OBVey HD28 .M414 ALFRED P. WORKING PAPER SLOAN SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT ANALYSTS* FORECASTS AS EARNINGS EXPECTATIONS Patricia C. O'Brien WP# 1743-86 revised March 1987 MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 50 MEMORIAL DRIVE CAMBRIDGE, MASSACHUSETTS 02139 ANALYSTS' FORECASTS AS EARNINGS EXPECTATIONS Patricia WP# 1743-86 C. O'Brien revised March 1987 ANALYSTS' FORECASTS AS EARNINGS EXPECTATIONS Patricia C. O'Brien Massachusetts Institute of Technology examine three composite analyst forecasts of earnings per share as proxies for expected earnings. The most current forecast weakly dominates the mean and median forecasts in accuracy. This is evidence that forecast dates are more relevant for determining accuracy than individual error. Consistent with previous research, I find analysts more accurate than time-series models. However, prior knowledge of forecast errors from a quarterly autoregressive model predicts excess stock returns better than prior knowledge of analysts' errors. This is inconsistent with previous research, and is anomalous given analysts' greater accuracy. I Sloan School of Management Massachusetts Institute of Technology 50 Memorial Drive Cambridge, MA 02139 M.I.T. LIBRARIES 1 Introduction . Analysts' forecasts of earnings are increasingly used in accounting and finance research as proxies for the unobservable "market" expectation of diverse set of forecasts firm's earnings, into a future earnings realization. a is available at any time for Since a given composites are used to distill the diverse set single expectation. This paper considers the relative merits of several composite forecasts as expectations data. primary result is a that the most current forecast available The is more accurate than either the mean or the median of all available forecasts. This suggests forecast timeliness as for distinguishing better forecasts. is that, A characteristic a second and related result conditional on only relatively recent forecasts being included, means or medians increase accuracy by aggregating across idiosyncratic individual error. A second contribution of this paper is analysts with time series models, expectations. a a comparison of competing source of earnings Consistent with previous research, I generally more accurate than time-series models. that prior knowledge of the forecast errors from find analysts However, a I find simple autoregressive model on the univariate series of quarterly earnings provides better predictions of excess stock returns than prior knowledge of analysts' forecast errors. This result is inconsistent with prior research, and somewhat anomalous given analysts' greater accuracy. A third contribution is a methodological refinement of techniques used to evaluate forecasts. existence of significant errors. t I me-pe r i od -spec i demonstrate the f i c effects in forecast time-series and cross-section data are pooled without If taking these effects into account, statistical results may be overstated, and results are subject to an aggregation bias. In section forecasts, 2 , well as the empirical I as tests. describe proxies for consensus in two quarterly time-series models used In section 3 I describe the data. statistical tests and results are discussed in section section 5 is a analysts' in The 4 , and summary with some concluding remarks. .El2^i§5_I°r_l5D£Cted_Earnings 2.1 Defining Consensus for Analysts' The motivations for seeking a Forecasts consensus expectation when many forecasts are available are primarily practical. In contexts earnings expectations are not the central issue, necessary data. For example, to many but are remove the effects of simultaneous earnings releases on non-earnings events, unanticipated earnings are necessary. in anticipated earnings, and therefore Reducing measurement error in unanticipated earnings, increases the power of tests of the non-earnings event. individual If forecasts contain idiosyncratic error which can be diminished by aggregation, more accurate forecasts can be obtained by combining forecasts.! Academic researchers have used variety of methods to a aggregate analysts' earnings forecasts into expec ta t i on . use and Brown, (1978) a (1979) Griffin, Hagerman, and Zmijewski select the "most active" forecaster for each firm from and Gultekin Earnings Forecaster. Foster and Noreen Elton, Gruber (1984) consider both means and medians published . Summary database. I the ValueLine Brown, (1981) the mean, and Brown, in the I/B/E/S Richardson, and Schwager (1986) use forecasts and the I/B/E/S Summary forecasts. compare three composites from An (1986) Givoly and Lakonishok those available in Standard and Poors' both Brown and set of forecasts. single forecast from ValueLine. a single Barefield and Comiskey (1975), and Fried and 2 Givoly (1982) use the mean of Rozeff a the median, a set of available forecasts: and the most current forecast. implicit assumption behind the use of either the mean or the median forecast to represent consensus are current, so is that all forecasts that cross-sectional differences in forecasts are attributable to differential use of the same global set of information. Gains from combining forecasts arise either from the employment of more by any individual, information in the aggregate than or from diversification across is used individuals' idiosyncratic errors. In fact, however, the analysts' forecasts available at any time have been produced at varying dates. If analysts incorporate new information into their forecasts as the year progresses as previous research suggests (Crichfield, Dyckman and Lakonishok (1978), Gultekin (1982)), Collins and Hopwood (1980), Elton, Gruber. and then more current forecasts are expected to be However, more accurate than older ones. individual i d a diversifying across osync rac i es is more important than eliminating out- dated forecasts, aggregations of many forecasts, may be more accurate than date, if a regardless of single current one. I provide comparison of the relative importance of forecast age versus diversification, by examining the most current forecast as an alternate to the mean and median definition of consensus. My results indicate that the single most current forecast dominates aggregations which ignore forecast dates. relatively recent forecasts are included is in When only the aggregations, possible to increase accuracy by aggregating forecasts. Since the aggregate forecasts in it 3 published databases (e.g. the I/B/E/S Summary data and the Zacks Investment Research data) ignore forecast dates, my results are relevant for researchers using these sources. 2.2 Quarterly Time-series Models of Earnings I use quarterly time-series models of earnings as benchmarks, against which analysts' forecasts are compared. Time-series models have been used frequently to provide earnings expectations. in previous research Analysts, however, have the advantage of a broader information set, firm sales and production figures, information, and other analysts' historical series of earnings. including industry and general macroeconomi c forecasts, Analysts' in addition to the forecasts, therefore, seem likely to be more accurate than forecasts from univariate models . Several studies (Brown and Rozeff (1978), Collins and Fried and Givoly (1982)) demonstrate that Hopwood (1980), analysts are more accurate than univariate models, presumably because of the broader information set they can incorporate. Fried and Givoly (1982) also find that analysts' are more closely associated with excess those of univariate models. remain forecast errors stock returns than are Nonetheless, univariate models common means of generating earnings expectations. a An advantage of univariate time-series models is the relative ease with which earnings data can be obtained for moderate samples of firms. This advantage is tempered by the caveat that the data requirements of the models impart "survivorship" bias to samples. models is the relative Another advantage to time-series simplicity of the models used to generate Parsimonious models with expectations. a a single, simple ARIMA structure applied to all firms have been shown to predict at least as well as univariate models with individually-specified structures, when one-step-ahead forecast errors are compared (Foster (1977), I Foster use ( the 1977 ) : Watts and Leftwich (1977)). following two quarterly time-series models, from E[a and .. J tq where a j t quarter q jtq ] . J . e j0 jl U jtq-l ^tq-S or egr e = a . + . . Jtq-4 year of s s and 6j t, The models are, i ve process have proven to be at models. ) in . ©jl j in and 6j2 are estimated respectively, a first order fourth differences with a drift. a I drift, and a chose these and because they least as good as other mechanical quarterly The data used and the estimation of these models are described in section 3.1 1 (2) j2 models because of their relative simplicity, . ( e .. random walk in fourth differences with 3 1 denotes quarterly reported earnings for firm q parameters. t 6 Jtq-4 : E[a au 3 ] 3. Data Sources The forecast data are from the Estimate System, brokerage house. or I/B/E/S, Institutional Brokers developed by the Lynch, Jones The database consists of & Ryan individual analysts' forecasts of earnings per share (EPS) 4 made between early 1975 and mid-1982, by analysts at between 50 and 130 brokerage houses. EPS are forecast for approximately on the month and year in question. 