!"#"$%#$&'%()&*(+,-.&/)-&011-2(&31&!"#"$-45&3#&6%47&83,%2%-5 9:()34;5<.&!"4%"##-&=-4(4"#>&"#>&9#(3%#-((-&*2)3"4 *3:42-.&/)-&?:"4(-4,+&@3:4#",&31&023#37%25A&B3,C&DDEA&F3C&G&;F3HCA&IJJK<A&LLC&DDMNODIJE 8:P,%5)->&P+.&Oxford University Press *("P,-&QRS.&http://www.jstor.org/stable/25053937 . 922-55->.&IITJKTIJDD&DG.UJ Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use. Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at . http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=oup. . Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission. JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org. Oxford University Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The Quarterly Journal of Economics. http://www.jstor.org THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL ECONOMICS OF Vol CXVIII Issue 4 November 2003 MANAGING WITH STYLE: THE EFFECT OF MANAGERS ON FIRM POLICIES* Marianne Bertrand This whether paper investigates and performance. We behavior rate set which We A enables us tional practices cate general sation are more and findings from earlier on the other more hand, aggressive individual a manager-firm affect managers matched panel firms over corpo data the effects in managerial "style" managers. to indi appear we show that that decision-making across Moreover, fixed effects to manager in performance related receive higher fixed effects compen performance to be found in better In a final step, we firms. governed likely to observable these executives how construct is significantly with higher management style and that managers tie back fixed patterns specific in differences identify and Schoar across time. different top managers matter for a wide decisions. range of corporate of the heterogeneity in investment, and organiza financial, can be explained of firms of manager fixed effects. by the presence to track find that manager extent significant We and Antoinette birth who managers We characteristics. managerial on average appear hold an MBA degree cohorts find that to be more seem conservative; to follow on average strategies. I. Introduction "In the bank. old days Garbage?it's I would have about the said guy it was at the capital, top. history, I am very the name much of the a process * We the editors thank and Edward Katz three anony (Lawrence Glaeser), Kent Daniel, Kevin J. Mur Rebecca Steven referees, Henderson, Kaplan, Sendhil Canice David Mullainathan, phy, Scharfstein, Prendergast, Jerry Michael at Harvard seminar the Warner, Weisbach, participants University, of Management Graduate School at Northwestern the Mas Kellogg University, Institute of Technology, the University of Chicago sachusetts School Graduate of the University at Urbana-Champaign, of Illinois Rochester Business, University, and the Stockholm School of Economics for many comments. We thank helpful us with Kevin J. Murphy and Robert Parrino for generously their data. providing Jennifer Fiumara and Michael McDonald assistance. excellent research provided E-mail: aschoar@mit.edu. marianne.bertrand@gsb.uchicago.edu; mous ? 2003 by the President and Fellows Technology. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, of Harvard College November 2003 1169 and the Massachusetts Institute of QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS 1170 person, a builder. Sandy is an acquirer. [Weil] Just totally different." ?John Reed, CEO Citicorp matter How much do individual managers for firm behavior so in finance and economics and economic performance? Research em to this question.1 far has given little consideration Existing or market-level studies pirical rely on firm-, industry-, typically to explain characteristics behavior and performance corporate but role that individual managers may largely ignore the possible in outcomes. in the these view Yet, a prevailing play shaping business themselves (as the quote by press and among managers John Reed at the beginning of the paper suggests) is that CEOs are in of and other top executives the determination key factors as are often perceived their corporate practices. Managers having own and other stra investment, financing, "styles" when making on the their personal marks decisions, thereby imprinting of this paper is The novel contribution companies they manage.2 in an to explicitly dimension introduce such a people, or manager, tegic study of corporate empirical practices.3 The relevance of this approach is further underlined when we in corporate practices that is left models that rely only on firm- and on the cross-sec research example, the large heterogeneity by more standard unexplained consider factors. For industry-level of capital structure and Wes tional determinants (e.g., Titman and and Watts and sels [1988], Smith Jarrell, [1992], Bradley, a amount Kim shows variation remains of that [1984]) large for firm-level characteristics after controlling (such unexplained or a firm operates as market-to-book assets the of ratios, type are papers in the theory 1. A few recent literature by Rotemberg exceptions the and Saloner model [2002]. These [2000] and Van den Steen papers explicitly of firm policy. determinant vision of the CEO as an important an article in a May issue of Business 2. To mention 2001 just one example, discusses the aggressive titled "The Koszlowski Week, Method," acquisition style of Dennis the CEO of Tyco. Koszlowski, in shaping has been virtu 3. While the role of managers corporate practices in the economics there is a large body of work and finance literature, ally ignored the determinants of decision in the management literature science analyzing and Mason Hambrick [1984] or Waldman, among CEOs (see, for example, making focus of this litera and Puranam [2001]). Yet, both the specific Ramirez, House, it follows from the ture and the methodological differ substantially approach in to undertake variables considered the outcome here. First, study we propose are mostly variables literature the management (e.g., communi process-related we care or charisma) outcomes economic rather than the actual cation process on science in management relies most of the existing work about here. Second, or subjective case studies, therefore survey responses, experiments, laboratory an empirical A paper that follows of our approach. the level of generality lacking more to ours is Lieberman, and Williams related [1990], Lau, closely approach in the U. S. and Japa in productivity fixed effects who find significant manager nese automobile industry. 1171 MANAGING WITH STYLE or industry fixed effects.4 tax shields) In a similar vein, in investment to cash flow the ongoing debate about differences to Q sensitivities and Pe and investment [Fazzari, Hubbard, tersen and Zingales the consider 1997] highlights 1988; Kaplan as to the roots of the wide variation in invest able disagreement across firms. One primary ment behavior this of paper is objective nondebt to ask whether managers' or market factors, dustry, as opposed to firm, in account for these unex personalities, can in part differences. we want Intuitively, plained to quantify how much of the observed can to fixed attributed be manager policies with other effects. Since manager effects might be correlated we estimate in the role of managers characteristics, firm-specific a framework we can and unobserv control for observable where we construct a across firms. For this purpose, able differences we matched track individual manager-firm panel data set, where in firm variation across different firms top managers estimate how much of the unexplained can be attributed to manager fixed time. This allows us to in firm practices variation over after controlling for effects, firm characteristics.5 time-varying we study relate to invest variables The specific corporate to ment investment Q sensitivity, policy (capital expenditures, firm fixed effects and to cash flow sensitivity, and acquisition investment policy), finan interest cash cial policy (financial coverage, holdings, leverage, and dividend (R&D expendi strategy organizational payouts), diversification tures, advertising policy, and cost expenditures, and cutting policy), performance.6 fixed effects are empirically Our results show that manager variables. determinants of a wide range of corporate important to models of On average, the fixed effects prac corporate adding firm account for observable and unobservable tices that already more in in increases of than characteristics results i?2's adjusted we find that manager four percentage interestingly, points. More 4. For Phillips a recent [2002]. study of intraindustry variation in leverage, see MacKay and to firm performance 5. A few recent papers relate managerial characteristics investment. and T?te Malmendier [2002] and Wasserman, See, for example, for firm fixed these papers do not control and Anand [2002]. However, Nohria, from firm effects. In a more and therefore effects cannot effects manager separate more to ours. recent paper Malmendier similar and T?te [2003] use a methodology across firms to study the effect of managerial overconfidence track switchers They on acquisition behavior. to measure used in this analysis 6. The intends fixed effects approach there is persistence of managerial different whether style over time and across in this paper. But we do not want is the very definition of "style" used jobs. This to rule out that managers their style over time. learn or develop may and QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS 1172 effects matter much and more for some decisions than others. Man in acquisition appear to be especially important interest dividend coverage, decisions, policy, ager fixed effects or diversification policy. these cost-cutting estimated fixed effects across manager we are also able to identify some variables, in managerial patterns decision-making. Among we find that managers seem to differ in their ap By correlating different corporate overarching other things, proach toward ness. Managers diversification company growth and in their financial aggressive and who engage in more external acquisitions lower levels of capital display expenditures also find that managers who have high investment to cash flow effects rank lower in their investment also and R&D. We to Q fixed that managers (and vice versa), may differ, sensitivity suggesting in the benchmark all else equal, that they use when making investment decisions. that top executives These results provide evidence vary con in their management "styles" and thereby siderably finance research. for corporate rather novel approach as to why managers also raise questions may behave a suggest Yet, they so differ in apparently economic environments. Do these similar or in relative absolute reflect differences findings preferences, are or the what More skills, efficiency importantly, opinions? these questions outline clear of these findings? While implications ently some preliminary evidence for future work, we provide in issues. First, we show that the differences re are documented above systematically managerial practices we show that in performance. More precisely, lated to differences directions on some of these are significant and fixed effects in performance managerial related to some of the fixed effects in effects are statistically who are more invest For example, managers corporate practices. there these and have higher administrative sensitive, ment-Q are less active in the acquisition and diversification In addition, fixed effects. have lower performance effects expenses, markets we show also and also that receive with fixed higher performance and that these managers higher salary and total compensation are more firms. These results likely to be found in better governed are suggestive of our of possibly important efficiency implications managers findings. In a final managerial are birth in style step, we tie back differences The two characteristics characteristics. We analyze cohort and MBA graduation. to observable we consider the extent to 1173 MANAGING WITH STYLE are affected decisions corporate by these two characteris across firms and for any fixed differences tics, after controlling firm factors. We find that older generations other time-varying of in their decision-making. CEOs appear overall more conservative which who hold an MBA degree appear hand, managers more to overall follow aggressive strategies. as follows. The rest of this paper II is organized Section a brief