• HD28 M414 Dewey ALFRED P. WORKING PAPER SLOAN SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT Exchange Rate Dynamics with Sticky Prices: The Deutsch Mark, 1974-1982 by Alberto Giovannini* and Julio WP# 1522-84 J. Rotemberg** February 1984 MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 50 MEMORIAL DRIVE CAMBRIDGE, MASSACHUSETTS 02139 Exchange Rate Dynamics with Sticky Prices: The Deutsch Mark, 1974-1982 by Alberto Giovannini* and Julio WP# 1522-84 J. Rotemberg** February 1984 *Graduate School of Business, Columbia University, New York **Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Cambridge, Massachusetts Revised November 1983 EXCHANGE RATE DYNAMICS WITH STICKY PRICES: THE DEUTSCHE MARK, 1974-1982 Abstract This paper estimates simultaneously dynamic equations for the Deutsche Mark/Dollar exchange rate and the German wholesale price index, which emerge from a model in which German prices are sticky. This stickiness is due to costs of adjusting prices of the form posited by Rotemberg (1982). The main results of the empirical analysis are two: First, the version of the model where prices are perfectly flexible is rejected. Second, real exchange rate variability is mostly accounted for by nominal exchange rate variability. We find substantial overshooting of the exchange rate to monetary innovations like those which appear to by typical in Germany. Alberto Giovannini 523 Uris Hall Graduate School of Business Columbia University New York, NY 10027 Julio J. Rotemberg E52-250 Sloan School of Management Massachusetts Institute of Technology Cambridge, MA 02139 irlARlES APR 1 7 1984 RECEIVED Revised November 1983 EXCHANGE RATE DYNAMICS WITH STICKY PRICES: THE DEUTSCHE MARK, 1974-1982 by Alberto Giovannini Columbia University and Julio J. Rotemberg Massachusetts Institute of Technology 1. Introduction The idea that purchasing power parity holds with flexible exchange rates at every moment in time has been shown by the data since 1974 to be wrong. Real exchange rates are not constant, and, moreover, their changes tend to persist (see Frenkel (1981)). Also, nominal exchange rates fluctuate much more than price indices. One possible explanation for these phenomena, which is advanced in Dornbusch (1976), is that the prices of goods produced for the domestic market change slowly. his deterministic model, a Then, in once and for all increase in money leads to an instantaneous depreciation which "overshoots" the new steady state exchange rate. Afterwards, the price level slowly increases and the This paper is a revised edition of the first chapter of A. Giovannini 's We doctoral dissertation at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology. are grateful to A. Zanello and L. Polman for helping us with various computational problems, and to L. Dyer for excellent research assistance. Financial support from the Ente Einaudi and the National Science Foundation is gratefully acknowledged. 074353G exchange rate appreciates. Our paper attempts to estimate this type on German data since 1974. slowly. a model of We too assume that prices move On the other hand, our paper differs in important respects both from Dornbusch's original formulation and from its empirical implementation by Frankel (1979) and Driskill and Sheffrin (1981) . First, we consider also the impact of nonmonetary variables both on steady states and on the paths of price levels and exchange rates. In particular we focus on the effect of changes in prices of various imported goods and on changes in real wages. The latter' effect on s exchange rates has been the focus of work Sachs (1980) among others. Second, our specification of the stickyness of prices relies on explicit costs of price adjustment on the part of firms. These costs of price adjustment are akin to those in Rotemberg (1982a) and attempt to capture the fear on the part of firms that customers will desert them if they follow erratic pricing policies. Finally, we do not impose the assumption that money is walk. a random This is simply false for Germany as is noted by Driskill and Sheffrin (1981). Hence the response of exchange rates and prices to monetary shocks differs from the responses considered by Dornbusch (1976) and his followers. So, we let the data inform us as to the plausible Then stochastic processes followed by the forcing variables we consider. we assume that exchange rates and prices respond optimally in that private agents are assumed to also know the stochastic processes of the forcing variables. While we feel that these differences constitute important improvements over previous work we must point out at the outset some important caveats. First, the period since 1974 is only partially a period of "flexible" exchange rates between Germany and the rest of the world which we aggregate into a dollar region. This is so because within Europe exchange rates are only allowed to move within bands. So, whether flexible exchange rate models can explain DM exchange rates is an empirical question. Second, from the theoretical point of view our model fails to explicitly take into account the intertemporal budget constraint that makes the present value of current account deficits equal to the current stock of net foreign assets. Unfortunately, explicit