Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium Member Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/organizingindustOOfish HB31 .M415 working paper department of economics ORGANIZING INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION: REFLECTIONS ON PARTS 2 AND 3 OF THE Handbook of Industrial Organization Franklin M. Fisher Number 566 October 1990 massachusetts institute of technology 50 memorial drive Cambridge, mass. 02139 is Fisher Franklin M. October 1990 Number 566 ' . • ORGANIZING INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION: REFLECTIONS ON parts and 2 3 of the HaDd&QQls-fif -iDdiistiial-QrgaDizatioD Franklin M. Fisher * Massachusetts Institute of Technology * Paper prepared for the B^og|siDg£_.P^pei§_OD_EcoD2mic_Ac£ir Yi£y Microeconomics Conference, December, This paper is 1990. dedicated to Carl Kaysen on the occasion of his 70th birthday. Turning and turning in the widening gyre The falcon cannot hear the falconer; Things fall apart; the centre cannot hold; Mere anarchy is loosed upon the world. W. B. Yeats, "The Second Coming" Bliss was it in that dawn to be alive, But to be young was very heaven! William Wordsworth, "French Revolution" 1.1.. My Introduction. task in this paper is to reflect on Parts 2§Dd^2Qi<_2f_lD5ustiial_QigaDisa£i2D. 1. Richard Scmalensee and Robert D. 2f_lD^usi£ial_Q£ganisatioD, Tokyo: These North-Holland, 1989) (Amsterdam, . are 2 and 3 of the sections the Willig, eds., 3and222k. New York, Oxford, and All references are to this unless otherwise stated. respectively cal entitled "Analysis of Market Behavior" and "Empiri- Methods and Results". sively theoretical, empirically The former section is almost while the latter, oriented. 3oth exclu- as its name suggests, sections deal primarily with is the analysis of markets, particularly of oligopoly. the Table of Contents of the entire low.) 2 "Determinants Issues Comparisons", and when Parts the of Organization", I speak about "the HSDdboQk" I be- Handbook: "International and "Government Intervention is being written by Alvin Klevorick. Marketplace" ence, Firm and Market of reproduced is of the remaining sections review A 2. BflDdlSQQlS (For convenience, For in the conveni- shall generally mean and 2U 2 Such reflection has two aspects. Does it succeed in Is it a good book? of the BaQd^QQk. itself. its stated aims? First, there is the matter however, is a broader and more impor- Second, Reading the SaodQSQk. provides the oppor- tant set of questions. tunity for thinking about the state of the art, organization as a field. principles? Where is it? about industrial What are the organizing Where is the field going? Is that the correct desti- nation? This latter set of questions are the subject of most of this But before paper. tion, and, in fact, I get to them, the former set deserves atten- the two sets are not unrelated. 2.»_Ih£_3aDdb22i;_a§_B02k. begin, I doing low) , so I then, (and, by considering the BaodaQQk. as a book. indeed, In in considering the state of the art be- necessarily paint with a pretty broad brush. The book is immense, and detailed review of the individual chapters would be tedious, if not impossible. As a result, there are plenty of exceptions to criticisms, and many of my general comments and especially to my hope particular authors will forgive me for not I pointing them out. said this, Having I add at once that my first reaction This is a very good that of enthusiastic praise. chapter is more far a than surveys of the state of the art in On the other hand, I BSDdkSQk straight through. I Every Most of them are well-written mine of information. They are coherent essays area. book. particular a which themselves add to the art. do not suggest sitting down to read the It is not intended for that. Indeed, edi- cannot do better here than quote the advice given by the of a rather good collection of political jokes tors is (Lukes and Galnoor 1987, p. xiii) One final word of advice to any prospective reader of the If you try to follow volume: Qq QSi igad it! King's instructions to the White Rabbit in &lJ.££^JLD_W2D3eir and go on till you come to ^Begin at the beginning, laod the end: then stop,' you will very soon become sated and overcome first with a numbed indifference and then with some some sweet, nausea (as with a box of chocolates We advise, bitter, some hard- and some- soft-centered). rather, judicious sampling. this — — — This intended wers) . is not criticism, however, for cover-to-cover reading Rather it for the Baodacjok. is (except by exhausted is intended as a handbook, whose purpose, as stated by the editors (p. a xi) not revie- reference work is to provide reasonably comprehensive and up-todate surveys of recent developments and the state of knowledge in the major areas of research . as of the latter . part of the 1980s, written at a level suitable for use by non-specialist economists and students in advanced graduate courses . Is the HaDd^agk. successful in achieving this goal? only partly so. In the first place, I think particularly in the theore- tical chapters of Part pretty heavy, going provided. (Sensibly/ overview the of 2, the non-specialist will often find the been even though the underlying tools have Part 2 begins with Fudenberg and Tirole's methods and results noncooperative of game theory. again especially in Part 2, Further, to the temptation to deal with their own succumb students because of their work in their respective subject chosen urge the areas. occasionally wrinkles to decribe all the latest and The authors were This is not necessarily a bad thing. friends). some- latest, unpublished work (and perhaps that of their times But the authors sometimes tells the reader more than he or she wants to know, and one comes away from such discussions without a clear sense that the literature has been systematically surveyed. That is less so in the empirical chapters of here a different