• / CENTER FOR COMPUTATIONAL RESEARCH IN ECONOMICS AND MANAGEMENT SCIENCE Competition and Human Capital Accumulation: A Theory of Interregional Specialization and Trade Julio J. Rotemberg Massachusetts Institute of Technology Garth Saloner Massachusetts Institute of Technology and Harvard University WP#3101-89 December 1989 Competition and Human Capital Accumulation: A Theory of Interregional Specialization and Trade Julio J. Rotemberg Massachusetts Institute of Technology Garth Saloner Massachusetts Institute of Technology and Harvard University WP#3101-89 December 1989 M.I.T. MAR 1J3RARIES 1 5 1990 ! Human Competition and A Theory Capital Accumulation: of Interregional Specialization and Trade Julio J. * Rotemberg Massachusetts Institute of Technology Garth Saloner Massachusetts Institute of Technology and Harvard University Current version: December 13, 1989 Abstract We consider a model with several regions whose technological ability and endowments are identical and in negligible. Nonetheless, certain all faw:tor which transport costs between regions are non- goods are sometimes produced by multiple firms of which are located in the ssone region. These goods are then exported from the regions in which their production is agglomerated. Regional agglomeration of production 2Lnd trade stem from two forces. the services of trained workers is First, competition between firms for necessary for the workers to recoup the cost of acquiring industry-specific humain capital. Second, the technology of production is more demand efiicient is when plamts are larger th£m a insufficient to niinimum eflBcient scale support several firms of that scale. We and local also study the policy implications of our model. *We wish to thank Ken Froot, D&vid Sch&r{itein, and Larry Sununer* for helpful convenationi and the National Science Foundation and the Sloan Foundation for financial lupport. Human Competition and A Theory Capital Accumulation: of Interregional Trade Julio J. Rotemberg Garth Saloner Regional agglomeration ize in the in the production of goods production of watches and chocolates; Silicon Valley iaute couture, and movies originate disproportionately the Swiss special- pervasive: is in computers; and shoes, in Italy, Paris, and Hollywood respectively. Regional specialization extends even to product subcategories. mobiles, liixury sedans tend to come from Germany, sports czirs from Within auto- Italy, and reliable forms of basic transportation from Japan. While, as the Heckscher-Ohlin model has some of this regional agglomeration results it is difficult from differences in factor it, endowments, much of to explain in that mzmner. For example, regional specialization in industrial products such as shoes and watches does not seem to be driven by the abundance of any particular factor. The standao-d alternative explzmation of regional agglomeration (e.g. Mju^hall (1920), Melvin (1969), Markusen and Melvin (1981) and Ethier (1982)) the output of an individual firm is Izo-ger the larger is is that, for given inputs, the aggregate output of other firms producing the szmae good in the saime region. So, for example, the level of inputs required by a new watchmaker to produce a given output Switzerland where there are other watch manufacturers. have shown that external returns of seem to A this type is lower Romer if that entrant locates in (1986) and Lucas (1988) can also explain the fact that some nations remain forever more advanced than others. possible source of external economies of this kind is the spillover of knowledge i.e., the possibility that knowledge acquired by one agent can be used by others. In order for knowledge spillovers to provide a compelling explanation, however, that they are somehow localized. If an engineer in it must be the case Taiwjm can reverse engineer a product of Silicon Valley as easily as an inhabitant of Silicon Valley, there is no good reason for regional concentration of computer companies. Marshall (1920) posits instead that the external economies arise from proximity to specialized inputs. As noted by Helpman and Krugman comparative advantage is incomplete. The for the puzzle is (1985), unless there is a natural production of these inputs in the region, this explanation simply rolled back to the previous production stage: Why do the producers of inputs locate in the region? Our theory is that the location decisions of the firms and their input suppliers are interdependent. Input suppliers find it advantageous to be located where they have potential customers because competition a fair return. In among their downstrecim customers severa.! assures them the absence of such competition, the relatively immobile suppliers would be subject to the monopsony power of the downstream power would be used to drive down input monopsony firms. Foreseeing that would not prices, potential input suppliers choose to invest ex ante in the accumulation of the capital necessary to supply the inputs efficiently. This critical role of competition in securing a return to suppliers is one of the elements in Porter's (1989) broad treatbe on regional agglomeration. For concreteness, the particular input we focus on •which to cut If is diamonds or the skills which capital a new chocolate concoction. several potential employers, they will be paid as a By contrast, if there is only one potential employer, impossible to write contracts that specify the level of training, there (in this industry or elsewhere). is no reason The hold-up problem described by Willizjnson (1975) Confronted with the prospect of a single potential employer, workers do not find worthwhile to accumulate human themselves refrain from entering The industry cam only If human monopeonist to pay trained employees any more than untrained employees earn for this arises. facilitate the creation of among function of their marginal product. it is industry specific costly for individuals to acquire, such as the specific hand-eye coordination needed trained workers can choose and is there is a capital. if Moreover, if entry by firms is it costly, firms will they can expect to be the only firm in the industry. exist with several closely located competitors. minimum efficient scale below which each firm cannot operate profitably, the necessity of having severzd competing firms for an industry to be viable implies that the region's output itself may be may have to be substantial. In particular, insufficient to accommodate the among of ensuring competition We produce for the world market. regions with the firms is it is number to have several of in the them access to the producing region Then the only way locate in one region and of firms. show that trade emerges between same endowments and are transport costs and requisite demand spatially sepjirated same technology even though there technologically feasible to produce all of a region's consumption locally.