discussion as to why of alternative provides hypotheses On the other individual III presents of the data for corporate decisions. Section may matter managers the different data sources, describes the construction the main variables of interest. Section set, and defines IV quantifies the importance of manager fixed effects for various and V Section discusses corporate practices, efficiency possible of these findings. Section VI studies birth cohort and implications as two specific MBA determinants of managerial graduation style. Section VII summarizes and offers some concluding remarks. II. Why Should Individual Managers Matter? as of corporate decisions implicitly are view of the firm in which top managers into the production and selfless process. homogeneous inputs are regarded Under this quite narrow view, different managers as perfect extreme for one another. An even more substitutes Many empirical sume a neoclassical studies for what is simply do not matter executives in differ their might or skill levels, none of this translates risk-aversion preferences, into actual cannot if a single person corporate policies, easily we would affect these policies. Under either of these scenarios, not expect individual managers to matter for corporate decisions. Two firms sharing similar technologies, factor, and product mar is that top managers assumption on a firm. While within going ket conditions will make similar choices, team. the same management whether or not they also share In contrast, standard that man agency models acknowledge have discretion inside their which agers may firm, they can use to own alter corporate and advance their How decisions objectives. do not generally ever, these models imply that corporate behavior as they typically do not focus will vary with individual managers, on idiosyncratic across managers. differences Rather, agency models attribute variations in corporate to heterogene behavior QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS 1174 across firms, of governance mechanisms i.e., ity in the strength to in firms' ability control managers.7 heterogeneity across managers in corporate will practices Heterogeneity to differ in their arise in models allow managers that explicitly risk aversion, skill levels, or opinions. But there are preferences, as to how these managerial two distinct differ interpretations ences translate into corporate choices. The first are extensions of a manager can impose his in which the standard agency models or her own idiosyncratic if corporate control style on a company, or limited. Under this view, one might that the expect as sources to increase of of the internal and managers impact some if controls weaken. external management Alternatively, than others, better gov styles are more performance-enhancing is poor erned firms may be more likely styles. A second to select managers set of models that imply manager-specific are of the neoclassical extensions practices with such effects in in model In in their match with firms. this quality style on the firm impose their idiosyncratic corporate which managers vary do not case, managers chosen by firms because of these they lead, but are purposefully a board may determine For example, the need specific attributes. an to go through external growth phase and therefore hire a new or more to engage in is more who manager prone aggressive and given the Under this interpretation strategies.8 we develop framework below, we would only find sig empirical in corporate if firms' optimal nificant manager effects practices a over time. if Indeed, strategies given change company's optimal expansion over invariant strategy were be the continuation would only two main variants These time, an incoming manager's style of the prior manager's style. view of of the "managers matter" have very different decisions corporate efficiency implications. some managerial traits or prefer Under the first interpretation, ences may cause corporations to adopt suboptimal The strategies. to extent to which this occurs will be limited by boards' ability a process is Hermalin and Weisbach [1998], who model by exception can gain more to which in turn allows them discretion, good managers concern career models their firm. the within Also, governance relationship change and owners show that the intensity between of the conflict of interest managers may vary over the life cycle of managers. one could argue that boards 8. Alternatively, get fooled and systematically on the manager's A infer a manager's prior job experience. mistakenly style based in her or his prior in a wave of acquisitions be involved may manager by chance as an "acquisition influence be wrongly may firm, which style" and perceived in in more view detail this alternative future hiring by other firms. We discuss IV. C. subsection 7. One which MANAGING WITH STYLE 1175 screen or monitor Under the second managers. interpretation, as in style will not lead to inefficiencies differences managerial select the right manager for the right long as boards optimally under either individual managers interpretation, job. However, are central in bringing in corporate about the changes policies. our primary is not to distinguish While goal in this paper these different but rather to first estab interpretations in the determination of do matter lish that individual managers we will provide some preliminary firm policies, evidence about in Section V. of our findings possible efficiency implications between III. Data III.A. Sample Construction A straightforward way to proceed when trying to determine in the way top manag whether there are systematic differences ers behave would be to ask whether there are important manager in corporate fixed effects for all relevant controlling practices, One obvious problem with firm-level characteristics. in is that there be differences persistent approach might some across to firms due unobservable third factors and practices observable this with the manager fixed be correlated might one man to needs effects. Practically, this implies that separate ager fixed effects from firm fixed effects. a manager-firm construct We therefore matched panel data us across different set that allows to track the same top managers firms over time. The data we use are the Forbes 800 files, from that these factors from 1992 to 1999. The 1999, and Execucomp data, on the CEOs of the 800 largest data provide information U. S. firms. Execucomp allows us to track the names of the top in 1500 publicly five highest traded U. S. firms. paid executives most often These include the CEO, but also other top executives, our then restrict the CFO, COO, and subdivision CEOs.9 We 1969 to Forbes to the subset of firms for which at least one specific top can be observed in at least one other firm.10 In doing so, executive we also impose that the managers have to be in each firm for at least three years.11 For each firm satisfying these requirements, attention in Execucomp to code the specific position 9. We use the variable of a titlean in a given firm. manager 10. We discuss selection below issues associ (subsection IV.A) the possible ated with this sample construction. ensures are given a chance 11. This three-year to that managers requirement in a given their mark" All of the results below were company. "imprint replicated QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS 1176 we keep managers all observations, the firm has years where i.e., including we in multiple firms. The resulting that do not observe over 500 individual about 600 firms and slightly sample contains can in at least two different who be followed firms.12 managers a given firm is a The average within length of stay of a manager in our data. As is customary in the study of little over five years investment insurance we exclude in the banking and firms regressions, as well as utilities from our sample. To industries across we in also these firms exclude results, consistency preserve the analysis of noninvestment variables.13 and SDC data For this sample of firms, we use COMPUSTAT a series of annual to construct variables. We concen accounting on three different sets of corporate trate our analysis decisions (investment strategy) policy, financial policy, and organizational as well as on corporate performance. The definition and construc are reported in tion of the specific variables used in the analysis the Data Appendix. III.B. Sample Description means I presents and standard deviations variables of interest. The first two columns for all the report sum for the manager-firm matched sample. For com sum I report equivalent the last two columns of Table parison, 1969 for the entire COMPUSTAT mary statistics sample between our sample to firms where we and 1999. As expected, constraining can observe at least one executive switch leads us to select larger executives from larger firms are more firms. Indeed, likely to Table corporate statistics mary move from smaller firms. Executives between COMPUSTAT a on to move the other have firms, hand, might higher probability are to private firms or positions firms below the within that large our in cannot tracked data be five level. Such executives top firm in our sample also has a somewhat sources.14 The average higher Tobin's Q ratio, higher rate of return on assets, and higher The results we in the sample construction. this three-year requirement ignoring were weaker. similar obtained but, not surprisingly, statistically qualitatively are observed in strictly more than two 12. A very small of managers subset different firms. we in the noninvestment 13. When include these observations regressions, are virtually our results unchanged. on in fact bias focus 14. One could argue that this required larger firms may on firm policies. our results effects of managers Indeed, systematic finding against a specific in a smaller that influential individual be more organization might more in day-to-day activities. of the top managers involvement requires personal more who have distinct would be that managers An alternative "styles" argument are more in larger firms. likely to be found 1177 MANAGING WITH STYLE TABLE I Statistics Descriptive Manager characteristics Manager-firm matched sample Compustat sample St. Total sales Mean St. 5606.5 0.39 Investment Average Cashflow Tobin's Q Mean St. Mean dev. 11545.6 5333.3 2.94 0.28 10777.4 2649.6 5878.2 0.50 0.34 2.40 3.85 2.67 2.03 2.05 1.70 0.44 1.43 1.91 0.45 2.10 0.43 2.47 1.45 dev. dev. of acquisitions 0.77 1.48 0.65 1.40 0.36 Leverage Interest coverage Cash holdings 0.35 0.39 0.34 0.28 0.45 1.21 35.0 875.1 40.5 663.1 27.6 166.2 0.11 0.16 0.08 0.11 0.17 0.80 Dividends/earnings N of diversifying 0.11 0.79 0.14 1.05 0.16 0.25 0.32 1.09 0.28 0.91 0.12 0.63 0.07 0.04 0.14 0.03 0.06 N acquisitions 0.05 R&D 0.05 0.06 0.05 0.06 0.04 0.06 SG&A 0.26 0.98 0.21 0.19 0.18 0.64 0.16 0.11 0.19 0.15 0.10 0.09 0.09 0.12 0.11 0.22 0.08 Advertising Return on assets return Operating on assets 10472 6766 Sample size 0.13 38489 a. "Manager-firm matched sample" refers to the set of firm-year observations for firms that have at least one manager observed in multiple firms with at least a three-year stay at each firm. This sample includes observations for these firms in the years in which they have other managers that we do not observe in multiple firms (see subsection III.A for details). "Manager characteristics sample" refers to the set of firm-year observations for which we can obtain information on the year of birth and educational background of the CEO (see subsection VI.A for details). "Compustat" is a comparison sample of the 1500 largest listed firms over the period 1969 to 1999. All samples exclude firms in the banking and insurance industry, as well as regulated industries. b. Details on the definition and construction of the variables reported in the table are available in the Data Appendix. c. Total sales are expressed in 1990 dollars. d. Sample size refers to the maximum number of observations; not all variables are available for each year and firm. and lower cash holdings but slightly of acquisitions, to the COM similar It levels. very average is, however, leverage to cash flow, investment firm with PUSTAT levels, divi respect and SG&A. dend payouts, R&D, in transitions of the executive the nature Table II tabulates our sample. We separate three major executive CEOs, categories: number CFOs, and "Others." category cent are correspond