Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium Member Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/howeffectiveispoOOfarr HB31 .M415 woTicmg paper department of economics How Effective Is Potential Competition? Joseph Farrell - Number 3 75 May 1985 massachusetts institute of technology 50 memorial drive Cambridge, mass. 02139 How Effective Is Potential Competition? Joseph Farrell Number 3 75 May 1985 JAN 2 5 /f^D TN 84-407.2 How Effective Is Potential Competition? by Joseph Farrell November 1984 Telecommunications Research Laboratory GTE LABORATORIES INCORPORATED 40 Sylvan Road Waltham, Massachusetts 02254 TN 84-407.2 1 1 INTRODUCTION . Competition among firms does many useful things. can prevent It from raising prices above (some appropriate definition of) costs. firms It can be a means whereby differences in belief about v;hat the market wants can be tested, mistakes corrected. and managers' It can be a means whereby production gets All these and more are supposedly carried out by the lov;est-cost producers. benefits from actual competition among firms. However, competition is often limited by economics of scale. case of this natural monopoly industry the is scale exceeds market demand at minimum cost. in which , The extreme minimum In this case, efficient there is an inef- ficiency involved in having actual competition, and there are also likely to be difficulties sustaining competition as an equilibrium. Old-fashioned anti-trust industries: for instance, competition than the is it better efficient worried economists and analysts to have such some productively inefficient unrestrained monopolist? but about But the more recent trend has been to assert that economics of scale in themselves need not lead to any failure of the benefits of competition, as long as potential com- petition is available: "contestability that is, theory" as (Baumol, long Panzar entry as not blocked. is and Willig, In suggests 1982) fact, that if entry and exit are costless, then an incumbent cannot charge more than average cost. In this paper, tive is poteri lal v;e present competition a in simple analysis of the question, doing what actual "How effec- competition is meant to do?" We study a model of an incumbent facing potential entry, and exa:-ine his limit-pricing behavior. testability's The claim by Schwartz conclusion of average-cost and Reynolds pricing is (1983), not robust that conto small changes in assumption, is not borne out in our model; but neither is the claim by Baumol, Panzar and V/illig (1983) that "where costs, markets are almost perfectly contestable." there are almost no sunk TN 84-407.2 2 A MODEL OF LIMIT-PRICING WITH SUNK COSTS AND RESPONSE LAGS 2. Consider an industry with per period. a flow demand which we normalize at this demand is completely inelastic, We suppose one unit both in order to economize on notation and in order to focus on the price-discipline effects of potential competition. A firm can satisfy this demand at a (flow) cost c, but only if it has invested an amount S in entering the This cost industry. is S sunk and not recoverable if the firm leaves. Initially, there is an incumbent firm serving I the market. It sets a pre-entry price p, which it can change with a lag, called the response lag, L. The second active player in the game is (potential) a entrant, The E. entrant observes p, and decides whether or not to enter. If E does not enter, his payoff is zero. a Since there is no entry, gets I payoff valued at /q e""^ (p - c) dt = Pl£ (1) in present value. However, 1982), then, I E arrives, if E chooses to enter, is unable to can I price then (as in Baumol, Panzar and Willig, react, by changing p or otherwise, until date L. below just and p, get the whole market. Once Until time L and E compete in some way we will not precisely specify,- possibly, one of them will leave the industry. We simply write W and W for the pres- ent values at date L of the two firms. We can readily calculate E's payoff from entering: n_ (p; enter) = c> = /J; U (p-c)e"'^^ dt + W^e""^^ (p-c) - S Ci 1 - r e''^ ^ + Wge'""^ - S (2) TN 84-407.2 3 This enables us to find the entry-preventing price which we denote p* , it is : such that (2) becomes zero. p* = c + r (S e'"^ - e - 1 = c + r S + rL e The last term in c + (4) W„) (3) E r ~ - 1 (S Wg) - measures the deviation of p* from the average-cost price In assessing the robustness rS. (4) of contestability theory to small sunk costs, we are thus concerned with the behavior of that term 6 -1 = e^^- when S 1 is small but positive. Proposition I exists S(e) > Proof ^'^ (S - W^) Set ; since W E : Given strictly positive such that if S(e) = 1/2 > 0, by free • z S S(e) then < (e"^^ 6 < (Equivalently, we exit. any and for there 0, e > < 1/2 £• Then l)/r. - and L, r (5) gives us can say 6 that any t < t, exit costs have been included in the sunkness of S.) Can 6 be negative? incumbent. This would correspond to below-average-cost pricing by the The analysis of and (7) (8) below tells us that this will happen only if the incumbent's costs are higher than the entrant's. Proposition 1 and Willig (1983) seems almost perfectly Proposition 2 to vindicate that "where contestable." will indicate: (in our there But are the model) the almost no matter is claim of Baumol, sunk not costs, quite so Panzar markets simple, are as 2 TN 84-407. 