J Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium IVIember Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/consequencesofemOOacem m-^.^B working paper department of economics «iiiiK_ CONSEQUENCES OF EMPLOYMENT PROTECTION? THE CASE OF THE AMERICANS WITH DISABILITIES ACT Daron Acemoglu Joshua Angrist September 1998 massachusetts institute of technology 50 memorial drive Cambridge, mass. 02139 WORKING PAPER DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS CONSEQUENCES OF EMPLOYMENT PROTECTION? THE CASE OF THE AMERICANS WITH DISABILITIES ACT Daron Acemoglu Joshua Angrist 98-13 September 1998 MASSACHUSEHS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 50 MEMORIAL DRIVE CAMBRIDGE, MASS. 02142 MASSAC ~ C^ JAN 2 -STlTint - 5Y 8 '959 LIBRARIES First Version; December 1997 Revised: June 1998 Consequences of Employment Protection? The Case of the Americans with DisabiHties Act' Daron Acemoglu and Joshua Angrist^ ABSTRACT The Americans With DisabiHties Act (ADA) workers and outlaws discrimination against the disabled in hiring, ADA The was meant to increase employment of the disabled, ADA had a negati\-e effect women under to profits. is ADA age 40. The effects appear to be larger in ADA. The men ADA most important and how ADA. CPS size firms, possibly effects is because where there have on hiring and affect separations. Finally, there suggest that the working ages and disabled effects are also larger in states reduced hiring of the disabled but did not a pure firing-costs interpretation of the are of all medium been more ADA-related discrimination charges. Estimates of the and pay. Although the Empirical results using the on the employment of disabled small firms were exempt from the firing, also increases costs for employers. it net theoretical impact turns on which provisions of the responsive firm entry and exit accommodate disabled requires employers to firing suggest This weighs against httle evidence of an impact on ADA have been the nondisabled, suggesting that the adverse employment consequences of the limited to the protected group. 'We thank Lucia Breierova and Chris Mazingo for outstanding research assistance, and Patricia Anderson, Peter Diamond, Alan Krueger, Paul Oyer, James Poterba, Steve Pischke and seminar participants in the N.B.E.R. Labor Studies Meeting, the 1998 North American Meeting of the Econometric Society, M.LT. and U.C.L.A. for helpful comments. Special thanks go to to Leo Sanchez for help with data from the Equal Employment Opportunity Commission and to Greg Weyland at the Census Burea for consultations regarding CPS matches and the CPS redesign. The authors bear sole responsability for the contents of this paper. ^Department of Ikonomics, Massachusetts Institute of Technology. E-mail: datronSmit edu.angristSmit edu . . Introduction I. Government Pay Act efforts to eliminate and of 1963 employment and wage discrimination date back to the Equal Title VII of the Civil Rights The consensus among crimination on the basis of race and sex. rights legislation and related Act of 1964. These laws prohibited labor economists is that improvement in economic federaJ regulations led to a substantial conditions for Black Americans (see, for example, Freeman, 1981; Heckman and Payner, or Leonard, 1990), while the evidence on the impact of antidiscrimination policy less clear civil 1989; on women is cut (Leonard, 1989). The most recent pieces of federal antidiscrimination legislation are the Americans with Dis- Act (ADA) and the abilities dis- to offer reasonable disabled in Act of 1991 (CRA-91). The Civil Rights accommodation wage determination, and The firing. requires employers and bans discrimination against the to disabled employees, hiring, ADA ADA seems to be more far-reaching Mian CRA-91, which essentially modified existing antidiscrimination statutes.^ ADA propo- nents hope the act will improve the labor market fortimes of disabled workers. Critics of the ADA have argued that adapting the workplace to the disabled can be expensive and that the costs of accommodation and ADA-related may have significant negative employment Rosen, 1991; Oi, 1991; Weaver, 1991; Epstein, 1992; Olson, 1997). effects (e.g., The litigation first objective of this paper economic conditions for the disabled. is A to evaluate study of the whether the ADA ADA has in fact improved also of broader interest, however. is Altliough high-profile reasonable accommodation cases have attracted the most media attention, the majority of ADA charges are for wrongful termination. ADA acts as a form of employment protection, similar ADA primarily affects a specific group, the consequences the therefore possible that It is to European of employment protection may be firing costs. Since the easy to detect in this case. Moreover, contrary to early experience with the Civil Rights Act of 1964, in recent years, most discrimination charges under wrongful termination (EEOC, various years). this change in civil rights law enforcement the disabled, a possibiUty raised by The theory If firing may all statutes have been related to costs have ultimately disemployment effects, then harm protected groups other than Donohue and Siegelman (1991, 1993). section of the paper uses a standard competitive model to highlight the distinc- tion between hiring and disabled workers. Although the reasonable accommodation provision creates an incentive to firing costs due to the threat of lawsuits and the costs of accommodating employ fewer disabled workers, the introduction of hiring and sis. If ^See firing costs comphcates the analy- the threat of ADA-related litigation encourages employers to increase the hiring of the Abram (1993). Oyer and SchaefFer (1998) explore the labor-market impact of CRA-91. and disabled, may if the increase the most charges are the ADA The number of employers employment not very responsive to profits or costs, the is ADA of disabled workers as ADA proponents had hoped. But when wrongful termination and costs of reasonable accommodation are high, for hkely to reduce disabled employment. is empirical analysis looks at the emplojonent and wages of disabled and nondisabled workers using data from the March Current Population Surveys (CPS) for 1988-1997. These data are useful ers, for and because the March and theoretical discussion, the impact of the matching CPS ADA in the ADA's compliance and rotation groups. Finally, men, with no men, the women aged results for effect sanction provisions. EEOC we use To investigate data on discrimination charges by state ADA activity. had a negative impact on the employment on wages. These results are unchanged by controlling and Supplemental Security Income women We are mixed. ADA The women aged impact on nondisabled workers consequences of the legislation in this case for pre- 40-58. in exempt from the ADA (SSI). In contrast to the results appears to have had a negative effect on We also find no evidence that the ADA any age group, suggesting that the adverse have been limited to the protected group. check the basic findings in a number of ways. cmplo\'mcnt of the disabled declined more ADA. work- a variable that figures in our market variables with the incidence of ADA-related charge 21-39, but no effect on liad a ncgati\-e are size, identifies disabled trends in disabled employment and for the increase in the fraction of people receiving Disability Insurance (DI) for has information on firm empirical results suggest that the of disabled ADA CPS supplement on turnover, we construct measmes of separations and accessions by to connect changes in labor The CPS income our purposes because the in First, there is some evidence that medium-size firms, possibly because small firms and large firms can more easily absorb the costs imposed by the Second, effects are generally larger in states where there have been more ADA-related discrimination charges. Finally, there is some evidence of a negative impact on hiring of the disabled, but little evidence for a reduction in disabled separation rates. This suggests that the negative effects of the ADA may be due more to the costs of reasonable accommodation than to the threat of wrongful termination lawsuits. The paper is organized as follows. Section II gives some background and discusses related literature. Section III provides a theoretical analysis of provisions that protect disabled workers. Section IV describes the data and oxn empirical strategy. Section findings and Section VI concludes. V contains the main empirical II. A. ADA Provisions and Coverage The ADA was signed Background into law in July 1990 and came into Jnly 1992. effect in Previously, there was no federal law dealing with the employment and wages of disabled workers in the private sector, although the Rehabilitation Act of 1973 covered disabled workers employed by A the federal government or working for federal contractors. number of states also had laws protecting disabled workers, but the coverage and effectiveness of these laws varied. Title the ADA initially covered all employers with at least twenty was extended to employers with fifteen or more employees. five Title I I of employees. In 1994, coverage requires employers to provide "reasonable accommodation" for their disabled workers. Examples include enabling wheel chair equipment access, purchasing special for disabled employees, and job restructuring to permit disabled employees to work part time or from home. Title the disabled in wages, hiring, firing, I also bans discrimination against and promotion. For example, a disabled employee should be paid the same amount as a nondisabled worker in the same job, and firms are not allowed to consider disability in hiring Enforcement of (EEOC) and and firing decisions.^ ADA provisions is left to the Equal the courts. Employment Opportunity Commission Disabled employees or job applicants discriminated against can file a charge with the EEOC, which who believe they have been will investigate If sue on behalf of the charging party, issues a letter of permission to sue party is free to litigate at his or her hiring, reinstatement, promotion, payment it for firms more employees (EEOC, The underlying and court also available (see, e.g. much worse than 1991). ADA are much The the nondisabled what nondisabled workers less likely to does not and the charging remedies that include costs. if As a consequence of CRA-91, intentional discrimination is found. 