1000 to 2500 firms, The depending individual forecasts are used by I/B/E/S to compute summary data, such as means, The summary statistics are sold to and standard deviations. primarily institutional investors. clients, medians The I/B/E/S Summary data have been analyzed extensively by Brown, Foster and Noreen among others. (1984), Each brokerage house in the database employs many analysts, but at most one forecast any time, for a reported from each brokerage house at is given firm and year. houses are identified Analysts and brokerage the database by code numbers. in The I/B/E/S data are updated once per month with new forecasts. use primarily two pieces of forecasts, information: individual analysts' and their associated forecast dates. selecting the sample of available forecasts for year, described more fully by Lynch, Jones & I/B/E/S publication dates, a COMPUSTAT a given firm and differs from that used I to use analysts' The most forecast dates, not define which forecasts are given day. is the announcement dates. the Wall My method of Ryan to produce the Summary data. important difference is that available on section 3.2, in I source of earnings data and most earnings The remaining announcement dates are from Street Journal (WSJ) and its Index. Stock return data and the trading day calendar are from the CRSP Daily Returns file. Data on stock splits and stock dividends are from the CRSP Monthly Master file. Some analysts occasionally forecast fully-diluted EPS, rather than primary EPS. This is indicated in the I/B/E/S detail 8 data. I convert forecasts of fully-diluted EPS to primary EPS, using the reported ratio of fully-diluted to primary EPS for that firm and year from COMPUSTAT. time series model I also adjust both analysts' and forecasts for any stock splits and stock dividends announced between the forecast date and the annual earnings announcement date. Sample Selection 3.2 The sample selection criteria and effects on the sample size are summarized in Table 1 . The initial sample comprises the set of firms in the I/B/E/S database with December yearends, at least one forecast available in each year from 1975 through 1981. This set contains 508 firms, year is excluded if the annual COMPUSTAT. if all on or and 3556 firm-years. and with A firm- earnings number is not available four quarterly earnings announcement dates are not available from COMPUSTAT or the WSJ. This criterion reduces the sample to 497 firms, with 3440 firm-years. The requirement that returns data be available on CRSP reduces the sample to 410 firms. The estimation requirements of the quarterly models. 30 continuous quarters of data prior to 1975IV, impose the most drastic reduction in the sample, to 184 firms with 1260 firm-years. Forecasts for each firm and year are selected at five fixed horizons of less than one year. 120. 60 and 5 The horizons are: 240, 180. trading days prior to the announcement of annual 9 The first four horizons correspond roughly to dates earnings. following each of the year's quarterly earnings announcements; the fifth is immediately prior to the annual earnings announcement. For example, corresponds to a a horizon of 240 trading days usually date after the previous year's annual announcement, but before the current year's first quarter announcement. A horizon of 180 trading days typically corresponds to a date between the first quarter announcement and the second quarter announcement; I define the set of available analysts' horizon, T and so on. The horizon date for horizon firm and year as follows. for firm j in year t is the date announcement of firm j's year t forecasts for each T EPS. trading days prior to the Given a horizon date, I select the most recent forecast available from each brokerage house forecasting firm j's EPS for year t. The number of available forecasts increases as the horizon shrinks, as reported in Panel B of Table 1 . Some brokerage houses issue forecasts before the start of the year, the year. and update them periodically during Many others add forecasts as the annual EPS announcement approaches. To determine this set of available forecasts, I use the dates assigned to forecasts by the analysts, not the dates of first publication of the forecasts. The publication I/B/E/S' lag, or time between the analyst's forecast date and the date of first appearance on I/B/E/S, the forecast's days, and has a averages 34 trading standard deviation of 44.5 trading days. Thus, 10 some recently-updated forecasts are omitted from each monthly listing by I/B/E/S. From the set of available forecasts for each firm and horizon x, current. consensus. the analysts' year t, compute the mean and median, and find the most I use the mean, I j, median and most current as proxies for Since published means and medians are computed from the monthly lists, reflect some recent updates. probably results in the I/B/E/S Summary data fail to Eliminating the publication lag my consensus analyst forecasts being somewhat more accurate than those published in the Summary data. Most previous studies of analysts' forecasts have used publication dates, not analysts' dates, to select forecasts. example, For Fried and Givoly (1982) and Givoly and Lakonishok (1979) select their samples based on the publication date of the Standard & Poors' Earnings Forecaster, their source of forecast Givoly go on to use analysts' dates within that sample to distinguish new and old forecasts. Brown and Rozeff Fried data. (1978), & Brown. and Zmijewski Foster and Noreen (1986) and Brown, (1984), Brown. Richardson and Schwager (1986) use datasets for which individual analysts' not available. Griffin, Hagerman forecast dates are Using publication dates instead of forecast dates probably biases results against analysts, by failing to include some recent updates of forecasts. In spite of eliminating the publication lag, for any given horizon date many of the forecasts available were made prior to the last quarterly earnings announcement. This may indicate 1 analysts' failure to incorporate new information, but need not. announced quarterly EPS may be close to the For example, analyst's expectation, so little new information is conveyed by the quarterly announcement and forecast is unnecessary. a revision of the annual EPS investigate I a subsample consisting of only those forecasts which have been updated since the most recent announcement of quarterly EPS. in section 4.4. reported 3.3 The subsample is described where the results of this investigation are . Measuring Forecast Errors Forecast errors are the elementary data The forecast error forecasts. between Aj t i, at a j in year horizon x and t, prior to 6 e, .„ UtT The source of following: use to evaluate defined as the difference is tT actual earnings per share of firm , the realization: analysts' i j forecast of EPS from source tne fi tt j e I = A . Jt the forecast, the mean, forecasts: the median, or one of i denoted by or (3) jtT i, is one of the the most current of available the two benchmark quarterly models described in section 2.2. The fundamental difference between the most current analyst forecast as median, is a consensus definition and either the mean or the that the former is constructed using the forecast 12 date, while the latter two are not. distributions of forecast ages forecast is in Table In 2, this sample. defined as the difference, compare I The age of trading days, in a between the forecast date and the horizon date chosen for this study. More generally, this might correspond to a lag between the forecast date and an event date of interest to the researcher. For Table as, 2, define the ages of the mean and median forecasts I respectively, the mean and the median of the ages of the forecasts in the set of available forecasts for each firm, year The distribution described in Table and horizon. firms and years, As has a over all the most current forecast for each horizon. expected from its definition, distribution of ages much closer to zero than either the mean or median. 