^ Our theory involves an externality. The presence firm to have access to suitable workers. of other firms is necessary for each However, unlike the alternative theory of trade based on external returns, we do not require that the presence of other firms lower the input requirement for producing output. Instead, the technology for producing output the same in all regions. Because ea^h firm needs other firnas to be present for workers to might be though that omi model has multiple equilibria b we This would be true and Saloner (1985), sequentially so that, through their ax:tions, they czm other. This makes which production of the external returns it is some we model trained, it of which no firm produces. made simultane- firms as mzJting this choice communicate their intentions to each impossible for equilibria with no production to coexist with others in positive. most important implications of the is in become insisted that the entry decisions of firms all be ously. Instead, following Farrell One is that nations can be made worse traditional theory of trade based off as a result of trade (see on Graham (1923) and Ethier (1982)). In our model such losses from trade are possible as well. These losses are intimately linked to the existence of multiple equilibria. In some agglomerated equilibria) only one region produces the good even though, good is produced can be worse off. in equilibria (the in autarky, the both regions. At these agglomerated equilibria the importing region In our model this happens because there are transportation costs so that an imported good costs more than a locally produced good. In Ethier (1982) it occurs 'Note that while monopiony power playi * role in our ttory, our formal model U rather different {rom tboee in the eiirlier on monoptony and trade (Feeratra (1980), Markuien and Robion (1080), McCulloch and Yellen (1980)). In thote model* monopioniitt are active in equilibrium. By contrait, in our model, the only •ectort that arc viable in •quilibrium have several flrmi competing for labor. literature when one can lead region produces nothing other than the good subject to external returns. This its price in terms of the other produced more We show efficiently) good to rise relative to autarky (even because factor demands rise in the agents to tell ea^ other that they would decision whether to ers from trade are not mechanism that allows the produce the good subject to the exter- like to Formally, losses from trade can occur in our model nality.^ it is producing region. that, in our context at least, the equilibria with losses robust. They, again, depend crucially on the absence of any though if workers must make their become trained simultaneously. To capture the possibility that work- can conmiunicate their intentions to each other we consider a variant of our model which workers become trained in sequence. In this case, the equilibrium is in unique and trade can only be beneficial. One difference between our theory in the role ascribed to antitrust policy. policy can be socially desirable. and the traditional external returns approa^ is In the traditional theory, relaxation of antitrust Cooperation among firms can lead them to internalize whatever externality leads the production by one firm to lower the input requirements of the others. This logic has led Jorde and Teece (1988), for excimple, to conclude that antitrust exemptions axe essential for certain a world By tion. contrast, in our theory as well as in Porter (1989), society benefits from competi- willing they are to make Section 1 firms the potential suppliers of labor expect, the promoting the creation of viable export industries. in presents the simple peirtial equilibrium setting in which workers decide multaneously whether to acquire industry in general equilibrium of goods we discuss if si- Section 2 embeds this identical regions. That the patterns of trade that emerge as the and the nimiber of regions that trade present our argument that 'The low specific himicin capital. and considers trade among ex ante section has several subsections in which we more industry specific investments. Thus a vigorous antitrust policy can play an important role number high-technology industries to succeed in scale. The more competition among model US varies. In one of these subsections workers decide whether to become trained in sequence. welfare-low activity equDibria in the rather different pecuniary externality modelt of Murphy, Shleifer and Viahny (1089) lack robuitneu for the lame rea«on every region benefits from trade. In section 4 we consider the and industrial policy, tariffs, governments pursue to policy implications of our theory. In particular encompasses those antitrust. Industrial policy imposing them. The reason that the goods subject to the is externality are sometimes produced disproportionately in one region. of transport costs implies that regions benefit policies that In our model, such policies can affect the location of industries. raise welfare in the region we study But, the presence from having such goods produced locally. Therefore, policies that ensure local production of these goods can be desirable from the region's point of view. While tsu-iffs can be a tool of industrial where they do not from such beacuse they improve the importer's terms of trade. However, who workers in the exporting region incentive to become trained. foresee that tariffs will be levied, have a smaller So, the perception that equilibrium price of the good in the exporting region. tariflFs will We show be imposed raises the that, as a result, tariffs which are foreseen when workers seek training unambiguously lower welfare This strengthens Lapan (1988) 's argument against 1. The Partial Equilibrium We assume that skilled duction. The in both regions. tariffs. Model labor and entrepreneurial activities are the only factors of pro- "entrepreneur" , who is also a skilled worker, necessary to create the firm and enable has disutility of effort tztriff" have become trained, importers after workers in the other region tariffs in situations The usual "optimum affect the regional pattern of production. argument implies that, benefit can also be imposed policy, they c for it to function. performing those must perform preparatory work We activities. If assume that the entrepreneur he is successful in creating a firm that actually operates, however, he derives utility of v from his success. Thus v—e, which we assume entrepreneur. We focus to be positive, is the net utility from becoming a successful mainly on the case where u —e is arbitrarily small. below, the role of these assumptions on the costs and benefits of managing As we is shall see to eliminate the indifference between producing and remaining idle that characterizes stjmdard zeroprofit competitive equilibria. We siispect that introducing even a 5 minimal level of market power would have The other essentially the same factor of production is effect. At the margin, each skilled labor. skilled worker can produce one unit of output. However, one of the central parameters in our analysis is minimum the efficient scale of assuming that, to produce at himself he must hire (i.e., capture the presence of the entrepreneur must employ all, 5—1 We production. additional skilled workers). successful, so that he receives v in utility, if his firm has An S S skilled more ihan S. These assumptions can be formalized L{eS) = skilled workers. L{es) where L{Q) S is when is thus deemed 5 is a measure the firm produces as follows: =S if e = es if e>i L{S) workers including entrepreneur of Tnin imiim efficient scale, but there are constamt returns to scale by efficient scale <1, the amount of labor required to produce and (1) (2) Q units. determines the number of firms that the industry can accommodate. If S zero is then production exhibits constjmt returns to scale globally and an arbitrarily large number of firms can be present at the accommodate at most a same time. For very single firm, S the indiistry can a natural monopoly. In between, the number i.e., it is of firms that can operate in equilibrium large values of falls as S increases. In order to obtain the requisite skills to be useful in this industry a worker must obtain training at a cost of h to himself. ly in If the worker chooses not to obtain training, he can earn an alternative occupation. Thus a worker can earn w+h will only be willing to become trained if he in this industry. The entrepreneur is the sole residual claimant of the firm: he collects revenues from customers and pays the other workers. So, in addition to his net utility from performing the entrepreneurial function, he earns whatever profits there are in equilibriimi. Despite the fact that the "entrepreneur" receives both the profits and the net utility of success, for clarity in decision to what follows we shall refer to the entrepreneur as the agent form a firm and enter the industry, and the firm who makes the as the agent that, once created by the entrepreneur, makes the operational decisions of the firm such as what wages to off"er workers. 