subdivision of the job titles in this "Others" The majority 44 per to operationally important positions: are Execu 16 percent CEOs or Presidents, are COOs; the rest are Vice and 12 percent tive Vice-Presidents, Presidents and other more generic titles. QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS 1178 TABLE II Executive Transitions between Positions and Industries to: CEO CFO 117 63% 52 4 75%69% 58 7 71%57% 1060 145 Other from: CEO CFO 71% Other 30 60% 42% a. This table summarizes executives' transitions across positions and industries in the manager-firm matched panel data set (as described in subsection III.A and Table I).All transitions are across firms. The first entry in each cell reports the number of transitions from the row position to the column position. The second line in each cell reports the fraction of the transitions in that cell that are between different two-digit industries. b. "Other" refers to any job title other than CEO or CFO. in our sample, Of the set of about 500 managers identified in one firm to 117 are individuals who move from a CEO position are a CEO position move to CFO 4 in another who CEOs firm; are move to who 52 other CEOs and top positions. positions; as CFOs, we observe 7 the set of executives Among starting 30 58 to CFO and another CEOs, becoming moving position, to other top positions. among the 251 managers moving Finally, in another 106 become CEOs, and 145 top position, to another non-CEO, Within this latter non-CFO position. are we more 40 than of the transitions found that group percent a or moves of subdivision CEO subdivision from presi position in another firm. dent in one firm to a similar position row of each cell in Table In the second II, we report the who move start in different firms of moves that are between two-digit to note that a large fraction of the It is interesting industries.15 For exam in our sample are between industries. executive moves are across different of the CEO to CEO moves ple, 63 percent as are to CFO moves. 71 of the CFO industries, percent two-digit of the moves from other top positions A relatively lower fraction fraction to other are across (42 percent) top positions seem if ones believes that intuitive industries. These CEOs CFOs and patterns and firm-specific need less industry knowledge relatively instead rely more on general management skills.16 15. The industry classification as reported in COMPUSTAT. 16. See, for example, Fligstein is based [1990] on the primary for a discussion SIC code of this of each argument. and firm, 1179 MANAGING WITH STYLE IV. Is There IV.A. Empirical Heterogeneity in Executive Practices? Methodology can be most The nature of our identification strategy easily Consider the dividend payout ratio as explained with an example. the corporate specification policy of interest. From a benchmark we derive residual at the firm-year dividend level after payouts across for differences firms and any average years as controlling for any firm-year such as an earnings shock, specific of a firm. We then that affect the dividend shock, payout might in these residual ask how much of the variance dividend payouts can be attributed to manager-specific effects. More specifically, for each dependent variable of interest, we to estimate the propose regression: following well as (1) = y it at + y? + ?Xit + \Ceo + ^cfo + ^others + *it, at are yit stands for one of the corporate policy variables, are a vector firm fixed fixed year effects, y? effects, Xit represents of time-varying firm level controls, and eit is an error term. The in equation variables (1) are fixed effects for the man remaining we we want in multiple to that firms. Because observe agers separately study the effect of CEOs, CFOs, and other top execu where on corporate we create three different groups policies, are fixed effects for the group fixed effects: \Ceo who are CEOs in the last position we observe them managers are fixed effects for the group of managers who are CFOs \Cfo tives manager of of in, in the last position we observe them in, and ^others are fixed effects for the group of managers who are neither CEOs nor CFOs in the we observe last position when them in.17 Finally, estimating we account for for serial correlation (1), equation by allowing error term at firm of the the level.18 clustering It is evident from equation of the (1) that the estimation never is not fixed for effects who manager managers possible our for leave a given company during sample period. Consider, example, advances a specific manager who never switches companies internal only through promotions, maybe moving and from 17. We also repeated all of the analyses CEO to CEO below after separating etc. The results were qualitatively to the more CEO to CFO moves, similar moves, in the paper. results aggregated reported two alternative 18. In subsection estimation to deal IV.C we propose methods issues with and better the serial correlation issues address possible regarding of the manager fixed effects. persistence QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS 1180 a CFO to a CEO in his/her position on cannot manager corporate practices from his firm fixed effect. The manager fixed are perfectly to extend possible effect tically observe collinear in this firm. The be estimated fixed case. effect effect of this separately and the firm It would be statis our analysis to top managers whom we in one firm but who stay in that firm for only a subset of in our estimation, sample period. To be conservative we decided to stay away from this approach. however, Indeed, the to period-firm-specific fixed effects for such managers correspond to other unobserv could be more easily attributed effects, which the entire to factors. for manager fixed effects Instead, time-varying we cor under our more that stringent require approach, across have to be correlated (at least) two firms porate practices when the same manager is present.19 able matter clarifies why our identification us highlight let hires, solely possible implica tions of this sample selection for more general inferences based on our results. First, to note that the outside hire of top it is useful is far from exceptional and especially of CEOs, among executives, the large U. S. public firms that we focus on in this analysis.20 While the discussion above on outside relies one could reasonably who are Nevertheless, argue that managers from the outside are different from internally recruited promoted one might have ones.21 For example, argue that outside managers or "better" styles on average, as firms are willing to "stronger" to find these managers. look outside their organization and most there is no such thing as a Finally, importantly, we are not random allocation to firms. Therefore, of top executives on in this section to estimate the causal effect of managers hoping our more to firm practices. is modest. We want Instead, objective assess whether there is any evidence that firm policies systemat in these firms. ically change with the identity of the top managers we replicate our results 19. For the sake of completeness, under this alter a much native As one might thereby larger set of executives. approach, covering we find even stronger have fixed effects. manager expected, to compute of CEOs 20. We use the entire the fraction Execucomp sample We find that who were hired from the outside rather than internally promoted. are internally In a more detailed [1997] only 48 percent study, Panino promoted. a lot by versus shows that the prevalence of inside outside succession varies industry. 21. Suggestive at stock market example, around Warner, outsider evidence responses Watts, succession to emerge for this seems from a set of papers looking turnover. For to the announcement of management returns and Wruck [1988] document high abnormally no overall effect. but events, significant 1181 MANAGING WITH STYLE TV.B. Results IV report F-tests and adjusted R2 from the sets of corporate policy of equation (1) for the different For each variable we report in the first row the fit of a III and Tables estimation variables. benchmark fixed effects, that specification and time-varying firm report the change respectively, add the CEO fixed effects tively of executives groups second and third (CEOs, rows also only firm fixed effects, year controls. The next two rows, in adjusted R2 when we consecu includes and CFOs, the fixed for all three The top positions). from tests of the effects and other report F-statistics sets of manager of fixed effects. the different joint significance in III and IV that man the Tables Overall, suggest findings effects matter both economically and statistically for ager-specific as other the policy decisions of firms. CEOs as well Including fixed effects increases the adjusted J?2 of the estimated managers' we are large the models find that F-tests significantly. Similarly, cases the null hypothesis that all and allow us to reject in most the manager fixed effects are zero. We also see that there are as to which seem to be differences decision variables important most affected decisions. different Moreover, types of by manager more matters for matter CFOs different manager e.g., decisions; now for financial in decisions. We discuss these results greater details. Table III reports our results for investment policy (Panel A) of the (Panel B). We start with a discussion policy in this table results. The first variable is capital of lagged net property, and (as a fraction plant, The benchmark includes controls for specification and financial investment expenditures equipment). firm fixed effects, year fixed effects, cash flow, lagged Tobin's Q, of total assets. The adjusted R2 for this and the lagged logarithm is 91 percent. Even though the fit of this benchmark specification model is already very high, the adjusted R2 increases by 3 percent we include the CEO fixed effects and by more than 5 fixed effects. Also, percent when we include all sets of manager are large, leading us to reject the null hypothesis the F-tests of no when effect joint two variables are investment to cash flow sensitivities, respectively. for these two variables differs slightly investment method in all cases. next The to Tobin's The from Q and estimation the one de in subsection IV.A. Indeed, the fixed effects of interest to the level of a given variable here do not relate (in this case, to rather the of but that to variable investment), sensitivity scribed 1182 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS TABLE III Executive Effects on and Investment Financial Policies Panel A: Investment F-tests policy on fixed effects for CEOs Investment Investment Investment Inv to Q sensitivity Inv to Q sensitivity Inv to Q sensitivity Inv to CF sensitivity Inv to CF sensitivity Inv to CF sensitivity N of acquisitions N of acquisitions N of acquisitions 16.74 (<.0001, 19.39 ?.0001, 17.87 (<.0001, 5.33 (<.0001, 2.00 ?.0001, 0.94 192) 53.48 9.40 ?.0001, 1.29 8.45 ?.0001, 1.74 199) 58) (.0760,55) (.0006, 55) (.5294,203) Leverage Interest coverage Interest coverage 0.86 (.9190,199) 0.56 Interest 0.35 (.99, 193) (.99, 192) 1.28 2.52 ?.0001, 2.48 ?.0001, 204) 201) 5.78 ?.0001, 4.95 ?.0001, 203) 199) .96 6631 .97 208) 6631 6631 .98 6631 .98 (.0058, 199) 6631 6593 .98 6593 .28 203) 6593 .36 20.29 ?.0001, 4.08 ?.0001, .97 .25 policy on fixed effects for 1.43 Other (.0225,54) 1.21 executives N Adjusted R2 6563 .39 6563 .39 (.0230, 203) 6563 6278 .41 .31 6278 .31 192) 6278 6592 .41 .77 .78 .80 .65 13.85 ?.0001, 50) 2.61 ?.0001, 3.68 ?.0001, 54) 2.53 ?.0001, 6592 202) 6592 6580 6580 .71 1.74 ?.0001, 203) 6580 .72 Dividends/earnings Dividends/earnings .95 B: Financial CFOs 0.99 Dividends/earnings .94 200) 6631 6631 204) CEOs Cash holdings Cash holdings Cash holdings .91 205) F-tests coverage 55) Adjusted R2 6631 223) 221) Panel Leverage Leverage (<.0001, N 6631 198) (.7276, 194) 2.01 (<.0001, 1.68 (<.0001, Other executives CFOs 1.07 (.3368,54) a. Sample is the manager-firm matched panel data set as described in subsection III.A and Table I. Details on the definition and construction of the variables reported in the table are available in the Data Appendix. b. Reported in the table are the results from fixed effects panel regressions, where standard errors are clustered at the firm level. For each dependent variable (as reported in column 1), the fixed effects included are row 1: firm and year fixed effects; row 2: firm, year, and