60 is 2 trading days), For the four longer horizons (240, 180. and 120. over fifty percent of the most current forecasts are less than five trading days old. By contrast, over fifty percent of the mean or median ages at all horizons are more than forty trading days old. While some of these older forecasts may represent circumstances where little new information has arrived, so there was no need to update, the accuracy results which follow suggest that this is not always the case. Quarterly models (1) and for each quarter from 1975-1 (2) are estimated for each firm, through 1981-IV. estimates are updated each quarter, quarters' observations. the number of Parameter using the previous thirty Observations are adjusted for changes outstanding shares. Annual forecasts are in 13 constructed from quarterly forecasts by summing the appropriate realizations and forecasts. For example, in quarter there 3, have been two realizations of quarterly earnings for the year, and two quarters remain to be forecast. The annual forecast from quarterly model during the third fiscal quarter a actual earnings for quarters and 3 4 A and 1 is the sum of and forecasts for quarters 2, . small number of influential observations altered the regression results reported below. Since analysts and brokerage 7 houses are identified only by code numbers in the database, was no way to trace these observations to other sources. this reason. I there For imposed an arbitrary censoring rule on the data forecast errors larger for errors which could not be traced: than $10.00 per share in absolute value were deleted from the Since typical values for EPS numbers are in the range of sample. $1.00 to $5.00 per share, errors of sufficient magnitude to be deleted are rare, and suggest error 3 . 3 data entry or transcription a . Stock Returns I measure the new information impounded in stock returns by the cumulated prediction errors from a market model in logarithmic form: E[ln(l where Rj s is + the return R. )] js to = a . + B j security . 1 n ( 1 + J j on day RM Ms s, (4) ) Rm s is the return 14 on the CRSP equally-weighted market portfolio of securities on day and s, denotes the natural logarithm In The parameters of (4) rans f orma t i on . are estimated for each firm in the study using 200 trading days of data at time, a beginning in July Estimated parameters are used to predict ahead 100 trading 1974. and excess returns are the difference between the days, realization each t 1 n ( 1 R + and tne prediction based on js> iteration of estimation and prediction, period After the estimation rolled forward by 100 trading days, is (4). and new parameters are estimated. The estimation procedure produces daily excess returns, forecast horizon, 4.1 u 1 form to arriving over horizon s . The are cumulated over each e j s from the horizon date through the announcement date of annual EPS, 4^__Re e j s stream of predicted a in x U j t t year the measure of new information • for firm t j. t Aggregating Forecast Errors If a forecast incorporates all the information available on the forecast date the usual forecast in unbiased manner, an it statistical sense of the word. is an expectation Let f* denote such in a : f • JtT = E[A . Jt I A y tT ] (5) 15 where 4> represents the information available at tT prior to the realization, and E [ • | horizon x the conditional is ] a expectation operator. Between the forecast date and the realization date, new information may arrive. ideal Even forecast like (5), which may be a the sense of employing all in forecast date, omits unanticipated information which arrives Forecast errors consist, later. information available on the in part or entirely, information revealed over the forecast horizon, i.e. of new between forecast and realization. Two closely -related implications of unanticipated information reflected in forecast errors are important for the specification of statistical tests. within to forecast errors year which are aggregated cross-sectionally may appear a "biased" because of the common new information reflected in be Second, them. this common information is not accounted for, if induce contemporaneous cross-sectional correlation will it First, in forecast errors. An example of errors has a an unanticipated macroeconomic is firms in a similar manner. non-zero mean, forecast errors, non-zero mean. t information which may be reflected in forecast then If a shock affecting many the effect of the shock on firms cross-sectional aggregation of even from unbiased forecasts, This non-zero mean is not bias, me-per i od -s pec i f i c new information. If will also have but rather is time-period-specific a 16 they induce correlation in forecast errors effects are ignored, across firms, within for a given year and horizon, and across horizons year. a forecast errors are positively correlated across firms If within years, statistical comparisons based on pooled time-series and cross-section forecast error data which assume cross- sectional independence will overstate the statistical validity of the results. Several studies Gruber and Gultekin (1981). (Brown and Rozeff (1978), Malkiel and Cragg (1982). Elton, for example) have compared forecasts using criteria such as the number or proportion of times that one forecasting method outpredicts another. This criterion, independent observations and is or any other applied to a that assumes cross-section, could obtain the appearance of statistically significant superiority in forecasting ability from an anecdotal difference. tests developed in this paper adjust for time-period- The specific shocks using and its A s simple fixed effects model. This model, importance for the results, are described below. Evaluating Forecasts 4.2 1 a - Bias simple model of time-period effects in forecast errors 9 e where u tT is . jtx = U M + tT P (6) jtT the average forecast error for year t and horizon x 17 and 'HjtT i random error term, a s representing the deviation of firm j's forecast error from the common annual mean. There may also be f rm- spec i f i c information effects which persist through time, but the unanticipated information argument does not apply. 10 a If forecast fully impounds information from previous mistakes in an unbiased manner, systematically recurring events will not remain unanticipated year after year. recurrent on f i r m- s pec i f i Thus forecast errors are not expected to arise c information that was unavailable at the time the the basis of forecast was made. estimate (6) using least squares with I each year. The test for bias is a dummy variable for based on the grand mean of the estimated annual averages: 1 (7) t?/ tT where T is the number of years in the sample, The average x. combination of 1 ea uT defined in (7) -squa r es coefficients, s u tT are the estimated separately for year-specific average forecast errors, each horizon and the is a linear with estimated standard error: T1 s- = T . [\' (X'X) _1 i] 1/2 (8) T where \ is variables, a vector of ones of length and s^ is standard error (8) is the a T, X is the matrix of dummy regression residual standard error. The weighted version of the residual standard 18 constructed from the error s^, nj t t • The residuals n j tt are deviations from the annual averages, and so are purged of average time-period-specific information which induces cross-sectional correlation Table In the in e-j tT . the bias results are presented. 3. The reported numbers are the forecast bias, estimated jointly for all forecast sources by stacking equation (7) to evaluated as is (8) hypothesis of no bias, and most current, and a (7) across sources. t-statistic, The ratio of against for each analyst composite, null a mean, the quarterly models. for forecast errors exhibit statistically significant Generally, negative bias. the Of three analyst consensus measures, median uniformly exhibits the smallest bias, indistinguishable from zero. bias in analysts' forecasts 11 is management. however, 12 in to Negative consistent with some conventional that analysts prefer optimistic predictions and recommendations, the usually Negative bias corresponds to overestimates of EPS. wisdom, median "buy" help maintain good relations with The evidence supporting this story is weak, two respects. appears to be unbiased. First, Second, the median analyst forecast and more importantly, analyst estimates are significantly negative, when the they are statistically indistinguishable from those of mechanical timeseries models. The motive of maintaining good relations with management cannot be ascribed to these models. the contention forecasts is at Thus, support for that analysts preferentially issue optimistic best weak. 19 An alternative explanation which also consistent with is these results is that analysts issue unbiased forecasts, seven-year period, 1975 through 1981, negative unanticipated EPS. to Unfortunately, the most obvious way distinguish between the hypothesis of deliberate optimistic years. - accuracy. section for evaluating relative forecast Accuracy is defined as absolute or squared forecast For the absolute error case, I 1 e . jtT 1=6. ljT tT )2 as the the model a similar model left-hand-side variable. In *ljT measure average accuracy for each firm measure average accuracy for each year deviations from the average accuracy and for year arise, t. is: +6 2tT +£.JtT 1 For the squared error case, (e-j Accuracy use an approach similar to the bias evaluation described the previous error. longer span of a This is not possible using the I/B/E/S detail data. Evaluating Forecasts I in in t. (9) is estimated, with equation (9) the j, The and the £ j t x are j Differences in accuracy across firms could for example, if there are persistent differences in the accuracy across years could arise larger, 6 2 t t this sample for firm amount of information available for different firms. in this one with primarily is bias and this alternative is to collect data for 4.3 but unanticipated events in if Differences there are more, or some years than in others. 