6 The quantity of this product that What matters for the and minimum efRcient scale 5. demanded equals D{P) where is form of equilibrium outcomes w + h, D{w + h). Then In particular, let: is the price. the relationship between is In particular, consider the marginal cost P demand when the outcomes depend on the ratio of demand price equals D{w + h) to 5. ^.i„t(^(^) where "int" denotes "the integer part oP Then we . will (3) show that the form of the equilibria depends on N. Our goal is to contrast the industry outcome industry - and hence it is when there is only a single firm in the a monopsony purchziser of skilled labor - with one in which wage competition firms compete for skilled workers. Since to attract workers is a critical firms' strategies in bidding for workers. By contrast, strategic interzwrtions in the output market are unessential to our argument. We aspect of our theory, we explicitly examine more than one firm therefore assume that whenever there fictitious Walrasian auctioneer which clears the output market. however, we in the make the natural assumption that output market The timing in is it is in the indxistry there exists If there able to exercise its is a only one firm, monopoly power in the \isual way. our model is as follows: N First, individuals decide to become en- trepreneurs and perform the prepjo-atory work necessary for creating their firms (incurring disutility e in the process). to obtain training. We Second, workers, including the entrepreneurs, decide whether denote the number of workers firms simultaneotisly announce wages for. If two or more firms {tZ'i, offer the highest . . . , who obtain training by L. Third, the Fourth, workers decide t^ i&}- whom to work wage, workers ase assumed to spread themselves uniformly across those firms. Finally, production takes place and goods are sold at a price P which the Walrasian auctioneer Our subgame sets to clear the goods market. perfect equilibrium requires that: Workers make optimal training decisions; (iii) (i) Entrepreneurs are successful; (ii) Firms choose {u;i,...,u>j^} to maximize * We could have com idcred another itage in which flrmi decide which of their worken they actually uk to produce goods. Thii would not change the analysis: the firms woukj ask all their workers to produce. The reason is that labor is the only factor of production and labor costs are sunk at the time the decision of how much to produce is made. profits; ajid (iv) We workers make optimal employment decisions given {tuj,.. ,tD^}. . consider two cases separately. while in the latter case to produce at minimum Case when efficient scale The is greater than or equal to 2 feasible for it is the "competitive" price is a natural monopoly. that, for v sufficiently close to c, the equilibrium has (i): We show smaller. In the former case N industry latter case that 1.1. it Ls In the first case is not feasible: two or more firms w+h prevails. In the N >2 N firms and produces the "competitive" outcome. In paxticulair, prices and wages equal marginal resource costs (including training), exactly the do w^ number required we this, P= = tv -\- h, and the number of workers who obtain training to satisfy market demand at that price {L begin by exogenously specifying the number of entrepreneurs and examine equilibria of the To that enter, subgames that ensue. We informally describe why the competitive outcome A we In Appendix Consider first e the entry decision of entrepreneurs. by entering as long as TV view, anticipating wages of w+ h (and receiving a wage of employment at en equilibrium of the subgame. B we show that it is the only in equilibrium. break even as long as they can produce at — is provide a formal proof and in Appendix one that can emerge cost N h)). 2<N <N {a) gain v — D{w + is h, is minimum in the h) = w+ eflBcient scale. h = w*, firms Thus entrepreneurs range specified. From the workers' point of any worker w+ With P* is indifferent between getting trained at a and not becoming trained and taking alternative a wage w. Moreover, since all firms offer the same wage in equilibrium, workers are happy to spread themselves uniformly across the firms. Thus workers have no incentive to deviate. attracts w + h. no workers,^ Finally, consider the firms: If a firm unilaterally lowers its if it raises its wage it loses money on each sale since then tD,- wage it > P* = So the firms have no incentive to deviate. precise, the firm kttrmcta no worken vith the pouible exception of the •ntrcpreneur hmuelf. If 5 > 1 thi* eniure that the firm doein't deviate by lowering the wage. If 5 = 1 the *flrm" can offer the "entrepreneur" (in hii role ai •killed worker) «< + /t - (v - e) and itill attract him. Even in thia extreme ca«c, however, the amount by which the wage can fall below tu -t- A vaniBhei as v - ( vaniihei. *To be more will 8 To understajid the motivations of the agents, consider first the firms' wage announce- Any ments. In equilibrium the firms correctly anticipate the market clearing price. it believes that are offering wages below the equilibrium market price, will its rivals a tiny amount more than the highest wage being offered by a offer firm, workers, and thereby maximize itself rival, attract all the This logic drives the firms to bid the wage its profits. up to what they believe the market if That clearing price will be. to say, they behave is analogously to Bertrand rivals in homogeneous goods output mzu-kets. The workers, which will be set to clear the market given that correctly anticipate that the training wage at understand that the wage for their part, xintil the number which a worker is wage will equal L will be bid up to the price workers are employed. They therefore D~^{L). Therefore, additional workers obtain trained workers drives the mzu'ket clearing price willing to become trained and work Although the industry can accommodate up to down in this industry, to the w+ h. N firms in the competitive equilibrium, the competitive outcome can be sustained with just two firms in the industry and the entry of additional firms doesn't affect the price or is wage that results (as long as because Bertrand competition drives the equilibrium wage to the two firms price with jxist Firms make zero in the N < N). This level of the final goods market. profits in equilibrium. However, entrepreneurs not indifferent about producing. They derive utility v who have entered are from producing. Therefore, each entrepreneur tries to attract suflBcient workers to produce at least S. So, trained workers can feel sure that entrepreneurs the wage to {h) w+ who have h. N> N The only possible equilibria have the for V sufficiently close to e there N > N. entered will compete for their services and drive To do this we suppose, is wage equal and 'The proof in (ii) fewer than in contradiction, that Appendix B NS workers do. kppliei to thii ca*e u ly + h. We show, however, that no equilibrium where the wage equals seriatim, the possibility that an equilibrium exists training, to well. 9 the wage equals where (i) NS or w+h w -\- h when and consider, more workers obtain If NS workers or more obtain training and all obtain employment in this industry the market clearing price is equal to D~^{NS) < w + h. But then the firms produce, the if all workers are spread evenly over the firms and the entrepreneurs earn v — e-\-D~*^{NS) — {w + h). For If sufficiently close to c, this expression t; NS fewer than be successful, workers obtain training is D~^{NS) < w + h).