CEO fixed effects; row 3: firm, year, CEO, CFO, and other executives fixed effects. Included in the "Investment to Q" and "Investment to cash flow" regres sions are interactions of these fixed effects with lagged Tobin's Q and cash flow, respectively. Also the "Investment," "Investment to Q," and "Investment to cash flow" regressions include lagged logarithm of total assets, lagged Tobin's Q, and cash flow. The "Number of Acquisitions" regressions include lagged logarithm of total assets and return on assets. Each regression in Panel B contains return on assets, cash flow, and the lagged logarithm of total assets. c. Reported are the F-tests for the joint significance of the CEO fixed effects (column 2), CFO fixed effects (column 3), and other executives fixed effects (column 4). For each F-test we report the value of theF-statistic, the p-value, and the number of constraints. For the "Investment to Q" and "Investment to Cash Flow" regressions, the F-tests are for the joint significance of the interactions between the manager fixed effects and Tobin's Q and cash flow, respectively. Column 5 reports the number of observations, and column 6 the adjusted R2s for each regression. MANAGING WITH STYLE 1183 Tobin's for investment to Q sensi Q and cash flow. In practice, on year fixed effects, investment tivity, we start by regressing cash flow, lagged Tobin' Q, the lagged logarithm of total assets, firm fixed effects, and firm fixed effects with interacted lagged Tobin's Q. We then add to this benchmark manager specification as well as manager fixed effects fixed effects interacted with coefficients of interest are those lagged Tobin's Q. The estimated on the interaction terms. We proceed in a similar fashion in our to of investment cash The flow results indicate study sensitivity. in adjusted R2 when increases terms of the interaction including fixed effects with cash flow and lagged Tobin's Q, espe for to Q sensitivity. investment The adjusted R2 goes up cially to 98 percent when we allow investment from 95 percent to Q to be manager specific. The last variable in Panel A is number of acquisitions. For we in adjusted R2 of about 11 this variable observe an increase manager percent following surprisingly, Maybe are very managers the inclusion we find that of the manager effects the fixed fixed effects. for the "Other" inclusion has an and that their significant not large impact on the adjusted R2. In regressions into more reported here we broke down the set of other managers CEOs specific job title categories. We found that the subdivision and COOs explain most of the increase in adjusted R2 within this especially "Other" category. B of Table III focuses on financial in all policy. Included are firm fixed fixed the regressions effects, effects, year lagged on assets.22 of total assets, and the rate of return logarithm in adjusted R2 in this Panel are of a similar the increases Overall, as those found for the investment order of magnitude variables. The adjusted R2 of the leverage increases from 39 regression to we 41 when include the fixed effects. manager percent percent an The adjusted R2 of the interest alterna coverage regression, Panel tive measure as 10 of capital increases structure, by as much to 41 31 CFOs have (from percent percent percent). Interestingly, a key financial the strongest effect on interest coverage, indicator. The adjusted R2 of the cash holdings goes up by 3 regression to 80 percent, from 77 percent when we compare the percent, benchmark with the specification that includes all specification fixed effects. Finally, managers manager appear to be important determinants of dividend in ad increase policy, with an overall 22. We advantage also experimented from debt in the with leverage for assets controls adding The results regressions. and uniqueness were unaffected. tax TABLE IV Executive on Organizational Effects Panel Strategy and A: Organizational strategy on fixed effects for F-tests CEOs N of diversifying of diversifying acquis. N N of diversifying acquis. R&D R&D R&D acquis. CFOs 2.06 ?.0001, 204) 1.23 (.0163,202) 1.74 1.86 ?.0001, 2.27 ?.0001, 145) 3.60 ?.0001, 2.88 ?.0001, 4.03 ?.0001, 95) 143) Ot 3.97 (.0007,53) 45) 4.46 Advertising Advertising Advertising SG&A SG&A SG&A 33.55 ?.0001, 13.80 ?.0001, 95) 0.84 (.6665,21) 6.10 0.82 (.7934,42) 0.7 123) 118) TABLE IV (CONTINUED) Panel B: Performance on F-tests CEOs Return on assets Return on assets Return on assets Operating return fixed effects CFOs 2.04 ?.0001, 2.46 ?.0001, 201) 2.61 ?.0001, 1.60 ?.0001, 216) for O 217) 3.39 ?.0001, 54) 4. on assets Operating return on assets Operating return on assets 217) 0.66 (.9788,58) 1 a. Sample is the manager-firm matched panel data set as described in subsection III.A and Table I. Details o table are available in the Data Appendix. b. Reported in the table are the results from fixed effects panel regressions, where standard errors are clustere column 1) the fixed effects included are row 1: firm and year fixed effects; row 2: firm, year, and CEO fixed effects; c. Also included in the "N of diversifying acquisitions," "R&D," "advertising," and "SG&A"regressions are the of diversifying acquisitions" regressions also include a dummy variable for whether the firm undertook any acqui "Operating return on assets" regressions is the logarithm of total assets. d. Reported in the table are F-tests for the joint significance of the CEO fixed effects (column 2), CFO fixed effe each F-test we report the value of the F-statistic and, in parentheses, thep-value and number of constraints. Also ?2s (column 6) for each regression. QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS 1186 we find that dividend R2 of 7 percent. Moreover, policy to be more substantially affected by the CEOs than by the CFOs or other top executives. our results IV reports for the organizational Table policy variables (Panel B). (Panel A) and for corporate performance we find that top executives on the have Again, large effects The fit of the diversification realization of these variables. regres sion improves by 11 percent.23 The adjusted R2s of the R&D and cost both increase by 5 percent. advertising Finally, regressions as to of total the ratio SG&A sales, by cutting policy, proxied on the identity to systematically of the CEOs.24 appears depend justed seems a priori intuition we find that CEOs and other top to have larger effects on organizational managers strategy than CFOs do. on two different mea IV focuses Panel B of Table Finally, we consider sures of corporate measure is The first performance. In line with seem in the benchmark of return on assets. Included here are firm fixed effects, year fixed effects, and the specification of total assets. Our results show that accounting per logarithm across The F-tests varies formance top executives. significantly are large for all groups and the adjusted of managers, R2 in creases by more than 5 percent. a standard rate concern with this latter finding is that the possible across on rate return assets in of differences managers systematic in not but rather differences reflect actual may performance or in aggressiveness of accounting differences willing practices ness to "cook the books."25 In order to address this concern, we use measure an alternative that is less of performance accounting One true captures a ratio of total (as operating performance: operating also of operating assets). We find that this measure performance on across The the F-tests varies top managers. systematically are in and the increase ad CEO fixed effects jointly significant of 6 percent. for this measure Interestingly, justed R2 is nearly subject to accounting and manipulations cash performance, we cannot reject the null better flow hypothesis that the fixed not reported down broke the set of other 23. In regressions here we again that the subdivision We found into more managers specific job title categories. in adjusted of the increase R2. and COOs CEOs explain most R&D and for advertising 24. The expenditures, regressions expenditures, on a smaller of due to the inconsistent estimated SG&A were availability sample in COMPUSTAT. these variables we are more the 25. In an ongoing investigating systematically project, to and how they relate in accounting of manager fixed effects practices importance on real variables in this paper. the results reported 1187 MANAGING WITH STYLE on the group effects of the CFOs and "Other" executives are all zeros. rV.C. Robustness of Results a series to verify of specification checks the we of the findings the reported above. First, replicate at above after collapsing the data the manager/firm analysis an alternative level. This provides serial way to address possible concerns. More correlation the firm starting with specifically, the residuals year data, we estimate firm-year by regressing We conduct robustness of interest on firm fixed effects, year fixed effects, policy variables and the time-varying then collapse firm controls. We these an the nual residuals by manager-firm spell. Last, we reestimate in this collapsed set. We find, in fixed data effects manager not reported here, that our results are robust to this regressions alternative estimation technique. fixed effects iden Second, one might worry that the manager of managerial above do not imply persistence style across a to and For firms. consider who manager jobs example, happens we be part of a firm during a period of intense acquisition activity; a positive fixed effect for that manager estimate acquisition might tified even though in his future firm. This that effect does not persist concern is especially for some of the lumpier policy warranted in our analysis. variables covered in the first column of Table V. Here We address this concern we use a more parametric to analyze the persistence specification in managerial we construct for each policy variable, styles. More specifically, as described residuals above. We then manager-firm a manager's in his second firm on his residual regress average in the first firm we observe her/him residual in.26 Re average coefficients ported in the first column of Table V are the estimated on the first firm residual for each of the corporate variables. We find a positive and statistically significant relationship a manager's in his last job and his residual in residual for all the with ?-statistics job varying policy variables, 4 and 16 and R2 between 5 and 35 percent. Moreover, the are also economically in these regressions estimated coefficients a top for most of the variables. For example, very significant between his first between 1 percent associated with manager is associated with about 0.5 percent the 26. Note investment that we cannot directly to Q and investment extra extra leverage leverage in his first job in his second this more parametric perform to cash flow sensitivities. exercise for QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS 1188 TABLE V Persistence of Manager Investment Effects: Real Data Real data 0.05 (0.02) [0.01] N of acquisitions Leverage Cash holdings Dividends/earnings (0.05) [0.13] 0.40 (0.03) [0.21] 0.74 (0.05) [0.35] 0.80 (0.04) [0.51] N of diversifying acquis. R&D Advertising SG&A Return on assets (0.06) [0.07] 0.65 (0.05) [0.33] 0.62 (0.08) [0.02] 0.14 (0.01) [0.03] 0.31 (0.07) [0.40] Operating return on assets (0.03) [0.07] and Placebo Data Placebo data 0.01 (0.02) [0.00] 0.49 - 0.02 (0.05) [0.00] 0.02 (0.05) [0.01] 0.05 (0.07) [0.01] 0.06 (0.12) [0.02] 0.25 0.04 (0.05) [0.00] 0.09 (0.05) [0.02] 0.11 (0.06) [0.01] 0.08 (0.08) [0.02] 0.02 (0.06) [0.01] 0.18 0.03 (0.11) [0.00] a. Sample is the manager-firm matched panel data set as described in subsection III .A and Table I. Details on the definition and construction of the variables reported in the table are available in the Data Appendix. b. Each entry in this table corresponds to a different regression. c. In column 1we regress for each of the policy variables a manager's average residual in his second firm on his average residual in his first firm. In column 2 we regress for each of the policy variables a "manager's average residual" in his second firm three years prior to the manager joining that firm on his true average residual in his first firm. See subsection IV.C for details. d. The first number in each cell is the estimated coefficient on the first job residual, the second number is the estimated standard error (in parentheses) and the third number is the estimated R (in square brackets). 