HD28 .M414 ALFRED P. WORKING PAPER SLOAN SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT Barter in Networks: A Revived Form of Inter-Firm Exchange Stephan Schrader December, 1991 WP# ^3^9-^1 MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 50 MEMORIAL DRIVE CAMBRIDGE, MASSACHUSETTS 02139 Barter in Networks: A Revived Form of Inter-Firm Exchange Stephan Schrader December, 1991 WP# ^3^9-^1 5RS Massachusetts Institute of Technology Alfred P. Sloan School of Management 50 Memorial Drive, E52-553 Cambridge, Massachusetts 02139 (617 253-5219) M IT. LIBRARIES FEB 2 1 1992 Barter in Networks: A Revived Form of Inter-Firm Exchange *^ Summary Firms frequently enter network type relationships such as strategic alliances and partnerships to barter difficult-to-price goods like technical know-how, market understanding, and management practices. The paper proposes that barter of difficult-to-price goods is easier to realize than a the double coincidence of wants is given. money-based exchange Under such circumstances, — as long as barter requires decisions of less cognitive complexity than are necessary in the context of a money- based exchange system. Networks support barter through allowing temporal separation of transactions, facilitating identification of transaction possibilities, and establishing role of mechanisms to enforce cooperative behavior. networks complements other explanations especially the ones derived ^ from a transaction cost The barter-supporting for the existence of networks, framework. thank Klaus Brockhof, Jack Brittain, Nicolaus Henke, William M. Riggs, Jill D. Teplensky as well as the participants of the 1991 Academy of Management Review Theory Development I Workshop for their insightful presented at the 1991 comments and suggestions. An earlier version of of Management Annual Meeting, Miami Beach. Academy this paper was -3 Introduction Inter-firm networks have received considerable attention in recent years. Popular business publications proclaim that the formation of networks constitutes an integral part of a successful business strategy academic Barley & articles 1979; Ouchi & Jarillo, 1988; Luke, Begun, & & (e.g. Kanda, 1990; Gemiinden, 1990; Pointer, 1989; MacMillan & Farmer, Bolton, 1988; Porter, 1990; Saxenian, 1989; Thorelli, 1986). This paper investigates a characteristic of networks that has been widely neglected literature: the Numerous Economist, 1990). attempt to conceptualize core issues of inter-firm networking Freeman, 1990; Furukawa, Teramoto, Hakansson, 1987; (e.g. support of barter as a Networks provide the frame mode for a by the of exchange. multitude of transactions, many of those involving barter. Firms engage in strategic alliances or partnerships to barter, for example, technical for technology know-how (Hamel, Doz, & for management experience or market understanding Prahalad, 1989; Leadbeater, 1990; Roberts, 1980). Several authors have described informal inter-firm networks in which goods such as technical information are not traded for — even 1991, if von bartered for other like goods the goods are of considerable economic value (Rogers, 1982; Schrader, Flippel, 1987). In this paper, distinct money but I propose that situations exist in which a barter system offers advantages over a trade-for-money system. These advantages exist especially if it is difficult to put a monetary value on the goods to be exchanged, as frequently the case for goods like information or market access. is Under such circumstances, networks help to establish barter systems and to capture the benefits of such systems. To characterize situations prone to barter, the ability to specify the attributes of a I introduce a distinction between good and the ability to price the good in 4- monetary terms. Most authors discuss only one of these dimensions (e.g. Williamson, 1975) or view them as closely linked Based on (e.g. Arrow, 1971). this unique transaction modes are characterized: discrete purchase and distinction, four discrete barter as well as relational purchase and relational barter. I argue that networks support both relational barter and discrete barter through allowing temporal separation of transactions, facilitating identification of transaction and establishing mechanisms possibilities, characteristic of argument This networks augments the traditional transaction cost and communication oriented explanations the to enforce cooperative behavior. that barter is for the existence of networks. the preferred transaction mode if Furthermore, prices are difficult or impossible to determine implies that those conventional control and decision practices relying on prices and related quantitative measures are barter-supporting networks. ramifications and should encourage the study of how The paper literature on This conclusion has considerable consists of four parts. inter-firm networks. Next, barter from trade-for-money. Then, mode of exchange in some settings. I First, I I to likely to fail in management govern such situations. review briefly some of the relevant introduce a framework to distinguish discuss Finally, why I barter appears to be the preferred investigate how networks support the emergence of barter systems. Networks as Governance Structures for Inter-Firm Relationships Firms face several alternatives for organizing their vertical and horizontal relationships. are markets The two and ideal types discussed hierarchies. between independent entities by Coase (1937) and Williamson (1975) In market relationships, transactions take place and are mediated by a price mechanism. hierarchical relationships, the transaction partners are part of In one corporate body -5 which somehow mediates the relationship through such mechar\isms as surveillance, evaluation, and direction. The market-hierarchy typology has served for more several authors as a starting point refined typologies. Ouchi (1980), for example, discusses