^ negative (becaiise not possible for it is all N entrepreneurs to there are insuCBcient trained workers for every entrepreneur i.e., who entered to produce at minimimi efficient scale. But then the unsuccessful entrepreneurs could have done better by not entering (and saving the {c) If N= disutility of effort c). 1 only one firm has entered amd some number of workers, L, has obtained training, the firm will pay them just slightly above their alternative wage w and charge a price equal to: jmx{D~^{L),&igmaixD{z){z-w)}. The first expression is relevant and charges a price which very lairge will of course, is small so that the firm hires clears the mao-ket. The second expression is after the workers have obtained training, no-one has work for this firm because they first place. entrepreneur suffers in vain his disutility of effort when L is an incentive to deviate: compensated result, for their training costs, This in turn means that the single Entry that entrepreneurs gain utility in equilibrium N but lose utility otherwise. of entrepreneurs As relevant e. We have discussed these outcomes by fixing the and is the trained workers do not have a viable alternative. The that, anticipating that they will not be workers do not obtain training in the (d) all so that the firm can act in the usual monopoly fashion in the goods market. Note that Workers when L (4) in other who We now if the initial nimiber of firms and have shown number of them who enter is between 2 turn our attention to the question of the number will enter initially. models of external economies, the entry decision of firms is subject to *Thc remkininc c««e« here - thow where tome of the tntined worker* arc not employed in thii indiutiy, or where tome of the who have entered do not produce - are unintereitinf the worken who end up unemployed and the entrepreneur! who do not produce in equilibnum could have done better by not obtaining training or not entering retpectively. entrepreneur! 10 a coordination problem. enter, then that it it potential firm If won't enter either. t believes that the only firm that enters, potential workers If it is would end up paying a wage of u; and will lose e. If, know on the other hand, firm believes that another firm will enter, then workers will obtain the necessary training, the entrepreneur will gain v We follow Farrell whether to enter — will Thus the firm not become trained. would not have a workforce and the entrepreneur would » no other potential entrants and e. and Saloner (1985) and assume that potential entrants must decide in sequence, the second potential entrant decides whether to enter i.e., only after he knows whether the first can communicate their intentions potential entrant will enter. This ensures that firms vis-a-vis entry through their actions. In the case where only a few firms will ever enter this seems more appealing than maJcing all firms decide whether to enter simultaneously. That assumption forces firms to maJce their decision in the absence of any information about what other firms are planning. sequential entry the Farrell and Saloner (1985) reasoning eliminates no-entry With N. equilibria in this case. Indeed, the only equilibrium has ff equal to All entrepreneurs that can possibly receive positive utility in equilibrium enter. Since the JV'th entrant enjoys positive utility v in fact — e by entering been a prior entrant, it if another entrepreneur has already entered, enters too. But then any b that the first N entrepreneurs enter. firms enter because the JV Case 1.2. This two firms price as (ii): is I'st For suflBciently small t; - e too. — e no more entrant would be sure to suffer a loss in the second major case, the natural monopoly case, where minimum hi this case the industry above, there a single firm. t; knowing The than N utility. N <2 to both produce at w -\-h. we saw + there has prior potential entrant, that the JV'th entrepreneur will follow, enters and obtains net utility of result if We is is efficient scale S and in impossible for also sell at the competitive not viable under laissez no equilibrium it is faire. The reason is that, which workers become trained when there also demonstrated that firms cannot break even when M the number is of th«r« U an interval of time *In fact, it U not necewary for the »«iuencing of movM to be exogenously (peeined. A* long during which entry can take place, if flmu endogenou»ly aelect when to enter the lame outcome r«»ulti. Farrell and Saloner (1985) also ihow that itraw polU can have et»entially the iame effect aa tequential entry in their model. 11 existing firms N exceeds N. Therefore, equilibria with more than one active firm also fail to exist. Discussion 1.3. The model results of the The competitive outcome emerges. when competitive output who become trained of entrepreneurs competition so that b is price be sunmiarized as follows. caji is social mau-ginal resource costs are equal to those costs who can wage up drives the to w+h. minimum If, firms operating at minimum is become h, and the of workers and D{w + h) < 2S hauid, efficient scale No when price firms enter and hence they have no trained. training before they have had ziny critically on our assumption that workers choose their formal relationship with the firm. We long term contract which guarantees the workers a wage of out any initial become trained. Similarly, w -\- not produced. This outcome results because the fixm cannot commit not This latter conclusion hinges be 25, the maximum number not viable. to exploit the workers once they have obtained their training, at a cost of h to > efficient scale enter, on the other equal to margined costs (including training), the industry incentive to w k) D{w + h). The number is create firms that produce at demand cannot support two is D{w + exactly sufficient to produce that quantity, the among them &nd the good If itself. we are thus ruling u; + /i if they do are ruling out arrangements in which the firm trains workers In the presence of such employer-provided training the and the allocation would be the same as when the worker is wage could sure to be paid w + h'd he becomes trained. Our assumption nient simplification. setting when that these alternative arrajigements are impossible We is only a conve- expect that similar conclusions would follow in the more realistic where such contracts are possible but Involve a variety of costs which are absent (as in the case of multiple firms) the Such costs workers make their arise because long-term contracts that specify future of worker training are hard to enforce and because it is own training decisions. payments difficult for firms as a function themselves to provide the appropriate training. Consider first the "solution" where the firms assume responsibility for the training 12 of the workers, i.e., they train their workers at a cost per worker of h to the firm. immediate problem with or may need this may that the workers not all be equally suited for training For instance, training different types of training. some workers but not that skill is of others. If workers know whether may improfve the skill of training will improve their ex ante while firms only discover this ex post, the equilibria with two firms considered above induce the right workers to obtain training. By contrast, w The ex post and simply pays for their training, likely to it is if the firm pays workers all obtain a rather mixed group of trainees.