Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium Member Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/minimumwagesonjoOOacem %£J working paper department of economics massachusetts institute of technology 50 memorial drive Cambridge, mass. 02139 WORKING PAPER DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Minimum Wages and On the Job Training Daron Acemoglu Jorn-Steffen Pischke No. 99-25 October, 1999 MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 50 MEMORIAL DRIVE CAMBRIDGE, MASS. 02142 njiASSACHOSETTS INSTITUTE QFTECHW Ol-OGY I NOV 2 G 1999 LIBRARIES WP No.: 99-25 Minimum Wages and On the Job Training By Daron Acemoglu & Jorn-Steffen Pischke ABSTRACT: Becker's theory of human capital predicts that minimum wages should reduce training investments for affected workers, because they prevent these workers from taking wage cuts necessary to finance training. We show that when the assumption of perfectly competitive labor markets underlying this theory is relaxed, minimum wages can increase training of affected workers, by inducing firms to train their unskilled employees. More generally, a minimum wage increases training for constrained workers, while reducing it for those taking wage cuts to finance their training. We provide new estimates on the impact of the state and federal increases in the minimum wage between 1987 and 1992 on the training of low wage workers. We find no evidence that minimum wages reduce training. These results are consistent with our model, but difficult to reconcile with the standard theory of human capital. Minimum Wages and On-the-job Training Daron Acemoglu Jorn-Steffen Pischke MIT MIT * First Version: April 1998 This Version: June 1999 Abstract Becker's theory of human capital predicts that minimum wages should reduce training investments for affected workers, because they prevent these workers from taking wage cuts necessary to finance training. We show that when the assumption of perfectly competitive labor markets underlying this theory is relaxed, minimum wages can increase training of affected workers, by inducing firms to train their unskilled employees. More generally, a strained workers, while reducing training. it minimum wage for increases training for con- those taking wage cuts to finance their We provide new estimates on the impact of the state and federal inminimum wage between 1987 and 1992 on the training of low wage We find no evidence that minimum wages reduce training. These results creases in the workers. are consistent with our model, but difficult to reconcile with the standard theory of human capital. Keywords: Imperfect Labor Markets, General Human JEL Capital, Low Wage Workers, Firm Sponsored Training Classification: J24, J31, J41 thank John Browning and especially Aimee Chin for excellent research assistance, and Joe Richard Carson, Ken Chay, Jinyong Hahn, Lisa Lynch, and Chris Taber for useful comments. Altonji, The first draft of this paper was written while Pischke was a visiting scholar at the Northwestern University /University of Chicago Joint Center for Poverty Research. He is grateful for their hospitality and research support. Acemoglu is grateful for financial support under the National Science Foundation We Grant SBR-9602116. Introduction 1 Much on the minimum wage has focused on of the recent debate cations. The theory important adverse human of effects capital suggests that its employment minimum wages impli- should also have by reducing training and wage growth. In the standard human by Becker (1964), Ben-Porath (1967), and Mincer (1972), a large part of human capital is accumulated on the job, and workers often finance capital theory, as developed A these investments through lower wages. workplace training, as it The negative impact on human in the we In this paper, minimum wage will therefore reduce prevents low wage workers from accepting the necessary wage cuts (Rosen, 1972). minimum wages binding The early empirical literature has confirmed this prediction. capital formation has been an important argument against minds of many economists and policy-makers. revisit the We provide new impact of minimum wages on training. empirical estimates that are quite different from those already in the literature, bringing a new perspective to this debate. We some new also provide theoretical ideas impact of minimum wages on training, which imply that minimum wages the training of low paid workers. a negative effect of Since the standard theory of minimum wages on human training, our evidence enables may on the increase capital predicts an evaluation of the empirical success of the alternative theoretical approaches. The standard theory implications of show that human minimum wages investments. The capital is market frictions, intuition for this result When is that minimum wages previously paid below the no option but new minimum wage. may be more intuition diagrammatically. It A binding less profitable relationship, to lay off workers who were who profitable to increase the productivity of workers, them off. Figure draws the relation between worker minimum wage, lay off the worker. However, with A 1 illustrates this skills, r, is productivity, the rent that the in the absence of such rents, forces the firm to sufficiently high, the firm worker despite the higher wages dictated by the would it employment and wages w(r). The gap between productivity and wages, A, firm obtains. the incentives In contrast, in the presence of labor are already receiving high wages, rather than laying /(r), shift minimum wages make there are no rents in the as in a competitive labor market, the firm has rents, it We from the worker to the employer, and may increase training employ unskilled workers. market based on competitive labor markets. The in noncompetitive labor markets are very different. in the presence of labor for training investments to of minimum also like to increase the productivity of the worker. would like to retain the wage. In this case, the firm Without the minimum wage, the gap between /(r) and w(t) was constant, so there was no point in incurring costs of training. However, with a minimum wage, profits are less at r = than at r = 1. So f(T) f(T)-A C(T) Figure if 1: Training with a the firm can increase do so. In essence, the its Minimum Wage and Employment Rents employee's minimum wage skills to has r made = 1 at a moderate cost, it will prefer to the firm the de facto residual claimant of the increase in the worker's productivity, whereas without the minimum wage, the worker was the residual claimant. This reasoning suggests that a binding more in the skills of their employees. As minimum wage may induce firms to invest in the standard theory, however, the some workers may have been low because they were compensating investments in general skills, therefore, predicts that and the minimum wage would prevent minimum wages human their employers for this. Our approach, reduce the training of workers taking wage cuts to finance their training, while inducing further training for those in their wages of capital investments. In the first part of the paper, who were constrained we outline this theory in greater detail. The broad aggregate trends in the data do not appear in line with the standard the- ory. A variety of evidence, (e.g. DiNardo, Fortin, and Lemieux, 1996; Card and Krueger, 1995), suggests that min- imum wages including the spike in the wage distribution at the are binding for some workers. Therefore, the standard theory minimum predicts that the decline in the real minimirm wage during the 1980s should have increased training for low wage workers. Comparing formal and informal company training among high school dropouts in the Training Supplements of the The CPS, we be the find this not to case. training incidence falls from 15 percent in 1983 to 11 percent in 1991, even though minimum wage was the real value in the lower in 1991 than in 1983 (see Acemoglu and Pischke, 1999a). Nevertheless, other aggregate trends training among low wage workers. may have been In our micro data work, trends and exploit cross-state and region variations in We use the National Longitudinal Survey of Youth This period encompasses a number of state increases in the minimum in 1990 of within state variation in responsible for the decline in how we binding (NLSY) Our empirical results 1987 to 1992. and 1991. Our data therefore contain a Furthermore, the directly affected specifications, suggest that it NLSY is large amount a panel of youths contains a relatively high by minimum wage show almost no evidence minimum wages. Some of our by minimum wage increases, are. minimum wage increases as well as two federal minimum wages. wage workers of low minimum wages for the period and oversamples those from disadvantaged backgrounds, so number control for these aggregate increases. of a reduction in training in response to which look most directly at workers affected minimum wages may have increased worker training slightly, although these positive coefficients are not statistically significant. No for minimum wages on (or small positive) effects of whom the minimum is training investments for workers binding suggest that the adverse effects of on the human capital of low wage workers may be rather contrast with the predictions of the standard theory. an increase in the minimum wage should eliminate minimum wages limited. These findings The standard theory all general training implies that among affected workers, as these investments have to be financed solely by the workers themselves. even harder to reconcile with the standard theory results are therefore NLSY in the waves. is general, as Loewenstein Our evidence be more appropriate and Spletzer (1997) find to if Our most training be the case in later may minimum therefore suggests that models with imperfect labor markets an analysis of training decisions and the impact of for wages on training investments than models based on competitive labor markets. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. The following section discusses the related literature. Section 3 presents a simple theoretical setup where, contrary to the predictions of the standard theory, setup is clearly. special and is In Section 4, increase training investments. This chosen to illustrate the main theoretical contribution of this paper we wages increase training we minimum wages consider a for more general and realistic some workers, while reducing describe our empirical strategy and give an overview presented in Section 6 and Section 7 concludes. it model where minimum for others. In Section 5, of the data. Our results are Previous Literature 2 Previous theoretical discussions of the effect of the minimum wage on training are based on the human capital model of Becker (1964). In the models of Rosen (1972) and Hashimoto (1982), minimum wages reduce training investments, becaiise they prevent workers from taking the wage cuts necessary to finance general Our ments. human capital invest- theoretical result deviates sharply from this conventional wisdom. We build on our previous work, Acemoglu and Pischke (1999b), which showed that a compression in the structure of wages can induce firm-sponsored training. Here, we show that minimum wages overall amount There is shift training investments from workers to firms, and may increase the of training. a small empirical literature investigating the impact of training. Part of this literature focuses minimum wages on on whether minimum wage laws lead to slower observed wage growth in micro data. Both Leighton and Mincer (1981) and Hashimoto and concluded that minimum wage laws lead (1982) have found this to be the case less training. a In our model, the introduction of a small shift of training it of the wage distribution, and More generally, since minimum wages typically create a spike at the appear to reduce age-wage profiles even when they have no fore, it is unsatisfactory to interpret ian (1999) find no effect of minimum wage sectional wage the shifts also found we training. There- find lower Sicil- wage growth minimum wage increase flatter profiles in California after increase. However, they point out that the Californian profile also is cross the previous age-wage profile. This pattern contradicts the consistent with the predictions of our model. changes in the slope of wage to look at the impact of minimum wages on profiles, we find training directly, but are only aware of four previous studies doing this for the US. Leighton and Min- cer (1981) use of states. difficulty of interpreting more compelling on Furthermore, Card and Krueger (1995) compared cross They standard theory, but it still after the 1988 up and does not Given the training, but and minimum wage minimum, they would effect profiles in California before with a number of comparison cut the lower Consistent with this view, Grossberg and minimum wages on workers. when the decline in age-earnings profiles as evidence of reduced investment in general training. for could lead to expenses from workers to firms, and reduce wage growth, even causes an increase in training. tail minimum wage to worker reported data on the receipt of training from the Panel Study Income Dynamic (PSID) and the NLS and find that workers in states with lower wages