1995, p. X-8). logic of the Kemp, some with 100 or fewer employees to $300,000 for firms with 500 seems to be that employers incorrectly perceive the disabled to be less productive, or are unwilling to them for in back pay, front pay, and reasonable accommodation, and for of attorney's fees, expert witness fees, These range from $50,000 is own expense. The law provides compensatory and punitive damages are or the charge EEOC not resolved and the cases try to resolve the charge or sue. and is make modest adjustments fact that the labor not in dispute. (see, e.g., accommodate market fortunes of the disabled are The disabled earn 40 percent or less of earn. Their labor force participation rates are be employed to much lower and they Burkhauser and Daly, 1996, or our statistics, ^xitle II covers discrimination in public programs, and Titles III and FV refer to public accommodations (busmesses) and telecommuiucation. Title V contains technical information related to enforcement (see EEOC 1995). ADA below). proponents believe the law induce companies to will make the investments and modifications necessary to employ disabled workers, and reduce imjustified discrimination. In recent years, interest in the labor market performance of the disabled has also been fueled by efforts to reduce the number of Disability Insurajice recipients From July 1992 various years). Of September 1997, the to these, 29 percent mention EEOC (i.e., our interpretation of the B. We t's How Costly is the The majority Leonard, 1991) ADA received 90,803 "failure to provide percent are for discrimination at the hiring stage. wrongful termination (see, e.g., charges accommodation", while as providing a 9.4 of charges, 62.9 percent, are for discharge, failure to rehire, suspension, or layoff). ADA (EEOC, This motivates form of employment protection. ADA? have not foimd representative data on the costs of accommodation, though the Presiden- Committee on Employment of People with Disabihties has surveyed some employers who contacted them for help accommodating their disabled workers (Job Accommodation Network, This survey shows an average cost of $930 per accommodation since October 1992. 1997). ADA regulations litigation. Since July Other costs of accommodation include time employers spend dealing with and reduced An efficiency due to a forced restructuring. important component of ADA costs results 1992, over 11,000 of the charges brought under the from the threat of ADA were resolved by the EEOC, and employers paid over $174 million in settlements (EEOC, various years). This figiue does not reflect administrative costs, lawyers we do not have data on ADA fees, suits alone, and private settlements Condon and Zolna in or out of court. Although (1997) report that employees file over 40,000 cases each year with state and federal courts, the majority related to discrimination, and win almost 60 percent of the time. They estimated an average award of over $167,000 and defence costs of over $40,000 (less than the $80,000 estimated by Dertouzos, 1988, for wrongful termination suits in California). The cies for ADA may also have been a factor in Employment lawsuits. the development of a new insurance market, poli- Practices Liability Insurance (EPLI), which covers the costs of employee The EPLI market started in late 1990 and has since grown rapidly, with minimum premia ranging from $4,500 to $20,000 a year (Clarke, 1996). This suggests that the costs of the ADA are indeed a real concern for employers. Related Literature C. DeLeire (1997) aware is and first He used the of. Income Dynamics fore the after the to ADA systematic empirical study of the impact of the Siurvey of that we are Income and Program Participation and the Panel Siu-vey of compare labor market outcomes ADA. Our approach for disabled and non-disabled workers be- and a number of empirical uses different data strategies not explored by DeLeire, but we also begin with similar comparisons of changes in outcomes ADA by disability status. Since the work on the impact of and creates firing costs, our paper Europe firing costs in Nickell, 1997). Related theoretical (e.g., is also related to empirical Lazear, 1990; Addison and Grosso, 1996; papers include analyses of labor market regulations by Mortensen (1978), Summers (1989), Lazear (1990), Bertola and Bentohla (1990), and Hopen- hayn and Rogerson (1993), and the analysis of optimal Slieshinski (1995). Finally, our mandated work benefits (e.g., Gruber, 1994; analyses of the impact of earlier on the impact of also related to the empirical hterature Ruhm, 1996; Waldfogel, 1996) and, as noted above, to civil rights legislation. Consequences of Protecting Disabled Workers: Theory III. The is by Diamond and disability benefits theoretical consequences of the ADA are explored using a standard competitive model with two types of workers. Nondisabled workers supply labor according to the function na{wa) and the disabled supply labor according to nii{wd), where Wa workers and wage factor wj^ is rate for P < i = the wage rate for disabled workers. All workers are infinitely lived a.d. There are I. M firms in the labor potential firms that can enter at cost F. This both a market characterized by is fixed {M > and F — free entry is We assume that and is is and a large number of a convenient formulation enabling us to discuss (when M —^ 0) and one where the number of firms t. may be assume F{Lt,Dt) and have access of nondisabled workers We assume that with probability also productivity of a worker at his or her current firm Lt falls to zero, and e < e 1, to the production and Dt the number of s every period, the though productivity elsewhere due, for example, to match-specific learning as in Jovanovic, 1979). = ^ m+ eD^)^ , where a < 1, and < p and Dt include only employees who have not received adverse match parameter and have a discount number the disabled workers employed at time We exit, increasing in the is oo). function F{Lt,Dt), where Lt imaffected (this n, risk-neutral, market which never All firms are risk-neutral, discount the future at rate P, is the wage received by nondisabled < 1. The quantities specific shocks. captures the relative productivity of disabled workers. For example, when p The = 1 disabled and nondisabled workers are perfect substitutes, but the disabled have a lower marginal product than nondisabled workers. This formulation cdso nests the case in which firms discriminate against the disabled The most often raised issiie ADA in for taste reasons as in charges Becker (1971). wrongful termination, followed by is fail- ure to provide reasonable accommodation and discrimination in hiring. Suppose disabled job apphcants who are not hired sue with probability pd at expected cost and lawyer and this happens with probability pa and has cost ha = Pa^a- is We the firm incurs therefore hd refer to ha when with probability qd and damages are are fd so h — and / act benefit it for like and hd as hiring costs, though more A We disabled worker expected costs of firing do not get transferred We begin with the simple case where also is fired sues costs are pure waste, (1 — to sue, but is we < Wa and /„ /?) We "accommodate" disabled workers, imposed on employers probably (1 — /5) < /^ Wd, which implies that firms always employees wlio receive adverse match-specific shocks. Dp treat a reasonable defer a discussion of this case. an excess number of applicants and Lp are nondisabled. like for may Obviously, a fraction of these costs do accrue to to disabled workers. off the fraction s of its assume there all and insurance companies. This seems as lawyers them a reason assume that wants to lay who a disabled and nondisabled worker starting place since a significant fraction of the litigation costs workers, giving precisely, these are costs that a tax from the point of view of the worker and the firm, though suits some other party such is For a nondisabled worker, the corresponding probabilities (pd- 0a, so the qa4>a- cost of not hiring a dis- while the corresponding cost for a nondisabled worker Pdi'd, damages = fa = The expected Ua- decides not to hire an applicant. and qa and qd<Pd including damages Rejected nondisabled applicants can also sue, falsely claiming to be disabled, fees. abled worker v^-, for every job, Dp- of and Lp as given. Finally, whom are disabled, we assume that example by purchasing special equipment We firms can at cost C per worker, and that this expenditure increases the marginal productivity of disabled workers by a fixed amoimt B per worker. The ADA requires employers to make such accommodations. C< B, employers would make these adjustments voluntarily, even in the absence of the The fact that government regulation The maximization problem required suggests that typically is of the firm at time t = C> can be written ADA. B. as: max n = ^P'[F{LuDt)-Wa,tLt-Wd,tDt-cDt-fasLt-,-fdsDt_, {Dt,Lt} c —C—B and = D_i = is costs of (1) ^^Q -ha {Lp where L_i If 0, Wa^t and [L, Wd^t - (1 - 5)L<_i]) - hd {Dp - [A - (1 - 5) A-l])] denote nondisabled and disabled wages at time the net cost of accommodation after the accommodation are assumed to be zero. ADA. The Pre- ADA first line firing of (1) is t, and and hiring costs output minus the wage accommodation bill, costs and Firms discharge a fraction firing costs. s of their employees who receive an adverse match-specific shock, incurring a firing cost of fj for each disabled layoff, and The second fa for every nondisabled termination. incurs as a function of the When — Lt number workers not = Lt-\ and Dt line gives the "hiring costs" hired out of the applicant pools, Dt-\ so that employment nondisabled and sDt-i workers to replace those who is Since adjustment costs are linear and there is As noted above, ha and off. = by hiring more workers. Wa, Wd,t These equihbrium employment and wage = "^d, = Lt L, and Dt = D = Wa + (5sfa-[l + P{l-s)]ha + eD"]^ = Wd + psfd-[l + ^{l - s)]hd + (2) c. Both equations equate the relevant marginal product to the flow marginal firing costs, hiring subsidies, also impose market clearing n~^ [mL) r?"' is of firms m the inverse supply function and is which holds with complementary slackness. the is = for nondisabled workers, Wa, (3) the equilibrium number of firms. The number determined by is n < r and profits cost, inclusive of and the net costs of accommodation.. To determine equilibrium, we where \n levels satisfy: LP-'[U + eD''p' eD"-' [L" hd. no aggregate imcertainty, firms immediately adjust to steady state employment levels, and Wa^t every period. Lp and Dp- not changing, the firm hires sLt-\ are laid act as hiring subsidies, because the firm reduces its costs the firm equal to entry costs, or that there is m > M, (4) This means that either the maximized value of no entry and the number of firms, m, is equal to minimum, M. Finally, the wages received by disabled workers are given by where 7] is (mD) In the absence of the ADA, a parameter. disabled wages. The = max [n^^ Wd ,T]Wa t] = (5) , and there are no restrictions on equal pay provision can be interpreted as setting 77 = 1. Inspection of the equilibrium conditions yields the following conclusions: 1) From since hd is effectively a hiring subsidy. be best described as hd case the ADA to reduce the costs of employing the disabled, The scenario envisaged by ADA proponents can probably (2), it is clearly possible for > 0, fa = ha = ADA can increase employment the 0, and minimal firing costs for and wages of the disabled. the disabled, in which It is also worth noting that as long as p> 0, this effect is 2) than ADA will the be small. likely to As we noted in Section hd. Similarly, costs of the II, ADA appears to have increased fd considerably more employing the disabled are increased by the accommodation Therefore, in practice, the c. reduce nondisabled employment eind wages in this case, though ADA may be more costs, reduce disabled employment and likely to wages. 