* Similar problems arise who workers if obtain training. The contractually implementable. must be taken, then the course the firm signs a contract conmiitting itself: If difficulty here it pay to in defining "training" in is w+ h to a way that is the contract only specifies that a specific training course difficulty is same the as when the firm provides the training adverse selection results in the "wrong" workers becoming trained. Instead, skill. The skill itself than the firm might try to write a contraict that specifies a required level of acquired problem here is that the completion of it is some much more difficult for a third party to verify training course. So, the workers cannot be sure that the firm will not attempt to exploit them ex post by claiming that they are insufficiently skilled and do not therefore 2. qualify for a skilled wage. General Equilibrium Models In this section we consider general equilibrium models in which trade arbes precisely because workers only obtain training among and who We regions they can be sure of competition firms located within the region in which they work. entail the We show that equilibrium can emergence of "developed" regions that trade high wage goods among themselves also trade their high build We wage goods up to a model with three ering two simpler models, goods. if among for the low regions and in Section 2.1 we wage goods of "undeveloped" two high wage goods, by first regions. consid- consider a model with two regions and two derive conditions under which equilibrium entails one developed region which 'In practice tho«« volunteering to join a training progr&m could well end up being those leut suitable for training. They who are unemployed precisely because they are not very suitable. are likely to include thoae 13 produces a high wage good of the kind we analyzed above, and which exports to the it undeveloped region which produces only a low wage good. In Section 2.2 we then consider a model with two regions each region specializes in jind derive conditions under which one of the high wage goods, exporting we combine in Section 2.3, We two high wage goods. it to the other. Finally, these elements in considering a model with three regions but only two high wage goods. 2.1. A Model with Two Regions and Two Goods One of the two goods, good Y, who have by workers and there is also One is a of the kind analyzed above: is received training, each skilled worker can produce a single unit of Y, minimum efficient scale 5. The other good, Z, which produced with constant returns to scale but there unskilled worker can produce supplied good that ensxires that, in can only be produced it is produced some sense Helpman and Krugman in good Z. Good units of it; is no minimum Z The presence both regions. at least, workers are paid the acts as the nvuneraire, efficient scale. serves as a competitively of such a same in common good both regions. As in (1989) the presence of this good achieves at least a limited form of factor price equalization. M workers There are in each region, eau:h of We region. assume that produce at minimum Eaxh M > 2S efficient scale in individual's utility function is given by: + Cz- K^h - the individual becomes trained. Kg who assume that v Goods is each region. Q represents the consumption of good individual spent is one if t. KeC The + K^v ac's (5) are indicator variables; he becomes an entrepreneur, Kv has become an entrepreneur produces at least — own in their so that there are sufficient workers for two firms to U{Cy) if supplies one unit of labor inelas- These workers are geographically immobile, they can only produce tically. where whom S is /c/j is one units. Hereafter we if one the shall e is arbitrarily small. ase costly to tr2Lnsport between regions. In particular, an when one unit of good Y is amount t of good Z transported from one region to the other.® Thus a well 'For timpUcity «c ignore tr&raport coitt on good Z. 14 . social planner meaning would avoid interregional trade, if possible. Assuming an solution where both goods are produced, a Pareto Optimal allocation is self i.e., sufficient would have Cy =w+ where U'{Cy) where marginal set at a level interior where each region marginal cost, utility equals Such a Pareto Optimum would therefore involve training L* h. individuals in each region where L* satisfies: U'{^) = since L* utility /M rv + h, (6) the per capita consumption of good Y. Finally, since entrepreneurs derive \s from owning active firms, this production should be spread across as many firms of TniTiiTniim efficient scale as possible. Note that our assumptions on preferences make sentially identical to the partial equilibrium = = or dy{p) p, aggregate amotmt of Y model of section 1. If we es- write dy{p) for the individual as a function of the price, then utility maximization amount demanded by each implies U'{dy) model this general equilibrium U'~^. Since there are demzmded in M individuals one region as a function of price in each region, the b now given by D = Mdy = MU'-'^ = M{^) = L\ (7) For both goods to actually be produced in positive quantities at the Pareto Optimal allocation it must be possible to satisfy the total domestic demand for good domestic workers. This requires that L* be no greater than We now Optimal assume The and those under which equilibrium involves interregional free entry into the production of issue then decisions are > 2.1.1. Case M analyze the conditions under which equilibria exist which result in the Pareto allocation, not L* Y by employing how majiy is made first. good Z so that the firms enter industry Y. As wage before in trade. terms of we assiime Z We is ty. that entry There are two main cases to consider, depending on whether or 25. When (i): L* > 25 L* exceeds 25 there efficient scale in is sufficient both regions. There is demand for two firnis to produce at minimum then an autarkic equilibrium in which each region '"Note th&t if V - c u large, tht P«r«to Optimum would involve cresting even more flmu »nd having them produce at Icm than minimum efficient tcale in order to allow more individual! to experieiKe the joy of entrepreneur«hip. 15 has N= Once 'mi{L* /S) active firms. N firms have entered, L* workers are obtain training and the firms have enough workers to produce at The Faxrell this is and Saloner (1988) reasoning we employed is impossible. between regions since there obviously remains an equilibrium It no incentive to is eration; one of the regions produces is all is thus an equilibriimi when trade allowed is for interregional trade at this equilibrium. Even though the Pareto Optimal outcome another class of equilibria when there efiicient scale. in the previous section implies that The Pareto Optimal outcome the only autarkic equilibriima. when trade minimum happy to may an equilibrium, there is also exist free trade. These equilibria have