use of the budget constraint appears at the present time to lead to models too complicated for estimation. Instead, we assume, as is standard practice in empirical exchange rate models, that there is perfect asset substitutability: that is that the expected yield in domestic currency of investing at home and abroad is the same. We do this also for tractability, since the specification of imperfect substitutability models is econometrically difficult. Moreover, the assumption perfect substitutability, while statistically rejected by several authors, could be a reasonable approximation of the data. The structure of the paper is as follows. model and its so]ution, Section 3 Section 2 presents the estimates the model using German data, for the period from June 1974 to February 1983. Section 4 presents simulations of the responses of the endogenous variables to shocks, under the rational expectations assumption. contains some concluding remarks. a variety of Finally, Section 5 The appendices describe the solution of the model and the data used in the empirical section. . The Model 2. Our economy is populated by a large number of monopolistically competitive firms, each producing good that is differentiated from a other domestic goods, and from foreign goods. Each firm faces the following demand curve for its product: where is demand for good Q. i at time The first term in the right t. hand side of (1) represents substitution between domestic and foreign goods, and captures substitution both by domestic residents and by foreigners. P, is the index of domestic goods prices, weighted average of P. P 's. is the price of foreign consumption goods each domestic producer does not face by foreign residents. a geometrically This implies that although our country is "small," taken as exogenous. represents a a perfectly elastic demand schedule The second term on the right hand side of (1) real balance effect on domestic demand, Q foreign activity, and N is a stands for random variable which affects demand for 1 . goods On the cost side, we assume that all domestic goods, together with imported intermediates and labor are used in the production of each good i. Marginal costs of production of good (2) with W Q lt Pp (1-ot -a dt the nominal wage rate, P M a ) w i is: _,_ 2 a t(VW N 2t the foreign currency price of imported When p = variable affecting productivity. is a random intermediate goods, and N„ we have the constant variable costs case. Real wages relative to the CPI are given by: W (3) where K is the real = K t CE^) 1 t pJ t "* consumption wage at time is assumed to be K t. This assumption is consistent with exogenous throughout the paper. recent empirical findings (von Jurgen (1982)). Domestic producers are assumed to observe M, P the time of their pricing decision: , P N , Q E and K at , price setting is synchronized. In the absence of costs of changing prices, domestic producers would charge P. at which marginal cost equals marginal revenue. , In natural logarithms, it is equal to (4) Pit = lTJ^ + (1 - {[pA(Y K)a + " *) + a ]e 2 l 1 + t VV - - [0(1 + [p(1 Aa ]p dt i \)(y - d) + (1 " M(Y " d) Mo^lp^ - + a P + a k + pdm + Pfq + n t t i t t* 2 Nt where lowercase letters are the logs of the variables represented by the = n„ corresponding uppercase letters, and n + Pn^- However, we follow Rotemberg (1982a) by assuming that monopolists They are assumed to also have convex costs of changing nominal prices. solve the following problem: 00 (5) Max E _Z t Q P J [n(p it+j ) - w.(p. 2 . t+ - p. t+ .) - c.(p it+ . - P^^Y where p stands for constant discount factor, and a is the expectations E operator, conditional on information available at time terms in the square bracket represent around p. , a second order approximation of the profit function of producer of changing prices; 3 i, in the absence of costs i the third term represents the decrease in current Setting c./w- = profits to be accounted for by price changes. every The first two t. c, for we have the final expression of the domestic producers' objective function: Min E (6) t P JQ J 2 [(P it+j " P it+j ) + c(p. t+ . - 2 P it+:hl ) ] Solution of the problem in (6) leads to the equation describing equilibrium price dynamics for each domestic producer: /I <•-,-> ( ? p t it + ) " + c + pc. ^~ ( l where for everyJ variable x, x t± } . t t+j P it + _ 1 - 1 P it-1 " -p7 P it p indicates the expectations of x at time t+j, conditional on information available at time Equation (7) t. can now be aggregated to obtain the equilibrium dynamics of the domestic price level: pA(Y (8) tPdt+1 "He" [1 + C + PC " 1_ pel -Xl\ p ^dt-1 + [p(l - A)(y - d) + PY ) (1 d) " {[P(1 - - - or (1 A)(Y WOjlp^ 2 - A) + - 1 p^ a9 ~Kt + PV) d) + " + a (1 ° A)a " + a k 1 + a l t + pdn> t ]e 2 t + pfq^ + under the assumption that exogenous variables in (8) are of exponential order less than 1/p, it can be shown that equation (8) has one stable n^ and one unstable root and that in this case there exists a unique stable path that leads to the steady state (Blanchard and Khan (1980)). domestic price level is The function of all future values of exogenous a variables, which for domestic producers include m, p p , , q , k, e and n. The model is closed with the specification of asset markets