and therefore a more binding federal minimum wage receive significantly training. effects, Cross state comparisons may be confounded by less the presence of other state however. For example, industrial and occupational composition of employment varies substantially across states, skill and different industries and occupations have different requirements. These considerations suggest that across state comparisons are hard to interpret. Schiller (1994) reports a similar finding using later data from the NLSY by comparing the training incidence of minimum wage workers with those earning higher The evidence from wages. this study is even harder to interpret because worker traits which lead to higher pay are typically also associated with more training. Grossberg and Sicilian (1999) use data from the Employment Opportunity Pilot Project (EOPP) and compare minimum wage workers both to workers earning slightly less ameliorating the problem of worker heterogeneity somewhat. negative effects on training for male effects for minimum wage workers and slightly more, find insignificant insignificant positive women. Leighton and Mincer only analyzed men, although women make up the majority of Some They and minimum wage workers. more recent study by Neumark and of these problems are overcome in a Wascher (1998), who use Current Population Survey (CPS) supplements to compare the impact of minimum wages on training within states using comparisons of workers in 1991 with older workers (who are less likely to young be affected by the minimum wage) and with young workers in 1983. These comparisons assume that state differences in training levels are the same for younger and older workers and remain so over long time periods, which are stringent requirements. They wages on training, but these be too large to be group consists of imum all effects seem to young workers, but not also find negative effects of wage. Their estimates imply that formal training California (a high minimum wage state) was that in than in states this reduction in training is en- due to workers being affected by the minimum wage. Assuming, quite generously, minimum wages affect all (which comprises 30% workers, training is vided by 0.30). workers earning is less lower by over 10 percentage points It is 2.7 percent, minimum among affected than 160 percent of the of workers aged 20-24), this estimate implies that (i.e. 3.2 percentage points di- important to note that the average incidence of training among workers aged 20-24 earning 160 percent of the states by the min- among workers aged 20-24 3.2 percentage points lower which were subject to the federal minimum. Suppose tirely Their treatment sensible. of these workers are affected all minimum much lower than among minimum all or less in low workers aged 20-24 minimum wage (for whom the in- minimum wage to low minimum wage states should have wiped out all training four times among affected workers in these states. This siiggests that the fixed effects assumptions made by Neumark and Washer are quite suspect. cidence is 10 percent). So this estimate implies that introducing California's Minimum Wages and 3 Training: Basic The main wages on training. result of this analysis perfectly competitive labor markets, which introduce clusions of Becker's seminal analysis. Namely, minimum wages can tions, to analyze the impact of we use a simple two-period model In this section, we Theory that plausible deviations from is firm-specific rents, find that change the con- with labor market imperfec- increase investments in general training, and they will increase training for employees previously constrained in their investments, while redxicing We model, start with the simplest are general, all skills petitive labor markets As a for those taking it model which wage cuts illustrates minimum in most human cases, capital to finance their training. our most original result. In this and workers cannot finance their own training. With com- and without minimum wages, there are no training investments. moderate minimum wages increase training unambiguously. result, These simplifying assumptions are unnecessary for our main insights, however, and they hide the potential adverse effects of minimum wages on training. In the next section, consider a less restrictive model where workers are potentially heterogeneous, we can take wage cuts to finance training. wages will increase training for wage cuts lasts for There neutral. start < 1, training Without is two periods, it for those previously taking in period 2 further, to > 4> 1. productivity applies equally in lower output in the all because training is r = To who supply common ability all agents are risk- labor inelastically. normalized to first period We simplify the discussion (no training) and r but with the experience of 1 in that no discounting, and is workers have all also receive training. indivisible, so only training, we assume There 2. 1. We the early career of workers. During this period a worker's productivity 1 as and he can is and a continuum of workers with density n, productivity increases to if 1 with the case in which view period 6 some workers, but reduce to finance training. The world is more general environment, minimum In this Environment 3.1 We and 2. first period and is 1 that (training) are possible. period employment, the worker's Training, in turn, increases his productivity assume that training all firms. = we assume The is general, so this increase in cost of training equal to c > 0. is incurred in terms of As noted above, in this section, training investments have to be financed by the firm. This could be non-contractible, so the firm can renege on its training promise even the worker takes a wage cut to finance his training (see Acemoglu and Pischke, 1999a, for a discussion). We now impose: Assumption 1: — (j) This condition ensures There is > 1 c. that, training is socially beneficial. a continuum 1 of firms competing to hire workers in both periods. firm can hire at most one worker. Firm j has to incur a setup cost k3 We equipment). assume that F(k) with lower support at k has a continuous distribution kj < and upper support at k < 6 +9 (6 buy some (e.g. among is Each firms given by defined below). This smooth distribution enables us to generate a downward sloping demand for labor in period A 1. negative value of k implies that the firm will make profits in the first period even after incurring the required capital cost, for example because it special expertise in this area of business. However, to realize these profits, and to produce. hire a worker k — — oo), > Once so that revenue per worker revenue 5, if <p if suppose that the lower support k minimum wages set up, all firms worker and We is 9. never stop have access to the the worker was employed in the firm and the worker. make take it , is first low enough In the We period with this firm. Therefore, 6 or leave <5, it offers to workers). initial (or equivalently, Since the second-best opportunity of employers capture the whole amount even though workers' productivity if is <5, only paying the higher than this. As will the worker captures a fraction demand for labor. product of labor in the the all f3 < is become crucial, but 1 of this surplus. workers will stay with their initial 2 an alternative assumption which generates a smoothly de— — oo in that case is that the marginal very large when very few workers are employed. This formualtion Decreasing returns at the firm level j'ields 2 is the only deviation from competitive labor Observe also that this mobility cost implies that creasing period, Also, the firm obtains an additional assume Bertrand competition among firms the results would be unaffected 1 first (e.g. 1 they employ an untrained apparent shortly, the presence of rents from the employment relationship employer. needs to in the first period. technology. is 1 if it 5 creates a match-specific surplus to be divided between the workers does not include "market wage" common they employ a trained worker. markets we introduce. employment Their second period revenue a firm-specific productivity increase, and firms all is has some same first The is equivalent of the assumption k period is > results. we could have that a worker who changes a job in the second period incurs a mobility because he has to acquire some costly firm-specific skills before becoming productive. All our results continue to hold with this alternative interpretation. Also, in practice, workers earning close to the minimum wage have high mobility. Our results continue to hold if a fraction s < 1 of workers Alternatively, cost <5, change jobs. Equilibrium can each firm and Minimum Wages Equilibrium Without 3.2 is pay up to willing to is willing to characterized by backward induction. now be pay <fi 1 In the second period, an untrained worker employed by another for 3 Bertrand competition then ensures that for a trained worker. w 2 (NT) = 1, w 2 {T) = <f>. Using the fact that in equilibrium all firm, (1) workers stay with their period employer, first the profits that firm j makes from an untrained and trained worker can be written The first is = (6 - Uj(T) = (9 - kj - Wl + fy -c- Wl + Substituting (1) into — 1 more firms have if it it is + 8 -w2 {T)) trains. and is see that is trained. (see profits is simple: = -c, a trained exactly the increase in his this is the full residual claimant of the profit of the firm is equal Since training costs c in the not optimal for firm to invest in firm-specific rents, because they no incentive to train is U(T) - Tl(NT) The reason and the second period independent of whether the worker Although there are {([> (2) period profits, while the second So the worker increase in productivity due to training, skills. first in the second period, period has to be paid by the firm, + 6 - w 2 (NT)) we immediately (2), contribution to the firm's output. 6, (1 ) the firm loses the training costs worker receives to ) bracket in each expression gives in period 2. that Uj{NT) as: its first employee's do not interact with training, Acemoglu and Pischke, 1999b). Therefore, with competitive labor markets, firms have no incentive to invest in their workers' general skills, even though training is socially desirable. To complete the characterization of the equilibrium, we have to determine first period wages. It is clear that only the n firms with the lowest capital costs will be active. So, the firm with the n th lowest capital cost kn has to Wl A noteworthy feature is zero profits. This gives: kn (3) that compensation can be front-loaded or back-loaded. Front- loading arises because firms anticipate and are =9+8- make 8, the rent they will receive in the second period, willing to bid higher than the worker's current productivity. compensation could be back-loaded is The reason why that firms incur the capital cost only in the 3 first Even though workers do not receive any of the firm-specific rents, there is no labor mobility in equilibrium. Suppose this were not so, then the firm could offer e more than the market wage and convince the worker to stay, so mobility cannot be part of an equilibrium. 8 period, and anticipate to compete harder for We workers in the second period. assume that Assumption +6— 6 2: kn < 1. This limits front-loading and ensures that there without training, a parameter i.e. — the n Now, denoting w < w 2 (NT). th a positive experience is Recall that kn x is premium even not an endogenous variable, but lowest capital cost. employment by E, we can summarize total this analysis (proof in the text): Proposition with kj < 1 There is a unique equilibrium in which there kn are active. All workers are employed, wage given by (3) and the second period So despite Assumption is no training This unwilling to invest in the general employment is full E, is n, skill and wage W2(NT) given by which ensures that training 1, in equilibrium. benefits of training, E= no training and is is all firms receive the first period (1). socially beneficial, there in line with Becker's standard theory; firms are is of their employees as they and workers are assumed unable do not receive any of the to "buy" training. However, there in this decentralized economy, in particular, the level of employment, equal to the labor force, n. The Impact 3.3 of Minimum Wages on Training Now consider the imposition of a binding minimum wage wm > 1- Assumption 2 ensures that w M > 9 + 6 — kn so the minimum wage is also binding in the first period. Since , the demand in this for labor is start minimum wage sloping, the economy. The main question minimum wage We downward will for the focus of this paper, reduce employment however, is how the affects training. by writing wages reasoning to above, (1) and (3) in the presence of change minimum wage laws. With a similar to: = wm, w 2 {NT) = wM w 2 (T) = max {w M ;</>}. ^i (4) , w 2 (T) features the "max" operator because the minimum wage may be greater than the productivity of a trained worker, </>. Profits with less than or and without training now become: = (9-kj -w M )+max[(l + 6-w M );Q] = (0-kj-c-w M + max[(<t> + 6-max{lv M -,<l>})-,Q] Uj(NT) Uj(T) where the ) operate in the second period suppose First, fact that the firm "max" operator takes care of the first wM > if minimum wage the decide not to too high. is so that the second period <P, may wage is equal to the minimum even for skilled workers. In this case, we have - Uj(NT) =(j)-l-c>0, Uj(T) which always positive by Assumption is So 1. in stark contrast to the economy without minimum wages, firms now prefer to train their employees. The firm has to pay the minimum wage irrespective of whether the worker is skilled or not, so the full return to training is captured by the employer. wm < Next, suppose that minimum. Then, the Ilj(T) so that second period - Uj(NT) = w M minimum wage depending on how high the At 4>, More there cannot be any training. minimum wages period. This requires We max {<fi,w M }, If + <f> W2(T) kn 2. 