regional agglom- Y and the other produces only Z. These of good are the only other equilibria. In particulzLT there do not exist equilibria in which one of the regions both produces some of Y To domestically and also imports some. Y to the contrary that there are two firms producing in one of the regions and that this region also imports Y. Suppose workers in the exporting region earn must equal w+h+ t in the importing region. But that would the importing region would obtain training. Similarly, is to w+ h it IB than that less become trained shortly. M w + . The the importing region. first when applies The landed ty w + h\s therefore given by: The in the wage in the importing region they exist, can be of two types depending on the if in the region that w+h+ M more workers M "lajge" in a sense to be is produces Y pay their workers a made precise wage of w+h Denote the producing region as the foreign region while home h. BO that that Then, wages exporting region and workers do not have an incentive in the equilibria, Then, the firms and charge mean w + h. there. The agglomerated magnitude of if see why, suppose home demzmd cost (including transportation) in the is MU'~^{w + U'-Uw + h + t\+ ^ + r>-U... . = MU'-\w + uu. h){l = since (1 + A)L*, U'-'^ ^^ X), h (^ + t). region b Aggregate demaind at a price of '^)] ,.,..,. where A/l/'-^(u; + home is + ._U'-'{-^ + h + X= /i) = t) ^,-i(^^^)% (8) L*. pzu-ameter A represents the per capita consumption of the high wage good in the 16 argiiment, A capita consumption of + in the the agglomerated equilibrium. type of equilibrium to exist It is number therefore the is now what clear h bo that per -\- minimum M must exceed + (1 other type of agglomerated equilibria which arise for w + h. when M to be large: For this Otherwise, even X)L*. efficient scale of entrepreneurs that enter in means it workers seek training, the market clearing price exceeds if w importing region above of firms that can operate abroad at X)L* /S]. This agglomerated equilibria, its lower there. it is The maximum number given by int[(l decreasing in is merely a reflection of the fact that transportation is wage good costs raise prices for the high is This thzin one. is less producing region. Since U' in the importing region relative to that M Such available the situation in the is than is less if all (1 + X)L*. These they exist, have higher wages and prices. In order for an equilibriima with agglomeration of either type to exist the transportation cost, t, must not be "too importing region is that, if t is high, the price of w case, the price exceeds we -\- h is even higher when in the M is less than (1 + A)L* thus focus on the case where two entrepreneurs enter in the 2S which, by assumption M exceeds importing region and produce is less thain L*. forms depending on the sign of U'{2S) between the prices th£Ln t. Thus there U'{2S) and that is greater than t, in (1 is pf The equilibrium - U'{L * (1 + A)) -t. + U'(L* (1 + A)). If, there would be an incentive to trade home region imports between U'{2S) and U'{L each. its [C7'-1 (p/ + <) + + A)L* Output price can If it is (1 * (1 + if t/'-^ 17 in that region of two negative, the difference entire production instead, U'{2S) home is less region - U'{L * (1 is + A)) both regions consume their entire some of good Y A)) while that at (P^)] = and that now have one and the equilibrium home In this case: M since, in this X)L*. in this case; the price in the no incentive to trade in the foreign region is is S two regions when each region consumes production of Y. Therefore, the price abroad in the exporting region as well. For purposes of illiistrating Suppose, for argument's sake, that the exporting region produces is Y high as well. Such high prices create an incentive for two firms to enter and produce 2S. This incentive these incentives The reason b large". (1 + A)L* + 25. equals P^ + 1. If t is b However, the larger bigger than t, 0, the equilibrium of this second type is w+ w and P' exceeds the more likely that the resulting equilibrium with trade has w + h or that U'{2S)-U'{L*{l + X))-t price exceeds minimum 5 > zero and workers w+ h. P^ +t negative. In either case the domestic is h so two entrepreneurs can enter efficient scale, offer their -\- in the importing region, produce at and make nonnegative h, But profits. then the Farrell and Saloner reasoning implies that they will enter. There thus cannot be y agglomeration of the production of Similarly, for a given smaller than S{t), P* + t, be smnmarized as follows: one region if f is sufficiently big.^^ there always exists a sufficiently small S{t) such that for thdJi is Icirger t in if 5 is w+ h. S Thus, the findings of this subsection can small relative to t the unique equilibrium is autarkic, otherwise there are multiple equilibria: both the autarkic equilibrium and equilibria in which one of the regions specializes on gains from trade (and prove in in the production of Appendix C) that decisions sequentially in each region, the Farrell equilibria with agglomeration. 2.1.2. Case As long (ii): as We exist. argue in our section workers also make their training and Saloner reasoning eliminates the equilibria are more robust when L* > 25. L* < 25 L* exceeds 5, the Pareto Optimal allocation with no trade However since L* < 25, scale in each region and it Is not possible for two firms to operate at so, for the reasons equilibrium in which the good The only Thus the autarkic if Y explored in Section produced by each region is possible equilibria where good Y is for its 1, is still feasible. minimum efficient there is no laissez-faire own consumption. supplied in positive quantities must therefore have only one region supplying the good, as in the equilibrium with agglomeration of the previous subsection. For such an equilibrium to exist here aggregate price of have (1 tv -I- + h must A)L* Compared regions. > exceed the minimum to autarky, trade for these parameter values Under autarky, "A •imilu' arcument + of the firms' efficient scales, i.e., at a we must 25. since L* The change from autarky {1 sum demand < is clezu'ly beneficial to 25, the regions do not get to consume good to free trade keeps the wages of workers the saane. demoiutratei th&t luch agglomerstion U impossible (even for tcro X)L'. 18 t) if M is On Y both at all. the other subfts.ntiklly smaller than hand consumers gain the consumer surplus: \u'{a)-{w + h)\da (9) /o producing region and in the XL' -[w-^h + \y'{a) j t] da of numerous trained workers makes (10) in the other region. Trade it is possible for the two firms producing among assuraince of competition the external returns makes workers Figure aire is no trade as long as 2/(1 + A) as L*/5 > 1. feasible varies. and X*/5 if positive production of and does not involve trade. The reason itself. However we czm support the Pareto is greater than 2. good Y in The and with only When L* IS not sufficient competition for skilled workers. amd 2 the equilibrium has this The Pareto Optimal active firms in each region, region, the equilibrium has international trade even is L*/5 an equilibrium only we cannot have two that otherwise is However, for workers. where one firm cannot obtain workers by describing the outcomes a£ 1 is useful for one firm there to be viable in one region. Similarly, the of another firms affects the competition for workers Optimal allocation without trade reason Y makes training worthwhile firms available to both firms allocation involves good not the usual ones. They might rather be viewed as a pecunijiry The presence externality: The presence driven by external returns. \s between one region. In this though the Pareto Optimal allocation for this is that it is necessary for a region to produce a relatively large amount of the good for there to be effective competition for workers. For L* IS between and 2/(1 1 + A), by contrast, the Pareto Optimal allocation has production in both regions while the equilibrium involves production in neither. region arises because A strictly less is than one. Put prices in the region that does not produce the and makes it more difficult for both firms in ''For tufflciently large L' /S thit i* differently, the costs of trade raise good above w ->r h. This reduces sales of the producing region to exceed their efficient scale. the only equilibrium. 