MIT LIBRARIES 3 9080 02618 0361 DUPL \ ^CBir«t^ :o; Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium IVIember Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/contingentreservOOcaba ^ , 1 DEWEY , Massachusetts Institute of Technology Department of Economics Working Paper Series Contingent Reserves Management: An Applied Frameworii Ricardo J. Caballero Stavros Panageas Working Paper 04-32 September?, 2004 Room E52-251 50 Memorial Drive Cambridge, This MA 02142 paper can be downloaded without charge from the Network Paper Collection at Social Science Research http ://ssrn.com/abstract=59522 MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY DEC 7 2mk LIBRARIES An Contingent Reserves Management: Applied Framework Ricardo J. Caballero and Stavros Panageas September 9, 2004* Abstract One most serious problems that a central bank in an emergeconomy can face, is the sudden reversal of capital inflows. of the ing market Hoarding international reserves can be used to smooth the impact of such reversals, but these reserves are seldom sufficient and always exIn this paper pensive to hold. we argue that adding richer hedging instruments to the portfolios held by central banks can significantly We improve the efficiency of the anti-sudden stop mechanism. lustrate this point with a simple quantitative hedging model, il- where optimally used options and futures on the S&PlOO's implied volatility index (VIX), increases the expected reserves available during sudden stops by as much JEL Codes: Keywords: as 40 percent. E2, E3, F3, F4, GO, Sudden stops, CI reserves, portfolio, VIX, hedging, options, futures. "MIT and NBER, and MIT, respectively. Prepared for the Central Bank of Chile's conference on "External Vulnerability and Preventive Policies," Santiago Chile, August 2004. We are grateful to Andres Velasco and conference participants for their comments, and to Fernando Duarte and Jose Tessada for excellent research assistance. Introduction 1 One of the most serious problems that a central bank economy can face, is the in an emerging market sudden reversal of capital inflows (sudden stops). Hoarding international reserves can be used to smooth the impact of such reversals (see, e.g., Lee (2004)), but these reserves are seldom sufficient and always expensive to hold. and Panageas (2004) we derive and estimate a quantitative In Caballero model to assess the (uncontingent) reserves followed by central banks. management strategy typically We conclude that this strategy is clearly inferior to one in which portfolios include assets that are correlated with sudden stops. As an illustration, volatility sudden we show that holding contracts on the S&PIOO implied index (VIX) can yield a significant reduction in the average cost of stops. This result should not be surprising to those following the practices of hedge funds and other leading investors. Except events, which unfortunately sudden stops are not, dom immobilize large amounts of and risk-aversion. The use for extremely high frequency institutional investors sel- jumps in volatility of derivatives, and the creation of the VTX in par- "cash" to insure against ticular, are designed precisely to satisfy hedging needs. Why should central banks, which aside from their monetary policy mandate, are the quintessenpublic risk tial management institutions, not adopt best-risk-management practices? In this paper we revisit this point in the context of a simpler model designed to isolate the portfolio dimension of the reserves management problem. We estimate the key parameters of the model from the joint behavior of sud- den stops and the VIX, which we then use to generate optimal We show that in portfolios. an ideal setting, where countries and investors can identify VIX and there exist call options on these jumps, an average emerging market economy may expect to face a sudden stop with up to 40 the jumps in the percent more reserves than when these options are not included in the central bank's portfolio. The main tify reason behind this important gain between jumps in the VIX and sudden is the close relation stops. We we iden- estimate that the probability of a sudden stop conditional on a jump in the when there is times the probability of a sudden stop VIX is about four no jump. Another di- mension of the same finding but that speaks more directly of the hedging virtues of the there is VTX, is that while the probability of a no sudden stop rises to over 70 percent in emerging markets when a sudden stop jump is slightly in the VIX when above 30 percent, it takes place in that year. Section 2 in the paper presents a simple static portfolio model for a cen- bank concerned with sudden tral the model stops. Section 3 presents the solution of under various assumptions on hedging opportunities. Section 4 discusses implementation issues. Section 5 quantifies the model. It starts illustrating the behavior