LIBRARY OF THE MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY MAR 7 ^^Kjjga»^ilMKiQ2ijj»228UiSiU 1973 THE FUNDAMENTAL CONTINUITY THEORY OF OPTIMIZATION ON A COMPACT SPACE I By Murat R. Sertel November 1972 629-72 Abstract Optimizers on a compact feasible region are abstractly specified and, as set-valued mappings, are studied for sufficient conditions yielding them (as well as certain associated maps and certain restrictions of all these) continuous, using function space methods. In particular, the study concerns the continuity of the set of optimal solutions as a function of the three arguments: (i) objective function used, (ii) an incentive (or "penalty/reward") function imposed, and (iii) an abstract "parameter". An interpretation of the mathematical apparatus is suggested and a brief gametheoretic illustration given. : Thanks are due Miss Janet Allen for kindly (and meticulously) typing what follows. RECEIVED JAN 18 1973 M. I. T. LIBRARIES Notation Let S and T be topological spaces. : tinuous mappings of W c T , the set { f T^ e I f (B) C will denote the power set of empty closed subsets of {A e C(S) I AC Given B . W} will be denoted by (B , W) . C S and (P (S) t(S) will denote the set of non- and S Given B S. S c: S , ^B) will denote the set Throughout, R will be a non-empty set equipped B}. ^ with a total order The set of all con- into T will be denoted by T S and a (Hausdorff) topology which is at least as fine as the order topology. Aim : Given non-empty topological spaces X = X is compact with X ^ X„ and Y, of which X (compact and) Hausdorff, in this paper we seek sufficient conditions for the continuity of (a) the optimizers R^""^ X ex': Y^ x^ ^ X ^(X^) defined by the specification a' (u,g,x ^ ) = {x 1112 e u(x ,x ,g(x ,x X I 12 )) >: Sup u(- ,x ,g(- ,x ))} 2 2 ^1 (ueR^""^, geY^, x^eX2) [a specification which is quickly seen to yield a' as being into C(X )], or (b) of its "associate" a: R^""^ X determined by a(u, g) (x "'(u,g) = ) Y^ - (P(Xj = oi'(u, g, ^ x ), or (c) of the restrictions «'|{(u,g)}xX^=-^(^> ^'-' G37018 ^° ^("'g)> ^^' -2- 2 ' X " "u Motivation : ^ ~" "|{u}xY^- ^ ^^1^ of to {u} ex Y^. Our motivation derives from a desire to understand in above) is continuous, what sense optimization on a compact space (X a X question we consider to be perhaps the fundamental topological question of the theory of constrained optimization. Interpretation The functions u : or objective functions R e XxY may be called utility functions perhaps the former being preferred so as to , These are understood to be emphasize their merely ordinal nature. representations of complete (i.e., "total" or "decisive") transitive relations on X x y. Concerning the existence of such continuous rep- resentations we refer the reader to [Debreu, 1954] and [Sertel, 1971b]. For the functions g e Y we prefer the term Incentive function [Sertel, 1971a] to the more restrictive terms "payoff function", "penalty/ reward function", etc. (although we use the term "payoff function" in a game-theoretic illustration below). For R we refer back to our Notation of the familiar feasible region . . As to X e Y, so that externally instituted rules g optimal behavior, i.e., a'(u, g, x it plays the role The role of Y is that the utility functions u are in general sensitive, not only to x y , ). X e Y e X, but also to may serve to influence may be considered as an abstract "parameter space" in which a point is exogenously determined, subject to which optimization is to be carried out. A game-theoretic context may