three types: markets, bureaucracies, and clans. The latter is characterized by a considerable correspondence of organizational and individual goals. Jarillo (1988) classic extends this typology by differentiating markets further into markets and strategic networks. Classic markets are characterized by a competitive relationship between transaction partners. Not so in strategic networks. Strategic networks are based on a potential for cooperation. The possibility of capturing long-term benefits from cooperative behavior induces firms to overcome short-sighted opportunism and to enter long-term relationships while maintaining most of their organizational MacNeil (1978) independence. differentiates market contracts even He further. introduces three types of contracts: classical contracts (the identity of the transaction partner irrelevant and each party's obligation is is well-defined), neoclassical contracts (mostly long term contracts that provide governance structures for solving potential conflicts instead of explicitly anticipating contracts (agreements that may on governance every contingency), and relational structures for entire long-term relationships evolve well beyond the originally planned transactions). This paper adopts Thorelli's definition of networks as "two or organizations involved in long- term relationships" (Thorelli, 1986, more p. 37), and thereby includes both neoclassical and relational contracts. These relationships can be of contractual as well as non-contractual nature. In most cases, a mixture of both will be present (Macaulay, 1963). The definition used encompass several forms of is sufficiently inter-firm relationship, ranging organized networks such as supply networks (Jarillo, from open to explicitly 1988) to implicitly evolved networks such as informal information trading networks between competitors (von Hippel, 1987; Schrader, 1991). The Hterature discusses networks primarily relationships. Note, however, that organizations frequently engage not only in but also in horizontal networks. Research consortia with competing firms vertical as in the context of vertical members are a case in point (Dimancescu & such consortia have developed formal horizontal resource pooling and risk sharing. competing firms is Firms participating in Botkin, 1986). ties to gain advantages from Informal information trading between another example (Carter, 1989; Schrader, 1991; von Hippel, 1987). Firms within one industry are linked by informal communication networks. Employees exchange information Why do networks in these networks without explicit contracts. The conventional explanation exist? as provided, for example, by MacMillan and Farmer (1979) argues that networks capture core benefits of markets while enjoying networks enable firms (Jarillo, 1988). good and benefit some transaction costs advantages of hierarchies. to realize economies of scale and specialization advantages One network member may distribute the good to the other specialize on the production of a entities. And the market test is still existing network (MacMillan & its Farmer, 1979, captive internal markets." networks allow a less p. 283). is spread better trading tie (as in Jarillo (1988, p. 35) in the case of concludes: an integrated firm, Also, in times of considerable technical change, expensive restructuring of a firm's ties to specific than would be possible in the context of hierarchies (DeBresson forthcoming). If Risk from forming new relationships outside the "Networking introduces a cost discipline that may be absent with firms. applicable. terms can be obtained elsewhere in the long run, no permanent vertical integration) stops either party specific members. Thus, the network partners from the organizational advantages of small specialized between different First, & technologies Amesse, Second, networks capture benefits of hierarchies. Networks help to 7- avoid some of the transaction costs that emerge in a pure market system due to opportunistic behavior and asset specificity Crawford, & (Jarillo, 1988; Joskow, 1987; Klein, Alchian, 1978; Thorelli, 1986; Williamson, 1985). Crawford and Klein, Alchian (1978), for example, demonstrate the negotiation problems that arise in supply relationships specific assets. if either of two contract partners has to invest in relationship- Such problems can be mediated by networks. For this, the network partners have to expect that they will benefit from an ongoing cooperative relationship result and that this benefit overcompensates any short-term gains that would from opportunistic behavior Consequently, network partners (Jarillo, 1988). are willing to invest in network-specific assets even dependency and thereby vulnerability members to threats. will not use this vulnerability to cause In this paper, I 1 . this increases their They trust that other network them undue harm. propose that the conventional theory of networks should be augmented by another of barter systems if characteristic of networks. argue that this is some goods can be bartered more Networks support the emergence an important characteristic of networks since effectively than they can be traded for money. Before this argument can be explored further, however, the concept of barter needs clarification. Barter Barter good is is a form of "reciprocal dealing" exchanged medium for another (Thorelli, 1986, p. 44) in good without using a separate unit of account or of exchange (Pearce, 1986, p. 36). These reciprocal dealings simultaneously. For example, IBM may gives Siemens access to (parts) of production technology and at the same time Siemens provides its technical expertise (Markoff, 1990). which one its occur chip IBM with access to Alternatively, a temporal separation of -8 transactions can occur (von Weizsacker, 1985). exploration industry as an example. Take information trading In this industry, observed to exchange well-logs informally (Schrader In some instances, several in the oil- employees have been & von Hippel, forthcoming). months can pass between giving one well-log and The party receiving another well-log in return. that first provides a good to the other party acquires a claim to receive a comparable good in the future. In the following, three types of barter are distinguished: discrete barter, relational barter, and pseudo Pseudo barter barter. sight appears to be barter but that can be readily money transactions. Bartering crude oil refers to a transaction that at first decomposed into two good-for- of a specific grade for an equally well- defined amount of wheat with both parties having the alternative of buying and selling the respective world market transactions out.