3) The equal-pay creating involuntary provision of the unemployment 4) 0) may have increased disabled wages, The equal-pay the disabled supply curve. Although the partial-equilibrium n = r > r/ to start with, then employment effect of hiring costs is to increase is an increase by reducing effectively financed in hd will profits. More fall. ADA the free-entry and fixed-number cases suggests that the generally, the contrast will and Ross, 1990, Chapter 5) Finalh', the tlic nondisabled. The / ADA and might also affect ha = should have no = hd firing like taxes is and /d > when / and h effect 0. We know are pure transfers on employment. To that workers anticipate they Wd can and keep Wd fall + may be fired, fd is may and hiring costs for from the work of Mortensen and side payments are allowed, a pure transfer + 13s fd)- 0s fd constant, changes ADA It is The reason for in fd straightforward to see that have no on disabled effect limits this possibility. include payments to third parties and because firms risk-averse, characterizing these costs as a tax and both parties and therefore include the discounted employment income. employment. However, the equal-pay provision of the because / and h firm size see this in our context, suppose that Under the assumption that fiow value of firing costs, /3s/d, in their as long as we use on the firm-worker relationship are risk-neutral, labor supply of disabled workers changes to nd[wd the change between profitable (see, e.g., Schmalensee, employment by changing presumes that / and h act (1978) and Lazear (1990) that = M ha- discu.ssion so far firing costs > 11). rather than a transfer from the firm to the worker. fa more for excess profitability, since large firms are 1989; Scherer m reduce employment most in firms or uidustries where profits are close to entry costs. In the empirical work, proxy If of the cause some firms to shut down, causing both disabled and nondisabled employment and wages to as a provision also exacerbating the dechne in disabled employment. disabled, the implicit hiring subsidy hd and (i.e. and the costs of accommodation by preventing wages from faUing to interacts with firing costs offset these costs, off ADA Moreover, and workers are on the employment contract seems like a better stylized description of reahty. Finally, we note that the analysis so far ignores the impact of firing costs on separations In a previous version of the paper (details available because separations are exogenous. we request), allow for time-varying productivity and endogenous separations. shows that ADA-related The firing costs are likely to theoretical discussion therefore provisions are most important. provision is shows that the net The accommodation and not binding, equiUbrium is This analysis reduce both hiring and separations. ADA depends on which imposed by the ADA axe effect of the firing costs reduce employment, while hiring costs have the opposite likely to upon effect. If the equal-pay on the labor supply curves of disabled and nondisabled workers, and employment declines are accompanied by wage declines. More generally, however, the equal-pay provision can create "involuntary imemployment" off the supply curve. We therefore estimate reduced-form equations of the form: y^t where Xii is i denotes individuals and t = x[^(3 + time; yu 6t + is weeks worked or average weekly wages; and a set of controls including disability status. changes in aggregate conditions. Finally, dummy and a for post-ADA years. The a^t is + E^t, -ita,t The term (6) 5t is a year effect to control for the interaction of a disability status indicator coefficient 7^ the disabled using the nondisabled as a control group. measures the impact of the Since the ADA ADA on potentially affects the emplo}'mcnt of nondisabled as well as disabled workers, we also explore empirical specifications that use \'ariation by firm size and state to separately identify effects on the disabled and nondisabled. IV. The sample women aged is Data and Descriptive Statistics drawn from the March CPS's from 1988 through 1997, and limited 21-58, since this age group has strong labor-force attachment. to men and Disabled workers are identified in the March CPS Income Supplement by the question: "Do you have a health problem or which prevents you from working or which limits the kind and the amoTmt of disability work you can do?" issues (e.g., SIPP Kr\ise, 1995), and of the ADA on employment diiring the previous calendar year is is similar to disabiUty questions in the PSID and Burkhauser and Daly 1996; DeLeire, 1997).^ The impact measure This question has been used by other researchers working on disability Krueger and (see, e.g., worked . levels is evaluated by looking at data on weeks from the March income supplement. The wage average weekly earnings, computed using annual earnings data from the supplement. ^Using data from the Retirement History Survey and the National Longitudinal Survey of Older men, Bound (1989) compares objective measures of health status with self-reported measures like the one used here. His results suggest there is no clear basis for preferring one type of measure over the other. . Although the 1994, CPS changed from paper questionnaires to computer-assisted interviewing and the main labor force status <piestions in were also revised at that time, the content of the income supplement was not changed. Appendix A discusses an analysis of data for March 1993 and 1994, and provides more information on the CPS matched CPS redesign and its possible consequences for our analysis.'' The variables in the income supplement refer to the previous calendar year, so the has data for weeks worked and wages supplement appears to The in 1987-1996. refer to respondents' status at the sample disabihty status question in the time of the survey (March of the survey year), but actually serves as a lead-in question prefacing additional and Figure supplement questions about disability income the previous year. Except statistics dated by survey year, the tables and figures label estimates according to the year of observation, which CPS is for Table I which present descriptive I, the survey year minus one. supplement respondents provide information on the Responses to for longest in the past year. this question are size of the employer they worked grouped into three brackets; 24 employees (small), 25-99 employees (medium), and 100 or more employees (large). analysis of hiring CPS and firing rotation groups from brought in outcomes March is The based on changes in employment status in a match of to April. Finally, each state since 1992 to see if EEOC we use charge activity is data on ADA-related charges related to employment.^ Descriptive statistics organized by survey year, age group, and sex, are reported in Table The table shows no major change in average weeks currently employed, although there and Figure rates for 1 show an increase men aged is worked by men or men aged between 1990 and 1994, which it proportion of in work-related disability rates for men and women. I. men I Disability 40-58 start increasing in the 1991 survey, and remain high thereafter, though starting in 1994. For lower than in the a modest increase in weeks worked by women. Table with a slight decline in 1996 and 1997. Disability rates is 1- was in 1990. 21-39, there is is for women aged 40-58 increase sharply a small increase in self-reported disability rates later reversed, and in 1996 the disabihty rate for this group These patterns suggest the ADA may have had an probability that people describe themselves as disabled, especially for effect women. ^ This on the raises the The estimates we report are weighted bj' CPS sample weights. The weights were updated in 1994 to reflect the 1990 Census. We use newly released updated weights for the 1990-1993 surveys as well. The 1988 CPS data come from the so-called March "rewrite" file. This file includes firm size and other variables not on the original 1988 release, and reflects a revised imputation procedure (Bureau of the Census, 1991). The extract excludes the hispanic oversample for each year. A few dozen households with duphcate household identifiers in the 1994 survey were also excluded because they could not be included in the matched samples. ^The analysis variables are state/year aggregates from our tabulations of EEOC microdata. These are similar to less recent statistics published in EEOC reports. ^The fact that the disabled may be an elastic population has been noted by 01 (1991) and Kubik (1997). On the other hand, Dwyer and Mitchell (1998) argue that disability status does not appear to be endogenous in models of retirement behavior. 10 we return possibility of composition effects, a point Results V. A. to in the discussion of results. Employment and Wage Effects Figure 2 plots average weeks worked by sex and disability status. While on average over 45 weeks a noteworthy men work year, disabled less first full year in which the disabled women aged ADA was There in effect. is 21-58 work than 20 weeks on average. Especially the 2 week decline in weeks worked by disabled is men aged men between no sharp decline 1992 and 1993, the in weeks worked by 21-58. Weeks worked FigTues 3a and 3b plot average weeks worked separately by age group. by disabled men aged 21-39 dropped sharply between 1992 and 1993, while those by disabled women aged 21-39 started falling in 1992. Weeks worked by men aged 40-58 was an increase decline between 1992 and 1993. In contrast, there women aged women when Table II 40-58 between 1992 and 1993, which the two age groups for women is why we do in not see a decline for disabled are pooled. (6). are from regressions of weeks worked and log weekly wages on age and race and year x disability interactions coefficients of interest. Because the as post-treatment years. 