equilibrium. Domestic and foreign bonds are assumed to be perfect substitutes. Therefore, the ex-ante real interest differential is zero: (9)J e y where t i and i - t+1 = e t i - i t t are the domestic and foreign interest rate, respectively. Finally, we have the money demand equation: m (10) where n„ is a random - t Ap dt - (1 - A)(e t + p ) ct = aq variable affecting velocity. - t bi t + n 3t In order to obtain the dynamics of the exchange rate, we need assumptions about equilibrium output. The hypothesis is that domestic firms are never rationed in the labor market, and intermediate goods market, and supply whatever quantity of the good they produce is demanded. In this case, equilibrium domestic output is given by aggregating (1): = (11) q t (e t + P^ )(Y " d)(l t - A) - [v - (y - d)A]p dt + fq^ +dm + ti^ t the dynamics of the exchange rate are obtained by substituting (11) into money demand, and using the relation (9): (12) , ejl " t t+1 ad where n = an - 1 -f^H + /b + n„ + ( -^)(l i Pct + (1 i^ )(1 a(y d))] - P/ , + a( * " d)) - H - f£ - |( Y - (y - d)A) L dt b + r\ + fi t . This completes the specification of the model. In matrix form, the two equations describing the dynamics of the economy can be written as follows: (14) t Y t+1 = Ay t + Bz t where: ct Nt 't-1 yt A = 1 P — pc = m. t pA (y [1 = Z - d) + c + r pc I [A - - 0^(1 1 + PY a(Y A) + 1 - a, - k)a (Y " d)A)] - A)(y - [p(l - - d) + (1 + 1 pc(l + Py 1 + 1- L^)d ( b + «(Y " d)l cr 2 ] 4 p(l - \)(y - d) + d) + - (1 (1 - \)a a. 1, B = pc( ( 1^)(1 pc(i + Py) + Py) 1 + a(Y - d)), o o a. Pd pc(i + py)' pc(i + Py)' ad af o 1 pc(i + Py) - pc(i + Py) 1 1 b ' The solution of (14) is: (16) p at dt = "'oPdt-i at i " ( L) r21 j 8 - J <r-> 1 ( _) z z w j ii t it+j it+i =Q k=Q 21 [ . r ] oo Iw 1Z i2 [ 22 i=l 1 j=0 ( rJ 22 )J z t lt+J it + i ] and LI s ^I.lCjf-)^^] fc). 22 i=l j=0 22 1 (17) = £<*dt-i- t - where the uj' s , J 2 z -) 5: r 2 (j J 1Z (r-) J t 1C Z i2 it+iJ 22 i=l j=0 22 and the 4' s i are listed in Appendix 1, J unstable roots of A and the z.'s are the elements of the and J z are the vector in i (14). Equations (16) and (17) indicate that the short run dynamics of the real exchange rate are indeed determined, among other things, by domestic price setters' expectations about the evolution of variables determining profits 4 . For example, given an anticipated future change in the price of imported intermediate goods, domestic producers would balance the loss 10 of abruptly changing prices when the increase in input costs conies by, with lower profits today, by partially increasing today's prices. Short run fluctuations of the real exchange rate are not exclusively due to financial disturbances (which would exclusively shift asset demands), although these shocks play a fundamental role here too. Furthermore, and more importantly, unanticipated nominal shocks do have significant real effects, as domestic producers are unwilling to instantaneously adjust output prices to the long run equilibrium level. In the long run, once and for all increases in the money stock can be shown to have no real effects. Another important feature of short run equilibrium is that, although steady state employment is always increased by lowering the consumption wage, these policies are relatively ineffective in the short run. Domestic producers do not decrease the relative price of domestic goods instantaneously, thus giving rise to with not expansionary effects. a short run increase in profits, In this sense, short run unemployment can be considered "Keynesian." 3. Estimation This section is divided in two parts. In subsection a) we present the estimates obtained from the Euler equations (8) and (12). b) presents the time series properties of the forcing variables q , i , p , p„, m and k. Subsection 11 Exchange Rate and Domestic Price Level Euler Equations 3. a. The Euler equations we actually estimate are given by: E (P$ t 3 Pdt + l (8') " Pdt - $ + + Vdt-1 ° • k + (1 - (12') (1 + p)$ E t [e 3 a )p^ + t 2 ? " t+1 CI - - <D 1 - " $ )e t 7 JL Ji~ + pH 3 + (1 fi t 1 - 4 )p dt Vt fi <t» 2 p^ t e t 1 'Mt " JL + $ m ' ? + «.> \ + 5 t + $ q^ + n 6 t t - l)p* ] = °" ] = t where <t> V ( V ( (1 ; "' *6 " and the (})'s ( (1 r l 3 + <j> } + <t> 2 7 7 + p) $3 + + P) «t> (1 + p) <t> 3 <t> "l " °2 (i + P ) V2 + 3 ^ <{. <t> + 3 + 7 } + 2 (J) <t> <t> + 2 7 H. 7 ^6 ( (1 + p) «J> + 3 are given in the Appendix. + (() 2 } (|» 2 The price equation is slightly different from (8) since, for estimation the equation must be normalized. The normalization we choose has the advantage of making it easy to test for the absence of costs of changing prices by testing whether <)> is zero. Note, however, that without other a priori restrictions it is not possible to recover all the the $'s and the a's. ty' s and the a's from We therefore also reestimate (8') and (12') 12 and a_ are given by .25 and .11 respectively. assuming that a These values are those which are consistent with the estimates of Dramais (1980). <h + <J> This, in addition to identifying D which is given by (1 + (see Table 1), and thus all the <t>'s, + p)(()„ also imposes an additional constraint. The residuals obtained when the expectations operators are eliminated from the left hand side of (8') and (12') have interpretations. number