of the VIX and its by coincidence with sudden stops in emerging markets (represented by nine economies: Argentina, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Mexico, Thailand aiid Turkey). Brazil, Chile, then estimates It the different parameters of the model and reports the optimal portfolios for a range of relevant parameters. Section 6 documents the impact of the on the ferent hedging strategies availability of reserves during sudden dif- stops. Section 7 concludes. Basic Framework 2 We analyze the investment decisions of a central bank that seeks to minimize the real costs of a sudden stop of capital inflows. Our goal is to provide a simple model to isolate the portfolio problem associated with such an objective. We refer the reader to Caballero and Panageas (2004) for a dynamic framework that discusses the optimal path of reserves as well as the microeconomic that frictions behind sudden stops. Here we simply take from that paper when a sudden for current stop takes place, the country's ability to use consumption tion of such a constraint is is significantly curtailed. its The immediate wealth implica- a sharp rise in the marginal value of an extra unit of reserves. There are two dates made, and date 1, when in the model: date 0, asset returns realize when portfolio decisions are and a sudden stop may take place. We assume that a central bank has an objective of the form: m^-p[{R,-K-l{SS}Zf] X > ((P)) a "target" where Ri denotes total reserves at date reserves at date which we take to be constant throughout, and captures 1, 1. is level of reasons for holding reserves other than the (short run) fear of sudden stops we emphasize. Deviations from this target are costly: a shortfall from the target implies that the objectives of the central bank cannot be met ade- quately. Similarly, an excess level of reserves implies costs of accumulation (which among other things captures the difference between the borrowing and the lending rate, the slope of the yield curve, etc.). The term 1{SS}Z is composed of two terms. An indicator function IfS'^'} that becomes 1 during otherwise, and a constant Z > that controls a sudden stop (SS) and is the need for funds during the sudden stop. This constant captures the in the marginal utility of shift wealth that occurs once a sudden stop takes place. Hence, by construction of the optimization problem, a central bank desires The program to transfer reserves to sudden stop states. ((P)) is to be solved subject to: = ttPo + Bo = Bi+ttPi Ro i?i (1) where Rq is the initial level of reserves, tt is the amount of risky securities held by the central bank, Pq is the price of such securities and Pi is the (stochastic) payoff of these assets at i = 1 Bq is the amount of uncontingent . bonds held by the central bank, whose so that Pi = interest rate we fix to for simplicity, Po, and Pi = Po + 7r(Pi-Po). Replacing this expression in ((P)) and computing the with respect to Rq and vr, first order conditions yields: ^ Ro = K + PriSS)Z == ^ yar(Pi) 4 (2) (^^ where we have removed Merton's portfoho term by assuming we maintain throughout): pricing of the risky asset (an assumption E[P,] = There are three observations about at this stage. First, the central this paper sudden worth highhghting bank has an aversion to over- accumulating — and 0. Under these circumstances, the 0, then Rq bank achieves the maximum of the objective. Our main concern in reserves. central Po. this simple setup K= UZ= fair-risk-neutral is stop, with those reserves that are due to the possibility of a costly Z> 0. Second, the level of reserves invested at date the portfolio, tt, Rq, 0, is independent of This or the properties of the risky asset. is due to the "certainty-equivalence" property of the quadratic model. In fact, with CRRA, general preferences that exhibit a prudence motive, such as a the an increase in hedging (tt) more reduces the total amount of reserves held (see Caballero and Panageas, 2004). Third, and most importantly, risky assets are not held if Pi uncorrected is with the sudden stop, Ij^S"}. Risky assets are only held to the extent that they succeed in creating attractive payoffs during sudden stops, i.e., as long as:^ E[Pi\SS = l] > E[Pi\SS = 0] Prom Conventional Reserves 3 Let us characterize the solution for to Hedges a few cases of special interest. base case model assumes away hedging completely, which what central banks do in practice. The second case is The third is first not far from an Arrow-Debreu setup where contracts can be written contingent on the sudden the opposite extreme. is Our an intermediate stop. It captures case, that allows for "proxy" hedging through contracts that are correlated, but not perfectly, with sudden stops. ^ Where we have re-normalized all potential assets to be held in positive amounts. 