^ commodities on the world market prices, the barter can is a case in point. Using be broken up into two good-for-money — including a side-payment if the respective amounts do not cancel Since pseudo-barter can be interpreted as a set of separate purchasing agreements, the term barter as used in the remainder of the paper will not include pseudo-barter. Discrete barter refers to the exchange of one well-defined well-defined good in a situation in which readily available. Assuming barter distribution of goods commonly accepted self-interested actors, is good for another valuations are not such barter occurs if the post preferred to the pre barter one. Yet, the parties need not to be able or willing to agree on precise monetary prices for the goods. Even if each party would be capable of valuing the goods in exact monetary terms, the valuations do not necessarily have negotiation space. ^ In this case, that is to be such that they determine a non-empty Barter necessitates only that ordinal rankings of goods are such an "objective" valuation of the goods exists insofar as the price is determined in a way market participants' preferences (Weizsacker, 1985). wridely independent of the individual -9 that an exchange is preferable, not that cardinal evaluations would an justify exchange. In the case of discrete barter, it is not possible for a third party to deduce without additional information the parties' valuations of the goods exchanged. What can be determined of another good. parties is that x units of one good have been exchanged This relation, however, only conveys the information that the have reached a specific agreement. information on the valuation of the goods. many units of a third good Von Weizsacker the parties It does not convey any further It is would have exchanged the goods in question. down (1985) argues convincingly that barter systems break and will require to be compensated by side-payments. The resulting negotiations will lead He as such valuations If occur, the parties will perceive, at least temporarily, inequalities introduction of money-based exchange systems. how not possible to conclude for soon as the parties evaluate specific transactions monetarily. either required in y units for to an proposes that valuation an exchange relation (money-based exchange) or that is it is explicitly or implicitly forbidden (barter). Relational barter ^ differs from discrete barter by the transaction content not being well defined are well definable. Technical know-how, for example, frequently falls into this complex category. Know-how can be set of subjective knowledge tacit, ill-understood, (Polanyi, 1958). If and embedded such know-how is exchanged, any attempt to precisely stipulate the content of the exchange to fail. Consequently, other (explicit or implicit) contractual to is in a be doomed mechanisms have to be employed. Relational contracting (MacNeil, 1978; MacNeil, 1980) provides an alternative. Here it is not the substance of the exchange that rather procedural aspects The notion and relationship of relational barter is characteristics. is determined, but Examples of procedural closely linked to MacNeil's (1980) concept of relational contracts. 10 regulations are control meetings, documentation requirements, and reporting Sometimes these procedures are never agreed on obligations. out of an ongoing relationship. An extreme case of relational barter In such collaborations, collaboration. explicitly but evolve monetarily value individual transactions (what a transaction in the context of an is may have academic discourse?). Nevertheless, the partners is academic frequently impossible to identify or to it is perceptions of wrhether the cooperation is w^ell-formed beneficial to each of them and of whether the exchange should be continued in the future. Barter Discrete Barter Relational Barter Pseudo Barter Substantive dimensions of exchange can be well-defined. Valuative dimension remains vague. Substantive dimensions of exchange cannot be Decomposition into two good-for-money transactions plus sidepayment easily Substantive contracting Relational contracting Figxire 1: 1 summarizes the proposed relational barter. distinction between discrete barter and for each barter component. A decomposition of the barter good-for-money transactions cannot be done without strong assumptions, and if it => Purchase Both are characterized by the parties not having to agree on a monetary price into several even possible. remains vague Types of Barter Figure precise well-defined. Valuative dimension — as von Weizsacker argues — probably would be possible. is not done by the parties This characteristic distinguishes barter from money- based exchange. In money-based exchange, the parties involved agree on precise prices. Frequently, such agreement is achieved by adopting established market 11- prices. Under other circumstances, each party to generate and at least a prices result fronn negotiations. rough monetary valuation of the good that the parties are able to agree with the valuations by Two specific monetary value (the price) that The two types are to goods to be transferred as classification discrete purchase