20 Equation estimated using least squares on is (9) Average accuracy dummy variables for firms and years. computed as a set of a is linear combination of the estimated effects;13 1 £ 7 1 JT t= l (10) 2JT Equation (10) defines the average absolute error accuracy. Average squared error accuracy defined similarly using the is coefficients from the squared error version of (9). estimated standard error of the average accuracy l s equation (10) : - [W' (Z 'Z In in The (11). Z ) 1/2 ' 1 u>] ( 11 ) represents the matrix of dummy variables used to estimate equation (9) or its squared error analogue, U) is the vector of weights that transform the estimated parameters into the average defined (10), in and s error from the regression equation The estimates in ^ is the residual standard (9). equations (9) through (11) are computed jointly for all five forecast sources (mean, median and most current analyst; and two quarterly models), across sources. by stacking equations Pairwise differences in accuracy are compared across forecast sources using a t-statistic constructed from the average accuracies from (10) or its squared error analogue, and the standard Tables accuracy. error from (11). 4 through 6 summarize the results on forecast The average absolute errors and average squared 21 errors, computed as described in equation (10) for each forecast source, appear in Table 4. Table 5 contains t-statistics testing pairwise differences in accuracy among analysts. Table 6 contains t-statistics testing pairwise differences in accuracy between analysts and the quarterly models. Table 4 displays the expected pattern of increasing forecast accuracy as the earnings announcement date approaches, for all Both average absolute error and average forecast sources. squared error decline uniformly as the year progresses, analysts and for quarterly models. For example, for the average absolute error of the most current forecaster declines from $0,742 per share at a horizon of 240 days (almost prior to the announcement) to $0,292 per share at year a full a horizon of days. This pattern of convergence toward the announced EPS number is 5 consistent with forecasts incorporating some new information relevant to the prediction of EPS over the course of the year . From Table it 4 appears that the most current analyst worse than the other sources, quarterly models in is results are highly correlated, the differences Table 4 In in 5 important caveat to that the relative performance both across horizons and across accuracy which are suggested by appear in Tables Tables An The results of statistical definitions of accuracy. and 6, 5 a no and that analysts dominate the longer horizons. this qualitative statement is a tests for perusal of and 6. positive difference means that the 22 Table first of the pair is less accurate. of 5 contains the results pairwise comparisons among the three analyst consensus definitions. In terms of absolute error, which is reported in when the differences are significant they favor the mean Panel A, over the median and the most current forecaster over either the mean or the median. For example, at the 60-trading-day horizon, the t-statistic on the difference between the mean and median forecasts in average absolute accuracy is -2.14, which favors the and is significant at the mean, the difference between for the same horizon is is 4.97, .01 contrast, Panel in The t-statistic on the median and the most significant at the In level. .05 accuracy are presented, current forecasts which favors the most current, and level. B, where differences in squared error there are no measurable differences in accuracy among the three analyst consensus definitions. The signs of differences in this panel generally are the same as those in Panel A, so the squared error evidence does not contradict the absolute error results. However, the very small t-statistics lend no additional support to the conclusions, either . The results reported in Table 6 indicate that analyst forecasts generally dominate the time-series models at the longer horizons. For the 240, 180 and 1 20- rad i ng-day horizons, wherever differences are statistically significant, This evidence is favor analysts over the quarterly models. consistent with the explanation that analysts use information set than can be exploited by the results a a broader univariate model. 23 At the 60-t rading-day horizon, however, the quarterly time- series models dominate the mean and the median analyst forecast in comparisons where significant differences exist. all current forecast is never dominated to a The most statistically significant extent by the quarterly models, but generally is indistinguishable from them. In through summary, 6 the accuracy results reported in Tables generally support the conjectures that presumably incorporating analyst forecast, set, is model, at and least as accurate as is at a a a 4 current broader information forecast from a time-series least as accurate as aggregations which ignore the forecast date. Although the statistical significance of results varies across forecasting horizons and accuracy criteria, wherever differences in accuracy between forecast sources are statistically significant, the results conform with expectations. The results reported here probably understate the difference between the most current forecast and the mean and median definitions which appear is in most other published work. My sample selected to eliminate the publication lag, and so the mean and median forecasts in my sample are probably more accurate than, e.g., those in the I/B/E/S Summary Data. The comparisons between analysts and quarterly models may understate differences because of the sample selection process. Since the sample of firms is weighted toward stabler and longerlived firms by the data requirements of the time-series models, the selection process may exclude firms where analysts' 24 information advantage is largest: newer, less stable firms, or where time-series models that assume stationarity are less suitable. However, stability, this may be mitigated. (1986) if firm size is a proxy for longevity or Brown, Richardson and Schwager find that the superiority of ValueLine forecasts to a random walk model increases with firm size. Accuracy Within 4.4 a Subsample of Timely Forecasts The results reported timeliness no worse in in section 4.3 suggest an advantage to forecast selection. single current forecast is A and sometimes dominates, than, aggregations which include both recently-updated and out-of-date forecasts. this, the question arises whether, Given conditional on timeliness, there is an advantage to diversifying idiosyncratic error. this section, I address this question using a In subsample which includes only forecasts made after the firm's most recent announcement of quarterly EPS. 14 described in Table The selection of the subsample, follows. For each horizon t, set of available firm j, and year I , is as select the forecasts which were made after the most recent previous quarterly earnings announcement. in t, 7 That is, all forecasts this subsample have forecast dates indicating they have been revised since the last quarterly earnings release. This criterion reduces the number of forecasts available by about onethird at the 5-trading-day horizon, more at the other horizons. and by 70 to 80 percent or 25 The dramatic difference between the 5-trading-day and the other horizons in sample reduction, evident in Table largely due to the definition of forecast horizons. by construction, trading-day horizon date is, months after the third quarter announcement. also by construction, dates, quarterly announcement 7, is The 5- approximately three All other horizon tend to be closer to the previous . Both the timeliness and the number of forecasts included in this subsample depend, among other things, on the number of days between the quarterly EPS announcement date and the horizon date. This fact is evident in Table the distribution of of where summary information about forecast ages in this subsample is reported. 