3.1 No Hedging Assume that we with respect to set tt. tt = Then in the obviously: Bo As one might to hold reserves why reasons base case model and drop the optimization = = K + Fi{SS)Z. Ro (4) expect, the possibility of a sudden stop induces the country beyond the "target" level K. This is probably one the main Chile, for example, holds four to five times as much reserves as Australia or Canada. 3.2 Hedging vvith Arrow-Debreu Securities Taking the opposite extreme, assume that there exists an asset that pays: 55 = if 55 = 1 if 1 In this case our assumption of fair-pricing implies Po It follows from (3) and the = Pr(55). fact that in this case: = Cm;(l{55}, Pi) yar(l{55}) = Var{P^) that TT Replacing this expression in Bo Not = (1) and = Z. (2) we (5) obtain: K + PviSS){Z-7r) = K. Arrow Debreu securities (and fair pricing) completely hedge away the sudden stop risk, so that: surprisingly, with perfect the central bank will Pi - 1{SS}Z = Bo = K. Now let us express the portfolio of Arrow-Debreu securities as a propor- tion of total reserves: ^^ ~ Ro In the interesting special case where the country finds it K + Pv{SS)Z' where K = (corresponding to the case optimal to hold no reserves in the absence of sudden stops) we have that: 0=1. That 3.3 is, all Arrow Debreu resources are invested in The intermediate In reality, one neither observes securities. case Arrow Debreu securities nor does contracts written contingent on the sudden stop (at least in an ficient to insulate in practice, the its occurrence Hence the ically as the country from sudden stop There are good reasons it). itself is unlikely may depend on a one observe amount for that: to be fully contractible since country's actions practical relevance of the simple suf- and private information. model proposed above rests crit- on whether there are assets and trading strategies that could function good substitutes for the idealized assets envisaged above. Let us develop a simple extension to the Arrow Debreu world above, by introducing an asset when an event that we call J happens (corresponding drop in some asset price). We introduce the notation: that pays 1 discrete i^' ^' V i; ^ = Pr(55=l|J = l) - = Pr(S'5= 1|J = 0) = Pr(J=l) = Pr(55 -- -- = 1) -0' < = to, e.g., a ryV'' and assume that < In this case it is suboptimal risky securities, but in general is for '0'' < 1 the country to invest all of its assets in willing to invest some, provided that The new optimization problem K + i>Z-'nr]. = 5o yields: Notice that these formulas encompass the ones obtained previously. ip^ as = ip^ V''* -^ then the two indicators are independent and thus and 1 completely. -0' — > 0, then ^ ip tt = 0. However, and the country insures the sudden stop rj Short of that, the central bank finds it optimal to do some of the hedging of sudden stops with uncontingent reserves: li < tfj'^ 1, a chance that the risky asset does not deliver during a sudden stop. ip > asset 0, If there is And if the country pays for protection that does not need from the risky -^ Note that we have as a percentage of total reserves, that the risky asset portfolio represents: ttPo Zrj -no -no , ,. , This expression has a natural interpretation. Let x G [0, 1] represent the share of reserves allocated to the prevention of sudden stops in the near future: _tpZ__ _ ^~ K + ipZ' Due number to quadratic utility this is independent of the hedging instru- ments (notice that the properties of J do not influence the optimal portfolio is, the portfolio is = x^ composed {^^ ^Note that with quadratic utiHty it is is subsumed in K= first = 0). and one is the fraction The second captures tp > The proximity for the country to of tp'^ to one only achieved by this strategy. is our fixed K, although financial markets, then this (7) . stops, x.^ suffices that ip 'Note that our sense of prevention volume) where a stock of reserves ^') sudden invest its entire portfolio in the risky asset (for how much hedging - of three terms: the of reserves used for the prevention of determines number). Then is: <t, That this is different from that in Garcia and Soto (this needed to prevent runs on the country. Their concept if runs are related to factors that tighten international term also should be analyzed as an optimal portfolio decision. 8 the relative frequency of jumps and sudden stops; as this rises the price of the insurance jump of a The rises. the difference between the probability is and not taking conditional on a sudden stop taking term captures the latter third one The place. risky asset's ability to transfer resources to the states where they are needed the most. Dividing (/!