19 This Y minimum The Pareto Optimal values of L*/5 below allocation continues to involve positive production for certain Let 1. S denote involves positive production. 1/(1 + A) 2.1.3. and there 1 is the highest Then L/S S for which the Pareto Optimal allocation smaller than 1/(1 is + A). But for L/S between no production without government intervention. The Gains from Trade When L* is less thaji 25 trade with trade but not without trade. beneficial in that the regions is When L* is can consume the good greater than 25, the autarkic allocation remains an equilibrium even with free trade. This does not establish that free trade good as autarky exist equilibria region is worse These plored by in this case because, for sufficiently low transportation costs, there also off. from trade as a Graham is result of multiple equilibria are analogous to those ex- (1923), Melvin (1969), A slight difference with Ethier (1982) losses are analogous to those is less than + is fully specialized in the These (1 A)L*. They Markusen and Melvin (1981) and Ethier (1982). when the ex- that he obtains losses from trade only production of the good subject to external returns. we obtain in the come about because, w+ we when the exporting obtain losses from trade even equilibria in hx our h. which trade leads to absence of transport costs when M in this case, the price in the exporting region exceeds the autzirky price The as where only one region produces good Y. In these equilibria the importing losses porting region is model with transport losses rely region is costs, by contrast, not fully specialized. on a coordination failure. Workers in the importing region do not believe that other workers will enter in sufficient numbers to make the industry viable. This leads workers to get trained of workers to them not in the other region. communicate to each other expect them not to be robust to chainges to get trained when they expect A)L* Because these equilibria rely on the inability their willingness to in (1 -H become trained one would the informational structure. This is what we argue next. Following Farrell and Saloner (1985) we capture the possibility that workers can com- municate to each other their intentions by assuming that they take the decision to become trained in sequence. First one worker has the option of becoming trained, then another and 20 Once a worker becomes trained so on. To ensure We show in in location of Appendix C that when V in the other region and so on. if training decisions take this form, the autarkic equilibria > 2S. Thus, with this small modification in the game, always beneficial. is A other potential trainees. we assume that the one region has the option, then a worker are the only equilibria 2.2. all has the option of becoming trained alternates between the two regions. who one worker trade becomes known to that the two regions are treated symmetrically the worker First this Symmetric Two-Region Version The outcome produces good We now Y involving trade is the previous subsection is asymmetric: only one region and, because of the transport costs, ends up slightly better ofi" as a result. present a symmetric version of the two-region model which has two high-wage goods. The technology now for also a third good, now two goods which Y producing goods X, whose technology Z and remains the same as before. There identical to that of is are produced by a relatively small number is good Y. Thus there are of large firms employing specialized labor. The preferences of the representative worker are U{Cx) A given by: + U{Cy)+C^-Khh-Kee + K^v (11) benevolent central planner would avoid the transport costs on goods having 2L* trained workers in each region, half of half produce good Y. Again, however, where both goods are produced Y now in if L* is whom produce good smaller than 25, there X and Y by X while the other is no equilibrium both regions. The only equilibria where goods X and are produced involve regional specialization even though this specialization leads to the expenditure of tr£uisport costs. In this model with two goods, it is much less likely that one region will produce the goods requiring the input of trained workers. The reason region has enough workers to supply both goods X and Y is that if 2(1 + X)L* > all M no to the entire world. Then, the only equilibrium where both goods are produced has two specialized regions which trade 21 One with each other. world's demand for region produces the world's good in developed region has lower less wages than the developed region. Moreover workers employed developed region eeirn To derive these Y and X (or y) scale ((1 (i.e., + Z wages that are higher than the average results we < L* > w+ h for the region as a whole. consider a model in which there exist the \s Moreover, 2(1 demand from + all three regions 2A)L*, the aggregate is demand same three goods any one region in too small for two firms to produce at 2S), but the overall 25). export sector of the in the but where there are three identical regions. Demajid at a price oi 2X)L* that which the "developed regions" export high wage goods to the developed region, and also trade with each other. The X, we now show each of the previous subsections, in capable of explaining the coexistence of multiple "developed" regions and is an "undeveloped" region less the other the with Three Regions Combining elements developed our model X and good for Y An Asymmetric Model 2.3. demand minimum efficient sufficient to for both X for do so and Y, exceeds Af , so that no one region can produce both on a world scale. Then the only equilibrium where wage good and imports the other, and one regions each of which exports one high X developed" region which imports both what follows we To develop w earn Z as All three regions produce X [Y) as Region that some workers X "less good Z. In (y), and the region Region Z. implications for wages, note while other earn w+ h. first in the developed region This meztns that the average wage in the region exceeds that in the undeveloped region where employed and Y. produces refer to the region that that produces only three goods get produced has two "developed" all all workers earn it;. in the exporting region of the developed region is Moreover, the wage of those it; + /i so that it exceeds the average wage in the region. This is also an implication of the symmetric model of the previous subsection. This implication of these models They is consistent with the evidence of Katz find that, in industrialized countries, the average industries exceeds the average wage paid in and Summers (1989). wage paid by a country's exporting that country's manufacturing sector as a whole. 