serve to illustrate. For simplicity, 3- consider a non-cooperative two-person game in which X^ and X^ are the strategy spaces of players 1 and 2, respectively. Then g specifies the "payoff" to player 1, for whom u serves as generic utility function, and a^ determines the player (1) cc-mpletely: for mathematical purposes, we are interested essentially in cx^Cg); how this x^ p ^ (x^ ) , and would study ("reaction function") varies as g is varied, given the "tastes" or "preferences" as represented by u. Here we also investigate how, from the viewpoint of continuity, " the whole map a, as well as its associate a' and the restrictions listed under Method/Procedure above, behaves. The nature of the investigation makes it natural to : proceed in the reverse order <(c) tinuity of the maps listed above. topology on (c) (b) , , in studying the con- (a)> We always take the unner semi-finite C(X^) and equip the function sp pcp.. with their respective compact-on e n topolo giP.-. and a^ (Theorem I). . R^"""^, Y^ and C(X First we study a' ^ ) (u,g) Then we turn to a'^ in the Corollary to Theorem I. Finally, we study a and a Topological Refresher : ' in Theorem II, taking Y locally compact. Let S and T be topological spaces. The compact -0£en topology on the function space T^ is the one generated by {(B, W) B I '^^^ { <W> 1 c S is compact and W c W c T is open} as sub-base. is said to be upper S ^ C(T) C(T) is the one generated by A polnt-to-set map ex: S ^ semi-continnnn.^ iff it is continuous when given the upper semi-finite topology. ex: T is open} as sub-base. "PPer semi-finite topolopy on ^ C T. C (T) is It is easily seen that is upper semi-continuous iff is closed for every closed D C (T) the set {seS| [Michael, 1951]. a(s) H D ?^ 0} -4- Proposition 1 Let X, Y and Z be topological spaces, of which X is : /yxY") locally compact, and let u = g co Then w is continuous. u Giving Y Proof: X and Z topologies, let (B, W) such that 00 (g) Z Define a map w . X e Y X X ^ Z X by and x e CZ X be a subbaslc open set, and take any g Denote G C and H = u"l (W) = a)-l((B, W)) G and, by continuity of u, H b e B, (b, (b, g(b)); furthermore, using continuity of g, we may assume g(A, e X x Y is open. H and there exists an open box nbd A^ x V, and, since X is locally compact, we may actually assume that relatively compact (i.e., its closure and A^ X V, C H. Now {A, b e | affording a finite subcover {A, G CI Y is a 1=1, | 1 ..., m}. to e A H of ) C Is C V, (compact) B, Defining A X Thus, . 1 basic open set with g is open and proving that C is compact) with g(A^) B} is an open cover of 1=1 we see that A C Y A, Y e Hence, for every g e g(b)) X. their respective compact-open (B, W). e Y : and g (x) = u(x, g(x)) for every g writing (g) e C is continuous. G , showing that V, ; -5- Lema_l: S Y: ^ compact. Proof; S Let S and T be compact spaces, of which S is Hauadorff. cm be a map whose graph Let D C T be closed. P is S\ { (s t) , e S x t| t e Let y(s)} Is Then D Is compact, since T is so. is compact, S x D is also compact. e = Then y is upper semi- continuous. that its projection P into (s T Y(s) closed. n S Thus is compact. , F O (S x d) Since is compact, so But P is precisely the set D ^ 0}; and, being compact in the Hausdorff space S, This proves that y is upper semi-continuous. # Proposition 2 Let X = X : Hausdorff; and, for every v aCv)Cx2) = {x^ so that V H- a(v) be a non-empty compact space with X X x R e Xj e define a , (v) x^) v(x^-, > 'X determines a map a on R . X^ : ^ (X -* Sup v(., x^)}, Then X (1) ^ ^ C(X^) maps