1189 MANAGING WITH STYLE for which we find particularly corporate policies in Tables III and IV (such as acqui fixed effects or R&D) to dividend also prove diversification, policy, job. Moreover, strong manager sitions, in this more paramet generate higher R2 and larger coefficients are consistent a persistence with ric setup. These results of the across fixed effects firms. manager to argue that the manager fixed effects cap Third, we want on corporate ture the active of managers influence decisions. an alternative There that is poten is, however, interpretation our findings, with but does not imply an active tially consistent on their companies. a model of the Suppose have no specific skills or styles but boards managers A manager be believe otherwise. may, by coincidence, mistakenly in a wave of acquisitions in her or his prior firm, and this involved as an "acquisition be wrongly may perceived style" by other If this leads to the hiring ofthat manager boards. by a firm that would have gone on an external expansion phase even without influence world of managers where we might a positive the manager, fixed effect estimate acquisition for that manager. we analyze To investigate this alternative the interpretation, in of the observed Un changes corporate precise timing policies. der the story outlined above, we would not expect to find a precise and the change the arrival of the new manager overlap between some of the one in corporate In that fact, expect might practices. new man in arrival of the the changes policies actually precede as has to the board the changes. undertake ager, already decided ifmanagers do play the active role in shaping in policy will only happen after the the changes policies, is hired.27 manager we construct in corporate residuals average Practically, pol in that each manager icies as described above but now assume On the other hand, corporate our data turnover turnover set joins his second firm three years prior to the actual date and leaves that firm at the time of the actual date. In doing this, we are careful to censure the data for the second firms at the actual date of arrival of the new managers in these firms. We then regress these average pre-turnover resid in the first uals in the second firm on the true average residuals firm. Column 2 of Table V presents the results of this exercise. We 27. This test relies on a specific One could still argue that timing assumption. to bring in about the manager any changes boards, they do not need although once the new the changes nevertheless corporate only go ahead with strategy, arrives. manager 1190 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS in these placebo find that the estimated coefficients regressions are economically 1. those in column very small compared with are very close to zero, and all Most of the estimated coefficients but two are statistically These results confirm insignificant.28 once in corporate that the bulk of the changes the policy happen new manager has joined the firm and not prior to his arrival, an active role of the managers in implementing these suggesting changes. IV. D. Magnitude of the Manager Fixed Effects a So far, we have seen that manager-specific effects explain in outcomes. fraction of firm the variation significant policies and we would like to assess how big the observed differ Additionally, ences we look at the distribu are. Therefore, managers tions of the fixed effects estimated above. For example, we can see a manager extra how much in the upper tail of the leverage to a man relative contributes, leverage fixed effects distribution In Table VI we ager who is in the lower tail of that distribution. between report the size distribution the regressions in Tables of the manager III and IV. We fixed effects show median, for each of standard and seventy-fifth percentile. we weigh each fixed effect by deviation, twenty-fifth percentile, When these statistics, computing error. error to account the inverse of its standard for estimation VI in variation size Table shows that the the of the Overall, is fixed effects To manager economically large. highlight just a row 1 of Table VI shows that the difference few examples, be tween a manager at the twenty-fifth the of distribution percentile of investment level and one at the seventy-fifth is 0.20. percentile To give a benchmark, to ratio of capital expenditures the average in our sample assets is about 0.30. The difference between the in the leverage distribu and seventy-fifth twenty-fifth percentile level of tion is 0.16 (row 5), compared with an average leverage we observe about 0.7 acqui .34 in our sample. For acquisitions, per year for the firms in our sample. Row 4 of Table VI in the bottom quartile shows that a manager reduces the number a manager in the top quartile of acquisitions while by -0.49, sitions increases the last in of acquisitions by 0.44 per year. Finally, in corporate VI we see that the variation in the top is also large. A manager effects the number row of Table performance fixed 28. We also repeated in Tables III and followed a similar in the less parametric exercise IV and obtained similar findings. framework 1191 MANAGING WITH STYLE TABLE VI Size of Manager Distribution Fixed 25th 75th deviation percentile percentile 2.80 -0.09 0.11 0.66 -0.16 0.12 1.01 -0.17 0.28 1.50 -0.54 0.41 -0.05 -56.0 -0.03 0.09 51.7 0.02 Standard Median Investment Inv to Q 0.00 -0.02 sensitivity Inv to CF sensitivity N 0.04 of acquisitions -0.04 0.01 0.00 0.00 Leverage Interest coverage Cash holdings Dividends/earnings N of diversifying acquis. return 0.22 860.0 0.06 -0.01 0.59 -0.13 0.11 -0.04 1.05 -0.28 0.21 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.04 0.66 0.04 0.07 -0.10 -0.09 -0.01 -0.03 0.02 0.09 0.01 0.03 0.00 0.08 -0.02 0.03 R&D SG&A Advertising Return on assets Operating Effects on assets a. The fixed effects used in this table are retrieved from the regressions reported inTables III and IV (row 3). b. Column 1 reports the median fixed effect for each policy variable. Column 2 reports the standard deviation of the fixed effects. Columns 3 and 4 report the fixed effects at the twenty-fifth percentile and seventy-fifth percentile of the distribution, respectively. c. Each fixed effect is weighted by the inverse of its standard error to account for estimation error. increases of the distribution the rate of return on assets quartile a manager In contrast, in the bottom quartile by about 3 percent. reduces the rate of return on assets by about 3 percent. fixed effects for most of the corpo Also, the median manager are not different as rate variables from zero. This is interesting one might have expected that the nature of the sample construc tion and the focus on outside hires might have led us to select a This seems to indicate that this pos different type of managers. sible selection issue is not an important factor in our analysis. rV.E. Management Styles a wide degree section documents of heteroge previous in the way managers conduct their businesses. We now to go a step further and investigate whether there are in managerial For exam patterns overarching decision-making. some do favor internal while managers growth ple, strategies The neity want others rely more on external observe that some managers sive than others? ceteris paribus? Or can we growth, more aggres overall are financially QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS 1192 To answer we analyze struc the correlation questions, we ture between the manager retrieve specific fixed effects which from the set of regressions above. We form a data set that, for contains the estimated fixed effects for the various each manager, in this the different variables corporate variables. More precisely, new data set are the manager in Tables III fixed effects estimated and these IV for the specification (row 3). In practice, we propose that to estimate = a + (2) F.E.(y)j all groups includes regressions of managers as follows: ?F.E.(z)j+eJ, and y and z are any two corporate j indexes managers, in equa variable variables. that the Note right-hand-side policy is noisy by definition. tion (2) is an estimated which coefficient of ?. This will lead to a downward bias in an OLS estimation we are with which the fixed effects Since know the precision where we use a GLS estimation to account measured, technique error in the right-hand-side measurement We variable. error of the standard each observation by the inverse independent which variable, oq we obtain from the first for the weigh on the step regressions. are reported in Table VII. Each a to The different corresponds regression. maxi 10 the for is about these R2 average percent; regressions mum R2 is about 33 percent, while the minimum R2 is about 0.03 seem to A few from this emerge patterns percent. interesting seem to differ in their approach toward table. First, managers external versus internal growth. We see from the last two rows of The element results in this table of this column 1 that there exercise is a strong negative correlation between as internal can be interpreted invest and diversifica through acquisitions growth which capital expenditures, and external ments, who follow expansion tion. In a similar vein, managers strategies in less and diversification external engage through acquisitions Row 7 of Table VII shows that the coefficients R&D expenditures. a different to account for this analysis 29. We also repeated technique using error in the estimated fixed effect. For each set of fixed effects we measurement of the observations observations formed averages by size), and by deciles (ranking on each other in the above set of fixed effects the transformed then regressed we also manner. similar results. This produces described Finally, qualitatively a factor to able effects. We were for the full set of fixed conducted analysis seem to support the The factor three different eigenvectors. loadings distinguish are two versus external and internal view that financial growth aggressiveness of style. dimensions important 1193 MANAGING WITH STYLE TABLE VII Relationship between the Manager Fd d Effects Return on Cash Investment Inv to Q Inv to CF holdings Leverage R&D assets Investment 0.00 Inv to Q sensitivity 6.8 (0.00) 0.03 (0.92) (0.01) Inv to CF -0.01 sensitivity 0.02 Cash holdings (0.6) -1.10 (0.11) -0.79 -0.46 Leverage (1.62) -0.39 (1.71) -0.28 (1.72) -0.63 -0.40 R&D (0.55) 0.07 (0.59) 0.08 (0.60) -0.03 (0.17) -0.23 -0.02 Advertising (0.00) 0.01 (0.02) 0.02 (0.01) -0.01 (0.04) -0.01 (0.01) 0.00 0.25 (0.11) 0.31 N of acquisitions (0.01) -0.27 (0.01) 0.08 (0.01) 0.23 (0.04) 0.01 (0.01) 0.02 (0.15) -0.01 (0.15) -0.01 N of divers, (0.11) -0.30 (0.10) -0.14 (0.10) 0.14 (0.00) 0.01 (0.01) 0.01 (0.00) -0.01 (0.00) -0.01 (0.13) -0.22 (0.15) -0.30 (0.14) 0.10 (0.01) 0.54 (0.02) 0.06 (0.00) -4.32 (0.00) -3.36 (0.01) (0.04) (0.03) (0.56) (0.21) (0.90) (0.62) acquis. SG&A -0.23 (0.01) -0.12 (0.05) -0.02 (0.02) 0.11 a. Each entry in this table corresponds to a different regression. b. Each entry reports the coefficient from a weighted regression of the fixed effects from the row variable on the fixed effects from the column variable. Observations in these regressions are weighted by the inverse of the standard error on the independent variable. c. Coefficients that are significant at the 10 percent level are highlighted in bold. are -0.01 from a regression of R&D on either of these variables errors of 0.002. Moreover, and standard capital expenditures are correlated. R&D expenditures significantly positively is that managers who are more Another finding interesting with to be less investment-cash sensitive also appear on ? in a regression to of the investment coefficient to cash flow fixed effects (column Q fixed effects on the investment error of 0.11. 