240 trading days, For horizons between 60 and the age of 8, differences between the most current forecast and the mean or the median forecast ages are much less pronounced than those reported in Table 2 for the full Table 7 sample. illustrates that up to 27% of the firm-years in the sample are eliminated entirely by this timeliness criterion. That is, for some firms in some years, none of the analysts' forecasts available on the fixed horizon date had been updated since the last quarterly EPS announcement. the 5-trading-day horizon, eliminated. A This is true even at where one percent of firm-years are related feature of the subsample is an increase in the number of firm-years with only forecast available. These observations, where by definition the mean, median and most current forecast are the same, reduce the power of statistical 26 tests to distinguish between the three consensus definitions. However, in the full observations. In sample they are this subsample, a trivial proportion of they are 4 percent of observations at the 5-trading-day horizon, but of 2 to 30 percent observations at other horizons. Tests of pairwise differences in accuracy among the three consensus definitions this subsample are reported in Table in the most current forecast In contrast to the results in Table no longer dominates when all forecasts are reasonably current. 5, 9. There are no statistically significant differences in accuracy in the longer horizons, in part due to the sample selection raised in the previous paragraph. issues the 5-trading-day horizon, At where sufficient forecasts are available to distinguish the different consensus measures, the most current forecast significantly worse than either the mean or the median. is That is, conditional on timeliness and on the availability of sufficient numbers of forecasts, there are gains in accuracy from aggregating to reduce idiosyncratic error. 4.5 Evaluating Forecasts - The criteria developed Market Association in relative accuracy, are common evaluation. They do not, forecasts are used. the previous sections, in the however, bias and literature on forecast address the context in which Both researchers' and investors' use of forecast data in contexts related to securities markets suggests 27 that association with stock returns may provide relevant a empirical comparison. If forecast errors reflect information relevant to the firm's prospects arriving after the forecast date, to two important qualifications discussed below, will be this forecast errors information relevant The first qualification is not precisely the same as the current-year earnings. to There are errors both variables with respect to the measured association Non-recurring events, whether they are treated as between them. extraordinary items or not. may affect earnings in year, particular events that influence longer-term prospects, Conversely, such as changes a inconsequential to the long-term value of the but may be firm. of in implied association is that the information relevant to valuing the firm's common stock in subject positively correlated with new information impounded stock returns over the forecast horizon. to then, investment opportunities, in may affect the value the firm without altering current earnings. The second qualification is that excess returns are constructed to exclude one source of unanticipated information. The excess return is purged of its systematic relation with market returns, which includes both anticipated and unanticipated market returns. It is desirable to purge the stock returns of the anticipated component of i n f or ma t i ona 1 1 y however, since inefficient forecasts will be correlated with anticipated information. return, the market return, Eliminating the unanticipated market may reduce the measurable association between 28 excess returns and forecast errors. the other hand, On it is important to note that while the power of tests for positive association the reduction reduced, is across forecast sources, the same excess in power does not vary since they are all evaluated relative to returns. other words, In the relative degree of association across sources will be unaffected. Both qualifications noted above will have the effect of reducing the measurable association between forecast errors and excess returns. Nevertheless, previous studies facing the same inherent difficulties have found statistically significant positive associations between unexpected earnings and excess stock returns (197 9), and Brown (Ball and Fried and Givoly Beaver, (1968), (1982), Clarke and Wright for example). The regression model used to estimate the association between cumulated excess returns, forecast errors. e In i (12), at f3i . ,. T U-jtT horizon returns. . lJtT x e M = a is t x , . represented by Uj . llJT + a„ . +8.IT U_ Jtl . 2ltT and + v . ( . ljtl 12) the portion of the forecast error from source which is systematically related to excess The slope coefficient in , is: • 8 T excess returns and forecast errors, effects, tT is the covariance between adjusted for firm and year units of the variance of excess returns. Using excess returns as the independent variable and forecast errors as dependent has the desirable feature that 8j T and t-statistic have the same scale for all sources of its associated i. If the roles these two variables were reversed in the regression equation, 29 the estimated regression slope coefficient would depend explicitly on the forecast error variance from source The constants oti;j and y ea r -spec i f i c and 0t2itT measure, T The play an important role in equation capture the t respectively, firm- average forecast errors, conditional on the systematic relation with excess returns. effects, i. me-per i od -spec i f i c cx 2 jtT- (12), the year since they information in forecast errors which is not captured by excess returns. I 5 Among other things, they include the average effect of omitting the unanticipated component of the market return. the model, they are omitted variable. the residuals, impounded This If in the the ot 2 i t T are n °t included in regression residuals as an induces cross-sectional correlation in which if ignored leads to incorrect statistical inferences, as was discussed above for the bias computation. 16 Equation (12) is estimated by stacking the regressions for the five forecast sources, and estimating them jointly. forecast sources are the mean, The median and most current analyst Estimations are performed forecast and the two quarterly models. jointly for the five forecast sources, and separately for each forecast horizon. Since the matrix of independent variables, which consists of cumulated excess returns over the forecast horizon and dummy variables indicating firms and years, forecast sources, is the same for each of the there is no efficiency gain over equation-by- equation least squares (see Zellner (1962)). stacking the equations is for The advantage of joint estimation of the firm and 30 year effects, so that observations from each of the five forecast sources are adjusted for the same firm and year effects. Tables 10 through 12 contain the regression results from Table 10, I slope coefficients and their associated t estimation of model (12). In report the estimated -s ta t i s t i c s , testing the statistical significance of the relation between forecast errors and excess Table returns over the forecasting horizon. 11 contains t-statistics which test for differences in the slope Table 12 contains coefficients across forecast sources. regression summary statistics, including adjusted , f - and sample sizes. and numbers of parameters, statistics, R2 According to results reported in Table 12, equation (12) explains between 9% and 16 % of the variation in forecast errors, with slight variations across horizons. appears at the 5-trading-day horizon, explanatory power are not large. The largest adjusted R2 though differences in The model has statistically significant explanatory power, according to the regression F - statistics, which reject the null of no explanatory power at the .001 level. The incremental F-statistics in Table 12 confirm that the year-specific effects are important statistic on the year -s pec H That is, the estimation to of the model. : a i = 2ilT f i c a in equation (12). ? The F- effects tests the null hypothesis: 2i2T • = a„ m 2iTx . =0 F-statistic tests the null hypothesis that year -specific intercepts adds no explanatory power This hypothesis is rejected at the .05 level at 31 all horizons, longer than and at the level or better at the horizons The importance of year effects in the model days. 5 .001 increases with the length of the horizon. This is consistent with the information-based explanation for their inclusion in the model, namely that forecast errors impound time-period-specific unanticipated information. speaking, Over longer horizons, loosely "quantity" of unanticipated information the greater. is The strength of this result also confirms the assertions made earlier that period is not cross-section of forecast errors for a a set of a single time independent observations. The F-statistics on firm-specific effects reported 12 in Table also reject the null hypothesis, which is: H : "lilt 1 a, i2T . . = There are measurable firm-specific differences forecast error at all horizons, in average even after the adjustment for firm-specific information impounded in excess returns. The strength of this result varies little across forecast horizons and across transformations of the dependent variable. The importance of the slope coefficients in model indicated by the F-statisic reported in Table 12. (12), varies across forecast horizons and across transformations of the dependent variable. 