> by x isolates the share of the risky asset in the reserves used for hedging sudden stops. henceforth by setting x 1 (or i^ = This the concept is we emphasize 0). Implementation issues 4 now take the analysis one step closer Let us we = component of start but by specifying a state variable, Sj, that not under the country's "control." is to actual assets. For this purpose, is correlated with Assume that sudden stops evolves according St to the (discretized) stochastic differential equation: sj+i where /^(sf) is and a jump is > 4.1 Q We let rj is + ctN{0, nist)At mean The most the volatility. process dJi, which section 3.3. = the drift (the one with probability fj,^ -St and standard deviation (8) interesting part of this expression zero except at date random + edJi appreciation rate of the state variable), and zero otherwise, e be a 1)-/At 1, when it is the takes the value in perfect analogy to the setup in variable normally distributed, with mean a^. Call Options Given the above framework, we consider the following thought experiment: Is there a simple strategy that can "create" an asset of the sort envisaged in section 3.3 by writing contracts contingent on s^? this, The answer is yes. To see take the continuous time limit of (8) and consider a contract with an investment bank or insurer in which the central bank pays an amount Kdt in exchange for each dollar received time such a contract is if St well defined. exhibits a jump at i = 1. In continuous In reality, one can approximate signing a sequence of appropriate (sufficiently out of the money) it by "digital" . options (furthermore, such options can be well approximated by regular puts and which cost calls) the period full per unit of time. -t]dt The cost of such a position over = and zero otherwise. Notice is: 1 = rjdt and the payoff is one that this strategy a jump a jump happens at if also feasible if is the process i 1, one extends the model to the case where can happen at any time r as in St In fact, this is 77 we estimate and Panageas in Caballero In conclusion, this sequence of short term "digital" options tical (2004). in the empirical section. purposes identical to the contract described in section for all prac- is 3.3.* Futures contracts 4.2 Consider now simple respect to St risk, futures contracts. a futures contract on entered into at a forward "price" are risk neutral with If investors St with maturity at t = 1 can be of: Po = E [si] with return: si The expected - E[si\so]. payoff of such a position at V ^ N{-l^^l,, a) i = 1 is approximately:^ + 1{J}N ill,, a,) where {J} corresponds to an indicator function that takes value one when a jump in the state variable takes place, It is and zero otherwise. important to note that futures have a price of zero. However, in order to keep the analysis comparable with the results obtained in section 3.3 we consider a slight variation of a futures contract and assume that the ''We refer the reader to Caballero and Panageas (2004) for a more extensive discussion of these issues. ^To make the argument in this section exact 10 one needs a continuous time model. country must pay for a payoff of upfront for every contract that rjfj,^ enters in exchange it : vr^N{0,a) + l{J}N{fi^,a,). Hence, the solution to the problem ((P)) in this case + 1-") (^ K+ = Bo 'tpZ — (^ + 1-") TXT]^^ There are several observations about we can set /i^ = without 1 in the risky asset hand that the right on let dollar us set is tt/i^ /i^ = tt that are worth highlighting. First, amount invested loss of generality, since the dollar at a price of per dollar invested. Moreover, observe 77 side depends only on the ratios 1 is and denote a = — — — , and similarly . Hence from now for 5^, 7?. Thus, in amounts we have: n Comparing declines = Z{^^-^') (9) to (6) when going from (the denominator is i^"^ shows that the amount invested digital options larger in (9)). The + a, a^ increase. the hedging opportunities, the central bank. Note that the -2 a,^ ratio +1- less between the two portfolios < 1 is portfolio (10) intuitive: 4) is: 77 The more appealing they become This in risky assets on the jump to the simple futures ^ 52 ^ which declines as (9) also is noise there is in to a risk averse attenuated by the ratio in (10). To summarize, we have that in order to justify adding a risky asset to the central bank's holdings, sudden stops must be severe, and the risky asset must be sufficiently correlated with such events. On the other hand, it is important to emphasize that neither causality nor predictability of sudden stops and returns are part of the argument for a positive 11 tt. Quantitative Assessment 5 The argument theoretical question is for hedging is difficult good enough hedging opportunities against sudden stops? Obviously, the answer to this question all is to a large extent country-specific, emerging market economies are exposed to the same sources of Our fragility. relevant then an empirical one: Are there global financial instruments and indices that offer as not The to argue with. goal in this section is more modest but also more robust: Rather than performing a collection of cases studies, we show that there least is at one global asset that has significant correlation with emerging market More importantly, absent crises. better country-specific alternatives, this global asset should constitute a significant share of these countries portfolios. 