R^ into a [i.e., for each v C (X semi-continuously into Proof (ad : Let v (1)): R e by ) ) ] R^, a (v) maps X^ upper X , and ; For every x . e e X^ x {x is compact, } so the continuous v attains a supremum on a non-empty closed subset, specifically on aCvXx^) {x x = { (x , X £ ) x| {x }, whereby a (v) (x x (X ) . X e a (v) (x ) } to show that) the function v: X ->- , ) range is Hausdorff, their graphs T = {(x, }, respectively, are closed. , r) e X X r| r = ^(x ) r) e X x r| continuity of v and compactness of X, v(X) is compact. set K = (X^ X r ) n r CX X v(X) is compact. into X is precisely the graph r, so is proved. -> = Sup v(*, X^ Since v and v are continuous (x C(Xj), X C(X^) (it is straightforward R determined by v(x is well-defined and continuous. { : is compact, and this we now do. From the continuity of v and compactness of X r_ = e ) To prove that a (v) using Lemma 1, it suffices to show that the is upper semi-continuous, r C into and we see that a(v) maps X graph c X } T x ) and their r = v(x)} and Also, by Thus, the closed Now the projection of K is compact and, by Lemma 1, (1) (ad P Q X Q => v(p) c R |> union ( Agreeing on the notation (2)): < Q , (- -, ((P, n t)) : + -)))) (t, (Q, U <W> such that a(v) for every b iust the is ((P, (- -, i)) C m and there is no and any non-empty open W X n C t e R v c X^ R X Claim (established in the next paragraph): there is a relatively compact open nbd V(b) of \ W, is a nbd of <| V(b) x w*^, V(b) In that case, {V(b) v. ) | i = | 1, K(b) x b e |>, b and a where B} is an open cover ..., m} , and it follows _ O V(b.) 1=1"" x <| <W> c: (B, P, is a subbasic open set, and take any ) of B affording a finite subcover {V(b a(G) <| e q) (p, | ^2 (X <W», (B, e B, c C C ) compact set K(b) c W such that that G = |> \J ( ^={(s, s)f;RxR|s.<s Take any compact non-empty B so that (B, W*^ = X R e (s.,s)eQ + «)))), where (s, = {v > <| P, Q teR (Q, | v(q)} for subsets P, Q «^X, first we note that < is open when P and Q are compact U P | V(b.) w'^, K(b )|> is a x nbd of v such that I showing that a is continuous. ), To complete the proof, we turn to establish our claim above. For each b (since W B, v e compact) is attains a supremum s(b) = s^(b) = Sup v on {blxw'^, Sup v on {b} x w, and {b}xW Now, for all b e B, {blxw"" s^(b) s(b) holds, and there are just two possibilities: < element t(b) such that element. If < s.(b) t(b) < s(b), and holds, define T (b) = (i) (- -, As these are both open sets and v continuous, v(b, w(b)) £ T (b), V^(b) X - u(b) C V -1 MT R owns an R owns no such t(b)) and T*(b) = (t(b), + -). taking any w(b) W with e using (local) compactness of X, we may find a relatively compact open box nbd V (b) - (ii) (i) * (b)). x u(b) of As W c (b , w(b)) such that (the closure) is compact, we may also find a relatively compact open nbd V (b) of Thus, writing V(b) = V^ (b) V(b) X K(b) and T (b) = |> is a nbd of v. (£(b) +<=°) , This completes the proof. b such that V (b) V^Cb) and K(b) = U(b), If (ii) holds, <| w'^ C V(b) x x define T^(b) = v"-' (T (b)). W^, (- <»,7(b)) and find V(b) and K(b) as in the case of (i). FUNDAMENTAL CONTINUITY THEOREM I Let X = X ; and Y be non-empty X x topological spaces, of which X is compact with X u e (XxY) R . each g e Y"^, \(&) Consider the function a (unique) map (x^) = {x^ e a Cg) u(Xj X^ I , ^ a u on Y X Hausdorff, and let which determines, for defined on X x^, g(x^ , x^)) by uC >^ Sup e Y^, a (g) maps X^ , x^, g(- , x^))}, Then (1) a^ maps Y^ into C2) a C(X ) ^ [i.e., for each g upper semi- continuously into Proof C(X and )]; is cont] Let g (ad (1)): : x. e By continuity of u, the function g^ = "u^^^ defined in Proposition 1 is continuous, i.e., g and (1) is proved. (ad in g , (2)): Proposition 2(2) shows that a and from Proposition 1 we see that g Thus, as the composition a ^ ' as to be shown. u = a o w : u Y X This completes the proof. e R . "X Thus, Proposition 2(1) applies, showing that a (g) = a(g = a(g (g) ) is C(X d?