an exchange in and relational purchase. which the good can be determined the classical purchasing agreement as it is Discrete relational purchase, the parties agree This precisely. considered by traditional microeconomic theory. Relational purchase provides a more interesting fail fits types of money-based exchanges can be distinguished, again using the purchase refers is on a in question all parties. ability to specify the attributes of the criterion. This requires on a price for the goods to case. In a be exchanged, but to precisely specify the substance of the exchange. Consulting contracts are a case in point. back Frequently, well established hourly rates exist and the parties can refer to those rates consulting when determining work cannot be agreed on the consulting work would be established, using means such the exchange price. Yet, the substance of the in detail before the transaction superfluous. — otherwise Therefore, a relational contract as reputation, control procedures, interactions to ensure that both parties are satisfied with the and outcome is iterative of the exchange. In conclusion, the — ability to specify attributes of determine prices — can be used to two dimensions discussed the goods to be transferred and ability to distinguish four types of exchange relationships that should be preferred under different circumstances, as shown in Figure 2. Whether or not the transaction partners are able to specify ex ante the attributes of the goods to be exchanged determines whether or not they will utilize substantive contracts or relational contracts. goods for Their ability to determine prices impacts their inclination to trade the money or to barter them. -12- 13 — information, access computer metal dies, technology and market access — are exchanged within networks without a Valuable goods to compensating flow of money. goods are provided The bank to use the other firms bartered access to own computer One These exchanges are part of a barter system. The in the expectation of receiving other valuable opened that facilities, its computer facilities to for some type of insurance against a is frequently bartered in networks leading user of printed circuit boards (PCBs) and motto was PCB "We customer." The close user decided to change are a world number information. its of suppliers was In addition, the its bank breakdown of its we want information. A to its suppliers. be a world The class greatly reduced to be able to develop a A system of long-term supply contracts was companies bartered valuable, proprietary technical Each firm was contributing some of production, and testing and is suppliers shall serve as an relationships to class manufacturer, network with the remaining ones. established. In other words, the system.^ type of good that example. The in return. a competitor thereby gained the right facilities in a similar situation. its facilities goods was receiving similar its knowledge regarding design, knowledge and other difficult to price goods such as greater supplier reliability in return. Barter of information in networks can also be observed between rival firms (von Hippel, 1987; Schrader, 1991). In some instances, the horizontal exchange of information is supported by other organizations that are placed in the vertical chain before or after the horizontal network. encourage their For example, some equipment suppliers customers to exchange technical information between each other in so-called user groups. Similarly, manufacturers frequently induce irxformation trading between their suppliers. Concast's In addition, the spillover. bank might have been motivated management to of its customer's relations help in order to prevent a negative image -14- demonstrates the vertical support of horizontal information exchange networks. Concast steel a leading supplier of continuous casters, a crucial piece of is minimills and nowadays for other steel the industry, Concast required modifications back to Concast. its companies as well. equipment for In the early years of customers to feed irxformation about equipment Concast in turn communicated this information to other customers. This system can be interpreted as an indirect barter system. Each equipment user contributes technical expertise to the network and gains access down when other users' expertise. The system, however, started to break community evolved and to the user the level of technical sophistication started to vary strongly between firms, leading to a perceived inequality of the exchange. Advantages of Barter The observation exchanged that many goods monetary compensation for are bartered in networks is puzzling economists have assumed barter to be an inferior to trade-for-money. A at first sight. mode and are not Traditionally, of exchange in comparison frequently cited argument in support of the supremacy of money-based exchange that barter requires finding a partner that is wants what one has and that has what one wants, the so called double coincidence of wants (Pearce, 1986; Samuelson, 1985). of A trade-for-money system, however, allows decomposition one barter transaction into two transactions No partners. double coincidence of wants is that may occur with different necessary. This , so the argument goes, reduces transaction frictions in comparison with a barter system. In the following, however, system. I argue that not The all advantages barter system has complexity of trading decisions advantages are discussed next. some is fall distinct on the side of the trade-for-money advantages as well, especially that the frequently reduced through barter. Three -15 (1) Barter decisions are of less complexity than corresponding trade-for-money decisions. A money-based exchange of two goods frequently requires considerable due sophistication to the transaction partners having to agree on a specific monetary valuation as transaction price. This might be simple for goods