5.1 We The basics: Sudden Stops and Jumps study a group of nine emerging market economies open to international capital markets during the 1990s for which we have complete data:^ Ar- gentina, Brazil, Chile, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Mexico, Thailand Turkey. These economies are representative of what "emerging market economies." Our main exclusion and Central European economies, who became is is and often referred to as the group of Eastern significant participants in in- ternational capital markets during the second half of the 1990s, but faced economic problems of a somewhat different nature during much of our sam- ple. The point to highlight the well known fact that there is signifi- cant comovement in private capital fiows to these econoinies. Figure 1 splits first is into two panels the paths of the change in capital flows difference ital flows —more precisely, the between contiguous four-quarter-moving averages of quarterly cap- — to each of these economies from 1992 to 2002. The shaded areas mark the periods corresponding and Russian crisis, to the systemic Tequila and the sequence of somewhat Argentinean-Brazilean crises. It is less crisis, Asian apparent from this figure that there are significant correlations across these flows, especially within regions. ^The exception is crisis, systemic Turkish- Malaysia, for which we do not have quarterly capital flows. 12 Turkey \ is somewhere ' between the two regions. These comovements are encourag- in ing, as they indicate the possibility of finding global factors correlated with sudden stops. Capital flows for Latin American countries 15 - 10 ~\ fi Asian -> Tur- ' 5 1 <^ 3 -5 a. O -10 -15 Arg . - - Bra Chi — -20 Mex Q1-92 Q1-94 Q1-98 Q1-96 Q1-00 Capital flows for East Asian countries and Turkey As an -» - Tur-> r - ^A ^— 'Ap' • ^^ -20 'tsi Tur V Tequila -* Q1-94 Q1 \ Q1-96 Q1-98 Capital flows for various countries. The The shaded areas show times second, and main point, global factors — sudden The key stops. is from puts and US The VIX Q1-00 major crises. that indeed there are clearly identiflable — correlated with emerging market when is to note that these episodes investors are reluctant to partici- precisely captures this reluctance since 1986. This calls (typically 8) Bra —> The figure depicts the difference and the same quantity one year in finding such factors are generally understood as times available in the of in fact, traded factors pate in risky markets. *- Russian \y between 4 quarter averages of capital flows before. -V^-' Kor -30 1: rA |vt3C^{>*^ ^' Indo - Thai Figure Arg -> i\\ y =<><^ Q1-02 is an index of the "implied on the 13 S&P 100. and is volatilities" (Implied volatilities are Daily VIX 1990-2004 Figure 2: Daily Q1-98 Q1-96 Q1-94 Q1-92 VIX series. The gray areas Q1-02 Q1-00 Q1-04 depict the periods of major crises. determined by using the Black and Scholes (1973) formula to determine the level of volatility that and calls). would be compatible with the observed prices of puts Figure 2 reproduces the shaded areas for sudden stops regions described in the previous graph, and plots the daily VIX. this figure that some of the sudden stops. In with a large jump is fact, largest "jumps" in the apparent in the only systemic sudden stop that does not coincide the Tequila enough to count as a In the next section crisis, where there was a distinct and jumps more detail the behavior of the the VIX but not formally the joint behavior of sudden VIX. But before doing so, VIX during the 1990s (the Asian and Russian rise in jump. we document stops in the It is VIX occur precisely during crises). 14 it is instructive to explore in the two largest systemic crises of The top panel in Figure 3 plots the path of the Asian VIX during the Crisis), while the last two weeks of October 1997 (the onset of the bottom panel does the same for August-September 1998, which corresponds to the peak of the Russian/LTCM events the VIX are close to the crisis. In these reaches levels above 30 and 45 percent, respectively, which maximum levels of the index. In a matter of days, the VIX doubled. Daily VIX during the Asian Daily VIX during the Russian Plots of the VIX Crisis Oct98 Jul98 3: Jangs Oct97 Jul97 Figure Crisis in the weeks surrounding major crises in interna- tional financial markets. Finally, Figure 4 reinforces the the path of the VIX message of high correlation by plotting together with the EMBI for three of the most fragile economies in emerging markets during recent years: Argentina, Brazil and Turkey. Again, the dips in the corresponding 15 EMBIs as the VIX experiences sharp rises are apparent/ "feelings" of investors in A variable that US is primarily meant to capture the equity markets, happens to be highly correlated with the fortunes of