4 Proposition For any 2: S exists strictly positive Proof e^^ Take : - 1 < r(S Proposition 2 any > such that L, r, r however small, and any VJ and > 0, to it only 6 > A, however large, there A. choose L sufficiently that W^)A. - has a bite = 0. if W But this, of course, and a very plausible one. cisely the case normally considered, rant's best strategy is "hit-and-run" entry, then certainly W we will small have W^ = after date if, E entrant L, and E the ent- If = 0. is pre- Likewise, incumbent play mixed- a strategy equilibrium of the war-of-attrition game they find themselves in. We now prove one to the case of W„ E Proposition = Proof: = E 0; then we turn 0. When W 3: 6 > further simple result on (5) v;hen W = 0, E and rL is small, > (5) is approximated by S/L (6) The ratio of the claimed approximation to the correct formula is: S/L S/L _ rS/(e^^ -1) 6 = rL e -1, rL This tells us (rL)/2! + (rL)^/3! + 1 + 1 for small rL. that, we if in every neighborhood of Thus, simply knowing that = S S think , p* of L = 0, 5 as a function of S and takes on all nonnegative values is small and L is positive then L, . tells us nothing at all TN 84-407.2 5 about the extent to which potential competition will discipline the incumbent price-setting. his in in relation to L as a Rather, current costs that amount running costs, the response lag L must expect is one the month, sinking of two 6 equal is to is only about 2% of c. 6 We now turn, as promised, 6 If entry costs are a week's running twice c, representing a major distortion. E intuitively by expressing if entry requires Thus, costs, and L is one year, then small is S depends on the number of time-period's S to S. and whether then we can say that the proportional price distortion allowed by the sunk cost to obtain, know to We can put this a little more . fraction or multiple of C; months' need we the case W^ to analysis of either that E > 0. For this case will leave the market at date I L, so that E would become the incumbent, or else that the two firms could share the market and make profit (not allowing for sunk costs). a The latter case is inconsistent with our motivating assumption that actual competition is infeasso we leave ible, it aside and concentrate on E expects to displace Such "displacement" case: as incumbent if he enters. I displacement is, a the former of course, one equilibrium of the war-of-attri- tion game which will result after date L on our assumption that the market is unprofitable for two firms. We can analyze the implications of equating W to the incumbent's value: = W where p* = c P* ^ - + rS + (7) enforcing) -W_) (8) E - e Solving (7) and (S r (8) etiquette 1 gives W is for = , p'^ = c incumbents get average-cost limit-pricing, not hard to understand: S since + rS. to leave In other words, if entered against, and no entry in equilibrium. there is if the (self- then we This result is no entry against incumbents in equi- librium, a potential entrant contemplating entry will calculate on the assump- tion that he would have the market forever, basis. and can thus amortize S on that TN 84-407.2 6 Proposition 4 : exit at date L, If it is the common expectation should E enter, that, I would then equilibrium involves average-cost pricing (and no entry) irrespective of the size of S. While Proposition 4 is of some interest in the model as we have described it, its main importance lies in its extension to initially the incumbent has costs in c. Suppose that rant, and potentially that E would displace other firms, I have costs is very plausible c c c < firms differ case where the . but that the ent- Then the assumption from being just one of (as distinct three equilibria of a war-of-attrition game), and it follows that, if I is to prevent entry, he must set price p* = Cg + rSg (9) He will prefer to allow entry if and only if Cj which is > c^ + rSg precisely the (10) condition under which it socially is desirable for entry to occur: Proposition 5 : If entrant's and incumbent's costs differ, but are common knowledge, then entry occurs precisely v;hen it saves costs overall (given that I's sunk cost is already sunk); and the price V7ill be the entrant's average cost if the incumbent chooses to prevent entry. long-run TN 84-407.2 7 CONCLUSION 3. As Panzar Baumol, dynamic S a = 0, function of L = 0. that positive average cost." is > S showed, natural to monopoly cost, The fixed; and L sunk cost does even when we include model is however, jointly, continuous in if we view the there is an S the in raise prices above model with sunk cost, we have investigated and seen in "average response lag L as a prices above raise cost story, In (1982) does not lead to monopoly power absence of sunk costs average cost. Willig and enable a particular incumbents interest on the (sunk cost) when to sunk the equilibrium limit price essential discontinuity at This means that we cannot predict the relationship of price to average cost based solely on the smallness of S have to have an estimate of their relative sizes. and the positivity of L: we TN 84-407.2 8 REFERENCES Baumol, William, Panzar, John Robert and ble Markets and the Theory of Industry Structure , Contesta- Willig, San Diego : Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, 1982. , ing in the Theory and of , Industry "Contestable Markets-. An UprisStructure: Reply," Ameri- can Economic Review 73, June 1983, 491-496. 3. Schwartz, Marius, and Robert Reynolds, ing the in Theory of Industry "Contestable Markets: An UprisStructure: can Economic Review 73, June 1983, 488-490. 585^1 U7U Comment," Ameri- 2r^'^C? MIT LIBRARIES 3 TDflO DDSflSflMS 1