10, The individual however, Table 10 show are of greater relevance. a first, Generally, the results in pattern of positive association between forecast errors and excess returns. if, slope coefficients reported in Table A positive association is expected there is some overlap between information relevant to 32 firm value and information relevant to current-year earnings, second, and some of this overlapping information is unanticipated both by investors and by the predictor of EPS. significance of the positive association The statistical varies somewhat across forecast horizons, across forecast sources. and more importantly The strongest results are for the 120- Among the analyst consensus forecasts, day horizon. the strongest results are generally for the most current forecaster, which is consistent with the most current forecaster acting as reasonable composite, expectation. or The strongest results, the only ones which are consistently positive and a and statistically significant, however, are for the quarterly autoregressive model, equation (1). This pattern of relative performance does not vary substantially across horizons or across transformations of the dependent variable. This result is anomalous, especially light of the quarterly model's relative inaccuracy. that prior knowledge of the forecast error from autoregressive model is a a It in indicates quarterly better predictor of excess returns than prior knowledge of the forecast error from analysts' forecasts. 18 The greater association of excess returns with forecast errors from a time-series model than with those from analysts not consistent with use quarterly data the in results of Fried and Givoly (1982). the time series models of annual while Fried and Givoly (1982) use annual data. is I earnings, Since models using quarterly data produce more accurate forecasts of annual earnings than models using only annual data (see Hopwood, McKeown 33 and Newbold presumably my tests are more demanding of (1982)), analysts than those used by Fried and Givoly. However, the result remains anomalous since analysts are more accurate and can employ more information than quarterly time series models. This anomaly is further investigated in Table 11, for the statistical coefficients. by testing significance of differences in the slope further advantage of stacking equations across A forecast sources to estimate them is that statistical testing is simplified, since a set slope coefficients Bj T of linear constraints on the estimated generates direct tests of differences For example, slope across forecast sources. of is the vector difference in 8 -r is the vector one for each forecast source, five slope coefficients, Q22' if (1,-1,0.0,0), then c 1 2 ' in and if estimates the £T slopes between the first and second sources, with estimated standard error: s In (13), sv is C , „ e = s„ . [c 1 - 1 1/2 (X'X)/c] ( 13) 6 the residual estimation of equation (12). standard error from the joint X ( ' X ~ ) 1 g the is lower-right submatrix of five rows and five columns from the (X'X)~1 matrix of equation (12). This submatrix determines the variance- covariance relations among the five slope coefficients. Linear constraints of the form of differences i.e. in the slope coefficients c j 2 are used to evaluate that appear in Table 10, differences across forecast sources in between excess returns and forecast errors. the association Table 11 contains 34 the results of these statistical Results are shown for tests. tests of pairwise differences between the quarterly au oregres s i ve model and all other forecast sources, and for differences between the most current analyst and the mean and median analyst forecasts. anomalous result, The statistical that errors from tests confirm the mechanical quarterly model a often are significantly more closely related to excess returns than errors from analysts. In addition, the tests indicate that while the most current forecast typically shows the strongest result among analyst consensus forecasts, statistically significant, 5^ the difference not is general. in §y!D!D3iy._§Qd_Conclusi_ons Analysts' predictions of EPS are "market expectations" information. different composite forecasts, span approximately the most current a year. on I a potential source of have examined properties of arbitrarily-chosen dates which Results reported here indicate that forecast available from an analyst dominates the mean or median of the available forecasts. Five alternate sources of earnings expectations are examined: the mean, analysts' forecasts; median, an and most current of available au tor egress i ve model in fourth differences of the univariate series of quarterly EPS, and fourth-differenced random walk using quarterly EPS. a The two 35 quarterly time-series models are included primarily as benchmarks . The most current forecast is at least as accurate as either the mean or median forecast, and generally dominates them in absolute error terms, when all available forecasts are This result indicates that the date of the forecast considered. is relevant for determining its accuracy, and dominates the diversification obtained by aggregating forecasts from different sources as "first cut" criterion. a Since most published aggregations of forecasts and much previous research treat all forecasts for a given firm as if they are equally current, they ignore this relevant piece of information. When forecasts are censored in a way that eliminates the most out-of-date forecasts from the sample, it improve accuracy by aggregating forecasts. When only forecasts from the fourth fiscal quarter are included, forecast at a announcement horizon of is 5 is possible to the mean or median trading days before the annual EPS more accurate than the single most current forecast. In this sample the forecast error from the most current forecast is more closely associated with excess returns over the forecast horizon than the error from the mean or the median forecast, but the difference in association is not, in general, statistically significant. Analysts generally are significantly more accurate than time-series models. Errors from the quarterly autoregressive 36 model, however, appear to be more closely related with excess returns over the forecasting horizon than those of analysts. Because of this anomalous result, provide a it is unclear that analysts better model of the "market expectation" than mechanical models. It should be noted, though, that the sample of firms was reduced sharply by the data requirements of the time-series models. This sample, with its selection bias toward longer-lived firms with continuous data available, does not clearly isolate cases where analysts might be expected to have the most advantage over mechanical models, cases. and perhaps eliminated many of these These firms, where there is a substantial amount of non- earnings information expected to have an impact on earnings, may be a fruitful area for future investigation. 37 ACKNOWLEDGEMENT This paper is based on work from my doctoral dissertation at the I am grateful to the members of my Univesity of Chicago. committee--John Abowd, Craig Ansley, Nicholas Dopuch, Richard Leftwich, Victor Zarnowitz, Mark Zmijewski, and especially to Robert Holt hausen --for their helpful comments. Others to whom I an indebted for their comments on previous drafts are Linda DeAngelo. Paul Healy. Rick Ruback, and an anonymous reviewer. I All remaining errors and omissions are my responsibility. acknowledge the generous support of Deloitte, Haskins and Sells Foundation . 38 FOOTNOTES ^ee Bates and Granger (1969) Figlewski and Urich (1982). Granger and Newbold (1977) and 1 use words like "aggregate", "composite" and "consensus" in the general sense, to include weighting schemes which put all weight on a single forecast, and none on others. 