problem arises. a large set of empirical studies. Part For one thing, the material is of certainty with which we know 16) and Cohen and Levin Here, it. (Chapter 18) have hard task of dealing with cross-industry studies. job of organizing their respective topics, at providing a detailed critical guide literature. open theoreti- is not easy both to describe what is known and also the It (Chapter ful a For another, empirical studies vary vastly in quali- cal theme. degree but It is hard to write a survey of typically less easy to organize than is the case with ty. 3, Since, as we shall see, the really They do a good but are less successto the underlying the studies surveyed are to considerable theoretical objection, importance Schmalensee it is of particular to sort out which studies and which conclusions are While both chapters (especially solidly based and which are not. Schmalensee's) deal with the underlying do problems involved, fall down in the perhaps impossible task of carefully sepa- they soundly-based studies from more questionable rating good, we Rather get the authors' own (and doubtless often ones. correct) impressions as to what the literature shows. It is also often theoretical chapters have only the of (but not always) of empirical work. results This, problem in the field itself, and this connection, In Theory "The I the case that the a general idea about reflects however, 2. 3 out 2 in Carlton the contrast is so sharp as to be jarring. wonders why Carlton's chapter appears in Part the deeper Dennis Carlton's essay (Chapter 15) on and the Facts of How Markets Clear" stands Indeed, considers a the shall discuss it later. sharp contrast from most of the chapters of Part 3. authors One at all. actual facts on such things as price changes and delivery lags and shows that simple theories cannot explain them. His chapter is a welcome blend of theory and facts. In level and tone, it comes far closer than most of the other chapters of Part 2 to meeting the purpose quoted above. The spend other theoretical chapters of Part 2, as indicated, little time on systematic examination of empirical facts. They mostly pay little attention to empirical work or else resort to casual Saloner's Antitrust" observation. Only occasionally, excellent piece (Chapter 9) on "Predation, as in Ordover and Monopolization, and does one find a real attempt to apply the theory to the detailed facts of particular industries. brings me to the subject of work in the field that This not well surveyed in the For a very long time now, UaDdfiQfllS. good deal of effort has been spent on in-depth industry Such studies, sure, provide the basic information from which can generalize. common (although important, HaQSteogk., I do I I can More . from it be still is certainly know that it still goes on) if anything about to theory not know to what extent such work cannot tell much, I a studies. varying quality and analytic content, of is the and this is a gap. realize, This is because each industry study tends to be systematic way. idiosyncratic that such work is hard to survey in a of course, with organizing principles linking them hard to do not believe that this is an acci- find. (As we shall see, dent.) But the BgDd&OQk. fails to make the attempt (although some I individual studies are mentioned in passing.) of the comes SaD^&QQk. to a Bresnahan's (and of the profession) symptomatic It is that the closest survey of work on particular industries tries with Market Power™. That chapter, Timothy is essay (Chapter 17) on "Empirical Studies one Indus- of excellent and interes- ting in itself, is focussed on work that uses a particular set of techniques; The it does not pretend to survey the wider area. second area that is not really systematically surveyed it is the area of public policy. Anti- trust policy issues are indeed discussed in several of the chap- is related to the first; ters (the Ordover and Saloner essay already mentioned, "Price Discrimination" tractual Relations" (Chapter 10), Varian on and Katz on "Vertical Con- (Chapter 11), for example). But the Handbook. makes no separate systematic attempt to tie together economic and thinking as to public policy on market power legal issues. and related Since much of the practical use of industrial organiza- comes in antitrust cases which also supply the occasion for tion substantial work on particular industries, this is an unfortunate omission. These two omissions (industry studies and matters) antitrust-related are also troublesome because of the opportunity that a systematic survey (were one possible) might afford to see theory in action. The authors of the theory chapters obviously believe theory that studying particular industries. after 409) provides a rich set of tools for Thus, an extensive discussion of Behavior (Chapter 6) application Carl Shapiro states "Theories of when (p. Oligopoly : Let me close with a sort of user's guide to the many By "user", one oligopoly models I have discussed. I mean who is attempting to use these models to better understand a given industry (not someone out to build yet another model). Here is where the "bag of tools" analogy applies. After learning the basic facts about an industry, the analyst with a working understanding of oligopoly theory should be able to use these tools to identify the main strategic aspects present in that industry. Had the Haodfeesls successfully surveyed industry studies and analysis of particular antitrust cases, instructive to it might have been see how those tools have been used or how ffliglat have been used. such an exploration would in fact have revealed that views as (As we shall see, however, I very they suspect that such that just quoted are far too sanguine about the usefulness of theory in its present state.) Before leaving my discussion of the Bankbook as a book and on to the wider arena of what it reveals about the moving of the art, must discuss