, William (2002), “An Index of Industrial Country Trade Policy toward Developing Countries,” Working Paper 14, Center for Global Development, Washington, DC. ----------------- (2004), Trade Policy and Global Poverty, Center for Global Development and Institute for International Economics, Washington, DC. de Gorter, Harry, Melinda Ingco, and Laura Ignacio, “Domestic Support for Agriculture: Agricultural Policy Reform and Developing Countries,” Trade Note 7, World Bank, September 10, 2003. Dimaranan, Betina V., and Robert A. McDougall (2002), Global Trade, Assistance, and Production: The GTAP 5 Data Base. Center for Global Trade Analysis, Purdue University Easterly, William, Ross Levine, and David Roodman (2004), “Aid, Policies, and Growth: Comment.” American Economic Review, June, 94(3). Grieco, Elizabeth M., and Kimberly A. Hamilton (2004), “Realizing the Potential of Migrant “Earn, Learn, and Return” Strategies: Does Policy Matter?” Migration Policy Institute, Washington, DC, February. Jepma, Catrinus J. (1991), The Tying of Aid, OECD Development Centre, Paris. 57 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition Kaufmann, Daniel, Aart Kraay, and Massimo Mastruzzi (2003), Governance Matters III: Governance Indicators for 1996–2002, Policy Research Working Paper 3106, World Bank, Washington, DC, August. Kee, Hiau Looi, Alessandro Nicita, and Marcelo Olarreaga (2004), “Calculation of the Overall Trade Restrictiveness Index,” World Bank, Washington, D.C. Processed. Knack, Stephen, and Aminur Rahman (2004), “Donor Fragmentation and Bureaucratic Quality in Aid Recipients,” Policy Research Working Paper 3186, World Bank, Washington, DC, January. Moran, Theodore (2004), “Rationale for Components of a Scoring System of Developed Country Support for International Investment Flows to Developing Countries,” Center for Global Development, Washington, DC, April. O’Hanlon, Michael and Adriana Lins de Albuquerque (2004), “Note on the Security Component of the 2004 CDI,” Center for Global Development, Washington, DC, April. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) (2003), Agricultural Policies in OECD Countries: Monitoring and Evaluation, Paris. Picciotto, Robert (2003), “Giving Weight to the CGD Rankings: A Comment on the Commitment to Development Index,” Global Policy Project, London. Roodman, David (2003), “An Index of Donor Aid Performance,” April, Center for Global Development, Washington, DC. -------------------- (2004a), “An Index of Donor Performance: 2004 Edition,” Center for Global Development, Washington, DC, April. -------------------- (2004b), “An Index of Rich-Country Environmental Performance: 2004 Edition,” Center for Global Development, Washington, DC, April. -------------------- (2004c), “Project Proliferation Costs: Modeling and Estimation,” draft, Center for Global Development, Washington, DC. Sawada, Yasuyuki, Hirohisa Kohama, Hisaki Kono, and Munenobu Ikegami (2004), “Commitment to Development Index (CDI): Critical Comments,” Discussion Paper on Development Assistance No.1, Foundation for Advanced Studies on International Development, Tokyo, draft. Walmsley, Terrie L., and L. Alan Winters (2003), “Relaxing the Restrictions on the Temporary Movement of Natural Persons: A Simulation Analysis,” presented at conference on “Quantifying the Impact of Rich Countries’ Policies on Poor Countries,” Center for Global Development and Global Development Network, Washington, DC, October 23. World Bank (2001), Global Economic Prospects and the Developing Countries 2002, Washington, DC. 58 Roodman, The Commitment to Development Index: 2004 Edition --------------- (2004), Global Monitoring Report 2004: Policies and Actions for Achieving the MDs and Related Outcomes, Washington, DC. 59