2 3 Dimson and Marsh (1984) find similar results for forecasts of Their data are from a designed experiment in stock returns. which forecasts were collected at regular intervals, so they were assured a sample of nearly simultaneous forecasts. In analysts' EPS forecast data such as those used here, the availability of recent forecasts depends, in part, on analysts' private decisions about when to update. This point is discussed further in section 4.4. "Earnings" and "earnings per share" (or "EPS") are used interchangeably in this paper. The data are forecasts of EPS. 4 ^Since firms' annual earnings announcement dates are remarkably consistent year after year, choosing fixed lengths of time prior to the announcement date is a fairly accurate means of finding dates that differ by one quarter. For the 6218 horizons in this paper, 13 horizon dates did not fall between the quarterly announcements as intended. The results are not affected by deletion of these observations. ^Results reported in this paper are for unsealed forecast errors defined in equation (3). Other forecast error metrics, or scales, may be appropriate, for example to control for he ter oscedas t i c i t y However, the qualitative conclusions of the paper, other than the bias results, are not affected by the choice of scale. The scales I have investigated are: (1) standardized forecast errors, where the denominator is (a) the average, over the previous five years, of absolute changes in EPS, or (b) the standard deviation of EPS changes; and (2) percent forecast errors, where the denominator is (a) the absolute value of the prior year's EPS, or (b) where the sample is censored to exclude negative denominators, or (c) to exclude denominators less than $0.20. These results are available upon request from the author. as . 7 The numbers of observations deleted are: 1, 2, 2. 5, the 5-. 60-, 120-. 180-. and 24 - t rad i ng-day horizons, respectively 8M of y and 5, at . results do not differ if the value-weighted market portfolio securities is used as a proxy for the market. ^The subscript i. which indexes the source of the forecast, is 39 suppressed in the following discussion for readability. 10 The estimation was also done with firm-specific effects in the model. The bias results do not differ qualitatively from those reported here. 1:1 Fried and Givoly (1982) report negative statistically significant bias in analysts' April forecasts for December yearends for the period 1969 through 1979, but none in timeseries forecasts. I replicate the bias test for percent forecast errors (see footnote 6), which is approximately their definition. find no bias in 120-day through 240-day analyst forecasts, and I significant positive bias in the time-series model forecasts. Thus, I conclude that their bias result is not replicated in this later (1975-1981) sample. 12 For example, see Dirks and Gross (1974), especially pp. 252257. Also see "Bank Analysts Try to Balance their Ratings", WSJ, May 29, 1984, p. 33; and "Picking a Loser", WSJ, September 28, 1 1983 p , . 13 The estimated effects are not the same as the estimated coefficients, because model (9) has two sets of effects, firms and years. A simple example will illustrate this. If there were two years and three firms in the sample, model (9) could be estimated with no intercept, using two year dummy variables (DY1 and DY2) and two firm dummy variables (DF1 and DF2): = JtT d 11T DF1 d 12T DF2 d 2lT DYl d 22T DY2 £ JtT' year 1 effect" is the average |e-j tT This effect for t = l not estimated by d 2 i T Rather, d 2 it is the average e j ^t for year 1 for the omitted (third) firm, year 1 effect" is The estimated in this formulation by: The | is . | = 21T The firm 6 The firm & 1 21T effect" + (1/3 13T " (1/2) is d 12T estimated by: is 1/2 y*'*> + * effect" (1/3) + lit =d lit +(l/2)d J/ ^' u 2lT 11T 3 d I ( ) d u 22t estimated by: 21T + ( 1/2 ) d 22T Since any non-redundant spanning set of dummy variables can be used, the particular linear combinations of coefficients to estimate the firm and year effects depend on the model used. ^This analysis was suggested to me by the referee. 15 Dropping the O-hjx, the firm-specific effects, does not alter the estimates of the slope coefficients 6j T or their statistical Omitting the a 2 ^ t T significance by a substantial amount. their statistical and however, alters both the estimates , significance. 40 lf>An alternate way to model the problem is to include the year or firm effects as "random effects", contributing off-diagonal elements to the covariance matrix of the vjj tT Mundlak (1978) shows that the estimate of the slope coefficient 6j T obtained from a model like (12), is identical to the GLS estimate which would be obtained if the firm- and year-specific effects, aiijx and 0C2itT- were modeled as random effects and included in the covariance matrix. . 17 The statistical significance of year -spec i f i c effects as a determinant of forecast errors, although not reported in the previous tables, is similar in the estimates of bias and accuracy . 8An alternate method of measuring the association between forecast errors and excess returns, similar to that of Ball and Brown (1968), is to construct portfolios based on foreknowledge of the sign of EPS forecast error. That is, a long position is taken in each of the securities for which the forecast error is positive, and a short position is taken in those with negative This procedure, applied to these data, produces results errors. qualitatively identical to those reported here. 1 41 REFERENCES Ball, and R. Brown P. An Empirical (1968). Accounting Income Numbers. 159-178 6 : Evaluation of Journal of Accounting Research . Barefield, R. and E. Comiskey (197 5) Forecasts of Earnings Per Share 241-252 Research 3 The Accuracy of Analysts' Journal of Business : Bates, and J. C Forecasts Granger (1969). The Combination of Operations Research Quarterly 20: 451-468 W.J. . Beaver, W.H., R. Clarke and W. Wright (1979). The Association Between Unsystematic Security Returns and the Magnitude of Earnings Forecast Errors. Journal of Accounting Research 17 316-340 : Brown, L., P. Griffin, R. Hagerman, and M. Zmijewski (1986). Security Analyst Superiority Relative to Univariate TimeSeries Models in Forecasting Quarterly Earnings. working paper . L., G. Richardson, and S. Schwager (1986). Financial Analyst Forecast Superiority: Is There an Information Interpretation?. working paper. Brown, L. and M. Rozeff (1978). The Superiority of Analysts' Forecasts as Measures of Expectations: Evidence from 1-6. Journal of Finance 33: Earnings. Brown, P., G. Foster and E. Noreen (1984). Security Analyst Multi-Year Earnings Forecasts and the Capital Market. American Accounting Association Studies in Accounting Research #21. Brown, Collins, W.A. and W.S. Hopwood (1980). A Multivariate Analysis of Annual Earnings Forecasts Generated from Quarterly Forecasts of Financial Analysts and Univariate Time-Series 390-406. Models. Journal of Accounting Research 18: An Crichfield, T., T. Dyckman. and J. Lakonishok (1978). Accounting Evaluation of Security Analysts' Forecasts. 651-668 Review 53 : Darl in . D . ( 1983 September 28 . ) . Picking p. 1 a Loser. The Wall Street Journal . An Analysis of Brokers' and Dimson, E., and P. Marsh (1984). Analysts' Unpublished Forecasts of UK Stock Returns. 1257-1292. Journal of Finance 39: 42 R. and L. Gross (1974). The Great Wall Street Scandal. McGraw-Hill Book Company. Dirks. E., M. Gruber, and M. Gultekin (1981). Pr of es s i onna Expectations: Accuracy and Diagnosis of Errors. working paper, New York University. Elton, Figlewski, S. and T. Urich (1982). Optimal Aggregation of Money Supply Forecasts: Accuracy, Profitability, and Market Efficiency. working paper, New York University. Time Series G. (1977). Quarterly Earnings Data: Properties and Predictive Ability Results. Accounting 1 -21 Review 52 Foster, : Fried. D. and D. Givoly (1982). Financial Analysts' Forecasts of Earnings: A Better Surrogate for Market Expectations. 85-107. Journal of Accounting and Economics 4: Gibson, R. and W.L. Their Ratings. Wall (1984). Bank Analysts Try to Balance May 29. The Wall Street Journal. p. 33. Givoly, D. The Information Content of and J. Lakonishok (1979). Financial Analysts' Forecasts of Earnings. Journal of 165-185. Accounting and Economics 1: Granger, C.W.J. and P. Newbold (1977). Time Series. Academic Press. , Forecasting Economic Hopwood W.S., J.C. McKeown, and P. Newbold (1982). The Additional Information Content of Quarterly Earnings Journal of Reports: Intertemporal Disaggregation. 343-349. Accounting Research 20: , Malkiel, of B. and J. Cragg (1982). Expectations and the Structure Share Prices. University of Chicago Press. Mundlak, Y. (1978). Section Data. Watts, R., and Earnings. On the Pooling of Time Series and Cross 69-85. Econometrica 46: The Time Series of Annual Leftwich (1977). 