2 and row 3 of Table VII) is -0.23 with a standard one two of This suggests that managers follow may strategies: investment-Q sensitive. The use either erated sions. the or use the cash flow gen the firm's market valuation as a deci benchmark for their investment by operations in light of the current debate on is interesting This result investment in firms. So far, most flow sensitivity across in investment behavior differences dimension. Our findings constraint sug to cash research has analyzed firms along a financial QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS 1194 di need to be aware of another gest that one might important mension: heterogeneity. manager-specific a negative On the financing correlation side, we observe between the leverage fixed effects and the cash holding fixed is a proxy for financial If cash holding effects. slack, this result the idea that managers may differ in the conservatism supports or aggressiveness else of their financing choices. Everything some less debt and managers prefer holding relatively equal, more do. cash than other managers from the last row of Table VII, we see that managers Also, with ment low levels of SG&A over and R&D expenditures, fewer acquisitions. Managers are also less investment-Q sales favor more while invest internal in significantly they engage levels of SG&A to sales higher sensitive investment-cash and more with flow sensitive. as we already in Table IV, there are system showed Finally, across the managers in in corporate performances atic differences we measure as rate of return our sample, whether performance on asset or use of Table VII, we systematically rate decisions.30 to Q sensitivities managers an operating In the last column income measure. see that the fixed effects in return on assets are in corpo to some managerial fixed effects related We who with higher investment that managers on assets fixed return effects. Also, higher more sheet or have cash on the balance find have keep levels of SG&A have lower rates of return on assets. Last, higher in more acquisitions and more diversifying who engage managers are also associated levels. with lower performance acquisitions latter findings that not only are there systematic These suggest in decision-making are systematically differences differences fixed between correlated but that these managers with the performance effects. V. Possible Interpretations As we discussed interpretations 30. Note on in return here we found fixed effects error of 0.05. in Section of the observed of the Manager II, there manager Fixed are at least fixed effects. Effects two different One view the fixed effects between that there is a strong positive relationship on assets. not reported return In a regression assets and operating on assets in a regression of the return coefficient that the estimated a standard on assets on operating is 0.41, with fixed effects return is 24 percent. The R2 ofthat regression is 1195 MANAGING WITH STYLE that managers impose their own idiosyncratic style onto the firm are some If less performance-enhancing than they head. styles some of these managers to adopt may cause corporations others, An alternative view is that managers policies. value-reducing or relative differ in their comparative skills and firms advantage are the best match who choose managers for their optimally current In this case, there is no such thing as a needs. strategic "better" or "worse" style but rather different styles that are best suited to different environments. While it is beyond the scope of this paper to fully sort out these two alternative interpretations, we provide some evidence in the following that the suggesting fixed effects cannot observed managerial a pure story alone. by optimal matching V.A. Sorting Based on Firm and be reasonably Industry-Level explained Characteristics stems from our results in A first interesting piece of evidence the last column of Table VII. Certain manager-specific styles seem to correlate with manager in fixed effects systematically more are hold less who invest managers cash, performance: in more M&A activity or spend more on engage sensitive, ment-Q also have lower performance SG&A, are consistent with the view findings for performance than others, we need ble alternative More interpretations. fixed effects. While these that some styles are better to be cautious about possi these results specifically, could also be consistent with the view that certain styles are of economic distress. Firms better suited than others to periods is whenever be "turnaround might hiring managers" performance are in to order that poor particularly implement specific policies seems less in those times. However, beneficial this interpretation when we consider convincing column of Table VII. Policies in the last patterns or more like high SG&A spending, are intense M&A and diversification which activities, negatively in performance, correlated with the fixed effects do not at first our intuition of turnaround sight coincide with practices. More the correlation that managers relies on the assumption are hired in the to changes in response This of the firm (e.g., poor performance). our seems inconsistent with that however, interpretation, finding most of the changes in firm policy happen after the manager joins a firm (Table V). of the matching to assess the relevance Yet another way is to whether there is ask any apparent sorting of interpretation over, this interpretation with particular styles economic environment QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS 1196 one For example, styles across industries. CEOs to be more prevalent in financially aggressive more industries while behavior be may high growth cost-cutting of a norm in more mature industries. For that purpose, we relate different management expect might the manager fixed effects to industry measures of Tobin's Q and sales growth. We fail to find any robust systematic relationship.31 a pure optimal matching Another piece of evidence against comes from replicating our findings in Tables interpretation III, the time-varying firm level controls. IV, and V after dropping a we under will pure matching Indeed, model, identify manager fixed effects only if the firms' strategic needs at a given point in time are not fully captured by the time-varying firm controls that we have in all of the regressions included above. A natural im we of this is that the manager fixed effects argument plication have identified should become economically if we drop the available time-varying this exercise, we find only statistically perform in our estimates.32 small changes economically stronger V.B. Governance, and statistically controls. When we insignificant and and Style Compensation, In addition, we propose to investigate whether the estimated fixed effects, and especially the manager fixed effects in are systematically to differences related in corpo performance, across firms. are rate governance If some management styles "better" than others, one might that better firms expect governed will be more with these "good" styles. likely to select managers To address this issue, we briefly turn to an alternative data some CDA which infor source, governance Spectrum, provides manager mation for most of the firms in our sample. From CDA Spectrum we compute, is in, the fraction of for the second firm a manager shares held by large block holders.33 We then regress the man on this in corporate and performance ager fixed effects practices governance vide other variable. governance Unfortunately, measures, this database does not pro as board composition such variables. The results of this analysis are reported in the first column of to the rest of this analysis for firm-specific relative conditions repeat the firm's deviation from its For each corporate industry. policy we compute mean in the year prior to a turnover. Then we check industry (asset-weighted) the direction to predict of the deviation from the industry mean the whether helps we find no statistically robust patterns. hired by the firm. Again, type of manager are available as well as other nonreported results below 32. These results from the authors upon request. for details. 33. See the Data Appendix 31. We their 1197 MANAGING WITH STYLE to a different corresponds are the fixed effects on where the dependent variables regression is the gov the corporate variables and the independent variable we find a positive ernance measure. Most and sta interestingly, Table VIII. Each cell in this column the manager between tistically relationship significant fects in return on assets and the fraction of shares held most of the policy fixed effects block holders.34 Moreover, to the manager fixed found to be significantly related are to also related governance performance significantly same fixed ef by large that we in effects with the to Q investment the for only relationships are at tra activity statistically significant sign, although and M&A sensitivity ditional levels. While we do not want to push these results too far due to the of the governance that variable, they appear to suggest with performance-enhanc better governed firms select managers ing styles and as such might point toward efficiency implications of the managerial heterogeneity. com fixed effects to manager Finally, we relate the manager crudeness levels. If the correlation of manager styles with perfor pensation mance is symptomatic of some managerial styles being better on average than others, we might expect boards to pay a premium this analysis, we first for managers with these styles. To perform construct manager-specific that are net of residuals compensation firm fixed firm effects, year fixed effects, and other time-varying characteristics. More precisely, we estimate regres compensation on firm sions where we regress of compensation the logarithm of total assets, the logarithm the fixed effects, year fixed effects, on rate return and of total the of the assets, sales, logarithm tenure on the job; we also include dummy variables for manager's executive. is a CEO, a CFO, or another whether the manager top we consider are the logarithm measures of The two compensation as bonus the total compensation cash (defined salary plus plus in a year) and the logarithm of of stock option granted value we From resid these compute regressions salary compensation. measures in our sample. We ual compensation for each executive on the fixed effects derived in Tables residuals above to account the GLS estimation described error in the right-hand-side variables. for the measurement in columns 2 and 3 of The results of this exercise are reported we see that managers with higher Table VIII. Most importantly, then regress these III and IV. We use able we 34. Similarly, and the manager find a positive relationship on operating fixed effects the governance between on assets. return vari QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS 1198 TABLE VIII Governance, and Manager Compensation, Percent Fixed Residual - shares held by large on assets Return block Total holders 0.012 0.72 compensation (0.24) 0.278 to Q Inv to CF 0.246 sensitivity 0.08 (0.053) (0.26) -0.33 0.009 -0.94 -0.33 0.008 -0.568 (0.08) 2.18 -0.617 (0.092) -0.027 SG&A (0.093) (0.90) 1.36 0.10 0.00 0.09 0.03 (0.131) acquisitions (0.18) -0.94 (0.007) of diversifying (0.29) 0.009 R&D (0.006) N (0.07) 0.04-0.01 (0.021) of acquisitions (0.13) (0.15) (0.007) N (0.03) -0.02 -0.26 Leverage -0.018 Advertising (0.06) (0.04) -0.001 holdings (0.01) -0.06 -0.06 (0.088) Cash (0.57) 0.19 -0.004 sensitivity Salary compensation 0.02 -0.08 (0.252) Inv compensation 2.86 (0.006) Investment Effects (0.93) (0.54) (0.05) (0.03) (0.04) -0.16 (0.04) (0.05) -0.09 (0.25) a. Each entry in column 1 corresponds to a different regression. The dependent variable in each of these regressions is the manager fixed effect on the row variable, as retrieved from Tables III and IV). The independent variable is the fraction of shares held by 10 percent ormore block holders in the second firm we observe the manager in (from CDA Spectrum). The first number in each cell is the estimated coefficient; the second number is the estimated standard error. Each observation isweighted by the inverse of the standard error of the dependent variable. b. Each entry in columns 2 and 3 corresponds to a different regression. The independent variable in each of these regressions is the manager fixed effect on the row variable, as retrieved from Tables III and IV). The dependent variable is a manager-level residual from a compensation regression where we control for firm fixed effects, year fixed effects, the logarithm of total assets, the logarithm of total sales, return on assets, tenure on the job, and dummies for whether the manager is a CEO, a CFO, or another top executive (see subsection IV.E for details). The two different compensation measures are the logarithm of total compensa tion (column 2), defined as salary plus bonus plus the Black and Scholes value of stock options grants, and the logarithm of