with well established market prices, but, Arrow (1971) argues that in it can be difficult for many unique goods, especially cases the value of a specific unit of information cannot be estimated without knowing the information. known, no further need for information. for acquiring it But once the information is exists. Barter does not require a quantification of value. transaction partners are able to order potential outcomes Barter requires only that the (i.e. according to their preferences. To establish ordinal rankings trade or is less no trade) cumbersome than to establish cardinal evaluations. This shall be exemplified using a simple case in which substantive contracting A manufacturer circuit boards. is has developed a Assume one possible. new printed circuit board technology for soldering components to And, assume another manufacturer B has improved existing technology considerably. Both firms would benefit from the other firm's technology. In a trade-for-money system the sale of the two technologies be linked. Each technology A's technology to B, determine its A is has to determine price. the final price for the transaction. Now and that its would not considered separately. For the decision whether to maximum buying considers selling testing A its minimum selling price and B has Subsequently both parties have similar set of decisions has to be sell to to negotiate made when B technology. assume both firms consider whether or not no additional transaction possibility is to barter their technologies considered at the same time.^ In this This argument assumes that both parties have identified the possibility to barter. The difficulty of identifying such possibilities creates one major obstacle to barter (Samuelson, 1985; Weizsacker, 1985). In the next section it will be shown that networks support the identification of barter possibilities. -16 case, the complexity of the trading decision whether or not they would be better two alternative. They merely have way to both it A and B deciding to quantify the value they attribute to rank order the alternatives. to the value of different alternatives, does not hold true the other reduced swapping technologies. These are the only offer The firms do not need decisions. is naturally can rank order If each a firm can quantify them But as well. this around. To be able to rank order two alternatives does not imply that the value of the alternatives can be quantified. Consequently, the decision whether to barter to trade the (2) goods for two goods is less complex than the decision whether money.^ Likelihood of valuation conflicts parties often quickly agree an is reduced. In contract negotiations, exchange would be mutually agree on the evaluation of the goods to be exchanged. This the good possessed by one party is of little beneficial, but fail to is especially a problem if or no value without the good possessed by the other party. In this case, the marginal value of each good is at the same time zero and equal to the joint value, thus creating considerable negotiation problems. Such situations arise, for example, in joint ventures specialized assets (Teece, 1986). One both parties provide co- party might provide market access and the other party technology, both goods being of situation, agreeing if little value without the other. In such a on barter and avoiding the need to agree on valuations increases greatly the likelihood that the parties will engage in a mutually beneficial exchange. Conflicts over valuations are thus avoided (von Weizsacker, 1985). (3) Barter communicates less information about firms' valuations. course of price negations, each party conveys considerable information to negotiation partner (Raiffa, 1982). To know The more fine-grained the barter problem is In the its the approximate price a competitor framed, the more it is approaches the complexity of the the smallest units to be bartered equal the smallest monetary the parties frame the barter decisions in these units, then both decisions are of related trade-for-money decisions. If units, and if comparable complexity. But frequently the units considered are not as fine-grained. -17- willing to pay for a specific technology can convey information about the competitor's technology strategy and technical capabilities. Negotiations in a barter system potentially convey less information. The transaction partners gain intelligence of each other's ordinal rankings, but not of the absolute valuations of Consequently, the different alternatives. convey less in a negotiation process to another to favor barter information a company wants company, the more it might be inclined over trade-for-money. money-based exchange of In conclusion, a difficult-to-price goods such as market access or technical know-how confronts the firms involved with highly complex decision problems. Using a barter based instead of a money based one reduces (once the barter possibility is mode in the that abstracting the complexity of these decisions considerably identified), thus decreasing the direct contracting costs from the difficulties to Yet, accuracy, then mode if it can be determine prices, a barter system can lead to inefficiencies in the allocation of resources, especially divisible. exchange of exchange and increasing the chance of reaching a positive agreement. However, shown to if goods are non- the firm-specific value of the goods cannot be determined with it is not meaningful to argue that barter than a money-based exchange; it is a less efficient allocation might be the only one acceptable to the decision makers involved. How Networks Support Barter One of the disadvantages of barter (Pearce, 1986, p. 36) is is that a "double coincidence of wants" required for a successful transaction. Networks reduce the severity of this disadvantage. First, frequent interactions help network members to develop a good understanding of potential contributions and