6 c If wm < when and all <p, then all firms with k in both periods <t>, then all 1 + then there c, firms with k there there is then in the so necessarily loses money. down all we have employment this section (proof in the text): to make in the So sure second 4 is is < now training, em-ployed workers are trained, w\ < is k* are active where k* equal to < k** are active is is no now k + are active where equal to E=1— w2 (NT) = 6 + + 6 — c — 2wm < wi if c > w = w 2 (NT) = w M and w 2 (T) = k + = 1 + 6 + 5 — 2tw A / G (k**,kn ), F(k + 6, , F{k**). x , and then we will never be in case 10 <fi, so ). gives "off-the-equilibrium" path wages, no training. Also notice that (J) = iu 2 (iVT) = w M and = 6 + 8 — c — w M & (k*,k n ), trained, where k** E=1— training, = w2 (NT) = E = 1 — F(k*). employed workers are All firms with k (p. employment When 0, + 6 — c. employment in both periods all 4 > wm > Ifl+c< w M < so 3. — = wm, w 2 (T) = = . Employment . If 6 rents. generally, in all this analysis can now state the main result of Proposition 2 1. <fi workers exceeds is. are not high enough to shut wm < for trained This can be positive or negative c. importance of firm-specific this point, notice the second period, a firm which trains pays that - 1 wage similarly for 2. w 2 {T), As in the standard neoclassical model, minimum choose to become inactive. But moderate will = 0, there is firm has to pay minimum wages market imperfections) are crucial training. Firm-specific rents (labor 6 reduce employment in all because some firms (jobs) making close to zero profits before the introduction of cases, the minimum wages no training and employment minimum wages even in the for unskilled for this result. Figure 1 workers and a binding some = and r the employer, as in case 1. may = 1, so The most all minimum wage Training raises of these rents. in the introduction gives the basic intuition. the wage both at r If second period collapses to zero. The reduces the rents the firm receives from the employment relationship. the worker's productivity, and therefore restores increase The minimum wage determines productivity increases from training accrue to interesting case might be case 2. If the minimum wage is some of the proceeds from the training, because the productivity of the trained worker low enough, it induce the firm to sponsor training but the worker receives minimum wage. 5 how minimum wages exceeds the Notice affect wage growth here. In case 1, the induces training, but will lead to a reduction in wage growth (from zero), so inferring whether minimum wages increase training by looking at the slope of the wage profile, as in Hashimoto (1982), first 1 minimum wage — 9 — 8 + k n to not possible. Since is minimum wages period wages, they will typically reduce wage growth (though in case sufficiently large, they may increase 2, if </> is wage growth). Finally, notice that the results contimie to apply minimum increase if w^ is a wage above the legal that the firm has to pay to the worker, due to other imperfections such as bar- minimum creates spillover effects to wages above the minimum, our analysis predicts that firms may also be induced to train the workers affected by these spillovers. In practice, minimum wages appear to create spillover effects (e.g. DiNardo, Fortin and Lemieux, 1996; Lee, 1999), so we expect them to also gaining. Therefore, if an increase influence the training of low in the wage workers earning above the minimum. The Effect of Minimum Wages When Workers Can Pay For Training 4 We now generalize the model of the previous section in two crucial respects: (1) workers can invest in their general training, but some of them are affected by credit constraints; returns to training vary across workers. (2) 5 This is special to the case where the firm has to choose a discrete level of training. If the firm it would never train the worker beyond the point where it has to could choose training continuously, pay above the minimum wage in the second period (see Figure 1). 11 More specifically, there is with support 77,77 second period if A . a distribution of abilities across workers denoted by G(r]) worker with ability untrained, and if 4>rji produces ?/; trained. The 6rji in the first period, cost of training in the independent of c is 77, ability. To we simplify the discussion, — also assume: 1)77 > c. This implies that training is beneficial for all workers, so Assumption 3: (</> we do not have to keep track of whether the worker in question should get training or not. Furthermore, we assume that workers can "buy" training from their employers, so the contractual problems discussed in the previous section are absent. Nevertheless, workers do not have access to perfect credit markets, and need to achieve a certain level of consumption in the distribution of 7 by wage income 4.1 < to A 77. We period. if (7), with of the distribution of income, and 7 first upper support worker i, distribution of level and denote the 7 is independent 7 out of his wage implies that the individual has other assets, so he does not need his meet his consumption obligations. 6 The Decentralized equilibrium without all The 7. 7* for worker needs to have a consumption firms with kj < rest of the setup is unchanged. Minimum Wages Equilibrium Without Once again denote this by minimum wages kn are is straightforward to characterize. Market wages are now conditioned on active. ability as well as training: w 2 {rn,NT) = m w2 U T) = (5) 4>r)i. (j] Writing profits with and without firm-sponsored training as before, we see once again that Hj(T) — Uj(NT) = — c. employees' But now, there can be worker-financed skills. Assumption cut. 3, all workers Therefore, worker i who can Firms therefore have no incentive to invest afford gets training Orji This inequality ensures that the afford to pay for his own More will prefer to get training and only +5- first training. if it training. kn > c Summarizing 6 specifically, by by taking a wage if + 7*. period wage in their is (6) high enough that the worker can this result (proof in the text): This amounts to lexigographic peferences, whereby the worker first tries to meet his minimum consumption level, and then maximizes the sum of consumption in both periods. Introducing a concave utility function for the worker in both periods gives similar results, as it creates a desire for smooth consumption, but complicates the analysis substantially, so we have opted for this simpler formulation. 12 Proposition 3 There is a unique equilibrium in which wages in the second period are given by receive the first-period whom for wage w\{r]i) and (5), = dm + 8 — (6) holds receive the first-period all all firms with workers for < kj whom kn are active, (6) does not hold k n and do not obtain training. wage Wifa) = 6m + 8 — kn — Workers and obtain c training. So in this competitive equilibrium there is investment in training. All training the Becker-type, financed by workers taking a wage cut in the why reason the equilibrium not first-best is is of The only period. first is because some of the workers are credit constrained and cannot invest in training even though doing so would increase total output. also possible to obtain a relatively simple expression for the incidence of training. It is Because of Assumption 3, all workers who can afford it We will invest in training. can write the incidence of training as T= [" H{6n + 8-k n - c)dG{n). Jr) Only workers for whom relative to first period wages which depend on The Impact 4.2 Now consider wm > Also r\. holds obtain training, and this depends on the size of 7 (6) of a binding their ability n. Minimum Wages on minimum wage, i.e. wM Training such that to reduce the cases to be studied, suppose that wm > wA < ,j &V + <fin + 8 — kn and 8 — c, so that second period employment does not collapse. Similar reasoning to above immediately gives second period wages as: w 2 {m,NT) = max{w A/ ,77;} w 2 (Vi,T) = (7) ma.x{w M ,(j)m} minimum wage on investment in skills. Some of the workers previously financing their own training are now unable to do so. For example, consider worker % such that 7* < Om + 8 — kn — c < w^j that is worker i was financing his training by taking a wage cut, to a level now below the minimum. Clearly, Let us start with the adverse effect of the , the minimum wage some workers. 7 This training is If 8 = prevents this. 7 So a binding minimum wage reduces training —so that we are in competitive labor markets — , this is for the only without a training subminimura. In our model, as in the standard Becker model, introducing subminima increases training. 13 impact of the minimum wage on minimum wage the eliminates In addition, however, the training; since all training all training among general in this economy, is affected workers. minimum wage induces firms to train their low skill workers > Orj, + 6 — kn — c, that minimum wage. It is then as in the previous section. Consider a worker with y, who could not afford to buy training before the the analysis in the previous subsection, that Similarly, even invest in training. wM > if when w A! < 4>r) wM > ^ + c, a worker from clear, ^i, then the firm would if u is prefer to the firm prefers to provide training. Therefore, as in the previous section, labor market rents and minimum wages induce employers to invest in general training of some workers. formally, as in the previous section, a worker receives firm-sponsored training More if wm > (since > <jn\i r}i + c, if Vi the trained worker's wage Alternatively, the worker will obtain training minimum wage. This happens the is c is ( at the when he +8- new equilibrium k* minimum, (8) is still satisfied). finances himself, despite the it - c> ma,x{w M 7J (9) , cutoff capital cost. These observations provide some insight into the effects of minimum wages on train- induce firms to train their workers, but prevent workers' Minimum wages ing. 8) if 9rji where k* + own To understand the whole picture, however, we need to charthe equilibrium fully, which is a little more involved than before. We have investment in training. acterize to determine rium level of first period wages for workers of different employment when a minimum wage is abilities, and find the equilib- binding. However, since wages are not central to our focus, we only give these in Appendix 1, first period and only determine equilibrium employment here. The key such that observation all kj < that there exists, once again, a cutoff level of capital cost, is k* will be Furthermore, given the additive relation between active. firm and worker heterogeneity, firm profit, II,-, from hiring any worker to hire (otherwise, his period 1 wage). rji all firms would So let i, j, if so that each firm want to make active, has to hire the is exactly the indifferent more profitable worker, pushing up us write the profit that a firm makes from a worker of talent IT,- (77O = max {II, { Vi , NT) , II, fa T) } , , where = total about which worker as: Uj{r)i,NT) same {erii -w 1 {rii ,NT)-kj + ) 14 {'qi + 8-max{w M ,r li }), Uj{rii, = T) after substituting (7). 77, - (6r)i AT) 101(77,-, not receiving training, and ing training. These for all first - kj denotes the + c) {<j)t)i < k* should To is make , period wage for a worker receiv- first period wages have to adjust to ensure that Hjfa) is — profits equal to k* characterize the equilibrium, Clearly kj. we need make n j* (t?*) = where kj* = k*, (077* - 77*, - wM - k* and we have used the Uj = k* — kj zero profits, so a firm with 101(77,, .) > wm by to determine k*. Since the binding, the marginal worker has to be employed at the the ability of the marginal worker as = the equilibrium cutoff capital cost. This ex- pression follows by noting that, the firm with k* will kj + 8- max {w M 0^}) period wage for a worker with ability first T) denotes the 101(77,, hired in equilibrium, where k* i - twifa, T) minimum. 