one minor matter. I the UdQ&hQQk is a disgrace. rect, The proofreading of Names are misspelled, sentences are references to other chapter numbers incor- ungrammatical, often while meaning is seldom totally obscured, one occa- and, has to think about what the author must have sionally state meant to say. Three will suffice here. examples Bresnahan to a "higher or at least higherf aulting 1020) guage". He also states (p. 1015, n„ 5) refers (p. theoretical lan- that he will "mention a consistent notation throughout, rather than adopting the notation of individual papers. But the greatest of all such quotes comes from Stiglitz (p. 773, n. 4) who says of the Walrasian auctioneer that "no one probably took the tantamount process seriously." And I single out these two authors only because the are amusing. slips The level of care here is consistently low, and I suspect that the authors were not given the opportunity to proofread their own papers. Having made these criticisms, however, I want again emphasize that my principal reaction is quite favorable. every chapter educational (which is not to say that substantive disagreements with the authors) . This is I to found I had no a book of which authors and editors should be proud. 3 A „Q£g3DisiDg„PiiD£iplg§^2£_lDdHsi£i§l„Qig3Diza£isD I important of considering the state of the art as reflected in Parts task and turn now to the more difficult but rather more 3 of the Handbook. . This is not easy to do, 2 for the writing of systematic essay requires that one find organizing a the very explosion of material reflected in In this regard, the is daunting. Hsndbofik. After considerable thought, I have decided to proceed in the way that some of the authors of the Bsndbosk. same themes. Schmalensee (Chapter 16) , for example, chapters do. organizes his summary of "Inter-Industry Studies of Structure and Performance" in terms of a begin Eaton and Lipsey (Chapter of "Stylized Facts". series essay on "Product Differentiation" with a their seven "awkward facts that are available to constrain (p. 725) that reports it BandkSSlSf and summarizes the field as seen shall proceed in similar fashion with a I "Organizing Principles." 4. authors I trust I series the of 4 shall be forgiven for emulating some of own work a bit too frequently. Fisher extent through of the BaQd'Qgok. in a different way and referring the field. of theorizing" the present paper is empirical to the Since . list 12) That, too, to the my is characteristic of The views here expressed are consonant with those of (1989) — an article whose publication certainly contri- buted to my being asked to write this review. lD£ys££i£l Qigsnizd^ioD ffil are tbQSfi £b§£ 31 £ has. no oigani.zi.Dg pxi.Dci.plss sscept subcases of this one* This is not a joke. As we shall see, deep reasons for such a lack, I shall begin with pure theory. number of different ways. I believe that there and it manifests itself in a issuli eiiocissl Tbe show tbeciy is is of osarly tbst anytbiog sso bapeeox The principal mode of theorizing in industrial creation of inter the is examples in which .-. problems of all but their most essential features. stripped in effect, is, ;>_,. organization strates result The formalized anecdote in which the theorist demon- a outcomes can in fact certain that are occur — sometimes contrary to what one might have thought. sort of theory is what This plifying theory" (Fisher 1989) have elsewhere called I producing counterexamples to general propositions. may lead method It is a powerful . "exemfor Further, it to insights about phenomena that can also be found in more general and complex situations. But the result does not appear to be leading to any "generalizing theory" real content. list of a (fisher 1989) or, indeed, to a theory with much Rather it has produced a taxonomy vast number of possibilities which — rules a laundry out very little. This fact has not escaped the attention of a number of authors of the Hand^osis essay on "Cartels, p. . the Thus Jacquemin and Slade state in their Collusion and Horizontal Merger" (Chapter 7, 416, emphasis added); Economic thought concerning collusive p-ractices and mergers has changed profoundly, mainly in the light of gametheoretic analysis. Unfortunately, this change has not led to more general and robust conclusions. contrary, On the it is the source of a more fragmented view. The diversity of models and results, which are very sensitive to the assumption selected, suggests a "case-by-case" approach where insight into the ways in which firms acquire and 10 It is maintain positions of market power becomes essential. nevertheless important to bring to light a typology of situations and practices for which recent developments in economic analysis offer sounder theoretical characterizations than in the past. They later say (p. 441) The multiplicity of equilibria is one of the problems Instead of associated with the repeated-game approach. it can explain all providing us with a theory of oligopoly, possible behaviors. states in his essay on "Mobility Barriers and Gilbert Value of Incumbency" (Chapter 8, p. the 478) scope for oligopolistic interactions is so wide [T]he that a predictive model of how firms behave may be no easier to construct than a model of the weather based on the formation of water droplets. He refers (p. 509) to "a taxonomy of behavior in response to entry. one very important sense, In not the fault of theorists. have recited them, rous One this situation is The theoretical facts are as they and the possible outcomes are extremely nume- and assumption-dependent. Further, the Folk Theorem with low enough discount repeated games assures us that, this of course, for rates, phenomenon is endemic in any situation of serious interest. must not blame the messenger for the bad news (although one can be skeptical as to just how surprising the news really is) theorists know about question whether are working