1992 is ADA show a marked weeks worked by disabled reports ordinary least squares (OLS) estimates of equation disability effects, also came for 1991-1996. The These estimates dummies, year and interaction terms are the into effect in July 1992, we think of 1993-96 possibly a transition year, while the effects for 1991 can be seen as '"pre-treatment" specification tests. The table also reports estimates from specifications including a linear time trend interacted with disability status, and a single-effect model that includes a trend interaction with disability status, 1991 and 1992 interactions with disability and a single post-ADA status, models with trends allow dummy for for the possibility that be explained by extrapolating different trends The results in Table II suggest that the changes in outcomes by disability status can for the disabled ADA and nondisabled. had a substantial and negative effect on the employment of disabled people under 40. Panel by A 1.8 statistically significant For example, column (1) of shows that weeks worked by disabled men aged 21-39 were stable until 1992, but weeks in 1993, and declined by an additional week in 1995. Column (2) controlling for disabihty-specific trends does not change these results. Results for 21-39 are similar (columns 4-6), but the decline starts in 1992. in 1992 The 1993-1996 interacted with disability status. and 1993 suggest that the the law became effective. This is costs of the ADA shows that women aged The sharp employment dechnes were not anticipated by employers before not too surprising since the 11 fell first years of ADA enforcement were characterized by some confusion regarding exactly what the act required and Sims, B weeks 1.8 in 1993, but this effect weeks after controlling employment into effect. The reports estimates for the 40-58 age group. is women aged Moreover, columns and (5) 40-58, but this show that these (6) is column (4) evidence that the ADA had an effect the other hand, shows a decline in 1991, before the is effects change on the employment of disabled we came control So there sign. women in the ADA disappear once for disability-specific trends, and, in fact, the coefficients of interest little On added. men generates a statistically significant, decline of 2.1 (3) for disability-specific trends. Finally, of disabled disabiHty-year interaction for halved when a linear trend the single-effect model reported in column relative Veres 1995). Panel is (see, e.g., is in the 40-58 age group. Columns women aged A (7)-(12) in Panel There 21-39. effects disappears in is an effect Moreover, inclusion of trends. decline in wages for older suggesting that the on men models with a trend. aged 21-39. The wage estimates for older in 1994, There is but not in other years, and the 1994 no evidence of a wage We starts too soon. ADA had little effect on women in therefore interpret the Panel B, the wage the relative wages of disabled workers. the paper focuses on further analyses of employment effects only, and the analysis demographic groups where the evidence in women effect for men, reported in Panel B, are also sensitive to the the employment effects for older like women men and report estimates for the log weekly earnings of for effects is strongest results as The is rest of limited to —women aged 21-39, and men both age groups. Composition Bias A Figure possible explanation for the shows an increase 1 employment results in Table 11 is in self-reported disability rates after 1991. were disproportionately more likely to identify We 1993 respondents. matched sample those who do worked in is effect. Tmemployed people II ADA, perhaps could overestimate ADA. investigate the possibility of composition bias using a and 1994 CPS's. In If themselves as disabled after the because disability became more socially acceptable, the results in Table the disemployment effects of the a composition principle, the matched sample from the 1993 matched sample provides two observations (In practice the match rate is used here to compare individuals lower; see who Appendix A for half of the for details). The report a disability in both surveys to not report a disability in either year. Since these surveys report data on weeks 1992 and 1993, the matched data set provides a short panel that straddles the implementation date and is ADA's imaffected by composition bias arising from changes in reporting 12 behavior. Results using the matched sample are reported in Appendix Table Al. the basic cross-sectional specification for 1993 and 1994 data only. sample of individuals for the for whom Column Cohrmn the mat.ch was successful. Al are similar to those in Table II. (1) reports results for The Comparing cohimns cross-sectional and (1) (3), it is apparent that the restriction to the same disabihty status in both years has almost no men aged the results for 40-58 and women aged 21-39. This is repeats (2) reports results (3) the sample of individuals reporting the same disability status in both years. estimates in Table Column effect on important evidence against the presence of composition effects since disabihty rates increased more for these two groups than younger men. for the men aged For 21-39, the results using a sample smaller than in the 93-94 cross-section. in weeks worked, as compared to a matched decline in the to a 1 week decline, cross-section. which is 1.2 The Adding controls closer to the 1.5 allocated by the Census effects either. In fact, the since disability rates for composition story men aged for personal characteristics a 3.1 week changes this in the corresponding full where supplement and weeks worked data were of -1.3 (reported in men aged is unchanged are in the full cross-section, or week decHne observed Bureau generates an estimate these estimates suggest that the results for disability status is disabihty-constant sample shows a 0.3 decline week decline Finally, excluding observations cross-section. where column (7)). Overall, 21-39 are not generated by composition not plausible for this demographic group anyway, 21-39 are actually lower at the end of the sample period than beginning, and the increase in disability rates could account for at most half of the decline at tlie in weeks worked. Changes in the SSI and DI Programs Another factor affecting the interpretation of Table II is an increase in the number of people receiving disability payments from the Disability Insurance (DI) and Supplemental Security Income al, (SSI) who worked programs in the early 1990s (see, e.g., Stapleton, et long enough are entitled to receive DI payments gainful activity. 1994). Disabled workers when not engaged in substantial Disabled people without a work history can receive SSI, which tested federal benefit that adverse labor supply is effects, supplemented by some Appendix B using CPS data on II social security Weidenbaum, program use. are not explained by trends in SSI the estimates). 13 account for the dechne in 1994). The a means- SSI and DI payments create may increased use of these programs disabled employment (a possibility suggested by that the results in Table states. Since is We address this issue in results of this analysis suggest and DI receipt (see Table Bl for Magnitudes The estimates in Table II can be compared to estimates of the effect of the ADA on the costs of employing disabled workers. Unfortunately, there are no good estimates of these costs, so The average our calculations are really just educated guesses. was about 12 per 1000 disabled employees a percent of all ADA charges, employers made fraction of charge rate EEOC, about In cases resolved by the year. 14 average payments of over $15,000 per case. In the remaining cases, either the charge was dropped, know what EEOC pending, or there was a is ADA charges end up in court. suit. We do not However, between 1995-97 there were over 56,000 employment discrimination cases brought in federal court (Administrative Offices of U.S. Courts, 1997). The total number employment discrimination charges of during this period was 245,000, which implies that 23 percent of We apply this fraction to ADA charges, charge does not go to court or get settled by the This is 50, ADA 400 x 0.012 charge = is with the EEOC charges went to court. and use the cost estimate of $210,000 per case offered by Condon and Zolna (1997). To be on the conservative average cost of an all filed EEOC, side, we also assume that + 0.14 x ADA The estimated there are no other costs. therefore equal to 0.23 x 210, 000 an if 000 15, = 50, 400. $605 a year per disabled employee, or $12 for each week of exposm-e to the risk of a suit. Assessing the cost of reasonable accommodation Network (1997) reports a monetary cost cost.' Our estimates a $23 increase in weekly 12+23=35 in even harder. The Job Accommodation accommodation, which we take as the net of $930 per of separation rates in the next section suggest that the average duration of a job lield by a disabled about $365 is employee employment 1991 and 1992. dollars, our is 10 months, which implies that accommodation leads The average weekly earnings costs. of the disabled were Since the total weekly cost increeise due to the rough estimate is that the ADA to ADA is about led to a 10 percent increase in the cost of employing disabled workers. In the theoretical and are always on model their labor employers take the total cost of labor as given in Section III, demand curve. Since the results in Table II show ADA falls of a change in disabled wages, the cost increase generated The 10 to 15 percent decline in weeks worked about -1 to -1.5 for disabled workers. Hammermesh This is is by the therefore consistent with in the little evidence on employers. demand elasticities of range of elasticity estimates reported by (1986) for workers in different demographic groups. ^This number excludes any productivity increases due to or sub-optimal reorganization of the work environment. 14 accommodation and any losses from job changes The Impact of the B. We iised ADA on Hiring and Separations matched CPS rotation groups from March on hiring and separation April match). is ADA employed An individual March in is rates (see of that year March while for details relating to the and not in in April. Similarly, March is employed an accession March-to- t if he or she (hire) is recorded in April. Separations are defined for accessions are defined for those not working in March. Disability status always refers to March. those used by Poterba and A coded as having experienced a separation in year when someone who was not employed those working in Appendix to April to investigate the effect of the These measures of accession and separations are the same as Summers (1986), and the resulting average accession and separation rates are close to those they report.® The estimates by the affected of effects CPS on separations and accessions are imprecise and also potentially come from the main CPS survey and redesign (since the underlying data not the supplement). Moreover, Poterba and Summers data are plagued by considerable measurement error. (1986) We show that labor-market transition therefore hmit the discTission in this section to a brief graphical analysis. Figure 4a-d plot log accession and separation rates by disabihty status, sex and age group.