8 law. minimum wage Hence, defining we must have c) + + 8 - max {w AI: &]*}) = (^77* worker at the fact that a 0, minimum wage in the second period necessarily receives training. Hence: k* The number = (6 + 0)77* + 8 — c — w M — max {it; a/, (pn*} of workers employed, of active firms, i.e. to the firms with k [1 where k* is as given by (10). while the right hand side by the (77*, fact that those with i.e. G and < has to be equal to the number 77*, Hence: k*. - Gtf)] n = Notice that the F(k*) left (11) hand side is strictly decreasing in 77*, boundary conditions implied is increasing. Together with the F are distribution functions, this ensures a unique solution k*). We can now summarize the results (proof in the Proposition 4 There k* is given by (10) The and is (11). _ F(k*) Workers with G(w M - 77* This would imply r\i c) - ??, > f) = [w^j level G(n*) + f who has + c + k* — is F{k*) where [1 now: - G(77( 7 ))] dHfr) lower talent but low 7, so that he can pay /9. However, 77 is unambiguously greater 6} obtained below, confirming that the marginal worker has to be at the 15 E= satisfying (8) or (9) receive training. among employed workers Alternatively, the marginal worker could be one for his training. text): a unique equilibrium with employment incidence of training rpMW than > 77 (10) . minimum wage. where is 17(7) = max {tuyi//</>; explained by noting [max{w M j} — , that, 8 + who have workers k* + c] j9} The second . terra in brackets high enough ability such that (8) does not hold could potentially finance their training, but in that case, they need to have sufficient funds in the credit constraints. first period, Therefore, i.e. low enough minimum wages 7, so that they are not affected by increase training for workers who were previously unable to finance their training, and have second period wages close to the minimum. They reduce who were financing their own training, and above the minimum so that it is not in the interest training for workers have second period wage sufficiently of their employers to provide As them with training. MW the above discussion suggests T could be smaller than or greater than T, so in this more general model, minimum wages could increase still employed. More or reduce training own T those they will increase training for some workers, especially specifically, those at low wages affected by credit constraints, and reduce cuts to finance their among training. it for those taking wage This discussion also suggests that we expect T MW minimum wages to increase training), when most workers are credit constrained, and when there are many workers with abilities between 77* and wm — c, for whom minimum wages lead to firm-sponsored training. Finally, we have so far compared an economy without minimum wages to one with a binding minimum wage. The results of comparing two economies with different levels of minimum wages are similar. The only difference is that in a model with a binding but low minimum wage, some workers with low values of 7^ are already prevented from paying for their own training. So increasing an already binding, but relatively low, minimum wage is perhaps more likely to increase training than introducing one in an economy without minimum wages. Whether this happens is an empirical question, and we will now provide some new evidence on this. to be greater than (i.e. Empirical Strategy and Data 5 minimum wage was unchanged between 1981 and 1990, but various states imposed their own minima above the federal level during the late 1980s. While minimum The federal wages were rather uniform across states before 1987 and after 1991, there was substantial dispersion between these dates. statutory minimum wages We use on in the We US will exploit this variation. Table 1 displays the states over this period. two complementary approaches to identifying the impact of minimum wages training. The first one, which we find most compelling, looks at the training of minimum wage. The second approach looks at the relation between training and a measure of how binding workers who are directly affected by an increase 16 in the state or federal minimum wage the This latter approach across regions. is most is closely related to the empirical work in the previous literature, and therefore serves as a check on the robustness of our results. Empirical Specification 5.1 The most direct way to look at workers is minimum wage on training outcomes by changes in the minimum wage. In to estimate the impact of the who are actually affected order to illustrate the approach, consider the following regression equation = amw rirt where rTit is like and individual t. lt t effects, i (12) irt in region r at time and x it are other individual d t, t , vr One measure to the for mw minimum wage Schiller (1994) this strategy minimum wage binds for individual i mw in region r at would be whether the actual wage of an individual irt for the region and Grossberg and and characteristics education, age, gender, and information about the job an individual holds. a measure of whether the is + j3'x + d + v r + & + e a measure of training for individual are time, region, fj,i irt is irt time close and time period. This has been the approach of Sicilian (1999) using cross-sectional variation. But. has the problem that other, possibly unobserved, person characteristics which are correlated with the individual's wage tend be correlated with training will also receipt. We therefore difference eq. (12) to obtain Arirt = aAmw irt + P'Ax + Ad + Ae irt it Changes in training should now be t (13) . related to changes in whether a worker is affected by minimum wage. As a measure of Amw irt we use a dummy variable which indicates that the minimum wage increased from one year to the next, and the worker earned below the new minimum wage in the base year. This measure captures workers who are directly affected by a change in the minimum wage, similar to Card's (1992) analysis of employment effects. The measure relies purely on the variation of the minimum wage and base period wages, but not changes in individual wages, which may be correlated with when a worker received training. Our analysis will focus on individuals who do the not move between states because moving would also confound AmiVi rt with behavioral effects. Therefore, differencing has eliminated the region effect in eq. (13). Although we wage most on eq. feel directly, that this analysis of eq. (13) exploits variation of the hence gives the most reliable (12) to study the impact of the level of 17 results, previous studies the minimum wage on minimum have relied training. To make our more comparable results will in this case We or region. t, measure how binding the minimum wage w™. What matters The same and regions, which a given effects in different regions wage level of the wT therefore just parameterizes the An level. time minimum wage wage regions than minimum wage in high median wage wage For this purpose, we is a measure of the location of older workers) over the whole minimum wage itself, and and w™/w r measures how high the wage distribution, wage distribution. Notice that level, we are not using and might create a training incidence were also cyclical. obvious choice for the regions are states, since minimum wages However, the wage distribution also varies within vary at the state states, so that the relative minimum wage measure can be defined for smaller regions. Apart from states, we two other measures. One partitions states into SMSAs and non-SMSA parts as This region definition. between large SMSAs wT is New York we Appendix City) rural areas in a state (like upstate When we 2. The second wages of male workers age 35-54 if use states or these smaller regions, states, if i.e. is should be more affected by a given tend to earn less wr uses the average of the the respondent the respondent is more dispersion regional measures federal we 1 we show wage by only 0.055 in in this male, and of the median minimum wage than men because the relative measure (which use below) than in the minimum wage median female. This measure exploits the minimum wages male medians by state and year over the sample period. substantially oiir than men. In the right hand panel of Table is New "region" definition distinguishes between the in the state wages of female workers age 35-54 women and distinguish 136 regions. Details on the construction male and female wage distribution within women our the average of the median wages of male workers age 35-54 in each year between 1987 and 1992. fact that use us exploit the often substantial variation in wage levels In total, of these are available in for lets (like York) in the analysis. measure is. allowed to have different is which would move with the business cycle at the regional if in region r at should not be affected by the relative to the region's spurious correlation a particular state in the depending on their average wages. sample period. This measure w rt in low , is is would not be captured by w™. Therefore, we prefer distribution in region r (the minimum wage how binding minimum wage measures w™/w r where w r consider relative of the is more workers affects this source of variation specifications in however, for the theory, minimum federal directly, the variable by using simply the actual minimum wage start undertake analysis also Rather than indicating affected workers of the levels equation. mwirt we to these previous studies, New is still minimum wage increases between 1989 It is using the apparent that there coarser than the other itself. and 1991 raised the For example, the relative minimum Jersey but by 0.085 in Arkansas, both states without a state 18 minimum wage above the federal minimum wage measure leverages level in 1989. This illustrates the increase in the federal how the scaling of the minimum wage across states with different wage distributions. There are a number of practical problems and (12) most training to all For example, training (13). is in implementing the estimation of equations not easily defined at a point in time. Because a short period of time, we will define rrit as referring spells only last for incidents of training within a single year. Thus, Trit will be received any training during the year, and 1 the individual if otherwise. In the differenced equation (13), the dependent variable takes on the values -1, 0, and 1. We will estimate the models and the inclusion as linear probability models, facilitating differencing of fixed effects in the levels version. Looking at a time period as long as a year has may change its drawbacks. The within a year. In order to minimize the impact of this, minimum wage we look at periods of minimum wage 12 months starting in April and ending in March. Both federal increases minimum wage increases also took effect on April 1, but many did not. Whenever the minimum wage changed during the year, we use an employment weighted average of the minimum wage in effect during the in 1990 and 1991 went into Some effect April 1. state year. The covariance matrix of the error term in eq. average structure at the individual Huber estimator, which covariance estimator the minimum wage is is level. robust to arbitrary cluster effects at the individual is variable, only varies at the region composed of an individual , level while is There is dard errors for this error structure. both an individual level component Aj, level we use indi- = A 2 + v rt +£r it, a region*time component uncorrected across individuals, regions, and time we are estimating a no straightforward way to calculate consistent stan- We extend the standard Huber estimator to allow component and a region*time component This estimator seems to perform well in practice in samples of our results of This therefore overstate the precision of Notice that the error E rit will be heteroskedastic, since linear probability model. for may and year Suppose the error term has the form e rit v rU and a component £rit which periods. level. consistent in this case but not efficient. In (12), the key regressor, the estimates (Moulton, 1986). the error order moving first We therefore estimate standard errors with the vidual level data. Conventional standard errors i.e. have a (13) will some small Monte Carlo experiments 19 in Appendix 3. in the error term. size. We report the The Data 5.2 Our data on The NLSY training is come from the National Longitudinal Survey a panel of youths aged 14 to 21 in 1979. because siiitable for this project it above the minimum wage interviewed in the set of questions work likely to Card and Krueger, We 1995). from 1987 to 1992, years of it is particularly oversamples those in jobs at or slightly will follow the cohorts significant changes in state and NLSY asked a consistent about on-the-job training during the previous year. The information minimum federal NLSY (see Youth (NLSY). This dataset samples young workers, and from disadvantaged backgrounds, who are more of wages. During the 1988 to 1992 surveys, the about the training includes length and type of the program, costs of the training were paid for and whether the site, by the employer or someone else. The explicit first set of training questions in 1988 refer to a longer time frame than the questions in subsequent years, because no similar data were collected in 1987. In 1993, the module on training in the survey was expanded substantially and the survey switched from paper and pencil to computer assisted interviewing. We use some data from the information on training during the April 1992 to 1993 survey to complement March 1993 year. There were some other minor additions to the training questions before 1993 as well. The sequence "I of questions would now like to on training begins with a lead-in stating ask you about other types of schooling and training you may have had, excluding regular schooling we have already talked about. Some sources of occupational training programs include government training programs, business schools, apprenticeship programs, vocational or technical institutes, correspondence courses, company or military training, seminars, and adult education courses." This suggests that respondents will mostly report relatively formal training programs and neglect other sources of informal on-the-job training, a suspicion which has been substantiated by Loewenstein and Spletzer (1999) using the more detailed training data in the is NLSY starting in 1993. While this may be a drawback, this limitation of the data pervasive in this literature. We are only interested in training programs which take place in firms, or are spon- sored directly by the employer, not in courses taken by individuals outside work on their own initiative or government sponsored training programs. the following forms of training as "employer related training" : We therefore classify any training the respondent gives as venue an apprenticeship program; formal company for which training; or seminars or training programs at work run by someone other than the employer; or 20 if the respondent classifies the training as on-the-job training or work experience; or the employer paid for the training (even though we do not interpret the answer to this We question as the employer necessarily bearing the investment costs). a training programs as employer related ment program. 