(X ) 1 , a u ) continuous is continuous in g ^2 -> ) e (g c Y is continuous, ) •10- COROLLARY In Theorem I, ; the map a' Y : x x a'^(B, x^) = a^(g)Cx^) is continuous Proof : argument (g e Y^, e e X^) (in both arguments together ) see that From Theorem I, we already ^ (g x^ Y^ and x e X ) separately. a' u But X is continuous in each is compact, hence locally compact, in which case the result is a well-known consequence of the compact-open topology (on C(X ) ). Lemma 2 Let X, Y and Z be non-empty topological spaces of which X and ; Y are locally compact. Z^''^ X y: Y^ (u e Z^'''^, g -> e 6 Y^, X X). e is continuous; (2) y, too, is continuous, C Z x) C X and V C be any open nbd of y'(u, g, x) Y such that u(U we may assume u(U assume that g(U) C x nbd of (u, g, x) with (ad (2)): C v) V g, in the domain of p', so continuity of u yields an open box nbd U U and Then Take any (u, g, (ad (1)): and let W .X xy^xX->-Z and y' ; Z z^ by y'Cu, g, x) = u(x, g(x)) and y(u, g)(.) = y'(u, (1) Proof XxY Define the maps v': c y W; V. ' (N) x v) c W. Then (x, g(x)) . x e u"-^ (W) As X and Y are locally compact, and, since g is continuous, we may also Now we have N = (U c W, showing that x y' V, W) x (u, V) x u a is continuous. This follows directly from (1) and the well-known fact that the compact-open topology on Z X , V of (x, g(x)) with is always splitting. 7 •12- FUNDAMENTAL CONTINUITY THEOREM II; compact space with X compact space. 6 reference to Theorem I) by a' g e Y^, , x x be a non-^empty Hausdorff , and let Y be a non-empty locally Consider the map "associate" map a on R (u e R^'' Let X = X^ x^ e g, x (u, Y x ) XxY = x Y X X x defined (with a^CgXx^), and consider the determined by a(u, g) = a Then X^). on R a' is into a' C (X^ ) (g) and a is into CCX^) and both maps ca/' K^''-'.^. are continuous, Proof: In Lemma 2(2), set Z = R. Also, using Proposition clearly, a = a CiX^). o Since X topology on 2 , R^""^ x y: a: R R^ ^ Then y: x Y^ ^ R^ is continuous. ^0 X C(Xj) -> Y^ ^ C (X^ ) ^ ^ is continuous. is continuous and a' is compact, hence locally compact, \ C(X^) completes the proof. is conjoining, 7 Now, is into the compact-open so a', too, is continuous. This '^ ., •13- Historical Note : An earlier study of the continuity of the set of optimal solutions is [Dantzig, Folkman and Shapiro, 1967]. It works with feasible regions lying in a metric space and with objective functions coinciding with real-valued incentive functions, and takes the "parameter space" X„ as singleton, investigating the continuity of the set of optimal solutions as a function of used and (ii) feasible region. (i) objective function Thus, neither does it contain, nor is it contained in, the present study. In a paper following the present and [Sertel, 1971a], we intend to study the continuity of the set of optimal solutions as a function of the feasible region as well. (The present study extends a corrected version of the author's "The Fundamental Continuity Theory of Optimization on a Compact Hausdorff Space", Alfred P. Sloan School of Management, Working Paper 620-72, October, 1972.) 