of If technology, money demand and output demand were all deterministic functions, then n case, these residuals variables. a and n would be equal to zero. In this would simply be due to innovations in the forcing That is they would be due to the revisions in expectations that take place when q^ +1 , k t+1> and P are realized. i^+1> P^ t+1 Nt+1 These residuals would thus be uncorrelated with any information available at time t. This suggests as a natural estimator the instrumental variables procedure of Hansen (1982) and Hansen and Singleton (1982). As Hansen discusses, this procedure is simply three-stage least squares if one is willing as we are to assume also that the residuals are conditionally homoskedastic. This is a particularly reasonable assumption in our case since our focus on short run fluctuations leads us to estimate with previously detrended data. Hansen (1982) also derives a portmanteau statistic J which permits the testing of the overidentifying restrictions. Unfortunately we cannot seriously entertain the hypothesis that the cost function and demand functions are deterministic. and n Thus n^ also form part of the residuals of (8') and (12'). Insofar as these residuals are independently identically distributed they are presumably also uncorrelated with certain instruments available at t. This would still allow us to use three stage least squares. 13 Another possibility is that the structural residuals of the cost and demand equations are serially correlated. in (8') is the sum of two components, e where u ) and n The first, £ . independently identically distributed. is residual in (12') is given by e„ where n + n 1r is the , is given by (p n Then, suppose that n expectational revision. u1 Suppose that the residual + Similarly the + u„ is p„fi Quasi- . differencing (8') and (12'): pVPdt+z-PiPdt+P (p " dt+r p iPdt ) * + [l-(l +P )i3-i 7 -a 2 ](p* t+1 -p lP t ) (8") VvrPi-V + e (12-) t+2 - (4> 1 + Vvfrf + c^-dcp'^^-p^) + P2H £ P^^ +P 2 )e t+1 + t+l = £ 2t + l + f>4 (m + U = £ - ^^-P^) + a + u e it + i m " it+r p i 2 ( PNt + rp/Nt ) it (l-S-t» A )(P dt+1 -P2 P dt ) t+ rp2 t ) 2t + 1 n-d^v^^vfpi^ + vd^O + p 2 £ 2t Clearly (8") and (12") can still be estimated by three stage least squares as long as only instruments available at u 's are uncorrelated with them. t are used and the However, now the residuals have a moving average component. The estimators are obtained by using two lags for p., e, p q , i , k and m as , Pvp> instruments and constraining p to be equal to the discount factor corresponding to 5 per cent per year. The monthly data which we use, from June 1974 to February 1983, is described in Appendix 2. The results are reported in Table 1. Column I shows the 14 estimates obtained from (8') and (12'). Column II shows estimates from the same equation when the a's are constrained. the results obtained from (8") and (12"). Column III represents Finally the last column presents estimates obtained by constraining the a's in (8") and (12"). In columns I and II, the coefficient estimates are essentially unchanged when we constrain the a's. Quasi-differencing improves the DW statistics of the exchange rate equation somewhat. When a's are fixed, however, the roots do not have the desired property that one is stable while the The estimates of column II do have this property so others are unstable. we use those in our simulations. The estimates of <))„ are substantively and significantly different from zero thus underlining the importance of the price dynamics captured This significance is undoubtedly due by the costs of changing prices. in part to the absence of purchasing power parity in the data. the other coefficients also have the required signs. <|>_ and 4> , the coefficients of q , . from zero, but have the wrong sign. ad ( " - ). values of Most of The exceptions are They are insignificantly different The sign of <|>, is the sign of Other studies (Goldfeld (1973), Rotemberg (1982b)) have found a and d below reported in columns I 1. This is consistent with the negative (J), and II. Finally, it must be noted that the J statistic rejects the overidentifying restrictions imposed by (8') and (12'). This may well be due in part to our assumption of perfect substitutability between domestic and foreign assets. While this assumption may represent a good approximation, it has been statistically rejected by Hansen and Hodrick (1980) among others. 15 16 Time Series Properties of Exogenous Variable s 3.b. In this subsection we explore the time series properties of the forcing variables in order to obtain simple forecasting equations. These simple forecasting equations can then be attributed to private This allows us to compute the effects of innovations in the agents. forcing variables on the paths of e and p.. First, we consider the vector autoregressions having as variables p , , e, q , i , p , p„ and m. Using monthly data from the middle of 1974 to February 1983, one can accept at the 5% level the hypothesis that q i , p , p , are not caused in the Granger sense by any other variable against the hypothesis that they are caused by all the variables in the system. The level of money, however, is significantly influenced by the past values of other variables. We also considered money and