9 if if do not classify the training was partly paid for by a govern- For each training program we record the start date as reported on the 1988 to 1993 surveys. date If this and 1993, we assign the training falls within an April to March period between 1987 We to this particular year. treat observations with a 10 missing start date as missing. We do not use any information on the job or employer in the estimation directly. However, training often takes place when individuals start new jobs and increases may affect turnover turnover in some fashion. and Hence, hiring. it minimum wage seems important to control for We include a dummy variable for whether a respondent started any new job within a particular year from information in the work history module of the data. We limit likely to our sample to workers weighted by the in the analysis, but NLSY it DC all a group most of blacks, Hispanics The results are Individuals living in the District had a plethora minimum wage rules, minimum wage. Our basic of different who report a wage at the interview for the current and who were employed for at least one month during the workers for the past year, according to the information in the work history module. to those with valid less, the military subsample. hard to define a sensible overall measure of the sample includes and we drop sampling weights throughout. Columbia are excluded, because making 12 years of education or We use the oversamples be affected by the minimum wage. and poor whites of who have wage information. For the who move between states. addition, we use the 1987 to 1993 11 We (13) we year sample also restrict the analysis using eq. year also include individuals In calculate the relative to do median wage for this files even for smaller areas within states. For example, each region-year is cells are that small, The most common government program, JTPA, by minimum wage The NLSY We cell has and the 274. involves wage subsidies up to 50 percent if trainees program is unlikely are placed with private sector employers. Hence, the incidence of training under this 10 CPS. rotation groups are large enough on older male workers, but few median number of observations to be affacted of the workers age 35 to 54 from this data source to construct the minimum wage measure. The CPS outgoing at least 27 observations 9 outgoing rotation group legislation. also provides information on the length of training. training directly, because of the frequency of missing values but We we checked do not use the duration of that our results are robust to excluding very short training spells. n The NLSY CPS wage may refers to this wage measure refer to a prior job if as the CPS wage the respondent 21 is because of the CPS style question. not working at the time of the interview. The Empirical Results 6 Table 2 reports means of some demographic indicators NLSY. least samples from the for the three All samples include respondents with 12 years of schooling or less working in at Since young adults one month during the year. still obtain additional schooling in samples changes over time. The non-mover sample this age range, the the unrestricted sample. About 20 from differs little to 25 percent of each sample report having started a new job during the calendar year. While this includes secondary and temporary jobs, the number matches who age group CPS. This same relatively closely the fraction of low education workers in the month report tenure of 12 or less on their current job in the relatively high rate of job starts reflects the large turnover January 1991 among young, low skilled workers. to The average nominal hourly wage in almost $10 in 1992. While a number less, as shown the basic sample rises from about $7.50 in 1987 of sample members earn the minimum wage in the last row, the majority of respondents earn far wage. These samples therefore include many workers whose wage by the minimum. These higher wage workers differenced analysis. When we effectively is above the members minimum not directly affected form our control group in the look at the impact of the level of the the other hand, most of the sample minimum are not directly affected wage, on by the minimum wage, a problem which has also affected previous studies. In order to address this we also use a low wage sample, defined as workers employed at a wage which percent of the federal minimum sample. These low wage workers include more school dropouts is The or less in the previous year. the basic descriptive statistics for this sample, which last women and blacks. The number and do not grow substantially over the sample period, due to the sample spillovers resulting much more from it. likely to of high much lower selection. row We Since a larger fraction of these workers are directly affected find larger negative sample. Table 3 reports sample means for some of the key variables in our regressions. first 150 be actually subject to the minirmim wage or by the minimum wage, according to standard theory we should effects in this is size of the basic only slightly higher. Average wages in this sample are think of this group as issiie two columns give about a third the is which of the table reports the incidence of training, only exception is 1987, where the measured incidence due to the fact that the training questions were first is much is around 10 percent. lower. This is The The presumably asked on the 1988 survey so that the questions referring to 1987 had a longer recall period than for later years. There also a small spells of 1 or drop in 1991, possibly due to the recession. day or less, If we exclude very short the incidence drops to about 7 to 8 percent. 22 is training Our measure of the minimum wage in a region minimum wage. In Table 3, we the higher of the state and the federal report the average minimum wage minimum wage was 1987, the average had state minima above the further to 3.51 in 1989, when only 3.36, of 3.35. in the California state due to new minimum wage laws Oregon, Washington, and Pennsylvania. minimum, and levels. increases among them deviation across respondents reaches a high of 29 cents in this year, indicating a substantial minimum wage to 3.44 It rises in other states, The standard In New England Alaska, and the minimum wage federal mainly reflecting the increase in 1988, state in a year across all These averages are weighted by the residence of our sample population. regions. states is amount of variation in This variation drops substantially in 1990 and 1991, when the two federal increases raise the minima in those states which had not taken action before. The averages wages of 3.80 and of 3.87 and 4.26 are now only New 4.25. In 1992, Jersey raises slightly its above the federal minimum minimum wage to 5.05, increasing the spread again. For our analysis of equation (13), by the minimum wage. The minimum wage report a first initial four different measures for workers affected one includes in a year prior to a wage below the we use all who earned workers minimum wage increase. minimum. The top panel less This includes workers of Table 3 sample were affected by minimum wage increases due to the increase in the California slightly more workers, but a wage. The large fraction of workers (7 minimum wage in the base year. It these workers should be considered affected or not. universal during the time period mostly measurement error. workers. Excluding An Lee (1999), for we state increases in 1989 affect The second measure is is excludes not completely clear whether Minimum wage coverage was fairly the first measure which includes these fraction of affected workers about in half in each year. minimum may also affect the and our model then predicts that example, finds large spillover during our sample period, and mostly consider, so that these reports prestimably reflect We therefore prefer them cuts the increase in the spillover effects, 12 in 1988, and 9 percent, respectively) only affected by the federal increases in 1990 and 1991. workers below the who shows that about 1.4 percent of the minimum than the new we wages of higher wage workers via their training should effects we affected. from the minimum wage changes report similar results below in Table investigate whether spillovers affect our results, be 5. also included workers In order to who initially minimum in the affected group. We choose alternatively 150 This yields about two to four percent and 130 percent of the new minimum wage. times as many affected workers as our original measure. The bottom panel of Table 3 reports the relative minimum wage measures, i.e. the minimum wage divided by the earned above the new 12 It is also possible that respondents receiving tips do not include these in the 23 wage measure. median state, regional, or state/gender the federal and 1991. Regression results for the differenced version of the first Apart from the minimum wage any linear a effects of age), full set model are displayed on these covariates are quite more of time dummies and variables for the change in high new This few workers who effect is imprecisely ifications we mum the is able to pick on the variable coefficients effect of raising estimated because there are up the expected variation for affected minimum wage on likely to receive training and These estimates are sensible and demonstrate estimated quite precisely. that the training variable The coefficients acquire a high school degree or equivalent during the sample period. Workers starting a new job are 3 percentage points more this effect is The job. High school graduates are 7 percentage points sensible. likely to receive training. in Table the regressions include a constant (capturing effect, school graduation status and for whether the worker took a (1), measures Results Using Affected Workers 6.1 4. in these minimum wages and over time reflect again the increases in various state increases in 1990 The changes for older workers. in the data. workers are directly interpretable as the the incidence of training. The four different spec- correspond to four different definitions of the "affected" variable. In column define all as affected. workers whose wage in the previous year The is below the current mini- minimum wage point. The effect is point estimate indicates that being affected by a increase raises the probability of receiving training by 1 percentage not significant, however, and a 95 percent confidence interval includes negative effects as large as 1.8 percentage points. The the previous minimum as discussed above, refer to column specification in it in the is (1) reporting wages below base year as affected. While we prefer this specification, possible that some of the wages below the initial minimum uncovered workers. Therefore we exclude these workers from the affected group The in the second column. results are not very different. specifications allows spillovers of the wages. who were counts workers If we redefine the affected group as workers 150 or 130 percent of the zero effects of minimum wage on new minimum wage minimum wages on training, in Neither of the previous workers with slightly higher whose previous wage was within columns (3) and but these specifications (4), we may find basically count too many workers as affected. The training question that we use includes very short training programs, and important to ensure that our results are not sensitive to eliminating these short With this purpose, we it is spells. also repeated these regressions excluding training spells lasting 24 a single day or from 0.004 We obtain less. for the measure slightly smaller coefficients for affected workers, ranging column in the measure in column (2) to -0.013 for (4), while the standard errors were basically unchanged. Overall, the results contrast sharply with the predictions of the standard theory. The standard model affected is predicts that by a minimum wage affected general training should be eliminated for workers increase. The average incidence of training in the sample may not be the right baseline, since