14- FOOTNOTES 0. Our notation R is intended to be mnemonic of the real line, i.e., the set of all real numbers taken with the usual (Euclidean) topology, since objective functions in the literature are almost always specified as real-valued. (N.B The usual topology on the set of reals coincides, of course, with the order topology, using the natural order of the reals). Thus, the reader may wish to interpret R, throughout this paper, as the real line; mathematically, (s)he is quite free to do so. . 1. A terminological warning may be in order. For, according to a terminology not used here, a mapping into a space of non-empty closed sets is called "continuous" iff it is continuous when the range space is given its "finite" topology (see [Michael, 1951]), a topology finer than the upper semi-finite. When we are given a map of a topological space into a space of non-empty closed sets and the topology on the range is understood (e.g., to be the upper iff semi-finite) we feel free to speak of the map as continuous it is so w.r.t. the topology on the domain and that on the , range! * 2. Note that a function Y S -> (f(T) which is singleton-valued (i.e., such that, for each s e S, ¥*(s) is a one-element set) is upper semi-continuous iff the function ^ S -> T, defined by 1'*(s) = {'f(s)} (s e S), is continuous. : : 3. 4. Denoting (R x pJs ^ by < by and by (s_, + °°) we mean {re , (- «, r| s^ < s) we mean {r e r| r}. r < s} Strictly speaking, as made* clear in announcing our Aim, a is .. As {u} x Y^ is homeomorphic to on {u} xY^ and a (g) = a' (u,g)' Y 5. , our informality in treating a See, e.g., Theorem 3.1 (2) on pp. as a Y'' should cause no map on Y^ 261 of [Dugundji, 1966] Notice that, if Y is the real line, it is locally compact. The relevance of this is that our theorem may be applied in the study of optimization subject to real-valued (e.g., monetary) inceative e.g., the case of functions, such as in the usual economic case: taxes or subsidies, the case of wages or salaries, and the general case of a price system. See § 10 of Ch. XII in [Dugundji, 1966]. REFERENCES [Dantzig, Folkman and Shapiro, 1967], J. Folkman and N, Shapiro, "On the Continuity Dantzig, G. B. of the Minimum Set of a Continuous Function", Journal of Mathematical Analysis and Applications 17 1967, pp. 519-548. , . 2. . [Debreu, 1954]. "Representation of a Preference Ordering by a Numerical Debreu, G. C.H. Coombs and R.L. Davis (eds Function," Ch. XI in Thrall, R.M. (New York, 1954). Decision Processes , , . , 3. [Dugundji, 1966]. Dugundji, J., Topology U. , (Allyn & Bacon, Boston, 1966). [Michael, 1951]. Michael, E. "Topologies on Spaces of Subsets", Transactions of the American Mathematical Society, 71 1951, pp. 152-182. , . 5. [Sertel, 1971a]. Sertel, M.R. "Elements of Equilibrium Methods for Social Analysis," unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, M.I.T., January, 1971. , 6. [Sertel, 1971b]. Sertel, M.R., "Order, Topology and Preference," Alfred P. Sloan School of Management, M.I.T., Working Paper 565-71, October, 1971, Date Due DEC 01 -^ mi ij^ w no.624- 72 Ronald Eu/The accelerated sun -J5 143 rv D/BK^ 36659 TOfiO 3 RM^M? DOO bfll ?til 72 lijliliiiiiiiii DD3 b7D AT? TDflD HD28.M414 no.626- D»PKS 63701B iii!i:!n''! TOflo 3 72a Zeno/The economic impact Zannetos, 00027782 'rrr ' 11 ill aaa vma 357 /:2 7-' 3 TDflO HD28.M414 no.629-72 Sertel 0*BKS lllllli 3 TDfiO TDfiD 3 fundamental contii Murat /The 6370l'8 0002775" DDQ 747 7SS DD3 7D1 TMD -l2 3 TDflD 3 TDflD 3 3 DD3 b7D TEl DD3 t.71 ^11 TOaO 0D3 701 TbS TOan DD3 t>7D ITb DD^ bb7 322