needs of other members, thereby 18 increasing the likelihood of recognizing the possibility for a mutually beneficial exchange. In addition, institutions to support the identification of barter possibilities are frequently created. regular meetings, and informal Such contacts. institution may be industry directories, Oil-exploration firms, for example, individuals specifically to trade information informally (Schrader & employ von Hippel, forthcoming). These employees, the so called oil-scouts, are organized in professional associations oil-scouts report prior on the week without and meet regularly, i.e. once a week. In these meetings, the drilling activities that their firms revealing the data gathered. to identify trading possibilities. on a one-to-one basis undertook during the In other words, the meetings help After the meeting, individual scouts might arrange to barter specific data. Second, networks provide an institutional setting to enforce commitments, generating the possibility for a temporal separation of the quid-pro-quo. In a network, two goods do not need to be bartered simultaneously. Rather, one party can provide the other party with a good while obliging the receiver to of the barter at an appropriate time in the future. and its risks own part Powerful mechanisms are available to enforce the fulfillment of such commitments. member fulfill its both the direct relationship to the party that A is non-cooperative to receive the benefit, reputation in the network (Axelrod, 1984; Hardin, 1982). Thus, not to honor commitments can lead The resulting to considerable network disadvantages (Jarillo, 1988).^ possibility for a temporal separation of contributions reduces the restricting effect of the have matching wants double coincidence of wants. The exchange partners need not at a given point in time. Barter is possible as long as they can expect that over time their (appropriately discounted) needs match. ^ Bhide and Stevenson (1990) doubt that these mechanisms really work. They speculate that parties fulfill their obligations t)ecause they feel morally obliged to do so and not because of any economic rational. 19 Third, networks support not only discrete barter but are especially effective for Networks can provide powerful frames relational barter. establishing procedures Thus, the and norms for relational contracts by for interaction (Aldrich, 1979; Tichy, 1981). (explicit or implicit) barter contract can be limited to a few special concerns, thereby reducing transaction costs. Fourth, tight-knit networks with high interdependence between members its frequently provide the possibility to turn one-to-one barter into a one-to-group barter, thereby eliminating the requirement for a double-coincidence of wants. those networks, one without expecting member might provide another member with to receive a service provision, however, the member from other members fulfills its The network the network other — even network if role thus legitimizing possibility of obtaining and to obtain or service membership no dyadic trading relationship benefits its goods and participants barter their contribution for the right to be a members (von Weizsacker, In good back from that specific member. Through the membership. The membership provides the services a In is formed. member of — created through contributions by 1985). sum, networks encourage the emergence of barter by providing a frame identifying barter possibilities. They increase the chance of barter by allowing for a temporal separation of contributions and by offering mechanisms for inducing cooperative behavior. They reduce the costs of barter contracts by having related procedures of interaction and relationship norms anchored in the network. Tightknit networks may even eliminate the need for a double coincidence of wants. Without networks, barter is difficult to realize. partners with matching wants can be The identification of potential barter cumbersome (Samuelson, 1985). Temporal separation of transactions creates considerable contract enforcement problems. And possible difficulties of precisely identifying the substance of the barter provides a challenge to the contracting process. 20 The barter-supporting characteristic of networks helps to explain the recent emergence of networks for management All these goods are difficult-to-value The practices. characteristics of such mode exchanging goods such technology, market access, and goods strongly favor and difficult-to-specify. relational barter as the interaction instead of traditional ones like purchasing agreements and simple licensing As shown, contracts. barter is difficult to establish if not supported by networks. Consequently, firms that want to exchange difficult-to-value goods are induced establish inter-firm networks such as alliances, partnerships, and to joint ventures to provide the framework supportive of barter. Mutual Reinforcement of Networks and Barter Two paths can lead from the identification of potential barter-possibilities to the establishment of barter-supporting networks. First, may firms establish network-type relationships to establish a governance support of barter transactions. This is many a central motivation of cooperation only vaguely hoping that once the network difficult to determine and realize specific barter Daimler Benz and Mitsubishi set framework in strategic Frequently, firms enter alliances after having identified areas of potential alliances. was consciously up in 1990, the firms is The a case in point (Sanger, 1990). merely agreed this, established possibilities. it will alliance When be less between this alliance to cooperate, leaving to the individual business units the task of determining specific market exchanged. In cases like is skills and technologies to be the establishment of networks drives the emergence of barter transactions. Barter transactions, however, can also drive the establishment