on a very useful research agenda. We now the On . other hand, one can reasonably that no general results will emerge that map market structure into performance while theory is often illuminating: 11 simple outcomes. facts Moreover, stiiBBedrdowD Tbs models Qf tbsfiiy o£££D fail to siovide very ijfilBful guides £21 ibe analysis Qt iesl situstiQDS^. The problem is that real firms operate in a far more complex world than state. set a its present exemplifying Real firms do not set quantity or else set price. complex variety of strategic variables. optimistic above, is captured by theory in the Contrary to They the view expresed in Shapiro's "bag of tools" quote given analyst working on a particular industry will not be able to decide what tools apply Quotations from the Fudenberg and Tirole state (p. (or are Haod^QSlS often if any do) illuminating here. 292, emphasis added) [F]irms typically do not only choose a time to enter a market, but also decide on the scale of entry, the type of product to produce, etc. This dstsil can prove unmanagewhich is why industrial organization economists have able, frequently abstracted it away . . . . Jacquemin and Slade state (p. 447) In all of these models, price wars are equilibrium This is strategies of supergames; no one ever cheats. models from practical perhaps a shortcoming of these a [1] intuitive if not from a game-theoretic point of view. Our feeling is that firms do intentionally cheat on collusive agreements (recall the electrical-equipment conspiracy) and that there are many reasons why price wars occur in addition to demand shocks. Nevertheless, economists have devised few theories to explain cheating in collusive agreements. Reinganum states in her essay on "The Timing of Innovation: Research, Development, and Diffusion" (Chapter 14, p. 905): One important goal of future research should be to develop testable models of industry equilibrium behavior. The papers summarized here have used stark models in order to identify the significant characteristics of firms, markets and innovations which are likely to affect incentives to invest and/or adopt [innovations]. But since it is largely restricted to . special cases . ., this work has not yet had a significant impact on the applied literature in industrial organization; policy its usefulness for . 12 . . For these purpurposes should also be considered limited. the one needs a predictive model which encompasses poses, innovation and characteristics. of firm, industry range full Cohen and Levin, writing on "Empirical Studies of Innovation and Market Structure" (Chapter 18) agree with this, although they are certainly not wholly pessimistic (p. 1096, emphasis added) One difficulty with testing recent game-theoretic models of R&D rivalry is that they analyze behavior in highly Moreover, many . stylized and counterf actual settings. depend on typically unverifia. of the results obtained ble assumptions concerning the distribution of information, and the sequence of the identity of the decision variables, moves. Nonetheless, empirical effort on the effect and Inspiration importance of strategic behavior is warranted. might be drawn from Lieberman's (1987) empirical examination of the role of entry deterrence in affecting capacity expanHe sion in a sample of chemical and metals industries. concluded that strategic considerations were not paramount in most industries, but he identified several specific instances in which strategic considerations may have been important. . . In (p. 538, . . something of the same vein, Ordover and Saloner state emphasis in original) [T]heoretical findings and prescriptions are difficult to translate into workable and enforceable standards that in 3££U3l fl)3£ls££ §§££iDgs would, without fail, promote conduct without fail, prothat enhances social welfare and would, mote conduct that harms welfare. The source of the problem is the strategic setting itself. In the context of strategic interactions, is difficult to distinguish between it those actions which are intended to harm actual (and potential) rivals [,] that stifle competition, and thereby reduce economic welfare, and those actions which harm present rivals and discourage future entry but which, nevertheless, promote economic welfare. as legal scholars are often Or, fond of saying, actions which are consistent with "competition on the merits". Stripped-down models can, Eaton tion" in fact, be very useful, but, as and Lipsey observe in their essay on "Product Differentia(Chapter 12, p. 759), results is no advantage." " [T] ractability in deriving incorrect For "incorrect" read "inapplicable". Industrial organization theory has a long way to go. 13 The journey is not made easier by: dq Iqy Same. wsans sill theoLists bsvs a attitude casual tflWat^S what CQQSti£ut£§ xerif icatiQD* With models choose to one can reasonably ask what could constitute the verifica- from, tion bewildering variety of possible a falsification or of a particular model. sometimes an underlying attitude that a there Here theory has been "success- or "applicable" if one can use it to tell a logically ful" story of what might have happened sistent is — a story con- consistent with the very few facts that the theorist happens to know. quote from Cohen and Levin given above is one illustra- The Others can be found in the very casual citation of certain tion. antitrust cases by some authors. This 5. Thus, to take an example that is definitely Q9£ to say that all authors are casual in this regard. 2aQ£JbQQk Ordover and of the Saloner, for example, have read the literature on the cases they cite. I know well, contracts only does cited again in IglS2J_y.»<_IB£J is cited as providing an and entry prevention (p. 502 n.). so in terms of the plaintiff's (p. 507 n.) example case In fact the allegations. of It is for the effects of "locked-in" customers producing alleged price discrimination. Here the allegation made no economic sense and the principal so-called "lock-in" part of the case was not the one cited. find. 7, (These points are not hard to See Fisher, McGowan and Greenwood 1983, pp. 196-204, 316- 325-8.) 