emerging market economies. This highlights another important aspect of our methodology, according to which the only require- ment for a variable like the VIX to be useful in hedging, change in the conditional probability of having a too. This is crisis in is that there be a emerging markets not a statement about causation, but about correlation. VIX and Emerging Market Bond Index 200 Q1-98 Figure Q1-99 4: Q1-00 Q1-01 The VIX and the EMBI Q1-02 Q1-03 for Argentina, Brazil E Q1-04 and Turkey. we stress that our claim is not that domestic factors do not play a paramount role in crises. Quite the contrary, our choice of Argentina, Brazil and Turkey in the previous figure is precisely because In concluding this section '^The EMBI data are from Datastream. also coincides with a spike in the Note that the Argentine (permanent) crash VIX. 16 . own domestic weaknesses make them more their responsive to global factors. Importantly, this compounding effect often raises rather than need for Quantification 5.2 We now turn into a structural Estimation of the 5.2.1 To VIX process St, = —9{\og{st) the continuous time limit of happen at to be which follows the continuous time process: dst is analysis of the correlations highlighted above. model of the previous section take the log(VIX) operationalize the the state variable This dampens the hedging global risk factors. — + adBt + edJt- y)dt (8), with the modification that jumps can any point in time.^ The functional form //(sj) = — ^(log(st) - y), corresponds to an AR(1) process in discrete time for the log(st). Thus, we start by estimating an AR(1) process for \og{VIX) with monthly data and focus on the residuals, v, which are distributed (for small At) roughly as t; ~ (1 - p)N{-T]ij.^At, aVAt) + pN {/j,^, cr^) Given the very few observations with jumps, we identify these directly by inspection; this process fixes 77 = the parameters are estimated by normal maximum p =1— The e"''^*. rest of likelihood of the mixing of two distributions. Table 1 reports the results. Estimate Table This 0.417 and hence is 1: V /J^ CT a. 0.417 0.356 0.353 0.047 Estimated parameters not a serious departure if for monthly VIX data the "horizon" in the decision model be one year and the probabiHty of more than 1 17 jump taking is understood to place in a single year is small. The Likelihood 5.2.2 The of Sudden Stops results in section 5.2.1 suggest the presence of five in our sample: The the simultaneous gulf war, the Asian crisis of crisis, jumps the Russian in the crisis, VIX 9/11 and Turkey/Brazil, and the corporate scandals in the US. Conditional on these jumps, we calculate the probability that a country experiences a sudden stop. We identify an observation as a sudden stop based on a mixture of information on capital flows reversals and reserves and Panageas 2004). losses (see Caballero Mainly, for an observation to cotmt as a sudden stop capital flows must decline by at least 5 percent of GDP with respect to the flows in the previous two years, and reserves must be declining. This procedure We then estimate The ip yields estimates of from the ip'^ and ip^ relation: results are reported in Table 2. Note, however, that the country- specific estimates are highly imprecise as they correspond to the product of binary variables with very few transitions in each case.^ we pool For this reason, the observations, which yields the result in the average row. also report results for Brazil, for each country. two sub-categories: High-risk economies (Argentina, and Turkey) and composed We for the East- Asian economies. The former group is of those economies that have the highest estimated likelihood of a sudden stop in the sample. The pooled estimate indicates that an average emerging market economy is more than four times more likely to experience a crisis at a time when the VIX has jimiped than when it has not. Again, this is not a statement of causation but of correlation. At times when the VIX spikes, the average emerging market economy has a 41 percent chance of experiencing a sudden stop. This chance drops to 11 percent when the VIX is tranquil. ^The case of Mexico is particularly revealing. The estimate of ^ =0 misses the fact that while Mexico did not experience a very significant capital flow reversal during the Russian/LTCM/Brazilean turmoil, it its stock market declined very sharply, reflecting that experienced significant pressure at the time, but adjusted primarily via prices instead of quantities. Chile and the Ea^t Asian countries have a single SS for each of them and we observe a 18 jump a, ip in the = VIX because we identify only during the same period. ^' ^ i^' Argentina 0.42 0.80 0.14 Brasil 0.42 0.60 0.29 Chile 0.17 0.40 0.00 Mexico 0.17 0.00 0.29 Indonesia 0.17 0.40 0.00 Korea 0.08 0.20 0.00 Malaysia 0.25 0.40 0.14 Thailand 0.17 0.40 0.00 Turkey 0.33 0.60 0.14 Average 0.24 0.41 0.11 High-risk Countries 0.39 0.67 0.19 East Asia 0.17 0.35 0.04 Table Estimates for 0, 2: when we observe a joint '^'^ jump by the number of jumps number of years in we 0'* is i/)'. in the in the estimated as the number of years VIX and a SS in the country divided VIX. Symmetrically, ip^ is the ratio of the SS when there was no jump divided in the of years without a jump. coincide and total In order to determine whether a SS allow for a 2-quarter number and a jump window around the date when we identify the jump, because jumps are identified at a higher frequency than SS. With the estimates for in the first 77, ip and column of the il) in hand we obtain the estimate for table. 