of networks. common Repeated interaction interaction and stabilization fosters trust (Axelrod, 1984), the formation of norms (Ullmann-Margalit, 1977), and the evolution of a shared 21 language (Hall, 1959), networks. all of these supporting the establishment and stabilization of In the very beginnings of the oil-exploration industry, firms a one-to-one basis valuable geological exchanged on and geophysical information, each exchange being independent of other interactions. Over time, the reoccurrence of such transactions led to the evolution of informal inter-firm networks. Later, these informal networks became institutionalized in the form of oil-scout-associations that provide a framework for the barter transactions. Once networks are established successfully, they are self-reinforcing. They support the identification of further barter possibilities and, due to the repeated occurrence of like interactions, reduce the transaction costs of individual transactions. Consequently, the overall number of transactions This, in turn, strengthens the networks even further. (1973) has shown demonstrated for personal for the some circumstances lies However, likely to increase. as Granovetter networks and as Glasmeier (forthcoming) has Swiss watch industry, this continual reinforcement can under actually be the cause for the long-term decline of the network. The network may become overly information that is beyond its self-centered, unable to detect and access realm of expertise. Figure 3 summarizes the discussed relationship between barter and the establishment of networks. It demonstrates the existence of different paths towards the establishment and/or stabilization of networks. facilitate the identification and And it shows that networks assist the realization of barter possibilities. 22 Identification of potential possibilities to exchange goods difficult to price 23- Conclusion This paper proposes that firms frequently use network-type relationships such as strategic alliances and partnerships to barter difficult-to-price goods technical know-how, market understanding, and management practices. like The paper argues that barter has some distinct advantages over a money-based exchange for such goods — as long as the double coincidence of wants is given. Under such circumstances, barter requires decisions of less cognitive complexity than are necessary in the context of a money-based exchange system. Networks support barter through allowing temporal separation of transactions, facilitating identification of transaction possibilities, and establishing mechanisms to enforce cooperative behavior. The paper suggests modes increases the opportunities may that the inclusion of barter in a firm's number of potential transactions. Some beneficial transaction not be realized without considering barter. however, that barter is for It is always the preferred transaction mode. In especially in situations in goods are available, mix of transaction which not argued, many situations, and widely accepted valuations of "objective" example through market prices, a trade-for-money has considerable transaction advantages. Network structures support the barter of such valuable difficult-to-price goods as technology and other organizational and at the skills. same time Many researchers have suggested that these goods are of increasing importance for the competitiveness of firms (Dertouzos, Lester, 1984). Since, as Solow, 1989; Hayes & Wheelwright, argued above, these goods are frequently more easily bartered than traded for money, firms that are not set up be are. at a «& disadvantage to those firms that to participate in barter transactions might Networks provide a context within which organizations can enter cooperative trading relationships based on a mix 24- between trade-for-money and possibilities and induce incentives to decide time, but rather on barter. Networks support the identification of barter actors to forgo opportunistic behavior. interaction strategies not They provide by evaluating one transaction by considering the potential stream of transactions within the network. Thereby, cooperative behavior The barter-supporting quality of networks augments the majority of the In some both barter and transaction costs explanations supplement each other. may fulfill several functions at the same may be time, encouraging barter only one framework for understanding networks. than one purpose, more than one explanation The proposition that barter is is it is not enough to consider Since networks may serve more needed. the preferred transaction mode if prices are impossible to determine implies that those conventional control and decision practices relying fail Other created only to support barter or only to overcome transaction problems of markets or hierarchies. This suggests that difficult or cases, Some transactions and, for example, allowing relationship specific investments. networks occur encouraged. is transaction-cost-based explanations for the existence of networks. networks may that at a on prices in barter-supporting networks. and related quantitative measures are likely to In this case other, more process oriented control measures might be needed. This conclusion has considerable management ramifications and should encourage the study of how to govern such networks. 