it includes higher wage not affected by the minimum wage. Average training incidence for workers by a minimum wage increase in the following year is 5.2 percent for the measure about 10 percent, but workers all this of affected workers used in column (1). The 95 percent confidence interval is consistent with declines in training as large as 1.8 percentage points. This means we can reject minimum wage the eliminates more than a that. third of the training in this group. Similar conclusions are obtained for the other measures of affected workers. Since according to the standard theory, an increase in the eliminate all general training with the standard theory if among affected workers, our results could only most training (1997) find in later waves of the NLSY 63 percent of be consistent But Loewenstein and Spletzer is specific. another 14 percent of training programs, most of the They minimum wage should all training to be general, skills in are reported to be general. We find similar results with other datasets as well. and can therefore reject the minimum wages should wipe out all However, we cannot rule out that minimum wages simply strongest implication of the standard theory that training for affected workers. reduce training for affected workers, without completely eliminating results indicate a substantially smaller effect of estimates in the previous literature. Results Using 6.2 While the results in our methodology minimum wages on effects of somewhat from the previous this section also includes workers sample differs little who move from minimum wages on effect it is For example, as we minimum wages reduce existing amount many In this section literature. The sample we use we in state to state between interviews, but workers not directly affected by the natural to worry about whether on the earnings of workers 13 training, from the non-mover sample. Recall that this sample contains wage, so training than the Minimum Wage Changes present alternative results based on the regression equation (12). this Nevertheless, our 13 Table 4 indicate no adverse differs it. will have a significant in this sample, since in the absence of such a finding, discussed in Section training minimum wages minimum 2, among workers Neumark and Wascher's (1998) estimates imply that close to the minimum wage by much more than the of training. 25 we may expect no effect minimum wages on on training incidence training, we Before turning to the impact of sample on the real value of the minimum wage and a in this dummies. The feature of the results first are affected by changes in the have an minimum wage on therefore look at the effect of the Table 5 displays quantile regression estimates of the real wage of workers actual wages. effect full set of year and state that low quantiles of the wage distribution is minimum wage, which shows that minimum wages do on the wages of low paid workers. So according to the standard theory, on there should be a negative effect A either. training. minimum wage raises wages of the 10 th percentile worker which may seem small. The second column in the table repli- one dollar increase in the in the NLSY by 37 cents, cates these results with a comparable sample using the with similar results, CPS outgoing rotation groups, showing that these results are not particular to the NLSY. There why the coefficients even at the low quantiles should be less certainly much measurement error in the wage reports of workers, are various reasons to expect than one. There is biasing these coefficients down. Furthermore, Table 2 revealed that even workers at the 10" percentile will typically earn above the old 1 may they not receive the full increase when the minimum wage already, and therefore minimum wage goes up. Nevertheless, t/l the results in Table 5 show that workers as high as the 30 percentile of the wage dis- tribution also be may be affected by minimum wage changes, and therefore their training may affected. Table 5 also shows that there are many workers in this sample by minimum wages. This means that our estimates of training biased towards zero. in the lower less effects will tend to be than 150 percent of the federal in the previous year, corresponding roughly to the percentile of the original sample. actually affected are not affected This motivates our strategy to compare our basic results to those wage sample using only workers earning minimum wage who workers up to the 30 th This sample more closely approximates the workers by the minimum wage or by spillovers resulting from the minimum. If the results in the larger sample are biased towards zero, then the more restrictive sample should lead to more extreme estimates. Table 6 presents our regression results for the incidence of training on the wage and relative minimum wage and without time and region measures. 14 If effects present four sets of regressions with fixed effects, as well as individual instead of region fixed effects. mies We for blacks, Hispanics, females, 14 minimum one specification which includes Other covariates in the regressions are dum- high school graduates, and whether the individual makes it less likely that the individual will be trained in the future, the individual model may be problematic. However, in our sample, training is positively correlated over time. training this year 26 started a new job during the year, and a linear variable for age. 15 demographic covariates are again Contrary to the typical finding in this low new more in the literature, individual effects are controlled If is no region or time and positive to have may more simply industrial mean and time higher receive less training, column wage increased by 81 cents reflects that states differ, for we in real terms from 1989 to 1991. We column mation, which is first Rows 3 if we The This increase led to about One reason for this minimum wage To will is that the minimum wage have very different exploit this information, inforeffects we next turn measures. results where we divide the minimum wage by The specification minimum wage measure in a moderate negative In row 5 below, where we coefficient. results, this coefficient is which exploits primarily column (2) which are much now even significant. This specification But the closer to zero, indicate again that the wage measure was picking up across region results in use more detailed regions compares most closely to the approach of Leighton and Mincer (1981). (4) or (5), Un- 2. and are consistent with both the cross region variation in the columns minimum federal look at the low wage sample in row the median wage of older males in the state. in control for state two rows does not exploit a relevant part of the and 4 of the table report and obtain more precise when we 16 that a given level of the minimum wage terms of their find similar results including individual fixed depending on how high wages are in a region. to the relative in (5). positive effects. are using in the or a small negative effect on training. fortunately, these results are very imprecisely estimated variable example in general, this This latter specification, which we prefer, suggests that (4). more negative and when strongest is minimum wage measure with higher minimum wages tend minimum wage measures below effects instead of state effects in substantial negative men In fact, the positive result in column (2) vanishes structure. 0.6 percentage points less of training. are training as and workers starting surprisingly, this latter effect that high and low wage states minimum wages have The estimates much Because these states tend to have higher wages at the relative effects in receive as for. This and occupational when we look women effects are included, the effect of the significant. training. Not training. on the coefficients Minorities receive significantly less training. sensible. wage group. High school dropouts jobs receive The results minimum differences in training incidence. We feel 15 Curvature of the age profile is empirically unimporant for the small age range in the sample, we do not include higher order terms. 16 In the specification with individual fixed effects, only the region*time clusters remain in the error term. The standard Huber estimator allowing for these clusters is consistent. Our standard errors in therefore column (5) are therefore the most reliable. Interestingly, the standard errors variable do not differ substantially from those in column 27 (4). on the minimum wage that the estimates including time and region or individual effects are most reliable. Some of the time variation of our training measure is likely due to the change in the survey questions and cyclical variations. Differences in training incidence across regions may and occupational compositions. The negative reflect differences in industrial of the minimum wage wage regions tend to have which are the most training. column in more reliable, (2) is therefore likely to reflect training. The effects of and region effects, minimum wages on 17 In order to interpret the magnitudes of the estimates this relative relative the fact that higher results including time do not indicate any negative effect and confidence intervals using measure of the minimum wage, return to the bottom panel of Table minimum wages To gauge the impact 3. The increased by about 5 to 6 percentage points from 1989 to 1991. of the federal increases, more it is only for the states that were subject to the federal useful to calculate the minimum in 1989. minimum wage measures by the federal increases raised the relative means For these states, 0.07 using the male and by 0.08 using the state/gender medians. This means that state or region medians, a 95 percent confidence interval for the estimates in column (4) using state medians for the unrestricted sample excludes negative changes in training of 2.9 percentage points or larger in response to the federal increases. It the findings by Neumark and Wascher that the California state increase between 1989 points among young workers age as our sample. We instructive to compare this result to (1998), for example. Their point estimates imply minimum wage and 1991) is (which was similar in magnitude to the federal led to a decline in formal training of 3.2 percentage 20-24, a group with a similar average training incidence can reject a decrease of this size for our sample. Looking at the low wage sample, we obtain a virtually identical point estimate when we include time and state effects. point estimate is When we include individual instead of state effects, actually positive now. Thus, the results with the low wage sample do not indicate that the estimates for the basic sample were attenuated. are unchanged of the when we look median wage. than the states. at the minimum wage measure In rows 5 and We 6, These conclusions scaled by alternative values we use the median wage for 136 regions smaller find small positive point estimates for the basic sample, slightly larger estimates in the low wage sample. To the degree is positive, rather Our theory predicts that more precise than the state results, however. minimum wages reduce employment, but our samples focus on employed When we use a sample of respondents including non- workers, workers. This might bias our estimates up. we actually find slightly minimum than negative. The within estimates using these smaller regions turn out not to be any 17 and that these results indicate attenuation in the basic sample, they suggest that the actual effect of wages on training the more postive results, however. 