19 ip presented (f) (Options) ({) (Futures) Argentina 0.66 0.13 Brasil 0.31 0.06 Chile 1.00 0.20 Mexico 0.00 0.00 Indonesia 1.00 0.20 Korea 1.00 0.20 Malaysia 0.43 0.08 Thailand 1.00 0.20 Turkey 0.57 0.11 Average 0.53 0.10 High-risk Countries 0.51 0.10 East Asia 0.79 0.16 Table 3: Representative portfolios for options and futures. Representative VIX-portfolios and Reserves Gains 5.3 With these numbers in hand we are able to operationalize formulas (10) to estimate the portfohos implied by the model. Again, country (7) and specific numbers are very imprecise and attention should be placed on the pooled results. Table 3 reports the portfolios. The values of contracts show shares percent in amount of noise in the VIX. call-options strategy all cases, are large. The futures of risky assets of 10 percent or higher for the different groupings, despite the large removed and the (p is When the noise followed, the shares rise to and to near 80 percent for the reason for the high share for East Asian economies is is above 50 Asian economies. The worth highlighting: in the sample they experience crises mostly when these are systemic (again, this is not a causal statement); this is in contrast with the high risk economies, which also experience idiosyncratic These are dramatically central banks in crises.^" different portfolios from those normally held by emerging markets. Finding out why seems imperative: Is it ^"Note also that the difference between the optimal precautionary behavior of a high risk and an average economy of reserves held. Recall that is Rq not only reflected in the different = K -\-i>Z. 20 4>s but also on the level the lack of liquidity of the potential markets, domestic political constraints, or simply institutional herding? 6 The Benefits Our reduced form model portfolio is not well suited for a thorough "wel- fare" comparison. Thus, in assessing the benefits of the hedging strategy, we rather focus on statistics that are robust across preferences and other hard to we quantify details. In particular, a sudden stop taking place. We report the expected gains conditional on illustrate this for the call-options scenario. The first step in computing this statistic is to estimate the likelihood of a jump given that the country has experienced a sudden stop. Using Bayes' rule, we have that: Pv{J=l\SS=l)=i^^^. V Column 1 in Table 4 reports the estimates. It is around 70 percent for an average emerging market economy and close to 90 percent for the relatively stable East Asian economies. This likelihood at times The when the is important. countries need rate of return of the "call" strategy I/t? - -1 Hence the expected gain to do so. it is: 1 if J = J = 0. if The VIX jumps with a high 1 in reserves conditional on entering a sudden stop is: Column 2 in Table 4 reports the results. pected gain is around 40 percent. That For an average economy, the exis, an average economy following upon the strategy described here can expect a 40 percent rise in its reserves entering into a sudden stop.^^ number, which exceeds This is a significant ^^Of course, the counterpart of this expected gain during sudden stops economy may expect to lose 13 percent of its reserves 21 when there is is that the no sudden stop. Pr( J Country = = 1155 Expected Gain (options) 1) Argentina 0.80 060 Brasil 0.60 0.14 Chile 1.00 1.40 Mexico 0.00 0.00 Indonesia 1.00 1.40 Korea 1.00 1.40 Malaysia 0.67 0.26 Thailand 1.00 1.40 Turkey 0.75 046 Average 0.72 039 High-risk Countries 0.71 0.36 East Asia 0.88 0.86 Table 4: Revised probabilities and Expected Gains when following the op- tions strategy. the actual reserves losses of sudden Of many of these economies during their respective stops. course, there are many caveats that can be raised and that are likely to reduce these large numbers. For example, in a dynamic model the central bank might find it optimal to hold a level of reserves above a certain mini- mum in all contingencies, even in "good" states. In the present reserves, i.e. K> 0, which implies x the portfolio of risky assets tively, is scaled < 1. down model this bank As we know from expression just equivalent to assuming that the central is targets a non-zero level of (7), proportionally with x. Alterna- one could imagine