14 To continue with the computer industry, Gilbert writes (pp. 514-5, emphasis added) the Gaskins model Despite its theoretical limitations, dynamic limit pricing (along with its refinements) is an appealing description of pricing behavior for industries The exogenous that are characterized by dominant firms. is not theoretically justispecification of the entry flow fied, but it may capture an important element of dynamic competition. . If it wsrs possible to model [certain underlying] aspects of the entry processs (sis) the result ££Ul£ be an entry flow rate that appears similar to the Gaskins model. For these reasons, it is not surprising that the Gaskins model has been used SUSSSSSfully in empirical models of dominant firm pricing, such as Brock (1972). of . . , . . The suggest computer of course, issue, that . . is what constitutes serious knowledge of the a "success". complexities the of does not lead one to believe that this industry I is a however appealing it may seem for its relative terrific example, simplicity. Similarly, the notion that merger policy should be made on the assumption that real firms follow Cournot behavior is naive, (Farrell and Shapiro 1990). The fact that theo- if not bizarre. can produce a simplified model with clean results does not rists mean that the world works in that way. Further, surveyed wrong. with in The the the idea that the cross-section empirical Part 3 somehow verify simplistic theory difficulties with such studies (perhaps studies is especially use of accounting profitability) do not appear fully appreciated by theorists. (See, for example, pp. now turn to a consideration of such empirical work. 15 to be 437, 449, and 455, and Shapiro 1989, p. 133.) I simply Musb is wcils^ The eopiiicai Dfit wciIsj. escecislly ciossriodustiy eiDBiiicfll iofQimed by loi SQmetimes aboutl tbegiy* years of drought of industrial organization theory were years in which the cross-section farmers went on planting. Not surprisingly, the harvest was not bountiful, and the recent flood of theory has not irrigated the crops Cross-sectional attempts to verify (or disprove?) the struc- ture-conduct-performance based in theory. tively paradigm have never been very soundly Not only has theory not provided much quantita- useful guidance as to exactly how structure affects per- formance, even at the level of what variables should be used, but the empirical practitioners have often had only a rudimentary understanding of what theory did say. An the outstanding (but not the only) area of capital theory, example of this came where inability to move beyond simplest one-period model was striking indeed. ly, in the More specifical- attempts to use profitability as the basic measure of perfor- mance simply misunderstood both the role and even the measurement of profitability in economic theory. In the first place, it is not true that there are no econo- mic profits earned in competition. of the competitive process. profits Profits are the driving force Only in long-run (adjusted for risk) driven to zero. equilibrium It is a major mis- take -- and one that runs consistently throughout economics behave as though all that matters is long-run equilibrium. petition is a dynamic process; and the fact real firms operate in real that economists find it hard to 16 are deal with — to Comtime, such dynamics does not make them go away. Put this aside firm f however, and suppose that comparison of industry's profitability to some "normal" standard is in or What profita- fact an appropriate way to test for market power. To the extent that it is bility measure should be used? priate a to present speak in terms of profit rates at all discounted values at some suitable opposed (as rate approto return) of economic thory teaches that the risk-adjusted profit rate that is under competition is the internal or economic rate equalized — return of that rate that makes the present value of the stream of returns from investment equal to the direct capital costs. The profitability rate used in cross-section studies is (admittedly hard to measure) magnitude. this dies used accounting rate of return the stockholders' equity or by the value of capital capital stock purchasc-d profits while current profits are earned in Since future to because of of information (Indeed, the remarkable fact that there should exist any circumstances under which the two are closely related.) Nevertheless, despite the fact that others had made similar points in the past, of surprise lot and by it should come as no surprise that about the economic rate of return. is part measures do not in fact carry a great deal such divided stock). now is done so with an eye investments made in the past, many stu- Rather, (profits not I this fact did cause quite a (not to say outraged protest) pointed it out some years ago. when John McGowan (Fisher and McGowan 1983; see also, e.g., Long and Ravenscraft 1984 and Fisher 1984).. A similar problem infects studies using a different profita- 17 — measure bility favorable the profits-sales ratio. assumptions, in fact equal of monopoly (or Even it turns out that this quantity does not (price minus marginal cost divided all except under yeiy special circumstances. price) measure possibly even approximate) the Lerner power quite making by (Fisher, 1987a). These are not difficult results to derive from the theory of Yet at least one leading practitioner seems to firm. the wholly unaware that the economic rate of return was of been importance. Others _"., : any HcGowan and Greenwood, 1983, p. 257.) (See Fisher, simply have _t hard to believe that they were measuring the wrong thing. progress Some has been made. Recently focus has shifted from profits to prices