interest rates are first differenced. a system in which Since this partially first differenced system is more consistent with univariate evidence presented below, it probably leads to more reliable tests of hypotheses. In this second system one can accept for each forcing variable that it is not caused by any other variable against the hypothesis that they are caused by all of them. These results obtain for vector autoregressions using four, five and six lags. This doesn't lead us to believe that these variables are, in fact, independent. It just means that, for forecasting purposes, univariate time series models of these variables are probably adequate. This conclusion is tempered somewhat by the fact that within the vector autoregressions certain individual variables appear significantly causally prior to other variables. The two variables which we concentrate on, p, and e, do not cause the forcing variables in any of the systems we consider. This is a 17 Table 2 Significance Levels for the Absence of Causality From X to Y in Partially First Differenced Vector Autoregressions VARIABLE Y VARIABLE X P XI p q i m p„ N — — .73 .19 .74 .46 .58 p* rc .59 - - .22 .70 .15 .99 q* .47 .88 .65 .15 .59 .95 .47 .55 31 m k Pd e .98 .68 .65 18 precondition for the applicability of the Hansen and Sargent (1980) formulae. Table 2 presents the significance levels for the tests that the coefficients of variable x are zero in the regression explaining variable y. These significance levels are obtained from the partially firsts As can be seen, changes in money are difference model with six lags. significantly (at the 5% level) causally prior to changes in the prices of imported intermediates while changes in interest rates are significantly causally prior to changes in money. causal relation on latter one. a We neglect the former priori grounds while we focus specifically on the So, we attribute to the agents on section 2 univariate JL -'- forecasting rules for q k, , p _t_ .A, , p„ and i . Instead we assume they forecast m using also information on past interest rates. We employ Box-Jenkins techniques to obtain parsimonious representations for the stochastic processes followed by these variables. Parsimony is essential here since the forecasting formula of Hansen and Sargent (1980) becomes very complex as one enriches the parametrization of these processes. The application of these principles to monthly data from 1974:7 to 1983:2 lead us to an AR(2) for p" which, when estimated by OLS gives: 4= 1 - 175 4-1 " (.095) Similarly p p" *ct (.093) 222 PMt-2 forecasted by an AR(2) . p r ct-l . DW=2.08 R 2 = .93 (0.95) is also well =1.247 - - .283 (.093) p . „ *ct-2 DW = 2.03 R2 = .95 : 19 is well explained by just one lag of itself so that: instead q q" = q" . t_1 .948 t univariate autoregressions cf 1 suggesting the presence of for the process followed by i - i t-1 = .325 (i R 2 = .91 (and m) have coefficients which sum to i A parsimonious representation unit root. a is: i r i t_2 t_ DW = 1.85 -248 " ) U t _ 2 -i t _ 3 DW = 2.00 ) R 2 = .12 (.094) (.094) The most parsimonious process for money which eliminates all significant serial correlations seems to be: m t " = Vi - 064 (m t-r m t-2 } (.093) - .086 ( m t.2 "m t- 3 ) + (.097) + .068 Ci*. r i*. 2 ) - -238 Ci^. 2 -^. 3 ) (.118) (.113) + 378 (m -3" m ) t-4 t (.096) - .023 (i*_ -i*_ ) 4 3 (.118) - -268 (i*_ -it- 5 4 5 (.113) DW = 2.00 R2 = Finally, the real wage k is well forecasted by an AR(3) k = .294 k (.096) + .194 k (.097) t_ 2 + .164 k (.092) t_ 3 DW = 2.06 R 2 = .27 .21 . 20 4. Simulations In this section, we use the estimates of the parameters of the mociel presented in the previous section to simulate responses of the price level and the exchange rate to a variety of shocks. In the simulations, we substitute the estimates obtained from Euler equations into the solution of the model, equations (16) and (17). Furthermore, we apply the Wiener Kolmogorov prediction formulae as in Hansen and Sargent (1980) to express the infinite summations in (16) and (17) in terms only of present and past realizations of the exogenous variables, using the estimates of the autoregressive parameters of these variables These simulations differ from simulations of rational expectations models as for example in Lipton and Sachs (1980), in that we specify a realistic process followed by exogenous variables, rather than implicitly assuming a random walk. some persistence. Given our estimates, unanticipated shocks have Some of the shocks, however, eventually fade away. By describing the effects of innovations in the processes governing the exogenous variables, we perform an exercise similar to impulse responses in vector autoregressive models. However, these simulations differ from impulse responses as all the cross equation restrictions arising from the rational expectations hypothesis are imposed here. These restrictions are bound to improve the efficiency of the forecasts under the rational expectations assumption. In this sense our simulations can be thought as constrained impulse responses. Figures 1 stock of money. to 4 illustrate the effects of a unit increase in the Starting from steady state (all endogenous and 21 I VO 1 00 50 O 00 -0 50 Figure 1 1 : Money rJO O 7S 0.35 -O OS -0 50 Figure 2: Domestic Prices (Innovation in Money) 22 >> o 4 3 2 ? 