salary compensation (column 3). In the reported regressions, each observation is weighted by the inverse of the standard error of the independent variable to account for estimation error. on assets fixed effects receive higher total com residual as as relation This well salary compensation. higher pensation variables. It for is both significant compensation statistically ship we a correlation such is interesting that find given strong positive com controlled for return on assets when that we have already to net out the residual pay-for-performance puting compensation return 1199 MANAGING WITH STYLE Firms thus appear to pay relationship. rates of who are associated with higher on to With effects the fixed regard a Two is murkier. the little ables, picture a premium for managers return on assets.36 the specific policy vari of the policy effects that are significantly to the performance fixed effects related (invest are significantly ment to Q sensitivity and advertising) related, The correlations of compen with the same sign, to compensation. same of the sation with and SG&A, while cash holdings sign as are weak. those obtained for performance, statistically Finally, we and diver that managers with high levels of acquisition on total compensation. earn a premium This is activity and since we saw in Table VII that the acquisition surprising, are negatively to the fixed related diversification fixed effects is statis this relationship effects on return on assets.37 However, find sification tically insignificant if we VI. Observable look at cash compensation Managerial Characteristics only. of evidence sections have provided suggestive previous in differences decisions among top manag corporate systematic ers. However, of managerial fixed effects does not the presence traits or character tell us much about which specific managerial In this section we their decision-making. istics might influence The characteristics: the possible role of two such managerial analyze One expects MBA edu MBA graduation and birth cohort/age.38 either cation to affect managerial decision-making through hu or because man of a selection and social capital accumulation a relevant managerial also be effect. Similarly, birth cohort might a mechanical we might be still be concerned about 35. While relationship we see that the positive tween and performance, stock option (or bonus) grants even for cash salary alone. relation holds not reported the relationship 36. In regressions here we also investigated If in performance and compensation between the manager fixed effects change. are particularly at to learn over time that certain managers successful firms were a bigger one would would that these managers value, creating expect experience we did not find in pay from their first to their second increase job. Interestingly, of managers could that the compensation This indicate any such relationship. bid up in their first job and that the with better styles were already perceived career. in the managers' earlier about managers' type happens learning in a study of the determinants of CEO pay, Rose and Shepard 37. Similarly, firms are paid more. diversified of larger and more [1997] find that managers and Ellison cross-sectional 38. In a related Chevalier [1999] paper study fund managers. in the behavior of mutual and performance differences They show earn higher rates schools better and those who attended that younger managers from schools with higher SAT scores are of returns. They also show that managers more and In a survey in their investment of CFOs Graham behavior. risk-taking an MBA also use more [2001] find that CFOs who degree report holding Harvey an MBA. than those without valuation techniques sophisticated QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS 1200 of managers trait as it is often suggested that older generations are relatively more in their decision-making.39 conservative V7.A. Construction Sample to a sample of the study, we limit ourselves we use 800 the Forbes data from 1969 to of CEOs.40 As above, 1999 and Execucomp data from 1992 to 1999 to create a list of two this information with CEO names. We then complement data sources that provide background information for different For this section and the Executives of Corporate Directory this data set of America. We then merge to COMPUSTAT characteristics and SDC managerial construct all the relevant variables (as de corporate the S&P CEOs: these is Who Who observable data of Corporate and in the Data Appendix). Means are in columns sample reported scribed this somewhat surprisingly, an MBA The average is only about 40 percent. completed in our sample was born in 1928. The earliest year of birth is we is 1966. Not find that and the latest surprisingly, Perhaps have CEO 1884 younger school. VLB. and summary statistics for 3 and 4 of Table I. of CEOs who the fraction generations Empirical are more likely to have attended business Methodology For all of the corporate variables y ?^ considered above, except to Q sensi to cash flow sensitivities and investment investment we estimate the tivities, regression: following (3) yijt = ?Xit + hMBAj + y]Cohortj + yTenure3 + a? + X, + eijt, t indexes is a time, Xit j indexes CEOs, a variable that vector of firm characteristics, is dummy MBAj an MBA and 0 otherwise, is 1 if CEO j' completed equals Cohortj the birth cohort of CEO j, a? are firm fixed effects, \t are year in equation included fixed effects, and eijt is an error term. Also of years the CEO has been in office, (3) is a control for the number where i indexes Tenure j. This firms, control should account for possible entrenchment we to characteristics the two specific 39. Obviously, propose managerial that we characteristics of the individual study here constitute only a small subset one would like to know to decision-making. For example, be relevant believe might or even personal more about past professional experience, family background, of the limit the richness obvious data constraints Unfortunately, psychology. we can perform. exercise on other more to find background information difficult 40. It is much top in the data sources that we consulted. executives 1201 MANAGING WITH STYLE we allow effects. Finally, at the individual manager level. There are two points worth emphasizing (3) includes firm fixed effects. First, equation or career error concern of the for clustering term not therefore about equation (3). is Our identification across firms in the differences our identification comes from driven by average hire. Instead, type they or birth cohort of the in the MBA status variation within-firm to equa of equation the estimation CEO. Second, (3), in contrast tion (1), no longer relies on our ability to track the same manager turnover into different still firms over time. While managerial of CEOs is changes for identification drives our test, the only requirement in CEO characteristics of within firms over time. One implication we rely on to our prior analysis, is that, in contrast this feature to isolate the effect of MBA both internal hires and external and birth cohorts. graduation on invest A study of the effect of managerial characteristics a some ment to cash and investment to Q sensitivities requires what different MBA and birth to Q sensitivities We estimate the effect of empirical specification. to cash flow and investment cohort on investment the following regression: by estimating (4) Iljt = ?Xit + ^MBAj + + * ^Cohortj ^{Tenurej + + b2MBAj ^Cohortj + ^{Tenurej * CFit Ki(t_1} + h^MBAj * CFit Kiit-1} + ^Cohortj * CFit Ki{t_1} + * Q?(?_1} * Qi{t-i) y3Tenurej * * + Xt + eijt, + CFit Ki{t_1} + ai3 Q?(?-i)Ot? ai2 Qi{t?1} * is a vector of interactions firm between ai2 CFitIKi{t_1) fixed effects and cash flow, a?3 * Q^-i) is a vector of interactions firm fixed effects and lagged Tobin's Q and all the other between as above. By analogy are defined with variables (3), equation where differences (4) allows for firm-specific equation to Q sensitivities. cash flow and investment VLC. in investment to Results in Table IX. Each row corresponds in all rows except rows (2) and to a different regression. Reported on the birth cohort and MBA coefficients (3) are the estimated the from equation (3). In rows (2) and (3) we report dummy on the interactions of these managerial coefficients estimated The traits results with equation cash (4). are presented flow and lagged Tobin's Q, respectively, from 1202 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS TABLE IX CEOs' Birth Cohort variable: Dependent (1) Investment (2) Inv to Q sensitivity and MBA on Firm Effects Year of birth (*10) .017 .016 (.010) (.003) .118 (.014) (4)N of acquisitions .001 (.037) (5) Leverage (6) Interest .000 (.003) of diversifying acquis. -.036 (.015) (10) R&D -.003 (.002) (11)Advertising -.001 (.002) (12) SG&A .002 (.003) (13) Return on assets -.003 (.004) (14) Operating return on assets (.056) .011 (.002) (9) N (.026) -.017 (.008) -.005 (8) Dividends/earnings -.075 (.007) (2.67) (7) Cash holdings .017 (.006) .024 -6.50 coverage MBA (.005) -.013 (3) Inv to CF sensitivity Policies -.002 (.003) .924 (3.41) -.001 (.003) -.009 (.004) .040 (.017) -.002 (.002) .003 (.003) -.004 (.003) .012 (.005) .008 (.003) a. Sample is the set of firm-year observations forwhich we could obtain information on the year of birth and MBA graduation of the CEO, as described in subsection VIA and Table I. Details on the definition and construction of the variables reported in the table are available in the Data Appendix. b. Each row, except rows (2) and (3), corresponds to a different regression. Reported are the estimated coefficients on year of birth and MBA dummy. Also included in each regression are year fixed effects, firm fixed effects, and a control for CEO tenure. Other included controls are as follows: row (1): lagged Tobin's Q, cash flow, and lagged logarithm of total assets; row (4): return on assets and lagged logarithm of total assets; rows (5) to (8): return on assets, cash flow, and lagged logarithm of total assets; row (9): return on assets, cash flow, logarithm of total assets, and a dummy forwhether the firm undertook any acquisition that year; rows (10) to (12): return on assets, cash flow, and logarithm of total assets; rows (13) and (14): logarithm of total c. The reported coefficients in rows (2) and (3) are from a unique regression of investment on year fixed effects, lagged Tobin's Q, cash flow, lagged logarithm of total assets, firm fixed effects, firm fixed effects interacted with lagged Tobin's Q and cash flow, CEO tenure, CEO tenure interacted with lagged Tobin's Q and cash flow, year of birth, year of birth interacted with lagged Tobin's Q and cash flow, an MBA dummy, an MBA dummy interacted with lagged Tobin's Q and cash flow. Reported in rows (2) and (3) are the estimated coefficients on the interactions between year of birth and the MBA dummy with lagged Tobin's Q and cash flow, respectively. d. Standard errors are in parentheses. Standard errors are corrected for clustering of observations at the individual manager level. 