as a performance measure (Weiss, ed. 1989) ~ something that comparison The 6. of prices by different firms that the goods being priced be (or be made) apparently simple cases, such Schmalensee, has its own serious problems. promptness, ease of That this can make a dealing, (1989) who understands the issues involved gets round them by literature and substantial diffe- rence has been forcefully pointed out by Newmark the Even in comparable. this may not be easy, since goods carry attributes as service, general firm reputation. requires surveying as providing "stylized facts" rather than solid results. Those "stylized facts" often concern accounting profi- tability, and industrial organization theory may need to explain them. But one must not yield to the temptation to suppose that the explanation is that the magnitudes studied in empirical are work necessarily closely allied to those which are the objects of 18 theory. (if less pervasive) A somewhat similar Temin and I long ago pointed out that the theory of does not yield an unambiguous prediction as to the firm of firm size on research and development the effects in the presence of (See Fisher and Temin 1973, 1979, Rodriguez economies of scale. That result holds both for and Kohn and Scott 1982.) 1979, (R&D) Here scale. literature on innovation and returns to empirical Peter problem arises in the input and R&D output. R&D Yet the literature keeps on growing. Cohen and Levin's treatment of this issue in their survey of "Empirical 18) is Studies of Innovation and Market Structure" perhaps indicative of the impatience with such demonstrations. feel They state (Chapter workers empirical (p. 1071, emphasis added) [Fisher and Temin] demonstrated, amsDg 2£h§£ £hiDS§r that an elasticity of R&D [input] with respect to size in excess of one does not necessarily imply an elasticity of innovative output with respect to size greater than one. Kohn and Scott established the conditions under which . imply the the existence of the former relationship does latter. . They then problem go . on to what they consider the stemming from the argument that fundamental" "more "Schumpeter did not postulate a continuous effect of firm size on innovation." The point is that the proposition as to the relations tween the two elasticities is a relatively minor one. be- Among the demonstrated was that the litera- "other things" that Temin and I ture (and probably was not able to test) was not in fact testing any of the propositions which it purported to examine. ly, that didn't stop anybody. 19 Apparent- picture of careless disregard for theory by This empirical workers is, of course, too general to be totally accurate. over, in one area, at least, More- it is certainly not correct. Bresnahan's essay (Chapter 17) surveys "Empirical Studies of It reports on econometric studies Industries with Market Power." of particular industries undertaken to test whether those indus- behave competitively and to measure tries literature recognizes [cannot cost be] (p. 1012) market power. This that "[f] inns' price-cost margins taken to be observables [since] economic marginal cannot be directly or straightforwardly observed." ... At least as important: Individual industries are taken to have important idiosyncracies. is likely that institutional detail at the It and even more industry level will affect firms' conduct, likely that it will affect the analyst's measurement strateThus, practitioners in this literature are skeptical of gy. indususing the comparative statics of variations across tries or markets as revealing anything except when the markets are closely related. literature stands out from most of the empirical This surveyed On the in the Ban^QfiQJs in that it certainly does the other hand, game-theoretic use work theory. the theory it uses is not closely related to analyses of Part 2. Further, while progress has been made in the detection of market power, some Bresna- han states (pp. 1053, 1055): Only a very little has been learned from the new methods about the relationship between market power and industrial structure. • • • We know essentially nothing about the causes, or even the systematic predictors of market power, but have come a long way in working out how to measure them. Maybe measurement so. I success, am more skeptical than Bresnahan but there can be no doubt 20 that about our empirical attempts to relations test, or estimate the parameters between structure and performance have not of and the kinds of analytic defects pointed ignoring results most only be said to be uncertain can grounds ambiguous. and The empi- literature makes essentially no use of the modern rical results, is hardly surprising, which methods since theory providing propositions that are testable in practice Principle above, out the explosion in theory is having no effect. Further, the succeeded. taking the general empirical literature on its own Even or verify, is not (Organizing 3) 4..-&_Besear£h_&geDda failure of the empirical literature is not an accident, The Indeed, in one (not very helpful sense) however. does indeed confirm the results of theory. that literature The principal result of theory in this area is that nearly anything can happen nizing Principle 2) . (Orga- There is no simple mapping from elementary (let alone imperfect) measures of structure such as concentration or Those models (such as the firm size into performance. sim- plest Cournot models) that suggest there is arrive at that result by stripping the problem of features essential to under- the Hence the standing of real industries (Organizing Principle 3) empirical ambiguous does the prediction of theory (although not in a very indeed finding verify that such relationships are . helpful way) short, In dead, simple if (and the structure-conduct-performance this is a big if) one thinks of it paradigm as structural measures to conduct and performance 21 is relating characte- The