25 References Aldrich, H.E. (1979) Prentice-Hall. Or ganizations and environments Englewood . Arrow, K.J. (1971) Essays in the theory of risk-bearing Chicago: Publications. . Axelrod, R. (1984) The evolution of cooperation . New Cliffs, N.J.: Markham York: Basic Books. & Freeman, J. (1990) A preliminary analysis of strategic alliances in commercial biotechnology Working Paper No. mimeo, Cornell University, Barley, S.R., . Ithaca. Why Bhide, A., & Stevenson, H.H. (1990) Business Review, 68(5), 121-129. Carter, A. P. (1989) Knowhow be honest if honesty doesn't pay. Harvard trading as economic exchange. Research Policy, 18, 155- 163. Coase, R.H. (1937) The nature of the firm. Economica, DeBresson, C, & 4, 386-405. (forthcoming) Networks of innovators: introduction to the issue. Research Policy Amesse, F. A review and . Dertouzos, M.L., Lester, R.K., & Solow, R.M. (1989) productive edge Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press. Made in America: Regaining the . Dimancescu, D., & Botkin, J. (1986) The new alliance: America's Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger Publishing Co. Furukawa, firm K., R&D R&D consortia . Y., & Kanda, M. (1990) Network organization for interExperiences of Japanese small businesses. International Teramoto, activities: Journal of Technology Management, 5, 27-40. in Geschaftsbeziehungen und Netzwerken Working Paper, Universitat Karlsruhe (TH), Institut fiir Angewandte Betriebswirtschaftslehre und Unternehmensfiihrung, Karlsruhe. Gemiinden, H.G. (1990) Innovationen . Glasmeier, A. (forthcoming) Technological discontinuities and flexible production networks: The case of Switzerland and the world watch industry. Research Policy, , Granovetter, M.S. (1973) The strength of weak ties. American Journal of Sociology, 78(6), 1360-1380. Hakansson, H. (1987) (Ed.). Industrial technological development: approach ed.). London: Croom Helm. Hall, E.T. (1959) The silent language . New A network York: Doubleday. Hamel, G., Doz, Y.L., & Prahalad, C.K. (1989) Collaborate with your competitors and win. Harvard Business Review. 67(1), 133-139. — -26- Hardin, R. (1982) Collective action Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press. . Hayes, R.H., & Wheelwright, S.C. (1984) Restoring our competitive edge: Competing through manufacturing New York: John Wiley. . (1988) Jarillo, J.C. On strategic networks. Strategic Management Journal, 9, 31-41. Joskow, P.L. (1987) Contract duration and relationship-specific investments: Empirical evidence from coal markets. American Economic Review, 77 168-185. , Klein, B., Crawford, R.G., & Alchian, A.A. (1978) Vertical integration, appropriable rents, and the competitive contracting process. Journal of Law and Economics, 21, 297-326. Leadbeater, C. (1990) The paradox of free markets. Financial Times, 11/19/1990, Luke, R.D., Begun, J.W., & Pointer, D.D. (1989) Quasi firms: Strategic interorganizational forms in the health care industry. Academy of Review, Macaulay, Management 14, 9-19. (1963) Non-contractual relations in business: S. American Sociological Review, A preliminary study. 28, 55-69. & MacMillan, K., Farmer, D. (1979) Redefining the boundaries of the firm. Journal of Industrial Economics, 27, 277-285. MacNeil, Adjustment of long-term economic relations under neoclassical, and contract law. Northwestern University Law Review, I.R. classical, (1978) Contracts: 72, 854-906. MacNeil, I.R. relations . The new social contract: An inquiry Haven: Yale University Press. (1980) New into Markoff, J. (1990) I.B.M. joins Siemens in developing chips. 01/25/1990, D1,D18. modern New contractual York Times, Ouchi, W.G. (1980) Markets, Bureaucracies, and Clans. Administrative Science Quarterly, 25. 129-141. Ouchi, W.G., California & Bolton, M.K. (1988) Management Review, The logic of joint research and development. 30(3), 9-33. D.W. (1986) (Ed.). The MIT dictionary of modern economics Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press. Pearce, (3. ed.). M. (1958) Personal knowledge: Towards a post-critical philosophy Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Polanyi, . Porter, M.E. (1990) The competitive advantage of nations. Harvard Business Review. 68(2), 73-93. The Art and Science of Negotiation Cambridge, Mass., London, Harvard University Press. Raiffa, H. (1982) Engl.: Roberts, E.B. (1980) 58(4), 134-142. . New ventures for corporate growth. Harvard Business Review. -T7- Rogers, E.M. (1982) Information exchange and technological innovation. In D. Sahal (Ed.), The transfer and utilization of technical knowledge (105-123). Lexington, Mass.: Lexington Books. Samuelson, P. A. (1985) Economics New (12. ed.). York: McGraw-Hill. Sanger, D.E. (1990) Daimler-Benz and Mitsubishi negotiating cooperative plan. York Times, 3/7/1990, Al, D5. New Saxenian, A. (1989) Re gional networks and the resurgence of Silicon Valley Working Paper No. mimeo. University of California at Berkeley, Department of City and Regional Planning, Berkeley, Cal. . S. (1991) Informal technology transfer between firms: Cooperation through iriformation trading. Research Policy, 20, 153-170. Schrader, Schrader, S., & von Hippel, E. (forthcoming) Information trading among rivals: The case of oil-exploration firms Working Paper, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Alfred P. Sloan School of Management. . Teece, D.J. (1986) Profiting from technological innovation: Implications for integration, collaboration, licensing and public policy. Research Policy, 15, 285305. Thorelli, H.B. (1986) Management Tichy, N.M. (Ed.), and Journal, (1981) 7, 37-51. Networks Handbook their Networks: Between markets and hierarchies. Strategic in organizations. In P.C. of organizational design. environments (225-249). Ullmann-Margalit, E. (1977) New Volume Nystrom & W.H. Starbuck 2: Remodeling organizations York: Oxford University Press. The emergence of norms Oxford: Oxford University . Press. von Hippel, E. (1987) Research Policy. Cooperation between rivals: Informal know-how trading. 16, 291-302. von Weizsacker, C.C. (1985) Zeit und Geld: Eine Skizze Photocopy, Unversitat . Bern, Bern. Williamson, O.E. (1975) Markets and hierarchies: Analysis and antitrust implications New York: Free Press. . Williamson, O.E. (1985) The economic institutions of capitalism: Firms, markets, relational contracting . New York: Free Press. 55U U70 wn 3 LIBRARIES DUPl TOaO 007M731D 6 Date Due ^^ 2.0 \^ jm, 9 1 fm \dd^ )ffR^ o-? m-'''"'' ^0^' OCT "" I 3 II » 111" II I" i{aw'ii:'i«l"tiWI \a\vuii ^060 007M7310 fi