3 -1 3 Figure 3: Nominal Exchange Rate (Innovation in Money) ».-» O 4 3 2 ? 0.3 -1.0 Figure 4: Real Exchange Rate (Innovation in Money) 23 exogenous variables = 0), observed. Figure 1 a unit disturbance in the money process is shows that the money stock does increase further after the shock, and eventually reaches is due to the fact that, a permanently higher level. as discussed abcve, This the data indicates the presence of nonstationarity of the money stock, and therefore we have estimated the money process, together with the foreign interest rate Figure 2 shows the response of the process, in the first differences. As stressed above (Section 2), the price level reacts price level. immediately to the innovation in the exogenous variable; after the shock, long run equilibrium is reached in a very smooth fashion, despite the sizeable swings in the stock of money. response. Figure 3 shows the exchange rate As predicted by the theory, the exchange rate is by far more volatile than the domestic price level. The simulations, which use the estimated parameters, do indeed provide support to the theory outlined above. At the time of the increase in the stock of money, the nominal exchange rate overshoots its steady state level as the theory, following Dornbusch would predict. The initial depreciation is four times larger than the steady state effect on the exchange rate. The large fluctuations in the nominal exchange rate generate big swings in the real exchange rate, as shown in figure Figures shock: 5, 5 4. to 8 illustrate the simulated effects of another financial an increase in the U.S., treasury bills rate. As shown in figure the estimated reaction of German monetary authorities implies that an increase in U.S. interest rates is followed by a large monetary contraction in Germany. a real depreciation of the This does not prevent exchange rate as shown in figure 8. 24 10 1 30 0.S0 -0 40 -1 CO Figure 5: Foreign Interest Rate and Domestic Money (Innovation in Foreign Interest Rate) <:- o 4 3 2.5 0.8 -1 O Figure 6: Domestic Prices (Innovation in Foreign Interest Rate) 25 20 21 3 12.5 3 S -5 e Figure 7: Nominal Exchange Rate (Innovation in Foreign Interest Rate) 30 O 21 3 12 5 3.8 -5 © Figure 8: Real Exchange Rate (Innovation in Foreign Interest Rate) 26 Finally, figures 9 to 12 show the effects of a real disturbance, the form of an increase in the real wage. in Here again the exchange rate responses to the shock is much larger than the price level response, as the path of the real exchange rate demonstrates (figure 12). Sone of the increase in costs is immediately passed into higher prices, which cause an excess demand for domestic money. For money market equilibrium, the domestic interest rate increases relative to the foreign interest rate, thus implying expectations of exchange rate depreciation, and an instantaneous appreciation of the exchange rate. 27 J 20 O 24 48 0.11 -0 25 1 II 6 Figure 9: 1* 31 Real Wages Figure 10: Domestic Prices (Innovation in Real Wages) 26 31 28 ••» 020 -0 015 -0 110 -0 205 -0 300 Figure 11: Nominal Exchange Rate (Innovation in Real Wages) 100 000 -0.100 -O 200 -O 300 Figure 12: Real Exchange Rate (Innovation in Real Wages) 29 5. Concluding Remarks This paper has specified and estimated a model of sticky prices in an open economy, under the assumption of rational expectations. In the simulations, we have allowed the data to inform us as to the stochastic processes followed by exogenous variables. Such a model can shed light on important structural parameters like the relevance of overshooting. This ability is to some extent independent of whether the model forecasts well. Thus we disagree with the view that the poor forecasting performance illustrated by Meese and Rogoff (1983) completely invalidates structural estimation of exchange rate models. It is our opinion that a large class of exchange rate models, those which do not assume perfect wage and price flexibility and purchasing power parity, have so far received little attention from empirical researchers. For that reason, it is too early to make general statements about the empirical relevance of flexible exchange rate theories. Our empirical analysis is partially successful. Estimates of the parameters of the model from the Euler equations do indicate that the empirical significance of costs in adjusting prices, the fundamental feature of our model, is considerable. parameters are very imprecise, and in However, the estimates of many a few cases, of the wrong sign. This latter phenomenon may be due to some simplifications on which our model is based, for analytical tractability : among these, the exogeneity of real wages, and the perfect substitutability hypothesis in assets markets are the most questionable. Simulations of the model, using the parameter estimates obtained from Euler equations estimation, and the estimates of autoregressive . 