theoretical counterpart to this is that the program ristics. of investigating how perfectly rational opponents will behave simplified settings has failed as well (or, overly has succeeded too far) of if you wish, Despite outward appearances, . in industrial organization is not in a happy state, the field at least as regards the analysis of oligopoly markets and related subjects. This conclusion, of rests on a somewhat limited view however, what the appropriate research agenda for industrial organizareally tion is„ as little to those who carefully read Fellner's CfilDPStitiflD-fllDfiDg surprise (Fellner tbg^Eey failures just described come The 1949) or have worked extensively on industry The simple-structure-measures-cum-rational-behavior mo- studies. does not lead to very useful results because the context del particular industries in which firms operates strongly of affects which outcome they will or can achieve I give the simplest example. low enough discounting) (with maximizing) of the sensible In an infinitely repeated game the , cooperative (joint-profit- outcome is typically a Nash equilibrium number of firms or of industry independent concentration. person supposes that such an outcome is just as Yet no likely when there are a thousand equally-sized firms as it is when there are two. nor a In this sense, justification modern theory provides neither a guide for studies that attempt measure the such an attempt is not thereby rendered senseless. We to effect of concentration or numbers on outcomes. Yet think that the two cases just described differ, not because the Nash equilibria are fundamentally different in the two cases, but 22 because two-firm the industry will somehow find it easier achieve the cooperative outcome than will the thousand-firm Further, true. If all give at least verbal reasons why can we numbers to one. that is and concentration were all that mattered to such ability, then empirical studies attempting to relate perfor- mance to numbers and concentration would (properly measured) be successful despite the Folk Theorem. Further, 7. policy merger would be entirely sensible. measures that relies on such On this, see Fisher (1987b) . The difficulty, of course, is that numbers and concentration are not all that matter. matter as well. A great many other things are likely to As Carlton states in his essay on how markets clear (Chapter 15, p. 911): [M]uch of industrial organization seems fixated on answering how the behavior of markets differs as industry concentration changes. Although this is certainly an interesting question, industry concentration is only one of many ways in which markets can differ. Market liquidity, heterogeneity of product, variability in demand and supply, the ability to hold inventories, and the ability to plan are also interesting characteristics, and differences in these characteristics lead to different market behavior. Yet the effect of these other characteristics has received much less attention from industrial organization economists than the effect of differences in industry concentration. Further, once one leaves the question of market clearing, list of interesting characteristics gets longer still. studies pay little attention to this, rical the But empi- and theory has ma- naged mostly to verify that the list is long. I believe that the proper research agenda for industrial organization is the study of how the context of particular industries or market situations affects the ability to 23 achieve the joint-profit-maximizing outcome. I do not believe that this Further, most of modern theory is doing. what as is have else- I do not believe that the theoretical tools currently so popular are particularly well explained in detail (Fisher 1989) where , I suited for that task. Lacking strong guidance from theory, we need to know what in This surely requires the dstailgd. study of parti- f§St happens. The cross-section literature is too simplistic cular industries. to be of much assistance here, theorists some of Principle 4) surveyed by but regard, structural *= K~ tit> U and the somewhat casual towards empirical is of no help at all. Bresnahan it verification richly adequate to describe the this in articulated con- underlying O / description wrong of course, empirical to jump into without any guiidance from theory, but it would to suppose that we do not have any such guidance. generally (but only generally) know what can matter. need literature is at least potentially useful It is always dangerous, is (Organizing (The econometric too suffers from a lack of variables attitude We be do The problem that we have known that for more than forty years. What we to know is what aspects of the contextual setting matter in practice. This may be where experimental methods come in. his essay, Plott, in "An Updated Review of Industrial Organization; Appli- cations of Experimental Methods" (Chapter 19) , lists number of a cogent reasons for the use of such methods (pp. 1165-9) . He does not explicitly mention the possibility that by carefully controlling the context in which market-like games are played, 24 one can insight into what aspects of context are likely gain matter non-experimental situations. in But really to possibility that comes across from his survey. 