253-271. Journal of Accounting Research 15: R. Zellner, A. (1962). An Efficient Method of Estimating Seemingly Unrelated Regressions and Tests for Aggregation Bias. 348Journal of the American Statistical Association 57: 368 . Table 1 Sample Selection Criteria and Their Effects on the Sample Panel A: Cr Elimination of Firms and Firm-Years Table 2 Selected Characteristics of the Distribution of Forecast Ages for the Mean, Median and Most Current Analyst Forecasts, Measured Across Firms and Years [forecast ages are measured in trading days] Table Forecast Bias, 3 for Five Forecast Sources, [bias numbers are denominated in Forecast Horizon, Source q q . . a r . . r -0.15 (-3.82) -0.11 (-3.15) (-5.18) (-4.11 -0.11 (-4.24) (-3.25) ) -0.12 (-4.70) ( (-1.52) (-2.25) -0.10 (-2.93) (-3.27) -0 . . -0 . -0 . 03 08 . 05 (-1.49) -0.12 08 (-1.91) Notes -0 09 (-0.72) current Trading Days 120 (-2.09) median in per share] 180 (-2.17) mean $ 240 -0 w Five Forecast Horizons at ( -3 .57 -0 . 05 -0 -0 -0 . . . 60 -0 14 -0 -0 -4 -0 06 . . . . . 5 08 ) 06 09 96 -0 ) 02 ( -0 -2 . . 04 34 05 02 .00) . (-1.19) 09 . (-2.74) ( 1 -0 ) . 02 (-1.42) : The computation of forecast bias and its associated t-statistic (in parentheses) are described in equations (6) through (8) in the text. The forecast sources are: q.a.r. - a quarterly auto regressive model in fourth differences; equation (1) in the text, q.r.w. - a random walk model with drift in fourth differences; equation (2) in the text, mean - the mean of the available analysts' forecasts, median - the median of the available analysts' forecasts, current - the most recent forecast from an analyst. The forecast horizons are measured in trading days prior to the annual earnings announcement. The degrees of freedom for all reported t-statistics are over 1,000, so they are approximately normal. For a two-sided test, the .05 and .01 critical points of the N(0.1) distribution are 1.96 and 2.58. respectively . Table 4 Average Absolute or Squared Forecast Error Forecast Accuracy: for Five Forecast Sources, and Five Forecast Horizons [forecast errors are denominated in $ per share] Table 5 Pairwise Differences in Forecast Accuracy Among the Mean, Median and Most Current Analyst Forecasts for Five Forecast Horizons Panel A: t-Statistics on Differences Average Absolute Error in Forecast Horizon, 240 mean - median mean - current median - current 1.06 0.11 1.18 2 Trading Days 120 98 07 05 1.11 2 82 93 2 . 4 . . 1 in 180 . . 1 . 2 . 60 . 14 83 97 5 -1 Table 6 Pairwise Differences in Forecast Accuracy Between Analysts and Quarterly Time-Series Models, for Five Forecast Horizons Table 7 Selection of the Subsample, for Each Forecast Horizon, of Forecasts Made Between the Last Announcement of Quarterly Earnings and the Horizon Date Forecast_Ho£2zon_L _in_Trading_Day_s Full Sample # # # # : forecasts firms f i rm-year s firm-years with forecast 1 Subsample 240 180 120 16134 19294 20969 22078 184 184 184 184 184 1198 1235 1254 1259 1260 68 32 31 22 25 60 5 22864 : # # forecasts 3017 5601 4425 3859 15352 firms 181 183 # firm-years firm-years witli forecast 1 875 184 104 1039 183 961 1246 209 246 259 53 # Notes 250 1 184 : The full sample, whose selection is described in Table 1, includes, for each firm and year, all available forecasts that have not been revised or withdrawn prior to the horizon date. The subsample includes, for each firm and year, only those forecasts which have been revised or initiated between the firm's last announcement of quarterly EPS and the horizon date. Table 8 Selected Characteristics of the Distribution of Forecast Ages, Measured Across Firms and Years, for the Subsample of Forecasts Made Between the Last Announcement of Quarterly Earnings and the Horizon Date Table 9 Pairwise Differences in Forecast Accuracy Among the Mean, Median and Most Current Analyst Forecasts, in the Subsample of Forecasts Made Between the Last Announcement of Quarterly Earnings and the Horizon Date, for Five Forecast Horizons Panel A: t-Statistics on Differences in Average Absolute Error Forecast Horizon, mean - median mean - current median - current Panel B: . . 0 . 240 180 034 240 275 0.210 1 . 258 1 . . . 048 . 60 059 169 228 Forecast Horizon, Notes Trading Days . 1 1 . . 067 106 039 5 . 388 -3 508 -3 896 . . t-Statistics on Differences in Average Squared Error 240 mean mean median in 120 med i an current current 180 078 -0.318 0.489 -0 008 -0.411 0.310 -0 . in Trading Days 120 . . . -0 . 101 704 603 60 -0 099 -0 370 -0 270 . . . 5 0.168 2 . 146 2.314 : The subsample includes, for each firm and year, only those forecasts which have been revised or initiated between the firm's last announcement of quarterly EPS and the horizon date. The computation of average absolute error is described in equations The computation of average squared error is (9) and (10) in the text. analogous to the computation of average absolute error. The forecast sources are: q.a.r. - a quarterly au t or egres s i ve model in fourth differences; equation (1) in the text, q.r.w. - a random walk model with drift in fourth differences; equation (2) in the text, mean - the mean of the available analysts' forecasts, median - the median of the available analysts' forecasts, current - the most recent forecast from an analyst. The forecast horizons are measured earnings announcement. in trading days prior to the annual Table 10 Slope Coefficients from the Regression of EPS Forecast Error on Excess Return, for Five Forecast Horizons: e . _tx =ot„.. 1 1 jt 1 j + a . 2 a ,_ tx +8.ix U . j tx ijtx (12) t i Table 11 of Pairwise Differences in Slope Coefficients from the Regression EPS Forecast Error on Excess Return, for Five Forecast Horizons e . 1 Panel . . JtT a„ = . 1 1 . JT 6 '2i tT U . IT 1 (12) JtT t-Statistics on Differences between Quarterly Autoregressive Model [eqn. (1)] and Other Forecast Sources A: Quarter Horizon: 1 2 3 240 180 120 q.a.r. - q.r.w. q.a.r. - mean q.a.r. - median q.a.r. - current 2.69 3.28 3.55 2.59 : Panel .. J tT 3 4 3 2 . . . . 08 08 82 85 1 . 3 . 2 . 68 09 74 2.16 4 60 1 . 1 . 1 . . 47 68 37 56 t-Statistics on Differences between the Most Current the Mean or Median Analyst Forecasts B: and Horizon mean median Notes current current 240 180 0.69 1.23 0 . 96 . 120 . 97 . 94 59 60 12 82 76 97 : sources are: a quarterly au oregres s i ve model in fourth differences; equation (1) in the text, q.r.w. - a random walk model with drift in fourth differences; equation (2) in the text, mean - the mean of the available analysts' forecasts, median - the median of the available analysts' forecasts, current - the most recent forecast from an analyst. The forecast q.a.r. The forecast horizons are measured in trading days prior to the annual earnings announcement. In equation (12), ejj tT is the forecast error, in $ per share, from source i for firm j in year t at horizon t, and Uj^ T is cumulated Equation (12) is excess returns for firm j in year t over horizon T. estimated jointly for five forecast sources and separately for each horizon. The aijj T are f i rm- e f f ec t s and the 0t2itT are year-effects. , slope B T is estimated for each forecast source i and horizon T. The t-statistic on each slope coefficient is reported in parentheses. For a The t-statistics have degrees of freedom greater than 1,000. one-sided test, the .05 and .01 critical points from the N(0,1) distribution are 1.65 and 2.33, respectively. A Table 12 of Regression Summary Statistics for the Regression for Five Forecast Horizons EPS Forecast Error on Excess Return, 1 JtT 1 i a jx 2 1 + tx 6 it U j tT + 1 Forecast Horizon, 240 adjusted R2 full model F(k-1 ,N-k) year-effect N-k . 5 ) 54 firm-effect F(k2,N-k) 3 excess returns F(k3,N-k) 6 d.f # . for F - s ta t F i ( kl s t i , 116 . . . . 02 4 13 36 34 3 89 7 095 . . . . in . 27 4 79 25 08 3 33 14 107 . . . . 79 17 (12) JtT Trading Days 120 180 . v 60 . 5 114 . 156 09 4 . 19.25 2 . 82 4 57 2.18 5 87 4 37 3 . . . . 60 94 65 c s sample size (N) (k) of parameters # of years (kl+1) # of firms (k2+l # of slopes (k3) 5986 6171 6267 6293 3779 199 199 199 199 195 7 7 7 7 7 184 184 184 184 184 5 5 5 5 3 Notes In equation (12), e^, tT is the forecast error, in $ per share, from source i for firm j in year t at horizon T, and U j £ T is cumulated Equation (12) is excess returns for firm j in year t over horizon T. estimated jointly for five forecast sources and separately for each horizon. The «jjj t estimate f rm- spec i f i c effects, and the a2itT estimate year specific effects model F-statistic tests the null hypothesis that the The year, firm, and regression model (12) has explanatory power. excess return F-statistics test the incremental explanatory power of Selected critical points including groups of parameters in the model. for the F distribution are: The full Dati telMLNT Lib-26-67 MIT LIBRARIES 3 TOAD DOS 131 171