^ Figure 4a shows a post- ADA decline in separation rates for disabled workers aged 21-39, though there is also a decline for the nondisabled. On the other hand. Figure 4b shows a post- AD A decline in the luring of disabled workers aged 21-39 that nondisabled, especially for women. is not mirrored in the data for the Figure 4c, which plots separation rates for the 40-58 age On group, again shows no evidence of changes unique to the disabled. as clear as the change in disabled hiring for the of a relati\-e decline in hiring for disabled liiring for men and younger women men the other hand, while not yoimg group. Figure 4d shows some evidence in the older group. are not surprising since The apparent reductions employment groups for these fell. in It important to note, however, that the lack of a clear reduction in disabled separations weighs is against a pure "firing costs" model of the ADA. Results By Firm Size C. Next, less we look at employment patterns by firm than 15 employees are not covered by the size. This ADA, and is of interest because firms with those with 16-25 employees were ^The average separation rate for 1988-1997 is 0.026 for men and 0.036 for women. The average accession is 0.18 for men and 0.08 for women. The disabled have higher separation rates and lower accession rates rate than the nondisabled. ^For instantanous accession and separation e = ;^- We plot log accession rates, and separation 77 and (, rates because 15 the steady-state ^ = employment rate (^^ - ^^) . (e(l - is e)). approximately exempt. The initially since, as ADA noted in Section might also have had a larger III, in small firms small firms are probably less able to absorb ADA-related costs. we might expect the Together, these considerations suggest on employment on employment effect in firms that are sufficiently large to enough to be vulnerable to an increase ADA to have be covered by ADA had the largest effect provisions but small in costs. Figures 5a-c plot the log of the probabihty of working in a particular firm size category As noted divided by the probability of not working. earlier, the size category refers to the The worker's longest job last year as recorded in the supplement. and 100 or more (small), 25-99 (mediimi), (large). The size categories are 1-24 figures give a visual representation of the coefficients in a multinomial logit model where the dependent variable size-category, and non-workers are the reference group. The log-odds effects. in The independent is employment-by- variables are year each figure were computed separately for disabled and non-disabled workers. The log-odds of working in a than log-odds of working groups. For medium size firm in a small firm after women, there is also a relative appear to have fallen somewhat more steeply 1992 for disabled workers in small contrast for men aged if ADA nondisabled workers, suggesting the there were effects on the nondisabled, effects (e.g., t=1.4 21-39), but they are negative for all three employment by firm In contrast with this pattern, the log-odds of for it three demographic decUne in the probability of working Estimates of these differing trends by firm size are not very precise vs. all had no seems effect in a large firm. for the mediimi demographic groups. size are essentially parallel on the nondisabled. Of course, even likely that they would be much smaller than on the disabled, and therefore harder to detect. D. Cross-state Variation The last strategy we use state-level variation in in ADA Charge to estimate the ADA impact of the charge rates. to separately identify the impact of the the purposes of this analysis, the ADA Rates ADA relates changes in employment to Like the firm-size analysis, this strategy allows us ADA on disabled and nondisabled employment. For charge rate is defined as the number of ADA-related discrimination charges, in a state, per thousand population disabled in the state in 1992 (the latter figiu-e estimated using the 1992 1993, 1994 CPS). Charge rates are calculated separately and 1995, but 1992 population data are always used Charge rates vary considerably by state. The average cumulative per 1000 disabled persons aged 21-58, varying from a 40/1000. Variation in charge rates is for the minimum for 1992, denominator. rate for 1993-95 of 6/1000 to a was 13 maximum of generated by idiosyncratic differences in state labor force 16 composition, local awareness of ADA provisions, cross-state differences in employers' compliance ADA, and whether with the Some workers. a state previously had an had weak states laws, while others penalties in cases where discrimination is FEP statTite that had laws that covered disabled set criminal as well as civil proved (Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental Relations, 1989). The estimating equation for this strategy is: 96 Vidst = x'iP + + 4>ds 5dt+ Yl adAfhrTs^T-l) + Vidst, (7) r=93 where ijidst is and t, X, is weeks worked by individual i with disabihty status d hving in state The a vector of individual characteristics (age and race dummies). interest are interactions between year dummies (e.g., /i.ga) includes separate state effects for each disability group, 0ds, of interest, 0^,93, 0^,94, 0^,95 and 0:^,96, regressors of (e.g., rs,92). Equation and year x disability are the coefficients now full set of state x year x disability interactions in the models. We play the role of control variables. also report estimates trends for each state x disability group to equation The with a large number of for women aged The show that results in Table III effects in ADA 21-39 and in 1993-94, on the state/year we do not The year x disability from a model that adds weeks worked by the disabled Some men of the estimates 40-58 are negative and significant in other years as well. 1993 are implausibly large, probably because the charge rate in 1992 was very annual charge rate of 4/1000 men aged is ADA mean predicted to reduce employment by 2.6 weeks based on the 1994 21-39. In contrast with the estimates for the disabled, there impact of linear in states low, but estimates for other years are of a plausible magnitude. For example, hah-ing the estimate for effects (7). charges declined relative to other states. men aged (7) also effects, 8dt- charge rate interactions for each disability group. These effects are identified because have a year and the charge rate per disabled person in the previous year in the individual's state of residence The parameters s in charges on the non-disabled. nondisabled appear in models that control The only is no consistent evidence of a negative significant negative estimates for the for linear trends. For the most part, these estimates are considerably smaller than the corresponding estimates for the disabled. As a nous. final strategy, we experimented with IV estimation The instnmient was a dimamy for of (7) treating diTTs,T-\ as endoge- whether a state previously had an discrimination against the disabled, interacted with disabihty status and mies. The presence of a preexisting probably because the ADA was FEP less of discrimination against the disabled. law is FEP law restricting post-ADA year dum- negatively correlated with ADA charge rates, an innovation in states with their own laws restricting For example, the states with preexisting 17 FEP laws had 15 percent lower suggest that the ADA charge rates. The resulting IV estimates are imprecise but they also ADA had larger disemployment effects on the disabled in states with more ADA-related charges. Conclusion VI. Some social critics see the ADA as part of a process eroding the traditional employment-at-will more doctrine and making the U.S. labor market ADA proponents see the ADA as like labor markets making the labor market more without appreciably inclusive, Economic theory increasing employer costs or reducing employment. Europe. In contrast, in useful for evaluating is these alternative views and suggests avenues for inquiry, but does not make imambiguous predictions. In 1993, the first full year in which the the employment of disabled employment seem men aged ADA in effect, there 21-58 and disabled trends, composition effects, and changes to account for this decline, leaving the ADA women aged were marked drops in 21-39. Extrapolating DI and SSI participation in do not rates as a likely cause. This interpretation supported by evidence that employment of disabled ADA-related charge activity and by was men fell more sharply relative declines in disabled in states employment in is also with more medium size firms. Since the ADA and accession rates provides a form of employment protection, for the disabled. There is little it can lead to lower separation evidence of an effect of the separations, however. This and the fact that costs of reasonable accommodation are probably larger than the costs of litigation for wrongful termination suggests that ha\'e been more important for we found no evidence its fiercest opponents (e.g. accommodation costs employers than lawsuits. The absence of an offsetting decline in wages suggests the equal pay provision has also played a Finally, ADA on disabled role in the of effects on nondisabled workers. Olson, 1997), it seems likely that the ADA's employment effects. Contrary to the concerns of ADA predominantly affected the costs of employing the disabled, and has not led to a fear-of-litigation climate that reduced the overall level of employment. 18 Appendix A: Data Issues 1. March 1993 to March 1994 Match In principle, households in rotation groups 1-4 in 1993 are interviewed in they are in rotation groups move or are lost for other For the piirposes of the 93/94 match, we selected individuals in the relevant rotation reasons. groiips, In practice, some of these households 5-8. March 1994 when with valid interview status (CPS item H-HHTYPE=1), and in the age range of interest (CPS (21-58 for 1993 and 21-60 for 1994). Records were matched using the household identifier H-IDNUM), person item fine H-MIS equaled 1993 H-MIS number (CPS item A-LINENO), and rotation group Of the March 1993 records ehgible plus four). for (i.e., 1994 matching, 76.2 percent were matched to a March 1994 record. We defined a successful match as a person with the same sex and race both years. 70.9 in percent of eligible March 1993 records were matched according to this definition, a rate similar to that reported in Peracchi match basic on the 1994 restrictions ICPSR and Welch 93 percent of the records that satisfied the (1995). were also matched on sex and race. Because the household incorrect, the file is matched data use a corrected household identifier identifier for 1994 provided by the Census Bureau. 