5*-£0D£ludiD9~&£Ha£k£ Despite my favorable remarks on the HaDdbflQk. itself, this Yet, des- essay will no doubt convey a somewhat negative tone. this need not be pite my comments on the state of the field, time to be depressed about industrial organization. The field revolution Even though that has been undergoing a revolution. has not produced results nearly as exciting or relevant as to some of the revolutionaries, seem a the revolution is not they yet over two poems quoted as epigraphs to this paper give diffe- The descriptions rent times. of what it is like to live revolutionary in The poem by Yeats can be taken as describing the anarchy consequent on the destruction of an old order; that by Wordsworth describes the opportunity that such times create, especially for the young. If attention can now be turned to the sort of agenda outlined, context to the I have theory and empirical study of the effects of enough to on outcomes, to the analysis of models rich capture the facts of real industrial situations, then the promise outlined in the Wordsworth quote can be achieved. But believe as just that promise has not been achieved as yet. Those that it has (and who are inclined to dismiss my those of an old-geezer-in-training) might do who remarks well to reflect on the fact that the full title of the Wordsworth poem is 25 "French Revolution, mencement." As I as It Appeared to Enthusiasts at Its said earlier, long way to go. 26 industrial organization Comhas a BefeieDces Brock, G. (Cambridge: Ibfi-U-S A -COBDUtfiI-lDdUStIX (1975) Ballinger) Fellner, W. (1949) GQmp££i£isD_3ID3Dg..£be_,E£W (New York: Alfred A. Knopf) "Horizontal Mergers: An Equili- Farrell, J. and C. Shapiro (1990) brium Analysis", Ameiican-EcflDQIDiS-BSYifiw 80:107-26. F.M. Fisher, "The Misuse of Accounting Rates of (1984) Return: Reply", AraeiisaD-BSGDfilDiS-BSYigw 74:509-17. Fisher, F.M. (1987a) "On the Misuse of the Profits-Sales Ratio to Infer Monopoly Power", BAiffl^JfluiDal-C/f-ECADGroisS 18:384-96. Fisher, F.M. (1987b) "Horizontal Mergers: Triage and Treatment", JSl»rD3l_of. ^ScoDSmic^EeiSPectiyes 1 : 23-40 Fisher, F.M. (1989) "Games Economists Play: RAND w j2UID3l~flf-ESSDSffliSS 20:113-24. View", Fisher, F.M. and J.J. McGowan (1983) Rates of Noncooperative a Return to infer Monopoly "On the Misuse of Accounting Profits", AmeiicaD-SSQDfilDiS BiYisw 73:82-97. Fisher, F.M., J.J. McGowan and J.G.Greenwood (1983) Eflldsd* SpiDdlsdx-aDd-r3u£il3£e^i-EssDfla)ic».AD3lysis-3Dd-l} J iS*-y J .IBtJ (Cambridge: MIT Press) Fisher, and F.M. Development: Imply? " Fisher, and P. , F.M. . Temin (1973) "Returns to Scale in Research What Does the Schumpeterian jQyiD3l-ef-E2li£i£Sl-£CflD2IDy 81 56-70 : and P. Temin (1979) Hypothesis . "The Schumpeterian Hypothesis: Reply", jQy£D3l-3f_E2li£i£3l-.E£0;D2Sy 87:386-9. Kohn, M.G. and J.T. Scott (1982) 27 "Scale Economies in Research and The Schumpeterian Hypothesis", Development: JfiUIDSl-fif-lDr dUStlial-fiCODfllDiCS 30:239-49. Lieberman, M.B. (1987) Empirical "Excess Capacity as a Barrier to Entry: An Reappraisal, JfiUlDSl-j ^LUStlial-SsCDfiSdcS 35:607-27. Lukes, and I. Galnoor S. (1987) NO^LsugbiDg-Ustteii-A^CfilleStiSD (London: Penguin). Q£-Esli£i£5l-Jclses W.Fo and D.J. Ravenscraft (1984) Long, Rates of Return: "The Misuse of Accounting Comment", Ame£isaD„£SSDfiSi£-Beyisy 74:494- 500. Newmark, C. "Do High Prices Indicate Collusion? A Critical (1989) Review of Price-Concentration Studies", North Carolina State University (unpublished) Rodriguez* C.A. (1979) Schumpeterian "A Conmment on Fisher and Temin on Hypothesis", the ZQULU&l*.Q£„EQli£,isal~ES9BQm 87:383-5. Shapiro, C. (1989) "The Theory of Business Strategy", BANQ_Jo-uj-- DSl^Qf«,£S9QQIBiSS 20:125-37. Weiss, ed. L., Press) (1989) CfiDC£DfcI3£iiHL.3DJ3..Erifle . 28 (Cambridge: MIT CONTENTS OF THE HANDBOOK VOLUME PART 1 I DETERMINANTS OF FIRM AND MARKET ORGANIZATION - I Chapter 1 j Technological Determinants of Firm and Industry Structure JOHN C. _ i PANZAR ! ! Chapter 2 The Theory of the Firm BENCT R. HOLM5TROM and JEAN TIROLE - Chapter 3 Transaction Cost Economics OLIVER E. WILLIAMSON Chapter 4 Vertical Integration: Determinants MARTIN K. and Effects PERRY "- PART 2 - ANALYSIS OF MARKET BEHAVIOR ~ Noncooperative Overview - - DREW FUDENBERG Chapter 5 Game Theory and JEAN for Industrial Organization: TIROLE Chapter 6 Theories of Oligopoly Behavior " CARL SHAPIRO " _. Chapter? and Horizontal Merger ALEXIS JACQUEMIN and MARGARET E SLADE Cartels. Collusion, An Introduction and Contents of the Handbook viii I Chapter 8 \ Mobility Barriers and the Value of Incumbency j RICHARD J_ i. GILBERT * Chapter 9 Preuaiion, Monopolization, and Antitrust JANUSZ A. ORDOVER and -{ GARTH SALONER ! -? Chapter 10 ] Price Discrimination HAL R. VAR1AN 1 Chapter 11 i - Vertical Contractual Relations MICHAEL L. ~ KATZ Chapter 12 ' Product Difierentiation B CURTIS EATON and RICHARD G. L1PSEY J 1M -. Chapter 13 \ Imperfect Information in the Product Market E JOSEPH ; - STIGLITZ '...-• » Chapter 14 i The Timing of Innovation: Research, Development, and JENNIFER 4 3 Diffusion REINGANUM F. 1 Chapter 15 The Theory and the Facts of How Markets Clear: Is Industrial Organization Valuable for Understanding Macroeconomics? DENNIS W. CARLTON 4 -3 VOLUME PART 3- II EMPIRICAL METHODS AND RESULTS Imer-Industrv Studies of Structure and Performance RICHARD SCHMA1.ENSEE Chapter 1 Empirical Studies of Industries with Market Power TIMOTHY F. BRESNAHAN Contents of the Handbook ix Chanter IM Empirical Studies of Innovation and Market Structure WESLEY M. COHEN and RICHARD C. LEVIN Chapter 19 ^ An Updated Review Methods CHARLES R. of Industrial Organization: Applications of Experimental PLOTT PART 4 -INTERNATIONAL ISSUES AND COMPARISONS Chaptei 20 Industrial Organization PAUL — -- -i Chapter 21 Internationa! Differences in Industrial Organization "_ ™F t; r RICHARD : f ^^ PART : ; and International Trade KRUGMAN R. 5 E. CAVES - -GOVERNMENT INTERVENTION IN ~ Economic Perspectives on y-Z -_i., A ; . -iTJiir:' "~~_ ROGER G. the Politics of Regulation NOLL _ Chapter 23 Polides Natural Monopolies ——.—~ Optimal RONALD BRaEUTIGAM '•" for R. - . ^»- -...; . .. Chapter 24 Design of Regulatorv Mechanisms and Institutions DAVID P. BARON Chapter 25 The Effects of Economic Regulation PAUL L. JOSKOW and NANCY L. ROSE - - Chapter - THE MARKETPLACE li?0?i£fr Chapter 22 --v;:ir-l' : 2t> The Economics of Health, Safety, and Environmental Regulation HOWARD K. GRUENSPECHT and LESTER B. LAVE 33 3 05 1 Date Due 30 igg'1 5 AUG 26 SEP 24 199 1991 ^> Lib-26-67 MIT LIBRARIES 3 DWl TOAD 0D7D1STS fl