30 processes for the exogenous variables, show that the data yields predictions of the effects of disturbances that match the predictions of the theory. By far the largest proportion of short run real exchange rate volatility is accounted for by fluctuations in the nominal exchange rate: effects through this mechanism, nominal disturbances have important real 31 APPENDIX 1 : The system of equations (14) has a unique convergent solution if and only if two eigenvalues of A have real parts whose absolute values are greater than one while the other eigenvalue's real part is smaller than one in absolute value. This is so because the system has only one initial condition namely P Hn If there are more "stable roots there are - infinitely many convergent solutions while on the other hand, the convergent solution if all roots are explosive may not satisfy the initial condition. The solution to the system (14) as long as these conditions are met uses the Jordan canonical form of A: -1 12 11 J 12 11 (lxi) (1X2) (lxi) A A 21 (2xi) 22 (2X2) r L l (1X2) r L 22 (1X2) 2i (2xi) C L ll 2 is the stable root C L '22 12 21 C 22 (real part less than 1), and J diagonal matrix containing the unstable roots. is the A and the eigenvector matrix C are decomposed accordingly. Following Blanchard and Kahn (1980): where y '21 = C C (16) 12 (2x2) where and J 11 (lxi) 'dt ' r U -l r L 22 21 P dt-l " r L -l T ,-(i+l) r 22.V2 i=0 comes from the partition of B: L Z 22^2t t+i 32 B = ~[Y 2 T We will write equation (16) by expressing all the eigenvectors as functions of the eigenvalues and the elements of A. premultiply both sides of (15) by C, solve for each of the elements of C. To do this normalize the eigenvectors, and Substituting into (16), the price and exchange rate equations are: 8 = p,* *dt e • t ^ph, dt-1 "W t~ i = to? _i dt dt-i ^ (t-) J - 8 oo )J z 1 z ( } ( + t it it+j J il J 21 k=Q 21 i=1 - . 21 =1 li il T- = UJ P J 22 J 21 <J. = UJ (J 2 11 4» + a (* 2 1 - J P<D (J 21 22 3 - 21 2 (J P<t> gl 21 " " ( *1 P4> (J 3 (( P<t> ' ( J ~ 3 (J »1 ~ p4> (J UJ 3 22 2 2 J ) 2 J 2i ) 21 22 ' J )a 22 22 21 )a J - " 22 )a - " 22 fl UJ 31 21 p$ (J 22 3 UJ " J ' (-J 3 )a i J 21 } i " J 21 } J J 21 ) ) t « (a 1) 22 IX) ID - l) 21 1 ) i J z z lt+ J (r-) t rt+j J j=Q 21 where: J 22 ) ( ] - rJ 22 } °° 1 z w 1 J t it+j i? (r-^it-H i2 =1 j=Q 22 [ . ii J z i c-p-) ^ t it+j (r-) j lt+i iz j j=Q 22 22 i=1 ] 33 V2 41 " V*! " *J*2 42 P4> Vg : 61 at V*! I - J (J 22 3 22 - c+i J p<t» 62 p<t) (J 3 (J 3 J - 22 21 ) 21 ) J - 22 (< J - "l p<t) ( (J *1 J - 22 - J UJ P 3 (J 22 72 ((, LU 81 (J p(). 3 h7 ) 21 ) } 2] 21 ) ) <K p$ (J 22 3 ~" " - *2 (<t> - J - (^ 0, J 1 21 ) J 21 )(^ J J 22 21 " 22 )[<t> 2 *11 (J - J 21 )[(|) (J 2 <D 22 (J 2 J - - 21 J <V (<!>! •12 ) 21 21 } a ^82 ^° J - 22 - J - 22 3 22 21> LU 71 } ) 21 j - 21 21 J - p$ 3 (J 22 51 U) J 3 ' W - p$ (J J " 22 ) + a 1) J " 22 - 22 1) - 21 + a J 21 ) J 1 21 } - («|» 2 - ((|» 2 1 J 22 )] )] 34 (<J» hi J - 1 <t> 2 (J i 22 <t, 2 «31 (» <t> ( 2 (J )(<l» J - J - 22 21 (<t) ^51 J " l J - 22 21 gl J 22 J (», *71 - J " J ( 22 " - J V J *1 <t) ( J 21 22 ) ) a 2 a 1 } V*i - V4 V*! " 2 " 2 <t> J " 22 6 ($ 21 $ J J " 22 - 4 7 J " 22 (0 21 21 21 21 )(^ 22 J (J 2 *1 ' J 22 " J J ' 21 )( 22 21 21 »l • J 22 } J - 22 ) } J - 21 } 21 22 } )] 22 )l ) J 21 21> 21 J 1 ' J J ) J (J )[ - " <t> 22> J - 4 72 ^81 5 V l '62 2 M<i> '52 *6l" ) 22 5 <D 2 (J - J 2 22 21 V Uj 21 )[0> )(<t) <t» = 2 - J ) 21 )(^ 22 ai (J - J ) 2 22 21 a 1 J J " J )0, J <t» (<J> " 1 " «4l 4 42 = J - 22 22 - 21 22 ) 21 )(*j 21 (J 1 4 32 J - J J - ((Jjj J 1 22 - ((^ )(4> 21 1 } J 22 )] } 35 J '82 x <j> 2 = + = P(l E (|) 1 3 3f A = ^5 *6 7 J 21 (^-g-^U \)(y - C(l + PY) _ ad - - - 22 r E Pf = Pd 1 - - a d) + (v - d)) (1 \)Oj + a 2 1 , 36 Appendix 2: The Data This paper presents an empirical analysis of the dollar mark exchange rate, but unlike earlier work, aggregates the rest of the world (for Germany) as a single dollar area. Data for P , is computed using geometrically weighted averages Q of the individual series from the countries appearing on table A2 . 1 below. Table A2 . Weight Country U.S.A. .157 France .275 Italy .184 Netherlands .252 United Kingdom .132 The weights are the average from 1974 to 1981 of the ratio of the value of imports plus exports of each country with Germany over the total trade of Germany with these countries. In 1981 the 5 countries in Table A2.1 represented 45 percent of the total trade of Germany. countries' and q are aggregated using the respective indices for P exchange rates vis a Individual vis the U.S. dollar. Most of the data is obtained from the International Financial Statistics (IFS) tape. The index of wages in Germany and the index of intermediate inputs prices are computed using data from the Deutsche Bundesbank, Monthly Report , various statistical supplements. . . 