a situation where a central bank wishes under no circumstances to lose more than c percent of its reserves, in which case the optimal portfolio would become: min{c, All these caveats notwithstanding, make a (f)}. we feel that the above calculations simple point: no matter which assumptions we make about erences and constraints, the driving force behind our results 22 is pref- the strong between the correlation VIX we propose simple quadratic framework that make this separation the effects that specifics of the Final 7 We shall for the particularly well suited to between preferences (which and Panageas (2004) X, is solely affect x) Even though a more elaborate model lation explicit. is The index and the incidence of sudden stops. like and corre- that in Caballero required in order to have a satisfactory theory for come from the strong correlations are independent of the model. Remarks a disclaimer. The portfolios we start our conclusion with illustrate emerging market economies we study, and the emphasis on the VIX, Our are neither country-specific nor instrument-specific recommendations. goal is simply to illustrate the potential benefits of enriching the portfolio options for central banks and, most importantly, of searching for assets and indices that are global in nature but correlated with capital flow reversals. Within this limited goal, our results are promising: the expected gains in reserves during sudden stops can be of reserves for an average country) . significant (slightly less This is than 40 percent noteworthy, considering that are only considering a single risky asset which is we not optimized to capture the risks faced by emerging market economies. The VIX is latter point raises useful because emerging markets but an The and risks in also captures problems that are US-specific. Ideally, it is it issue of international financial architecture: correlated with implied volatilities one would want an index that weights differently US-events that are to have world-wide systemic effects from those that do not. It likely should be relatively easy to construct implied volatility indices that isolate the former factors and still preserve the country-exogeneity properties of the VIX. Con- structing such indices is important to create benchmarks and develop liquid hedging markets for economies exposed to capital flow An issue that we avoided entirely is volatility. the incentive effects that a modified may have on the private secas the private sector may undo some of the central banks' policy of hedging external shocks tor. This is an important concern, external insurance in anticipation of a the central bank's intervention. This 23 is a complex issue that probably requires coordination of the hedging pol- icy with 2003). monetary and regulatory However, even in the policies (see Caballero and Krishnamurthy absence of these complementary policies, per- verse incentive effects are unlikely to be strong enough to fully offset the more aggressive hedging justification for from these problems and are policies also suffer many practices. After in the private sector are justified current reserve all, on the grounds that simply not forward-looking enough to hedge aggregate risks in sufficient amount. Moreover, if such practices were to be adopted observe the emergence of new implied collectively, soon we would volatility indices that better The the needs of emerging market economies. match welfare improvement from may such enhancements could be very significant and therefore justify a coordination role by the IFIs and central banks around the world. In fact, such coordination costs from hedging To ital may be conclude, a necessity, if we losses. we reiterate that our emphasis flow volatility does not seek to shift the volatility is a hedgable component and that Moreover, there is for much be hit this is of caj> of capital flow simply to show component is significant. an important interaction between the issue we highlight Weak countries are more by global turmoil, and hence should put an even bigger effort here and the domestic sources of external likely to on external sources blame away from the countries themselves. Our goal that there in are to limit the potential political hedging these global shocks. 24 fragility: References [1] Caballero, R.J. Stops," [2] and A. Krishnamurthy, MIT Mimeo, and Caballero, R.J. tionary Recessions: [3] Model Garcia, P. of S. A Panageas, "Hedging Sudden Stops and Precau- Quantitative Approach," Sudden Stops," MIT Mimeo, MIT Mimeo, 2003. Management 2004. and C. Soto, "Large Hoarding of International Reserves: Are they worth it?" [5] and Sudden 2003. Caballero, R.J. and S. Panageas, "Insurance and Reserves in a [4] "Inflation Targeting , in this volume, 2004. Jaewoo Lee, "Insurance Value of International Reserves," IMF mimeo, August 2004. 25 Date Due MIT LIBRARIES 3 9080 02618 0361 ;ii;i!imi»!iiiiiii'"iu'i