28 The wage two rows last Table 7 present results scaling the results for the basic Controlling for time However, this result less if we precise, and state effects, we now not replicated is because there more is The variation in the measure For the low wage sample, the results are a bit different. exploiting gender differences. earned the median sample are again rather similar to the previous measures. now somewhat more In addition, minimum wage by workers in the same state and of the same gender as the respondent. The for older results are in find a negative effect for when we wage sample tighten the low than 130 percent of the federal is wages. control for individual effects instead. further to include only workers minimum wage much more in the previous year, We a coefficient of 0.097 (with a standard error of 0.294). estimate for the low wage sample minimum likely we who find conclude that the negative an indication of the sampling variation of these estimates rather than evidence that the estimates for the basic sample are attenuated. Concluding Remarks 7 Standard theory of pact of minimum human capital makes an unambiguous prediction regarding the im- wages: training should decline for affected workers, because workers finance the provision of the general minimum wages prevent this. We component of training by taking lower wages, and show that this conclusion is not robust. In labor markets where employers obtain rents from the employment relationship, the theory has quite different implications regarding the impact of While minimum wages reduce training also for some workers encourage firm-sponsored training and increase minimum wages on training. as in the standard theory, they human workers. Therefore, our model predicts offsetting effects of capital investments for other minimum wages on training, minimum wages increasing training investments. In the second part of the paper, we provided some new empirical evidence on the impact of minimum wages on training. Focusing on workers actually affected by minimum wage changes we find no evidence that minimum wages reduce training. In addition, we can reject negative estimates of the magnitude previously found in the literature. and is even consistent with This result is not an artefact of our methodology, since we find comparable results us- ing specifications which are negative estimates states. more when we simply similar to previous studies. regress training real obtain the most minimum wage within However, these estimates are also the most imprecise, and therefore the least informative. When we rely on relative minimum wage the differential impact of the changes in the federal effects on the We on training. We measures, thus better exploiting minimum wage, we find no negative probe these results by comparing estimates from a larger base- 29 line sample to those from a smaller sample of low wage workers. resembles what other researchers have used, in that by the minimum wage. minimum wage on If includes many baseline sample workers unaffected these unaffected workers simply obscure the impact of the training, low wage workers, but this it The is we should find systematically more negative effects using not the case, once again suggesting that binding minimum wages do not reduce training. A drawback of oirr a much analysis is that we only focus on rather formal training. larger part of on-the-job learning in low plausible that formal and informal training are not shed any direct light on the receipt of more extensive questions on informal a period with little aging so that fewer less wage jobs is more Possibly informal. positively related, but our analysis does formal training. training starting in 1993. The NLSY introduced Unfortunately, this minimum wage changes, and the NLSY sample workers receive the minimum in the 1990s. dispersion in 30 It is is is also Appendix 8 Wages With Worker First Period 1: Heterogeneity First, take a wM > satisfying ii l In contrast, we could have worker in the second period if = k* Then, n,-^) = IT/ — w^ i is if r)i if (8) and (9) G (rji Some of the level wage — - + 8-w M - T) = 6r}i +8- k* - c} (14) . binding. that the is k* i — c} . takes a wage cut in the first k* - c> w M . do not hold, then, = max{w M ,(l + 6)7], + 8 first k*} , period wages for given k*. Construction of Regions 2: minimum wage measures used by a regional reference wage. in this An NLSY paper scale the state minimum wage respondent's reference wage in his/her geographic region for 35-54 year old CPS Outgoing is kj solves for minimum wage is binding but does not bind when he is trained. c, (jrqi), not trained, which completes the characterization of Appendix k* = max {wm, 6r]i + 8 — Wi(r)i,NT) 9 = so: wi(r]i, Finally, Ylj then by construction, worker satisfies (9), period to obtain training, 6)ii l = kj solves for wi(i]i,T) Next, IIf(?7j) when the minimum wage period wages first then =ma,x{w AI ,(<p + Wi{r]i,T) So (14) gives frfr, Rotation Groups. is the median male workers calculated from the This appendix explains how the regions were con- structed. To account states, for the fact that there is significant variation in average wages within and to allow the minimum wage measure to have greater within-state we used information on an NLSY respondent's Because of sample MSAs. For all sizes, other areas an individual resided The CMSAs following list in CMS A/MSA of residence, we used msa_code only (i.e., an smaller MSA variation, ("msa_code"). for individuals residing in the large and non-MSAs), we used data on whether ("msa_status"). contains the 35 defined by the 1990 MS As many MSAs we FIPS Guidelines 31 classified as large. (plus the St. Louis, We MO included the 20 CMSA, while we CMSA do not distinguish the Providence, RI added 15 MSAs from other metropolitan parts of RI) and with large populations. GA Atlanta, Baltimore, MD Boston-Lawrence-Salem, MA-NH CMSA NY CMSA Buffalo-Niagara Falls, CMSA Cincinnati-Hamilton, OH-KY CMSA Cleveland-Akron-Lorraine, OH CMSA Columbus, OH Dallas-Fort Worth, TX CMSA Denver-Boulder, CO CMSA Detroit-Ann Arbor, MI CMSA Hartford-New Britain-Middletown, CT CMSA Houston, TX CMSA Chicago-Gary Lake County, IL-IN Indianapolis, IN Kansas KS City, CA CMSA Miami-Ft. Lauderdale, FL CMSA Milwaukee-Racine, WI CMSA Los Angeles- Anaheim-Riverside, Minneapolis-St. Paul, MN New Orleans, LA New York-New Jersey-Long Island, NY-NJ-CT CMSA Norfolk-Virginia Beach-Newport News, FL Orlando, Philadelphia- Wilmington-Trenton, Phoenix VA , PA-DE-NJ AZ Pittsburgh-Beaver Valley, Portland- Vancouver, PA CMSA OR CMSA CA St. Louis, MO CMSA San Antonio, TX San Diego, CA Sacramento, San Francisco-Oakland-San Seattle-Tacoma, Jose, CA CMSA WA CMSA Tampa-St. Petersburg-Clearwater, Washington, DC, FL DC-MD-VA 32 CMSA The full set of regions consists of state-msa_code level regions for the above 35 and state-msa_status how living in Massachusetts illustrates lived in the Boston The example level regions for all other areas. CMSA, the reference wage is chosen. If of an individual If the individual the reference wage would be the median wage for 35-54 year old male workers living in the Massachusetts part of the Boston median"). MSAs CMSA "MSA CMSA, (the the individual lived in a metropolitan area other than the Boston the reference wage would be the median wage for 35-54 year old male workers living in Massachusetts metropolitan areas other than the Boston in a non-metropolitan area, the reference CMSA. If the individual lived wage would be the median wage old male workers living in Massachusetts non-metropolitan areas for 35-54 year ("non-MSA median"). NLSY and CPS sometimes suppress the specific smaller MSAs and/or smaller states. In the CPS For confidentiality reasons, both the MSA of residence for individuals in data, there were five states in which msa_status Nevada, Rhode Island, Utah and Wyoming. as non-MSA, with the We classified CMSA. Reno MSA. In Rhode New London MSA. In Utah, they are Finally, no MSAs in Wyoming are identified. fringes of MSAs an In Nevada, they are from the non- Island, they are of the classified as living in these suppressed observations following rationale. In Maryland, the suppressed observations are from the Maryland part of the Philadelphia central city part of the was sometimes suppressed: Maryland, from the Rhode Island part from the Utah part of the Flagstaff MSA. For all five states, MSA or the information was an individual was either suppressed, observations from i.e. were grouped with the non-MSA observations to ensure confidentiality. Thus, classifying all the individuals living in areas with suppressed codes as non-MSA seems the most sensible choice. In addition, there are MSAs which straddle different states MSA in a particular state is not identified if the part is the Indiana part of the Cincinnati MSA, and sometimes part of an too small. This was the case the Maryland part of the Philadelphia for: CMSA, the North Carolina part of the Norfolk MSA CMSA groups these areas with other metropolitan ar- eas, and Minneapolis MSA. The and thus NLSY. MSA land's CPS and the Wisconsin part of the Chicago appropriate to use the state-MSA median for these observations in the it is Finally, in Maryland, the Cumberland, are not separately identified. non-MSA median is really a MD-WV MSA and the Hagerstown, MD Here we assign the non-MSA median since Mary- median excluding the Baltimore and Washington, D.C. MSAs. In the NLSY was suppressed data, there were two complications. First, as in the for certain individuals. We dropped of 21,680 observations from the Basic Sample). the New England states whereas the CPS uses 33 CPS, msa_status the suppressed observations (62 out NECMAs for CMSA/MSAs. The NLSY switched to Second, the NLSY uses NECMA codes for 1987 by using information on state and county of residence. We then mapped NECMA codes into MSA codes. Specifically, individuals living in the Boston NECMA or Hartford NECMA were classified as living in the Boston CMSA and Hartford CMSA, respectively. Also, individuals living in any NECMA were classified as living in an MSA. NECMA codes in we constructed the 1988; NLSY All together, the unrestricted regions sample contains 21,618 observations from 136 and 753 region-year categories. Of the 136 level regions, 45 to state-MSA level regions msa.code regions, 44 correspond to state- and 47 to state-non-MSA regions. These regions form a partition of the country. The median number of observations in each region-year Chicago of CMSA in all cells the cell in is 274 and the range fall 27 (for the Indiana part of the 1990). Less than 10 percent than 5 percent of the less NLSY into those cells. Appendix We assume that is CMSA in 1991) to 2261 (the Los Angeles have fewer than a 100 observations and observations 10 CPS Estimation of the Standard Errors 3: = the error term has the form e tj + Vj + ^j Xi and j denotes region*time. Let x^ be a vector of right-hand where i denotes individual side variables, Xil Xi £• = il *U J the matrix of right-hand side variables for individual the Xi's. To simultaneously adjust i, X the stacked matrix of and and region*time for individual effects, all we use the covariance matrix v= (x'x)- l x'nx(x'xy l where X'SIX = 2_J X'i£i£'iXi + X, > i^k i In order to get an idea how „ £ij£kj%ij%ki- j this covariance estimator conducted a small Monte Carlo experiment. performs in our sample, we For this experiment we generated samples with the same number of observations, individuals, regions, and time periods as in our unrestricted sample according to the design y *. = OA + O.lxuj + O.lXij + O.lxai + f Vij \ i ifp<y*- iip>y*j 34 Xi + Vj+tij where p and each of the ~A r x's are In regression (0, 0.1). drawn from a uniform and (0,1) distribution ^ A,, Vj, we computed the OLS estimate of y on the three x's and matrix above. In regression 2, we estimated the regression 1, constructed the covariance of y on the x's also including region and time fixed effects. We replicated each regression 10000 times with the following results: Regression regressor standard deviation of /? mean of estimated standard error x Uj %2j ^32 Elij X 2j X3 0.0116 0.0320 0.0126 0.0116 0.0355 0.0124 0.0116 0.0314 0.0124 0.0115 0.0304 0.0122 No No Year Effects Region Effects Regression 1 x 2j , Yes Yes indicates that the covariance estimator does a sampling variation for for Regression 2 1 all regressors. However, in regression which only varies at the region*time wage measure, is good job level, i.e. understated by about 15 percent. 2, in estimating the the sampling variation the analogue to our Of minimum course, these results are only suggestive. In our design, Vj contributes a third to the total variance of the error term. The would change results as we change the relative variances of this error component. 35 i References [1] Acemoglu, Daron and Jorn-Steffen Pischke (1999a) "Beyond Becker: Training in imperfect labor markets," Economic Journal Features 109, Fl 12-142. [2] Acemoglu, Daron and Jorn-Steffen Pischke (1999b) "The structure of wages and investment in general training," Journal of Political Gary (1964) Human [3] Becker, [4] Ben-Porath, Yoram Journal of Political [5] Chicago: The University human (1967) "The production of Economy 107, 539-572. of Chicago Press. capital over the minimum life cycle," 75, 352-365. Card, David (1992) "Using regional variation in wages to measure the federal [6] capital. Economy effect of the wage," Industrial and Labor Relations Review 46, 22-37. Card, David and Alan B. Krueger (1995) Myth and measurement. The new eco- nomics of the minimum wage. Princeton: Princeton University Press. [7] DiNardo, John, Nicole Fortin and Thomas Lemieux (1996) "Labor market and the distribution tutions, of wages, 1973-1992: A insti- semiparametric approach," Econometrica 64, 1001-1044. [8] Grossberg, Adam J. and Paul Sicilian (1999) "Minimum wages, and wage growth," Southern Economic Journal [9] [10] Hashimoto, Masanori (1982) "Minimum wage ican Economic Review Lee, David (1999) "Wage inequality or falling [11] 65, 539-556. effects on training on the job," Amer- 72, 1070-1087. minimum wage?" in the U.S. during the 1980s: Rising dispersion Quarterly Journal of Economics 114, forthcoming. Leighton, Linda and Jacob Mincer (1981) "The effects of the human on-the-job-training, capital formation," in mum wages. Washington: Simon Rottenberg American Enterprise (ed.) minimum wage on The economics of legal mini- Institute for Public Policy Research, 155-173. [12] Loewenstein, Mark A. and James R. Spletzer (1997) "General and specific training: Evidence from the NLSY," mimeographed, Bureau of Labor [13] Loewenstein, Mark A. and James R. Spletzer (1999) "Formal and informal training: Evidence from the NLSY," in Solomon Polachek vol. 18, Statistics. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press. 