2. Consequences of the As noted CPS Redesign in the text, the redesign computer-assisted interviewing changed the main questioimaire and instituted universal (see, e.g., Pohvka (1996)). The supplement questionnaire was unchanged but these other changes may have affected the nature or likelihood of supplement sponses. A conducted parallel survey and paper-and-pencil interview that some in 1993 showed few differences between computer-assisted Later, however, results for the supplement. of the annual earnings data collected in the 1994 lected for subannual amounts (Bureau of the Census, fixed in later surveys. re- To minimize the consequences 1994). it was discovered supplement were mistakenly The problem appears col- to have been of errors in annual earnings, we exclude observations on weekly wages below $25 or above $2000 (in 1988 dollars). One rates, possible consequence of the redesign which were low .in the 1994 CPS and high in the 1995 from G. Weyland, Bureau of the Census) This . people who do not respond of the redesign is affects the in CPS supplement non-interview (personal communication data because Supplement variables for are "allocated" by the Census Bureau. Another possible consequence a change in the type of people the impact of these phenomena, data were collected using the old these two years to people was fiuctuation who report themselves as disabled. we used the March 1993-94 matched CPS data. To assess The March 1993 methodology. This allows us to restrict the sample for who responded to the 19 CPS supplement in 1993 (i.e., their responses were not allocated), and/or who identified themselves as disabled in both years, and/or who answered the supplement questions on weeks worked in both years. The 1994 results of this analysis are reported in Table Al. Again, the coefficient of interest dummy dimimy interacted with a being disabled. Except for for men aged is a 21-39, results under a variety of sample restrictions are remarkably consistent with the main set of crosssectional results, though less precisely estimated. The considerably across columns, and in some cases are column sectional results in lower for this age group. This variability (1). results for much men aged 21-39 fluctuate larger or smaller than the cross- may be due to the fact that match rates are Controlling for schooling, marital status, and veteran status reduces the fluctuation in estimates across samples. 3. March to April Matches for 1988-1997 March households in rotation groups 1-3 and 5-7 are eligible for interviewing in April. Observations to be matched were selected on the basis of rotation group, interview status, and age, as described for the March 1993-94 match. Revised Census Bureau rules necessitated additional criteria for matching records in some years. We confidentiality therefore matched households using the household identifier (H-IDNUM), person line number (A-LINENO), rotation group status (i.e., code (HG-STCO). Of the April H-MIS equaled March H-MIS eligible March April record using these basic criteria phis one), and 1960 Census state records, 92.8 percent were successfully matched to an (H-IDNUM, A-LINENO, H-MIS, and HG-ST60); percent were successfully matched on both the basic criterion and sex and race, which is 88.6 95.4 percent of tliose matched using only basic criteria. Appendix The CPS B: Effects of SSI and DI on Employment of the Disabled SSI and social security income (OASDI). For identifies individuals receiving workers below retirement age, the latter consists of disability benefits and survivor benefits. We coded everyone receiving more than $75 (in 1988 dollars) a week in social security income as receiving DI since survivors benefits are typically smaller than (Department of Health- and of men and women and SSI rolls The still ADA, for pre-retirement Services, 1992, Tables 5A.5-6). Figure of different age groups receiving SSI and/or DI. predate the programs might Human DI the timing is close Bl age groups plots the fraction Although increases enough that disemployment in the DI effects of these provide an alternative explanation for the decline in disabled employment. investigation of this possibility is compHcated by the cause and a consequence of employment status. 20 fact that disabihty income is both a We iise the following simultaneous equation model to describe causal relationships and employment: Social Security benefits where yu weeks worked is disability status; of disability status Vit = x[i0o + as,t su = x[iPi + 6iyu for individual that are orthogonal to have (5i < x^t and a^- for and Sit But who works more even after controlling also time at £,( in fact this increase Table II One Table xu is (8b) a vector of controls, time dummies, and transfer payments, and a,^ The parameters years. and t^jj is the interaction of interest are the are almost certainly negatively correlated, will generally be observable characteristics. income less likely to receive disability Since DI and SSI are means-tested, we captures the possible labor supply consequences of any transfers and in Table II, may is II amount to omitting greater for those reporting a work-related disability. therefore be biased downwards (i.e., strategy to correct this omitted variable bias ignoring the fact that benefit receipt dummy for income from SSI or DI resulting coefficient estimate men aged 21-39 receipt has still + Vit, Sjj is from equation Figure Bl shows that the proportion receiving SSI and DI increased over the sample, and (8a). The (8a) are error terms that capture unobserved effects rj^t presumably negative. The regressions reported a + itdit + Sit 0. The parameter a in t, dummy indicating federal and a dummy for post-ADA interaction coefficients 7j as before. since an individual i a s^t is between is reduced, but is is is still is add to endogenous. and negative. As a an even larger impact on weeks worked, so the group disappear s^t in later years. As to the regressions reported in We do this in Table Bl by adding men and women aged result, the statistically significant. negative and precisely estimated in 1993 and 1994. for this of 7t too negative). to our basic specification for large The estimates For impact of the men aged effects of the ADA 21-39.^° ADA 40-58, SSI or DI are smaller, but However, the disemployment before, the effects for women aged on effects 40-58 appear to start too early. Next, we expand imphcit tax rate the model to recognize that federal benefits can have both income and effects. Instead of the constant coefficient a, the effect of benefit receipt in ^°These models also include the regressors used to predict wages in other specifications described below. The regressors are age, age squared, a dummy for age 30-39 or age 40-49, two race dummies, dummies for high school graduates, some college and college graduates, dummies for married, separated, widowed, and having served in Vietnam or other mihtary service, state dummies and finally a dummy for answering yes to the question "Did you ever retire or leave a job for health reasons" Adding these covariates to the regressions in Table II does not change the results since the post-ADA/disabihty interactions are essentially uncorrelated with individual characteristics. . 21 equation (8a) now assumed is to be: = Oiit where wn is Oio + aiTiWit, the predicted wage of the individual (as a function of the observables Xu), and Ti is the tax rate induced by DI or SSI means-testing, qq captiu-es the effect of additional unearned income, and qiTi captures the fact that after-tax wages are are presumably negative. model with tax Both and Sit Columns and (2) (8) in — (1 TiSit)Wit- Both qq and ajTi Table Bl report the results of estimating the effects: have negative u),fSj( the income effect is 13 weeks, For example, in column coefficients. and the coefficient worker earning $500 a week, an increase employment by one week. Estimates men aged 21-39, on the interaction term suggests that in the tax rate for a from 50 percent to 60 percent reduces impact of the of the (2), for ADA in these models are similar to those estimated in regressions without WnSit. The estimates so far do not account for the likelihood that benefit receipt determined. (i.e., It is straightforward to show that the resulting estimates of too small in absolute value). strategy. We endogenoiisly are biased upwards therefore experimented with an instrumental variables This approach begins by assuming that Su has two components, means-tested and non-means-tested benefits. In particular, like jt is = let s^t 5,t -I- where s^ Sit, is a means-tested benefit SSI or DI. Only means-tested benefits should have a tax-rate effect so the estimating equation becomes Vrt To implement = this strategy ing veterans benefits, SSI, any payment (military, railroad, eral stipend that ^uPo is we + set Ck'oS,( s^t + aiTiWuSu federal 'jau + (9a') Sit, equal to an indicator for any federal stipend, includ- OASDI payment, and + or another federal pension or disability-related employee disability pensions). subject to means-testing, i.e., SSI, s,t DI and any veterans benefits that are means-tested. Means-testing of veterans benefits can be determined from a asks whether respondents are required to of Veterans Affairs. benefits who The instrument fill indicates any fed- CPS question that out an income questionnaire for the Department for s^ is an indicator for individuals receiving veterans are not subject to means-testing, on the presumption that these benefits are not endogenous.^^ The interaction term, iy,«s,t, is instrumented using the interaction of predicted '^Means-tested veterans' benefits include some veterans pension and survivor benefits. Non-means-tested veterans benefits include veterans compensation and schooling benefits (see, e.g., Department of Veterans AiTairs 1990) 22 wages with an indicator The reasoning 9). is here having had a previous disability that led to job loss (see footnote for is that a worker potentially eligible for DI. The who left a job because of a work-related disabihty regressions include a main effect for having had a previous work-related disability, so the identification comes from the interaction with Wn. Cohimns (3), (4), (9), and two-stage least squares (2SLS). for (10) report OLS This generates results similar to those using only an indicator SSI or DI as a control. 2SLS estimates of models without an interaction term, reported in columns and (5) (11), show much smaller effects of disability benefits consequently larger disemployment effects of the Finally, These columns results (6) and show smaller of disabled effect is men aged The e\-idence of in the OLS men aged ADA models. both Su and WitSit as endogenous. on young workers, but there are 21-39 by 2.3 weeks in 1993. For yoimg disabled ADA on weeks worked, and ADA still appears to have reduced the employment still women, the implicit tax has a statistically significant negative effects in 40-58, the estimates are week decline over the whole sample period. The little than effects of federal disability benefits considerably larger, but the 1993 and 1994. For ADA (12) report the results of treating precisely estimated implicit tax effects. 2 estimates of the models to be estimated by effects after controlling for 23 more precise, results for and show an approximately women aged endogenous benefit 40-58 again show receipt. References Abram, Thomas Effect (1993), "The Law, its Interpretation, Levels of Enforcement Activity and on Employer Activity," American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 83, 62-66. Addison, John and Jean-Luc Grosso (1996), "Job Security Provisions and Employment: Revised Estimates," Industrial Relations, 35, 585-603. Administrative Offices of U.S. Courts (1997), Judicial Business of the United States Courts, http://www.uscourts.gov/judiciaLbusiness/contents.html. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental Relations (1989), Disability Rights Mandates: Federal and State Compliance with Report A-111, Washington DC: Gary Becker, Employment Protections and US GPO, Architectural Earner Removal, April. The Economics of Discrimination, Second Edition, Chicago: The (1971), University of Chicago Press. Bentohla, Samuel, and Giuseppe Bertola (1990), "Firing Costs and Labor Bad Is Eurosclerosis?," Review of Economic Studies Demand: How 57, 381-402. Bound, John (1989), "Self-reported Versus Objective Measures of Health Status ment Models,", Journal of Human Resources Bureau of the in Retire- 26, 106-138. CD-ROM, Census (1991), Current Population Survey, March 1988-91 on Technical Documentation CPS-91-CD, Washington: US Department of Commerce (issued Oc- tober 1991). Bureau of the Census (1994), Income, Poverty, and Valuation of Noncash Benefits: 1993, Current. Population Reports, Consumer Income Series, Report P60-188, Washington: US GPO. Burkhauser, Richard and Mary Daly (1996), "Employment and Economic Well-Being Following the Onset of a Disability," in Jerry Marshaw Benefits, Kalamzoo: The Upjohn Clarke, Richard (1996), Underwriters Property & DeLeire, Thomas & "Employment Practices Liability Risks on the Rise," National On the Rise of EPL Insurance," National Casualty-Risk &Benefits Management, 09/15/97. (1997), of Health Social Security Bulletin, Work and Cash Casualty-Risk &Benefits Management, 11/11/96. Disabilities Act," University of Department Disability, Institute. Condon, David and Stan Zolna (1997), "Stakes Underwriters Property et al, eds.. and "The Wage and Employment Effects of the Americans With Chicago Department of Economics, mimeo, November. Human Services (1992), Annual Statistical Washington DC: US Government Printing 24 Supplement Office, 1992. to the Department of Veterans USGPO, Washington, DC: Affairs (1990), January 1990. Dertouzos, James N. (1988), The RAND End Report P-7441, Santa Monica: the of Employment- at- Will: Legal and RAND Diamond, Peter and Eytan Sheshinski Benefits" Journal of Public Federal benefits for Veterans and Dependents, Economics Economic Costs, Corporation. "Economic Aspects of Optimal Disability (1995), 57, 1-23. Donahue, John and Peter Siegelman (1991), "The Changing Nature of Employment Discrimination Litigation" Stanford Law Review 43, 983-1033. Donahue, John and Peter Siegelman (1993), "Law and Macroeconomics: Discrimination Litigation Over the Business Cycle" Southern California Employment Law Review 66, 709- 765. Dw'yer, D. S., and 0. Mitchell problems as Determinants of Retirement: (1998), "Health Are Self-Rated Measures Endogenous?," NBER Working Paper 6503, April. Epstein, Richard A. (1992), Forbidden Grounds: The Case Against Employment Discrim- ination Laws, Cambridge: Harvard University Press. EEOC EEOC (various years). Annual Reports, Washington DC: US GPO. (1995), Technical Assistance Program, Disability Discrimination: Employment crimination Prohibited by the Americans with Disabilities Act of 1990, Washington Dis- DC: US GPO, May Freeman, Richard B. (1981), "Black Economic Progress After 1964: Why?," in Sherwin Rosen, ed., Studies in Who has Gained and Labor Markets, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 247-294. Gruber, Jonathan (1994), "The Incidence of Mandated Maternity Benefits," American Eco- nomic Review 84, 622-641. Hammermesh, Daniel S. (1986), "The Demand for Labor in the Long Run," Chapter 8 O. Ashenfelter and R. Layard, eds.. The Handbook of Labor Economics, Volume /, in Amsterdam: North-Holland. Heckman, James and Brook Payner (1989), "Determining the crimination Pohcy on the Economic Status of Blacks: Economic Review A Impact of Federal Antidis- Study of South Carohna" American 79, 138-77. Hopenhayn, Hugo and Richard Rogerson (1993), "Job Turnover and Pohcy Evaluation: A General Equihbrium Analysis" Journal of Political Economy 101, 915-38. Job Accommodation Network (1997), Accommodation Benefit/Cost Data, mimeo, West Virginia University. 25 Jovanovic, Economy, Boyan (1979), "Job Matching and the Theory of Turnover" Journal of Political 87, 972-990. Kemp, Evan and Work: Jr (1991), "DisabiUty in Our Society," in Carolyn Weaver, ed.. Disability Incentives, Rights and Opportunities, Washington DC: The American Enterprise Institute Press. Krueger, Alan, and Douglas Krnse (1995), "Labor Market Effects of Spinal Cord Injuries in the Dawn of the Computer Age," NBER Kubik, Jeffrey (1997), "Incentives Disabilities: ment The Growth of Economics, Lazear, Edward Working Paper No. 5302, October. for the Identification of the SSI Child Disability and Treatment of Children with Program" University of Syracuse Depart- mimeo, September. (1990), "Job Security Provisions and Employment," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 105, 699-726. Leonard, Jonathan (1989), "Women and Affirmative Action," Journal of Economic Per- spectives 3, 61-76. Leonard, Jonathan (1990), "The Impact of Affirmative Action Regulation and Equal ployment Law on Black Employment," Journal of Economic Perspectives 4, Em- 47-63. Leonard, Jonathan (1991), "Disabihty Pohcy and the Retm-n to Work," in Weaver op. cit. Mortenseu, Dale (1978), "Specific Capital and Labor Turnover," Bell Journal of Economics 9, 572-586. Nickell, Steven (1997), "Unemployment and Labor Market Rigidities: Europe versus North America," Journal of Economic Perspectives Oi, Walter (1991), "Disability and A 11, 55-74. Workfare- Welfare Dilemma," in Weaver op. Olson, Walter (1997), The Excuse Factory: ican Workplace, The How Employment Law is cit. Paralyzing the Amer- Free Press. Oyer, Paul and Scott Schaeffer (1998), "Layoffs and Litigation," Northwestern University, Department of Economics, mimeo. Peracchi, France and Finis Welch (1995), "How Representative Evidence from the CPS," Journal of Econometrics, Pohvka, Anne E. (1996), "Data Watch: are Matched Cross-sections? 68, 153-179. The Redesigned Current Population Survey," Journal of Economic Perspectives 10(3), 169-180. Poterba, James and Lawrence Dynamics" Econometrica, Summers (1986), "Reporting Errors and Labor Market 54, 1319-115. Rosen, Sherwin (1991), "Disabihty Accommodation and the Labor Market," in Weaver op. cit. 26 Riihm, Christopher Lessons J. (1998), "The Economic Consequences of From Europe," Quarterly Journal of Economics Scherer, Frederick Pcirental Leave Mandates: 113, 285-318. and David Ross (1990), Industrial Market Structure and Economic Per- formance, Third Edition, Boston, Houghton Mifflin. Schmalensee, Richard (1989), "Intra-Industry Profitabihty Differences in U.S. Manufacturing:" Journal of Industrial Economics 37, 337-358. Stapleton, David, et al (1994), Labor Market Conditions, Socioeconomic Factors and the Growth of Applications and Awards for SSDI and SSI Disability VHI, Benefits, Arhngton: Lewin- Inc. Summers, Lawrence (1989), "Some Simple Economics Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, Veres, John, and Ronald Sims (1995), xvith Disabilities Act, of Mandated Benefits," American 79, 177-183. Human Westport, Connecticut: Resource Management and the Americans Quorum Books. Waldfogel, Jane (1996), "The Impact of the Family and Medical Leave Act on Coverage, Leave- Taking, Employment and Earnings," Columbia University School of Social Work, mimeo. May. Weaver, Carolyn (1991), Weaver op. "Incentives versus Controls in Federal Disability Policy," in cit. and Alec Levenson, eds., "How Government Reduces Employment" in Lewis Solomon Labor Employment Policy and Job Creation, Boulder: The Westview Weidenbaum, Murray (1994), Press. 27 o m so 00 d o 00 d ON 00 oo OS 0\ en 00 O O o o d NO rf 00 iri NO O d 00 00 o vO oo ON ON On d <u o o 00 00 00 ON o NO o NO ^3- oo ON ON o o ON 00 NO O 00 00 ON m O o d NO U-1 NO 00 00 ON to oo p oo o (N NO 00 m O 00 o > NO rON ^ ^ On O o -a 00 00 On o « 3 NO -a a> BO > o ON or) r^ -* (N in 00 CO 00 a o O d O NO r- 00 0- U o oo r^i d CN 00 00 d o o C^J CN CN 00 o (N f- nD On ON ^ — d 00 o oo d o o CN in o o C3 o CN E o 00 ON (N On OO c-~i o o Q CN aj < On ON 00 00 ON ON C-Nl oo U~) On O o tT m ON On ON CN 00 o o CN NO CO o o « 3 o o 00 2 1) DO < 00 C3 o o 00 oo o d o tu wo ^ 1 -^ o 1) "o u r<-, m ^ 00 o 00 On d u r3 § « ^ o d <r~> ^ ^r 1= O x> CO t/3 C/5 •5 t/5 •a U > C3 t/5 ra D <n X Si On Tf OO CN CN On >0 CN CN C3 > lyj C >^ C« a. Qi t-^ Q o Z NO 00 00 CJ d CN d d o NO CI _ u-i VO CO 00 r<0 d d d r- d «/o iri NO >n o NO m r- 00 ON 'a- ON On o d o d o ON o d O On o NO ro 00 On On NO OJ m d in CO en o >iO 00 ON 0\ d <N d d On d < O o ON 00 ON in oo ^^ oo 00 On f3 ro NO 00 00 ^ ^-^ d o d 00 NO r~ NO vO d d (N On p in ON (N d d O d 00 OO NO OO NO O O O d 00 00 ON (U •a T3 t) 3 C O Ov NO On On 00 o E- 00 O m ^-> o 00 ON On o ON -* m On NO 00 On ON o ro O O O C: (^J 00 O (^J o o NO o ^_^ ^ r4 ON NO rr-, NO ON u CO O o ON 00 0- U NO in rtN O d o o o '^ o d d CO o OO O fN < o >n O d ON On 00 OO ON ON nD 00 d ""^ O fN ON NO 0^ ^ o r^, fN ON ON CO d d -sT On NO ON ri Q ON o o o OO * ON m d ON ON OO > -^ OJ C3 =1 o o JZ u c HJ E o ^ OQ 00 < CO X o T3 5 to CO "i O (U SSI C3 o payments <u 1) 00 <u c "o U >. _o a. C3 -a U E Receives u 1 W ^f DI o 2 — CN in O od c u E o '- OS '^ CN — r~ — o o o OS o\ OJ — m o d d O o 9 o 00 o d d (N O d d E •^ ON 00 r- v~i o o o o o vo OS r~~ o — o d d o o in Tt o o o o o o o o o o o o 00 (S -^ >n o -J — t~ O — o d d o o c5 d m o o d d oo rf oo — ^ o o o o lO 0\ 00 OS o o d d — — o o (N Tl- d> di r^ Tj- o o — OS o o d d> o o — d d — — o o d cS 0\ o o d d 00 00 VO in u u 00 00 so r~ IT) o u 00 00 so rin — o o o d d vO o o o o O o o o so OS rso > d. Q oT c m o O o (U Os o o o CM u-1 O o O o o o o 3 o o 3 o ^^ o o o o o OS O o o B o fN o O o O o 00 o ^^ o 00 so o o o o ^ r~- o o 9 o O o o Os rsO -§ o 00 o o o o o o m o o ros m o Co o o o r-~ so >^ 00 oo p^ d OS rj S ~ — rj OS r- T3 5^ ON in 00 o O ^ (N o s. r*-, > s 9 2. 00 OS sO o P- fN O CO 9 o so >n so m O o — o — o 00 00 o ^ — o c o 00 Tf o 2; "^ Zi so so r^, Os oc r~, ^^ OS ri o) 'f oT (^1 o c, o in O o "3- Os 00 o ir-, Os ri "~ r^. 