1203 MANAGING WITH STYLE start with We from earlier birth the investment variables. We find that CEOs are associated with lower investment in year of increase ten-year equal. Each (as a ratio to lagged prop expenditures cohorts else levels, everything birth decreases capital erty, plant, and equipment) by about 1.7 percentage point. MBA on average, more 1.6 appear percentage graduates point but this effect is more noisily estimated. Rows (2) and (3) consider to cash flow and investment to Q sensitivities. investment We on more to find that MBA graduates Tobin's Q average respond to invest and less to cash expenditures. cation appear when making flow availability when about capital deciding is interesting. CEOs with MBA edu pattern to follow more the "textbook closely guidelines" This to investment decisions. They are less responsive sources of funds but more responsive the availability of internal as embodied to the presence in Tobin's Q. of growth opportunities to We find that older generations of CEOs are less responsive investment level. However, somewhat setting we do not find that younger generations weigh sources of financing less internal when making deci investment to cash sensitiv sions. To the contrary, we find that investment we find no sig ities are larger among younger cohorts. Finally, Tobin's Q when more surprisingly, nificant relationship behavior acquisition We next consider between the two managerial (row (4)). the financial attributes and policy variables. We find that lower levels of financial lever older generations of CEOs choose increase in else equal (row (5)). Each age, everything ten-year CEO year of birth increases financial leverage by about 2.5 per on the effect of MBA gradua centage points. The point estimate tion on financial is but statistically leverage positive insignifi cant. Consistent the leverage interest (row coverage results, birth cohorts and CEOs from earlier (6)) appears among higher In row (7) lower (but not significantly so) among MBA graduates. we find a significant between cash holdings negative relationship as lower levels of cash holdings and year of birth. If one regards with or more financial the sign of a more sophisticated aggressive these results indicate that older generations lack policy, might or aggressiveness. The effect of MBA that kind of sophistication on cash holdings is economically and statistically graduation we no find robust divi While between insignificant. relationship dends negative graduation. over earnings correlation and birth between cohort (row dividend (8)), there payout is a robust and MBA QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS 1204 Next, we study the with MBA degrees, and to ger tendency engage and, to a generations less R&D variables. CEOs strategy organizational CEOs from earlier cohorts, have a stron moves in diversification (row (9)). Younger in lesser degree, MBA engage graduates between (row (10)). We find no consistent relationship advertising expenditures (row (11)) or SG&A (row (12)) and the CEO characteristics.41 In summary, in Table IX suggest the results that the man we in fixed the of the effects first ager paper can, in part identify to be attributed observable individual characteristics such part, as education and year of birth. CEOs with MBAs appear to be on in a higher to engage level of average more aggressive, choosing more hold debt, and pay less dividends. expenditures, capital on to be less aggressive CEOs from older generations appear a lower level of capital lower expenditures, and higher cash holdings. leverage, we also investigate status the effect of MBA and Finally, and The birth cohort on accounting (rows (13) (14)). performance average, financial most choosing is the positive between finding relationship on return of and Rates corporate graduation performance. are more assets MBA than 1 percentage for gradu point higher are associated ates. Similarly, CEOs who hold an MBA degree on assets. returns with higher operating interesting MBA VII. Conclusion The primary systematic objective of this paper is to document across man in corporate differences decision-making an empirical to analyze framework the impor agers. We develop tance of a manager in the observed unexplained varia dimension behavioral in several across geneity hetero corporate practices. We find considerable of all investment, The realizations managers. to variables and other organizational appear strategy financing, on in While executives the charge. systematically specific depend we follow does not allow us to estimate the causal the framework on firm policies or performance, a it provides effect of managers tion simple and intuitive approach that such selection problems 41. sample values This lack of statistical smaller becomes much in COMPUSTAT. to deal with many of the first-order a study might face. significance in these in part reflect the fact may due to the many regressions that our missing 1205 MANAGING WITH STYLE in differences We also find that some of the managerial are to in related differences corporate practices systematically with higher perfor managers Moreover, corporate performance. mance and are fixed effects receive higher levels of compensation more more concen to in is be found firms where likely ownership across in behavior trated. Finally, we can tie back the differences in part managers Older generations to some observable managerial characteristics. on average, are financially more an MBA who hold follow managers degree of managers, while conservative, more aggressive strategies. Data The corporate four major data Merger and variables sources: Acquisition Appendix used in this paper COMPUSTAT, database, Spectrum. is a data source COMPUSTAT ables for more than 7500 individual are extracted from the SDC Platinum Execucomp, that reports and financial CDA vari in The data are territories) drawn from annual 10-K filings and 10-Q filings, and reports, with substantial sample large companies public ownership. is a finan SDC Platinum and Acquisition database Merger cial data set collected Financial. It contains infor by Thompson on M&A in mation transactions firms and the public by private the United States (and corporations since 1976. established States from 1979 to the present. Reported for each trans are the name and industry of the acquiring and target as as well other variables about the of the sale. firms, specifics on Standard and Poor's Execucomp data contain information the name and total compensation of up to the five highest paid United action executives for all firms in the S&P 500, S&P MidCap 400, and 600 since 1992. The reported S&P SmallCap data compensation cover base salary, bonus, and the value of granted stock options in the current year. on institutional CDA Spectrum collects information share to the from the SEC's 13f filings. The 1978 amendment holdings and Exchange Act of 1934 requires all institutional with more than $100 million to under management are reported to the SEC. Holdings their shareholdings report on 13f filings. Institutions fall into five distinct catego quarterly Security investors ries: insurance mutual banks, funds, companies, independent investment advisors (such as brokerage firms), and others (which include pension funds and endowments). mainly QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS 1206 The are defined as follows: used in the analysis specific variables is capital Investment item (COMPUSTAT expenditures at and the 128) over net property, begin plant, equipment ning of the fiscal year (COMPUSTAT item 8). Tobin's Average Q is defined as the market value of assets divided by the book value of assets (COMPUSTAT item 6), the market where value assets plus the market sum of the book value item 60) and balance item 74). Cash flow is defined of assets equals the book value of common of value less the equity of common (COMPUSTAT equity sheet deferred taxes (COMPUSTAT as the sum of earnings extraor before dinary items (COMPUSTAT item 18) and depreciation item 14) over net property, and (COMPUSTAT plant, at the beginning of the fiscal year (COMPU equipment STAT item 8). Leverage as long-term is defined debt (COMPUSTAT item 9) plus debt in current liabilities (COMPUSTAT item 34) over long-term debt plus debt in current liabilities plus the item book value of common equity 60). (COMPUSTAT as cash and short-term invest Cash holdings is defined over ments net item (COMPUSTAT 1) property, plant, and equipment at the beginning of the fiscal year (COMPU is earnings before depreciation, coverage item 13) over interest (COMPUSTAT expenses STAT item 8). Interest and tax interest, (COMPUSTAT item 15). Dividends over earnings is the ratio of the sum of common dividends (COMPUSTAT item 21) and preferred dividends before 19) over earnings item 13). (COMPUSTAT item (COMPUSTAT and interest, tax depreciation, R&D is the ratio of R&D expenditures (COMPUSTAT item 46) over lagged total assets (COMPUSTAT item 6). Advertising is the ratio of advertising expenditures (COM PUSTAT item 45) over lagged total assets (COMPUSTAT item 6). is the ratio SG&A expenses of selling, and administrative general, over sales item 189) (COMPU (COMPUSTAT STAT item 12). N of acquisitions fiscal year. N of diversifying is the total number acquisitions of acquisitions is the number in the of acquisitions 1207 MANAGING WITH STYLE industries during the fiscal year in two-digit in. those the acquirer operates currently on assets is the ratio of EBITDA Return different from (COMPUSTAT item 18) over lagged total assets (COMPUSTAT item 6). return Operating on assets is the ratio of operating cash flow (COMPUSTAT item 308) over lagged total assets (COMPUSTAT item 6). com is the total value of a manager's as It is for the fiscal defined the year. pensation package sum of cash salary, cash bonus, and the Black and Scholes in that year. value of options granted Total compensation Percent is the fraction of shares held by large block holders or 10 percent shares that are owned by block holders with more on of the firm's outstanding shares the last (based quarter University of each year). of Chicago Graduate and Research, Institute Massachusetts Economic National Policy Bureau Centre School for of Technology of Economic of Business, National Bureau and Policy Research of Economic Sloan Research, and School Centre of Management, and Economic for Research References A. Jarrell, "On the Existence of an and E. Han Kim, Michael, Bradley, Gregg XXXIX Journal Structure," (1984), 857-878. Optimal Capital of Finance, and Glenn "Are Some Mutual Fund Managers Better Chevalier, Judith, Ellison, in Behavior Jour than Others? Cross-Sectional Patterns and Performance," UN nal of Finance, 875-899. (1999), R. Glenn Hubbard, and Bruce Petersen, Constraints Fazzari, Steven, "Financing on Economic I (1988), and Corporate Investment," Brookings Papers Activity, 141-195. MA: Har The Transformation Control Neil, Fligstein, of Corporate (Cambridge, vard University 1990). Press, and Campbell "The Theory and Practice of Corporate Graham, John, Harvey, LX Finance: Evidence from Journal the Field," Economics, of Financial 187-243. (2001), A. Mason, The Organization Donald and Phyllis Hambrick, C, "Upper Echelons: as a Reflection of its Top Managers," IX Review, Academy of Management 193-206. (1984), S. Weisbach, Chosen Boards Hermalin, E., and Michael Benjamin "Endogenously of Directors and Their Monitoring of the CEO," American Economic Review, LXXXVIII (1998), 96-118. "Do Investment-Cash and Luigi Flow Sensitivities Steven, Kaplan, Zingales, Provide Useful Measures of Financing Constraints?" Journal Quarterly of CXII 169-215. Economics, (1997), Lawrence "Firm-Level Lieberman, Marvin, Lau, and Mark Williams, Productivity A Comparison and Management Influence: of U. S. and Japanese Automobile XXXVI 1193-1215. Science, Producers," (1990), Management an Optimal and Gordon "Is There Struc Peter, McKay, Phillips, Industry Capital ture?" Working of Maryland, 2002. Paper, University and Geoffrey "CEO Overconfidence and Corporate Malmendier, Ulrike, T?te, 2002. Stanford Investment," Working University, Paper, and Geoffrey "Who Makes CEO Over Malmendier, T?te, Ulrike, Acquisitions? 1208 confidence 2003. QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS and Market's Reaction," Working Paper, Stanford University, and Outside A Cross-Section "CEO Turnover Succession: Robert, Parrino, Analy XLVI 165-197. Economics, sis," Journal (1997), of Financial and "Firm Diversification and CEO Andrea Rose, Nancy L., Shepard, Compensa or Executive tion: Managerial RAND Entrenchment?" Journal of Ability XXVIII 489-514. Economics, (1997), Julio and Garth and J., "Visionaries, Saloner, Rotemberg Managers, Strategic RAND XXXI Journal 693-716. Direction," (2000), of Economics, L. Clifford Investment and Ross "The Set and Smith, W., Watts, Opportunity Journal Dividend and Compensation Policies," of Fi Corporate Financing, nancial XXXII Economics, (1992), 263-292. "The Determinants of Capital Struc and Roberto Titman, Wessels, Sheridan, XLIII 1-19. ture," Journal (1988), of Finance, Van den Steen, and Managerial Massachu Beliefs Eric, "Organizational Vision," setts Institute of Technology of Management Sloan School Working Paper No. 2001. 4224-01, J. House, Gabriel and Phanish G. Ramirez, Robert Waldman, David, Puranam, The Moderating Performance: Effect of "CEO Leadership and Organizational XLIV Environmental Journal, (2001), of Management Uncertainty," Academy 134-143. L. Watts, and Karen Jerold "Stock Prices and Top B., Ross Wruck, Warner, XX Journal Economics, (1988), Management Changes," of Financial 461-492. "When Does Nitin and Bharat Anand, Noam, Nohria, Wasserman, Leadership View The Contingent of CEO Leadership," Matter? Working Opportunities 2002. Harvard Paper, University,