36 (ed.) Research in labor economics, [14] Mincer, Jacob (1974) Schooling, Experience, and Earnings. New York: Columbia University Press. [15] Moulton, Brent. R. (1986) "Random group effects and the precision of regression estimates," Journal of Econometrics 32, 385-397. [16] Neumark, David and William Wascher (1998) "Minimum wages and training ited," [17] NBER Working Paper No. 6651. Rosen, Sherwin (1972) "Learning and experience in the labor market," Journal of Human [18] revis- Schiller, wage Resources 7, 326-342. Bradley R. (1994) "Moving up: The training and wage gains of minimum- entrants," Social Science Quarterly 75, 622-636 37 Table Minimum Wage and Statutory Relative 1 Minimum by State and Year Minimum Minimum Wage IVage/Avg. Median Wt ige Age 35- 54 1990 1991 1992 1992 1987 1988 1989 4.25 4.25 0.308 0.306 0.305 0.344 0.383 0.381 4.75 4.75 0.215 0.214 0.213 0.237 0.260 0.259 3.80 4.25 4.25 0.262 0.261 0.260 0.293 0.326 0.325 3.35 3.80 4.25 4.25 0.342 0.341 0.339 0.382 0.426 0.424 3.35/4.25 4.25 4.25 4.25 4.25 0.234 0.279 0.294 0.292 0.291 0.290 3.35 3.35 3.35 3.80 4.25 4.25 0.245 0.244 0.243 0.274 0.305 0.304 3.37/3.75 3.75/4.25 4.25 4.25 4.27 4.27 0.236 0.265 0.279 0.277 0.277 0.276 Delaware 3.35 3.35 3.35 3.80 4.25 4.25 0.242 0.241 0.240 0.270 0.301 0.300 Florida 3.35 3.35 3.35 3.80 4.25 4.25 0.304 0.303 0.302 0.340 0.378 0.377 Georgia Hawaii 3.35 3.35 3.35 3.80 4.25 4.25 0.290 0.288 0.287 0.324 0.360 0.359 3.35/3.85 3.85 3.85 3.85 4.25 4.75/5.25 0.251 0.276 0.275 0.273 0.300 0.343 Idaho 3.35 3.35 3.35 3.80 4.25 4.25 0.296 0.294 0.293 0.330 0.368 0.366 Illinois 3.35 3.35 3.35 3.80 4.25 4.25 0.239 0.238 0.237 0.268 0.298 0.297 Indiana 3.35 3.35 3.35 3.80 4.25 4.25 0.281 0.280 0.279 0.314 0.350 0.348 Iowa Kansas Kentucky 3.35 3.35 3.35/3.85 3.85/4.25 4.25/4.65 4.65 0.285 0.283 0.293 0.330 0.363 0.386 3.35 3.35 3.35 3.80 4.25 4.25 0.270 0.269 0.267 0.301 0.335 0.334 3.35 3.35 3.35 3.80 4.25 4.25 0.291 0.290 0.288 0.325 0.362 0.361 Louisiana 3.35 3.35 3.35 3.80 4.25 4.25 0.289 0.288 0.286 0.323 0.359 0.358 Maryland 3.35 3.35 3.35 3.80 4.25 4.25 0.235 0.234 0.233 0.262 0.292 0.291 3.55/3.65 3.65/3.75 3.75 3.80 4.25 4.25 0.250 0.256 0.256 0.258 0.287 0.286 3.35 3.35 3.35 3.80 4.25 4.25 0.231 0.230 0.229 0.258 0.287 0.286 Minnesota 3.35/3.55 3.55/3.85 3.85/3.95 3.95/4.25' 4.25 4.25 0.256 0.272 0.288 0.292 0.312 0.311 Mississippi 3.35 3.35 3.35 3.80 4.25 4.25 0.340 0.339 0.337 0.380 0.423 0.422 Missouri 3.35 3.35 3.35 3.80 4.25 4.25 0.279 0.278 0.277 0.312 0.348 0.346 Montana 3.35 3.35 3.35 3.80 4.25 4.25 0.292 0.290 0.289 0.326 0.363 0.361 Nebraska 3.35 3.35 3.35 3.80 4.25 4.25 0.303 0.302 0.300 0.338 0.377 0.375 Nevada 3.35 3.35 3.35 3.80 4.25 4.25 0.266 0.265 0.264 0.297 0.331 0.330 New Hampshire New Jersey New Mexico New York 3.45/3.55 3.55/3.65 3.65/3.75 3.75/3.85 4.25 4.25 0.257 0.263 0.269 0.277 0.308 0.307 3.35 3.35 3.35 3.80 4.25 5.05 0.216 0.216 0.214 0.242 0.269 0.319 3.35 3.35 3.35 3.80 4.25 4.25 0.284 0.283 0.281 0.317 0.353 0.352 3.35 3.35 3.35 3.80 4.25 4.25 0.238 0.237 0.236 0.266 0.296 0.295 North Carolina North Dakota Ohio 3.35 3.35 3.35 3.80 4.25 4.25 0.315 0.313 0.312 0.352 0.391 0.390 3.35 3.35 3.35 3.80 4.25 4.25 0.291 0.290 0.288 0.325 0.361 0.360 3.35 3.35 3.35 3.80 4.25 4.25 0.260 0.259 0.258 0.291 0.324 0.322 Oklahoma 3.35 3.35 3.35 3.80 4.25 4.25 0.282 0.281 0.279 0.315 0.350 0.349 Oregon 3.35 3.35 3.35/4.25 4.25/4.75 4.75 4.75 0.262 0.261 0.287 0.336 0.364 0.363 1990 1991 3.35 3.80 3.85 4.30 3.35 3.35 3.35 3.35 California 3.35 Colorado 1987 1988 1989 Alabama 3.35 3.35 Alaska 3.85 3.85 Arizona 3.35 Arkansas Slate Connecticut Massachusetts Michigan 2 3.35 3.35/3.70 3.70 3.80 4.25 4.25 0.269 0.273 0.294 0.300 0.334 0.333 3.55/3.65 3.65/4.00 4.00/4.25 4.25 4.45 4.45 0.281 0.302 0.321 0.324 0.338 0.337 South Carolina 3.35 3.35 3.35 3.80 4.25 4.25 0.305 0.304 0.302 0.341 0.379 0.378 South Dakota Tennessee 3.35 3.35 3.35 3.80 4.25 4.25 0.337 0.336 0.334 0.377 0.420 0.418 3.35 3.35 3.35 3.80 4.25 4.25 0.331 0.329 0.328 0.370 0.411 0.410 Texas 3.35 3.35 3.35 3.80 4.25 4.25 0.280 0.279 0.278 0.313 0.348 0.347 Utah 3.35 3.35 3.35 3.80 4.25 4.25 0.259 0.258 0.256 0.289 0.322 0.320 Vermont 3.45/3.55 3.55/3.65 3.65/3.75 3.85 4.25 4.25 0.306 0.313 0.320 0.324 0.361 0.360 Virginia 3.35 3.35 3.35 3.80 4.25 4.25 0.252 0.251 0.249 0.281 0.313 0.312 Washington West Virginia Wisconsin 3.35 3.35/3.85 3.85/4.25 4.25 4.25 4.25 0.236 0.244 0.277 0.294 0.293 0.292 3.35 3.35 3.35 3.80 4.25 4.25 0.294 0.293 0.292 0.329 0.366 0.365 3.35 3.35 3.35/3.65 3.80 4.25 4.25 0.270 0.269 0.286 0.302 0.336 0.335 Wyoming 3.35 3.35 3.35 3.80 4.25 4.25 0.263 0.262 0.261 0.294 0.327 0.326 Pennsylvania Rhode 1 2 Island Minnesota: Only large employers covered by the new 1991 minimum wage. Oregon: Minimum wage changed from 3.35 to 3.85 and then 4.25 during the year. minimum wages in each state and year. Years begin in April minima are shown if the state minimum changed during the April to minimum wage divided by the average median wage for male workers 35-54 Notes: Left hand panel of the table shows the higher of the state or federal of the year shown March period. until The March of the following right year. Multiple hand panel of the table shows the years old in the state during the 1987 to 1992 period. 38 Table 2 Sample Means of Demographics (Standard Deviations in Parentheses) Variable 1988 1992 Unre stricted Sample 1987 1992 Female 0.434 0.428 0.432 Black 0.134 0.132 Hispanic 0.067 Non-move) Sample • Low Wage Sample 1987 1992 0.427 0.527 0.602 0.128 0.133 0.169 0.203 0.067 0.064 0.067 0.061 0.073 27.2 31.2 26.2 31.2 25.8 31.1 Less than High School 0.187 0.171 0.192 0.173 0.262 0.240 New Job 0.273 0.216 0.268 0.220 0.338 0.323 8.16 9.71 7.58 9.70 5.12 5.91 (5.36) (6.54) (5.51) (6.52) (2.57) (2.82) Age Nominal Hourly Wage Real Hourly Wage (1982-84$) Fraction Earning Minimum or Less Number of Observations 7.30 8.52 6.81 8.51 4.60 5.18 (4.79) (5.73) (4.95) (5.72) (2.30) (2.47) 0.042 0.058 0.068 0.059 0.155 0.162 3872 3094 3979 3136 1673 1048 NLSY. Unrestricted sample consists of individual-year observations that have high one month of the year and in both the prior and current year have non-missing wage data. Non-mover sample excludes from the unrestricted sample individuals who have moved to a new state since the previous year. Low wage sample imposes on the unrestricted sample the restriction that the "CPS wage" in the previous year is less than or equal to 150% of the federal minimum wage. Year refers to April to March (of following calendar year). New job refers to the start of any new job during the year. Hourly wage is the "CPS wage" for workers employed at a "CPS job" only. NLSY data include black, Hispanic and poor white oversamples. The poor white oversamples were discontinued in the 1991 survey year, accounting for the lower number of observations in 1992. Statistics are weighted by Notes: Unbalanced panel from the school education or the NLSY less, work in at least sampling weights. 39 Table 3 Sample Means of Key Variables (Standard Deviations 1987 Variable in Parentheses) 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 0.099 0.106 0.094 0.103 Non-mover Sample 0.099 Training Incidence Nominal Minimum Wage Minimum wage in prior year is increased and wage 3.51 3.87 4.26 4.28 (0.29) (0.16) (0.05) (0.15) 0.014 0.020 0.069 0.091 0.001 0.007 0.008 0.034 0.050 0.034 0.062 0.085 0.263 0.293 0.011 0.041 0.058 0.166 0.204 0.007 3872 3793 3187 3122 3094 0.100 0.107 0.094 0.102 below the current minimum wage Minimum increased and wage in prior year is below the current minimum and above prior year minimum Minimum wage increased and wage in prior year is 3.44 (0.21) below 150 % of the minimum wage Minimum wage increased and wage in prior year is below 130% of the current minimum wage Number of Observations current Unrestricted Sample 0.064 Training Incidence Nominal Minimum Wage Minimum Wage 0.099 3.36 3.44 3.51 3.87 4.26 4.29 (0.06) (0.21) (0.29) (0.16) (0.05) (0.15) 3.02 3.08 3.12 3.42 3.75 3.76 (1982-84$) (0.05) (0.19) (0.26) (0.14) (0.05) (0.13) Minimum Wage/Median Wage (men 0.267 0.271 0.276 0.301 0.331 0.332 (0.030) (0.027) (0.028) (0.031) (0.038) (0.037) 0.272 0.277 0.282 0.307 0.338 0.340 (0.043) (0.041) (0.042) (0.045) (0.053) (0.051) 0.324 0.330 0.336 0.366 0.402 0.404 (0.077) (0.076) (0.078) (0.086) (0.097) (0.097) 0.068 0.044 0.050 0.047 0.072 0.059 3979 4043 3958 3295 3207 3136 Real 35-54, states) Minimum Wage/Median Wage (men 35-54, regions) Minimum Wage/Median Wage 54, state (35- and gender) Fraction Earning Minimum or Less Number of Observations Notes: See Table 2 for a description of the sample composition. Training incidence refers to employment related training. refers to the higher of the state or federal minimum applicable to an NLSY respondent. Median wage for 35-54 year old workers are calculated from the CPS Outgoing Rotation Groups. The poor white oversamples were Minimum wage discontinued in the weighted by the 1991 survey year, accounting for the lower number of observations NLSY sampling weights. 40 in 1990 to 1992. Statistics are Table 4 The Effect of Minimum Wage Increases on Affected Independent Variable Minimum wage increased and the current wage increased and in prior year is prior year wage below minimum Change in in high school graduation status new job status (3) (4) — — 0.016 — (0.019) — — (0.008) — — — in prior year is % of the current minimum wage Minimum wage increased and wage in prior year is below 130% of the current minimum wage Change (2) 0.010 (0.014) in prior year is minimum and above Minimum wage below 150 wage minimum wage increased and below the current Minimum (1) Workers — 0.005 -0.002 (0.010) 0.070 0.070 0.070 0.070 (0.053) (0.054) (0.054) (0.054) 0.032 0.032 0.032 0.032 (0.008) (0.008) (0.008) (0.008) Non-mover sample, consisting of all workers with a high school education or less, who do not move between states from one year to the next. Dependent variable is the change in training incidence between two consecutive years. All regressions also include a constant and year dummies. Regressions are weighted by NSLY sampling weights. Standard Notes: errors are adjusted for the presence error. Sample size is of individual effects in the error 17074. 41 term, and therefore robust to the MA structure of the Table 5 Quantile Regressions for Real Wage on Real Minimum Wage Unrestricted Sample Quantile NLSY CPS 0.10 0.376 0241 (0.087) (0.024) [0.084] 0.20 0.156 0.137 (0.105) (0.011) [0.109] 0.30 0.146 0.052 (0.163) (0.016) [0.121] 0.40 0.049 0.032 (0.158) (0.045) [0.102] 0.50 0.137 0.000 (0.178) (0.025) [0.111] 0.60 0.029 0.130 (0.173) (0.053) [0.113] 0.70 -0.120 0.030 (0.247) (0.043) [0.135] 0.80 0.296 0.011 (0.446) (0.044) [0.198] 0.90 0.312 0.157 (0.593) (0.143) [0.282] Year Effects Yes Yes State Effects Yes Yes Notes: Samples include respondents with a high school degree or regressions are weighted by the NLSY sampling weights. less. Dependent variable Standard errors in is the real hourly wage. error term. Bootstrapped standard errors using state*year blocks are in brackets (100 replications). is 21618 in the NLSY, and 1 1 9464 in the CPS. 42 NLSY parentheses are not adjusted for clusters in the Number of observations H <1 i i > » ' i re JO -o i_ c o © P P 2: ^ o r- — r- -* CN CN ON S ro ^t °0 ON © CN ^ M cm © © P © P — CN o —i rcn ro o 9o 9© ©© OO O O *£> no NO "3" on ro CN — oo _ on <u °2 r~- r- Co p o P o P— P P o 9 ©' 9 ©' 9 co p. NO CN ro on <— co —i co o o © © O P o© © "~: c^ ^3" 1 *—> 1 1 . «N s_ Sh "" •"* en t3 re I" cc re .2 u cu rs >h 1 O NO in oo vo ^ On —: ~ s° CN ^ o o£ ^1 o P f> o o P o °°o © £ 2o Zo o © P CD P CD 9 CD 9 CD 9 9 P © rt oo WD O sH § J= <u <2 ",o •a '<«J T3 t(5 m E V, '"^•^ en"P re -^ c <n re •I re cn . "L> a- re 2 -—.ret ^r "— ^~ re m .a 1 O T3 on BO C ^^ c re JO o E & re S3, "C m w 3 > 5 ' i/-> ^m — £- no oo CN oo g Po 9 P o O © © 9 CD 9 CD P OO CN 'c '3 h t_ aS z S CU O on *- • co on in .2 CL> o u c re o ON On oO •— o o © CD CD Z r- ro ro oo CN CD S - S c o E E '3 u '-5 u c o t~~- »-h in ^ ^ t> CN O in NO o o ro T— oo f— o o in o ro o © o CN — o «— O o ^f © © © © © © © CD CD © *— 00 oo CN E o >« o o o r^ cn re ^ ON CD oo oT © ;5 £T £ NO _ £3 00 o o o P o P o £} P P o z !Z P' CD P CD o P' CD © 9o ^ ^ ON co £> oo - • ,-; _<L) O ,-; C is! a S5 j= a o Q c C3 c C3 3 3 3 3 03 03 03 03 T3 TJ T3 TD -3 -3 <U <D <D CO l_« CO s s s s -3 O s o ob s > 03 ^ ~o t/3 > 1) < c3 ~u CO 0) 00 00 00 03 C3 £ £ ^ B 3 g s s 3 g "S a in 3 m g c m "S 1 1 1 13 a oh oa 00 00 03 ""St in ^ C/D 4—* 3 > _o < 03 o» 00 OO ^ <n on 00 ~ 00 > 3 < ~o 00 03 03 ^ ^ in i I "3 "c3 CO Pi B in 3 m s C CD "3 E, s, | u 03 03 ^ Pi ^ CD 00 >n s ro 3 g 3 o '3 | CO _o 00 Cl) u. ^ "* in in 3 3 m 3 3 1) CO > < ~co 00 d £ 3 3 3 3 CO 00 "O 3 Tt"" ^ 03 ^ "c3 CO CO O tn u S o w "~ CO -t— § pq 03 J2 to IS t° -1 C/) t2 ^ O 00 00 CO -3 •3 CO 03 ^ CO 4-* CO 00 co CO 00 03 CO C>4 3 3 o hJ 3 D 4-* "3 CO CO 00 CO 00 03 03 £ £ £ o -1 GO CO 3 p o _1 00 CO p o J U E —D. Cm3r CO *— 2> on £ o 3 ' 1^ *3 &*c «) E re 9- to > u 2 ? o E J -^s « c 5 o. « •a .a <u C "5 irt o d 03 t-l 3 £ CO E on^i ,£tj -«— 00 CN en.>< 03 CO ^ trt J3 &o (U 5 ca ~^ S-J2 -3 ^o (N 0X) CO 03 '3 in CO CO t «) -a -a T3 00 Pi c re CO 3 *" 3 3 in 00 13 03 £ 3 3 ^ 00 u« CO ~co 03 s 8 o 1o °° u J= S on 2 "3 00 "3 CO CO | > £ S o £3 B-S-2 < 03 | 00 ob 00 '3 00 13 03 s 03 in "3 in cn 3^ 3^ 00 13 03 00 CO u c "S Mo E re 00 CO re °^ •o *-> t/i - c o o "3 fc o re <u £ •£ S o I- •- >2 re ^re ;— o i- > Ores S^ S 52 E fi > c o E Z t" — 3 xi J= C to u n o. •is T3 oi .S - S ro MM LlbHAHIhS 3 9080 917 7465