00 OS in ir, — O m — o in ^~ oo m o m m o CO C3 OS ^ 3 5 u E c OS OS — o tN "" > 1- O — m rj TT C u u OS r) O n o o o — Os ~ o O r- OJ in OS ^^ ^ — m (N d d 00 OS r^, ~~ E Ti- OS rt^ r^, "~ =0 ii _ 00 \0 — — o o in (N (N O d d OS m CO u OS OS in tN o o OS C 00 U C o so Os OS QJ uLU Os P^ 1 CM UJ 6JJ < c a S OS OS OS OS OS OS OS OS m OS OS * SO OS Os Uri H m OS c U. c3 * o J3 X3 K3 C3 C3 Xl a Xl J3 C3 X c o X a O >> — E 3 QJ ^- Os O. c -5 X5 C3 o o o S Z 30 » 00 — m o oo -"a- fn CO c c u E o rn ON ^ o d d o o o d d \o o — o d d <^ so vO VO OS Oo Oo O o o o o OS O 00 oo 1 rsi oo -^ — o d d ^ 00 rr o o d d o o o d d O m o o o m o o o o m IT) mo d d oo ON r- oo d d -"I- mo OS <N Tt oo — O d d r-~ o o n — o o o o d d o — m o dd ON o o d d -^ OS >0 00 ro t-~ O o o o oo 00 o OS o r^ so ro — m o d d o O so On -J •^ -rf (N SO OS o o d d o o o > OS OS d. 1) Q f7 i o o o 00 O o o o so u-1 o o o o O o O so o o o o SO o o o o SO o o o O m o O o so 00 oo m — O d d — — o — d> d ON oo SO >n >/^ (N d o ON o so SO so cN in so sD SO __ O o d — m o o o o — — d> m O — o d SO m X) a a > c r Q. P. ON 53- o ro o d d n-) 00 — CO o o d d -Tt m so — m m o o d d so SO SO D QJ -o J= H <1> n •a >-, — o — o o u so ON O 5 o 00 O O cp "^ "" rn ~ o in so r4 ^~ m o 00 00 r- ^~ (N d d m m t> <NI in ^ C/5 SO 00 "^ cu OS 00 csi O in in 00 a u d d d d — — — oo r~ — I c '^r 1:3 OS 00 in (^ in r^ so r- I^ ON c o l~ >-. oo ON [^ E -a "2 c c •0 -a aj ^ H 01 r^ ro O sD sD SO in so — O o m Cp so O m S o O o O ON OS so (N ON 00 in SO m fN o m c t/1 C/5 aj o;i »^ (ij ? < in 1 0/) :3 — d > ' O m d d OS so ON O t^ so CN d d CN O o o o m so c C c F 1) •n d. 3 ^ -:<: OJ O O c Tt in o OS so o o in so "" O oo OS O o o o 9 -" s o •"~ '^ •~ oo n (N — d d Tl- ~ OS O m so t <u S1 D. n n (1) v: o O o m ? ^ O o r-1 OS OS o O ^3- — O m ^ — o t^ m ^ O ON 1 «) o J= H o O o ro 01) f^ > a on r<-l SO 1 T3 o u so OS OS Lb UJ 00 vn o '^ y 60 < oa c C3 S ™ -D ^^ ON ON * OS ON OS OS * ON so ON OS * * >> X5 C3 Q OS ON m OS eg C8 a X) (5 ro OS OS * c lU H £2 Urn a c £ (1> (A T5 * C3 XI O Xi = P XJ XJ ca C3 •0 CO .. -a ID ^ o o S 2 ?/ ' T3 C o vO 00 \0 vo O — — .' 00 ON \0 CN vo o\ t~~ (^ o o C\ CO — o o Tt CO — O («« lA O u o <u trt ca T3 : -1 U g> ou < c C o r~ 00 00 OS — m 00 m ON CN VO C^ (N 00 — o ON r—I o ' o o Ul < o Qi < a> o "u c > n JLJ E u U '5 C3 U O 00 (/: O DC u ct u, r3 U U O OS O ri O m m r>r) — Tt (^ VD — vo en o— r~- O— m O CM — -o T3 < C3 r^, in \D 00 (N CN O -5 ON VO C o O ON m (N O -* o Z < < Ml U —^ il CQ 4J 3 00 en o o — rn CN r<^ 1 h- (N ON <N O — CM OS " c — c/j Ov O O a. o »y-i — < CN to XI n u -a H \0 r4 00 rj CN ro l/~l m m IT) ON CN m O VD O ro o r-~ r^ o o 00 o u c Q. - U-, 2 i ^ = o B t s-g "E m C3 U ro ON Ov ^ Ov ON m ON ON VO ON as f»^ Ov ON ^ ON ON U-1 ON ON VO ON ON "- " ^ oj — 2 C5 S O U J3 Z J2L "^ >< D. >, 1 A Table Robustness of Basic Results to Sample Restrictions Matched March 1993-March 1994 Data Full All Same Valid Valid Valid Sample Matched Disability Supplement Supplement Supplement Records Status in Response Response Response 1993&1994 (1) (2) 1993 (4) (3) in in 1993&1994 (5) Previous & Column Excludmg Same Allocated Disability in 1993&1994 Weeks Worked (6) (7) Men Aged 2 J -39 Without -1.23 -3.11 -0.30 -3.47 -3.57 -0.04 -0.87 Covariates (0.98) (1.10) (1.35) (1.13) (1.18) (1.41) (1.43) With Covariates -1.54 -3.16 -0.98 -3.42 -3.55 -0.67 -1.27 (0.95) (1.05) (1.31) (1.09) (1.13) (1.37) (1.38) 19271 13251 12669 12072 11247 10811 10656 N Men Aged 40-58 W:thoul -3.75 -3.62 -3.40 -4.18 -3.68 -2.76 -2.65 Covariates (0.77) (0.83) (0.91) (0.86) (0.88) (0.93) (0.93) With Covariates N -4.15 -3.99 -3.58 -4.52 -4.06 -2.99 -2.94 (0.74) (0.79) (0.89) (0.82) (0.85) (0.91) (0.91) 15105 12719 1914 1488 10637 10060 9951 Women Aged 21-39 Without -2.69 -1.13 -2.50 -1.75 -1.51 -2.46 -2.54 Covariates (1.39) (1.69) (2.28) (1.75) (1.81) (2.33) (2.35) With Covariates N -2.29 -1.24 -2.79 -1.90 -1.78 -2.76 -2.85 (1.35) (1.63) (2.21) (1.70) (1.75) (2.26) (2.27) 21372 15130 14467 13878 12958 12469 12388 Women Aged 40-58 Without 1.09 1.55 -0.42 2.32 2.21 -0.17 -0.19 Covariates (1.12) (1.24) (1.55) (1.30) (1.35) (1.61) (1.62) With Covariates N Notes 1.01 1.38 -0.59 2.27 2.18 -0.36 -0.38 (1.08) (1.20) (1.51) (1.27) (1.31) (1.57) (1.57) 16407 13925 12907 12523 11522 10807 10699 Standard errors are shown in parentheses. All entries are OLS estimates of coefficients on the disabled* 1994 equations for weeks worked. Models without covariates include year, age, race, and disabled main effects. Models with covariates also contain education, marital status, and veteran status controls. : dummy in 33 rj 00 io «t On > O ^ V V VO in ro 00 (N o 1 o o o \o 00 00 ^ ^^ VO 00 ra o ^ oo tT (N \o 00 ' 1 ON o o ^ >n o so so d — o— *^ C- — o d d oo 00 On "Z - - > c u E o ^ 2 c^ on o ~ J O '=' — o d d — d — — o 00 so 00 00 m o d 00 o ON rn rt-; d 0\ vo SO r~ mo r- so o cs 00 so — o rn d rn t d >n t^ ^ d — o ro ^^ * --0 00 Tf c-^ d m O so 00 00 r~ ^ d r^ os so d 11 o O o Bo -Eu d d (N 1 • y—»v Os ro o O O o o o 0\ 00 ^^ rso r— o OS so ro r~r<-> ' m o SO r- o rn r~ 1 m o r~- E I 00 00 04 t^ (N «N oi o rsi d u Q ^ o ^ u I T3 aj o i- ^ ^— on oo -J su On ro O O ^ m o 00 — o o o o on ^.— ,,<-*v sD OS CO On r~ p~- i^ — o OS rr- p- — o O in so 1^ r<", ^ f. so ^ r^ ^-v ,,^-s r-- o OS so r~ O o ^.—^ m — o Tf so t~ 0\ 00 t~- r- — o 1 OS 00 so 00 o <1- 00 r- — o o OO <N o OS r<-i 3> sO f^ P-^P-' oo o "J O T oo — <^ 2 T 2 <n. S '^ 2- ro oo <n IT-, o o T 3 O — O O r— d OS SO sD (N Jd u E := o " CO O " c .u -- 00 00 « m o o o o o 1 0\ so o m o ^— „«— > -a >< a o\ 1 ON -J ^ o o d d C/5 ^ > "a (J tLt « I 3 O > — Q on on n ^ -3- F _ r-, •* > ^ OS Ov "" oo in — on -1 2 1^ Ov on -J 9. o o ^ — OS ^ 2 tN m O O in so in in >n — OS in m, O rs) in in in o m o in so OS in r<-i in — in no — o o o — o O sD M O in in O ro in d M in — d d (N d — oo tN in sD ^- in ri CQ S in o m (N o m, r«-, (N CO — d o O o d d r^. On sd r^, d r«-i oo fN rs| d ' ^ on •"" ri -J in rrN o o r^ n mi o —o ) n o o 1^ so in 00 r4 so in o o 1 oo r^ ^ — li^i £• 00 ^r-- in o "^ i^ 00 in ^~ 2- O m "" o ^p- mj rj On in ^ — O o o m ro so in ^" o 1 ^ C o o m in m — o m — o tT r- in o in o in m £ rs< (-) rs O O o o E E 3 — rr- CN r~- o -o Q.T3 OS (N On OS OS OS On On On On * * in ON On SO OS OS !0 on C u Q J3 Q T5 * S" < a X) XI J3 XI o on on (5 ?7 00 -o -d Si E u .S- .E S « 2 .9- ^ "s a >. on -;? T3 »O on on <U 00 5 5 b. c < 2 (>n I o — 1 fN > >o m o O o m O O U1 On VO CTn ra 00 o o O o OS O VO O o o Ov 00 {N VD — O — OV O — O o d d 00 OO Ov ^ X a - > f^ in t^ o m vD — O so VO s 1 sS 9 o m ON >n o o r~- n 00 m o m <N 1 O u u u u OO < « « 3 S >n •o r-- t/v > -n ^ 00J o c u E o VD (N 30 <n o in CO 00 o O in Ov 00 VO vO — o o o m O o VO ov — o o 1 1 ^^ — (N (N o 00 m o o O Ov O o o Ov 1 -C j= o o E 1) q> ^ (N --o in — rn (N (^ vO ~> 00 -J -O — vo — d m O 00 vD d d m ^ vO — d 00 ^ 00 -"t (N vO — d — in vo d d VO vD 0\ vD in d d ON ov ro m d d VO r- r<-) O m oi d r-~ vD in Ov (N 00 r- — ^ d OO rCO d c* 03 -n 9> ^ d — d — rr- m — d E o u ^.^ Q O u F o m m o o O d d o •o ii Q. 4; .^ OJl 00 a 00 :S — ^ I m o 00 — O VO d d n o 00 O vO vO rn o in r<-, O vO — O fN VD — O — ° — vO S o ^ a^ m o o m — O Ov in VO OO — o > •a u m O h) _^ HJ P 3 o a — > c r4 ^ 3 O vO ri ~ -T 00 -1 ^ 00 OJ ^ ^ o (^j :r^ Ov ^ — r~- o OO GO ll: r^, * 9 o O; (-.J B O ^ 2. vO (^) — -* — O ov 00 ^ o o in ^ vO ^~ o^ m £, 3 S- o (N M "* o ^ s o ov Ov" "" O 00 00 "" s t^ in rJ — ^ O vD ov vD OJ Ov Ov 00 m ^ "" vO OO in >n "~ O O in O O^ r<-. r<^, ri S "~ r-i m o ^ OO rn 00 -^ o o OO ov ov ov OO (N — O ' " O 2- OO O vD ^ O OO vO OO 00 r^, — m o o O u u o o — in vO rj m o O O O vO t^ — £ > E "5 2 22 5 C3 ^ c/; 00 -J —o (-4 — — Q 00 (N — £ OO ^ O o in Ov "^ O in o^ " 2- OO 00 "^ 2- 9 O OO OO o o ^" OO O o ^ O vO o o o o o is .E u *^ C OJ -§ > >1 ^ 00 —O r- CM t^ ] o 00 in ^ o o ov" 00 — o o^ o — O — O vO O o o 00 vO O o tN Ov O (N o ffl — D.T3 T3 T3 ^.^ OO l/'l o >^ jz 60 ov ov fN Ov OV * * 'jz: .^ Xi C3 DQ Q OV Ov Tt ov m Ov Ov Ov * vO OV OV x> XI C3 1/5 t/5 t/5 03 V5 Q Q Q i5 ?S' c Q. O (U n . 00 -O 2i * * 0) o T3 Q X3 C3 Q r^. t= C 00 C3^ > > 00 o u 1) # l-H Urn Q. o Q * I X C3 o o (U H^ 60 Q OD 00 00 00 T3 C C « aj o. CO 1) < OO < 0.U ^ 0.10 e a 1 ^^/ 0.09 / / / t h 0.08 A f f 0.07 e c t 0.06- s W 0.05 I 0.04 0.03 - - 88 89 90 92 91 93 95 94 96 Survey Year Sex/Age Group Men age 23-39 Women age 21-39 Figure 1. Work - related disability rates for Men Women men and women aged 21-58 J6 age 40-58 age 40-58 in the 1988-97 March CPS. 97 — r 50 45 W - 40 4 e e k s 35 ^ W 25 -f r k e d 20 15 10 — — I 87 88 89 90 92 91 94 93 Year nondisabled nondisabled Figure 2. Weeks worked last year by sex and men women disabled disabled disability status, 31 CPS men women respondents aged 21 — 58. 95 96 nondisabled nondisabled Figure 3a. Weeks worked last men women disabled disabled year by sex and disability status, 3S CPS men women respondents aged 21 — 39. 50 45- w 40 e e k s 35 W 25 r k e d 20 15 10 - - 87 89 90 92 91 &4 93 Year nondisabled nondisabled Figure 3b. Weeks worked last men women disabled disabled year by sex and disability status, J*? CPS men women respondents aged 40 — 58. 95 96 Separation Rates -1.0 4 -1.5 y. -2.0 -2.5 3.0 - -3.5 - -4.0 88 I I 89 90 93 92 91 94 95 Survey Year nondisabled nondisabled Figure 4a. (Log) Separation rates by • •""• ""• men women disability status and sex. io disabled disabled CPS men women respondents aged 21-39. 96 97 Accession Rates -1.0 -f -1.5- Z.0 -2.5 -3.0- -3.5 - -4.0 1 88 89 1 90 i 91 1 1 92 93 1 94 1 1 95 96 Survey Year nondisabled nondisabled men women • • • *--*--* Figure 4b. (Log) Accession rates by disability status and sex. Vf CPS disabled disabled men women respondents aged 21 — 39. 97 Separation Rates -1.0 -f -1.5- -2.0- -2.5 - -3.0 - -3.5 - -4.0 - -4.5 -5.0 I 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 Survey Year nondisabled nondisabled Figure 4c. men women disabled disabled (Log) Separation rates by disability status and sex. V^ CPS men women respondents aged 40-58. —r96 97 r Accession Rates -1.0 4 -1.5- -2.0 - -2.5 -3.0- -3.5 -4.0 - 88 — 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 Survey Year nondisabled nondisabled men women —— • • •""•-" "• Figure 4d. (Log) Accession rates by disability status and sex. H3 CPS disabled disabled men women respondents aged 40 — 58. 96 97 r Log odds 1- -1 — 87 88 89 90 92 91 93 96 95 94 Year Firm — —• • Figure • 5a. MNL size < 25, nondisabled < 25, disabled size plot of log employment size ^ -•--• and size probabilities disability status 25-99, nondisabled 25-99, disabled size by firm Reference group consists of nonworkers. yv size size 100 size + , nondisabled 100+ , and disabOity status for men aged disabled 21 — 39. — Log odds 1- -1- 2- 3 - — I 1 89 87 90 92 91 93 96 95 94 Year Firm size < 25, nondisabled < 25, disabled size Figure 5b. MNL plot of log employment size and size *--•--• probabilities disability status 25-99, nondisabled 25-99, disabled size 100 size by firm Reference group consists of nonworkers. V^ size and disability status for + , size 100 nondisabled + , disabled women aged 21-39. Log odds 3 1 - 0- -1 87 88 89 90 92 91 93 94 96 95 Year Firm size Figure 5c. MNL < 25, nondisabled < 25, disabled size and size disability status 25-99, nondisabled 25-99, disabled size ^-•--•- plot of log employment probabOities by firm size 100 size size Reference group consists of nonworkers. y^ and disability status for + , size 100 nondisabled + , disabled men aged 40—58. 0.06- 0.05- / s s I / 0.04 r 0.03 D I 0.02 0.01 87 88 89 90 92 91 94 93 Year Sex/Age Group Men Women Figure Bl. SSI or DI recipiency for Men Women age 21-39 age 21-39 men and women aged 21-58 yf in the age 40-58 age 40-58 1988-97 March CPS. 95 96 707 D J Lib-26-67 MIT LIBRARIES 3 9080 01972 0819