37 The exchange rate is the price of a U.S. dollar in Deutsche marks, line rf in IFS (average over the month) The domestic price level is line 63 of IFS, the index of wholesale prices is computed P aggregating the various countries indices of consumer prices, line 64 in IFS. P„ is a weighted average of the IFS index of all commodities prices excluding oil, line 76a, and the index of the dollar price of oil for Saudi Arabia, line 76aa. The weights are chosen from the geographical composition of Germany's imports, using data from the Deutsche Bundesbank Monthly Report For the period 1974-1982 we computed the average share of . imports from OPEC, in total imports less finished goods. The average value share of imports from OPEC is 22 percent. i is the U.S. Q is the treasury bill rate, line 60c in IFS. weighted average of industrial production indices, line 66c, expressed in dollar terms, by dividing each country's index by the real dollar exchange rate. M is line 34 in IFS K is the index of wage costs in industry, per man/hour, divided by the CPI . The former is from Bundesbank Monthly Bulletin , the latter is IFS line 64. Theory requires that all series be realizations of stationary stochastic processes. All series have been demeaned and detrended by regressing the log of each against a constant, time and time squared. All seasonally unadjusted data has been adjusted by regressing each series on 11 monthly dummies. s 38 FOOTNOTES The presence of real balances in the demand function for good i Then real money can be justified by making money yield utility. balances are a proxy for the marginal utility of income. In our model, since money demand is explicitly specified in equation (10), nothing would be lost if d were zero. 2 3 Constant terms are not reported for simplicity. This approximation is spelled out in Rotemberg (1982(a)). 4 This feature distinguishes this model from the traditional Dornbusch (1976) specification. There, the inflation rate depends only This is due to Dornbusch' s assumption that on the current value of m. changes in m last foreever so that current m is the best forecast of future m. Driskill and Sheffrin (1981) have interpreted Dornbusch' continuous time model as saying that p is predetermined at t and thus doesn't depend on any current variables. For monthly data it is more plausible, and an equally correct interpretation of the continuous time model, to assume that p does indeed respond to m . Estimation of Euler equations for an exchange rate model with flexible prices is carried out in Glaessner (1982). The covariance matrix of the estimates is computed using the This technique described in Eichenbaum, Hansen and Singleton (1984). requires that one obtain the parameters of the vector moving average of To do order 1 followed by the products of instruments and residuals. this we first fit a vector autoregression of order 1 to the product of instruments and residuals. Then we explain these products by the lagged residuals of the vector autoregression. The coefficients of these This lagged residuals are treated as the moving average parameters. procedure is only valid asymptotically as long as the order of the vector autoregression grows with the number of observations in such a We use this method way that, asymptotically, its order is infinite. because the simpler procedure of Hansen (1982) does not always lead to a positive definite covariance matrix. 39 REFERENCES Blanchard, 0. J. and C. M. Kahn, "The Solution of Linear Differential Models Under Rational Expectations," Econometrica July 1980. , "Expectations and Exchange Rate Dynamics," Journal of Dornbusch, R. 1976. Political Economy , , Dramais, "Trans-Log KLEM Model for France, Germany, Italy, and the U. K.," Working Paper No. 41, Mimeo DULBEA, 1980. Driskill, R. A. and S. M. Scheffrin, "On the Mark: Economic Review December 1981. Comment," American , Eichenbaum, M. L. P. Hansen and K. J. Singleton, "A Time Series Analysis of Representative Agent Models of Consumption and Leisure Choice Under Uncertainty," manuscript, 1984. , A Theory of Floating Exchange Rates Frankel, J. A., "On the Mark: Based on Real Interest Differentials," American Economic Review September 1979. , Frenkel, J. A., "Flexible Exchange Rates, Prices, and the Role of 'News': Lessons from the 1970s," Journal of Political Economy 89, August 1981. "Formulation and Estimation of a Dynamic Model of Exchange Rate Determination: An Application of the General Method of Moments Technique" Mimeo, December 1982. f7laessner, T. J. Goldfeld, S. M. "The Demand for Money Revisited," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 3, 1973. , , Hansen, L. P., "Large Sample Properties of Generalized Method of Moments Estimators," Econometrica July 1982. , Hansen, L. P. and R. J. Hodrick, "Forward Exchange Rates as Optimal Predictors of Future Spot Rates: An Econometric Analysis," Journal of Political Economy 1980. , Hansen, L. P. and K. J. Singleton, "Generalized Instrumental Variables Estimation of Nonlinear Rational Expectations Models," Econometrica 1982. Hansen, L. P. and T. J. Sargent, "Formulating and Estimating Dynamic Linear Rational Expectations Models," Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 1980, Vol. 2. , Lipton, D. and J. Sachs, "Accumulation and Growth in a Two-Country Model: A Simulation Approach," NBER Working Paper No. 572, October 1980. , , 40 Meese, R. A. and K. Rogoff, "Empirical Exchange Rate Models: Fit Out of Sample?", Journal of International Economics February 1983. Do They , 14, Rotemberg, J. J., "Monopolistic Price Adjustment and Aggregate Output," Review of Economic Studies 1982(a). , "Sticky Prices in the United States," Journal of Political Economy 90, December 1982(b). , Sachs, J., "Wages, Flexible Exchange Rates and Macroeconomic Policy," Quarterly Journal of Economics 1980. , von Jurgen, R. "Mehr Beschaftingung durch Reallohnzuruckhaltung," fur Weltwirtschaft Kiel, Marz 1982. Institut , , 3 5 0^ 18 1 1 • 6 "I Lib-26-67 MIT LIBRARIES TOflO •%fitoEftj* ODD 175 Ifll