22 Our model have found in the it also gives difficult to amount some guidance as to why Katz auid Summers account for inter-industry wage differences by looking at differences of formal education the workers in different industries possess. In our model, wages are determined by industry-spec'iBc skill which is often obtained in through formal education. For example, workers often acquire those This could explain change in (1989) and others why the wages of workers who move from one ways that are related to the inter-industry wage acquired some industry-specific skill in ways other skills on the job.^' industry to another differentials. Workers who have one industry and move to another where those are not valued, will experience a reduction in their wages. Conversely, workers acquired skills skills who have that are not valued in the industry in which they are currently employed but which are valuable S. thcin in the one they move to will raise their wages by moving. Industrial/Commercial Policy some goods In our models the production of involves high wages while that of other goods does not. In such contexts, protection has been viewed as beneficial by numerous authors We e.g. Hagen (1958), Bhagwati and Rcimciswami (1963), Katz and Summers (1989).) are thus led to explore whether a region can gain by unilaterally deviating from free trade. We consider two types of deviations. In the first, which we call industrial policy, the central authority attempts to encourage the emergence of a specifically targeted industry. In the second, the central authority is not interested in changing the pattern of regional specialization but nonetheless taxes imports industrial policy often involves the use of because the first tries whose production requires tziriffs, we skilled labor. distinguish between the two policies to affect the composition of trade without trying to affect while the second affects mainly the While its level level. S.l. Industrial Policy. Industrial policy can be carried out using various tools. subsidy to firms who produce One approach the desired good. Suppose, for example, that is we to give a are in the **Of cour»« one might attempt to control for that in part by including "y**" of expyerience* variablei in the regresiion, However luch v&riablet do not identify time ipent on the job acquiring induftry- specific tkilli. typically done. 23 af ii simple case of Section 2.1 where there are two regions but only a single high wage good. The is wage good central authority in one region, acting unilaterally, can ensure that the high produced suppose it by locally offering a subsidy to firms announces that u Then, two &rms will in the for this b that domestic market wage equal to No ly such that is = w + h-MU'-'^{{l + if if X)L*). (12) they do not in f&ct end up exporting at aW in equilibrium. the foreign market will entail somehow is foreclosed to them, equilibrium an equilibrium price of P* = MU'~^({1 + A)L*) and a + h}^ foreign finns will enter this mzirket been offered this subsidy. They is know that the domestic they if firms have out of the market since they will be will decide to stay unable to export and their domestic market eflBcient scaJe In particular, be willing to enter the domestic market and to produce enough output to satisfy world demeind even The reason the good. domestic firms face foreign competition in the event that the they will receive a per unit subsidy, u, which who produce not sufficiently large to support production for two firms. Therefore, if minimum the central authority annoimces its subsidy plan before any entry decisions are made, the outcome will be that the domestic firms will be the sole world producers of the high wage good. Moreover, since the central authority only had to conamit to paying the subsidy in the event that foreign competition materialized, domestic dominance of the industry is achieved without any subsidy actually being paid in equilibriiim. This outcome is desirable from the perspective of domestic residents since the utility of the region that produces the high wage good is higher than the utility in the other however, the subsidy to one good makes region. In the symmetric model of Section no There each region can only produce one high wage good and that difference. 2.2, is the equilibrium outcome with or without the offer of the subsidy on a single good. While the •*To MC this note flr»t that domettie coniumert are willing to eoniume (1 per unit that the firms receive (including the subsidy) is MU'-'(1 + X)L' + w + A Thus the flmu arc wiUing to bid the wage up to «; + fc Afi;'-'(1 + X)L' at a price of + X)L' = w + MU'~^{1 + X)L'. The h. and so workers arc prepared to obtain training. 24 revenue subsidy csin determine which of the high wage goods the domestic industry produces by "Hargeting" that good, the country is indifferent in that model which of the goods as to it produces. In a slightly richer model, however, the subsidy can be socially costly. Suppose, for example, that foreign workers can more easily become trained domestic workers. This thaji could arise for example where the high wage good involves a new technology and where the workers of the foreign country have built up some relevant industry-specific know-how with the old technology. In that case efficiency may foreign firms whereais the offer of a subsidy may call for production to be done by lead to the emergence (and domineince) of a domestic industry. Not only would foreign consumers be hurt by this since they must bear the transportation costs, but even domestic consumers may be imposing a prohibitive import foreign firms market is mi^e tariff The While they save now pay the transportation cost they would otherwise have to pay, they training costs of the domestic workers. hurt. industrial policy can also be for the higher implemented by on the targeted good. By announcing the tariff before and thereby convincing them that the domestic their entry decisions, foreclosed to them, they can be deterred from entering. The end result, again, be the emergence of domestic firms as the sole world producers of the good. This will is a simple case of "import protection leads to export promotion". ^^ 8.2. Nondiscriminatory Import Taxes In this section we study tariffs which reduce the volume of trade but do not pattern of specialization. This analysis tariffs tariff of such policies in the context of our mind the symmetric model free trade has is will continue to import the good on has been levied. To make sense Y thus closer in spirit to traditional analyses of which are conducted assuming that a country which a in is affect the of section 2.2 with one of the high wage goods, X M less **Se* Krugtnan (1984) for the original tao-iff on good »tatement of thit X so that potsibility. 25 it than 2(1 might be best to have -f- A)L*. In that model produced by one region while the other, produced by the other. Suppose that, as described region imposes a prohibitive model it is in the previous subsection, sure to export X. The one analysis of this subsection then corresponds to the analysis of relatively small tariffs on by the other region. Such moderate tariffs on Y Y levied not affect the regional pattern of will specialization in this case. We show Lapan that the benefits from tariffs depends critically, as in whether the government that imposes the by "surprbe". In our model tariff taikes on (1988), the agents in the other country depends, in particular, on whether workers in the for- this eign country correctly predict the imposition of the tariffs when they make their training decisions. Suppose the tariffs. rmpK)rts of for Y Then Y less w + h. As exceeds u;, (1 -I- X)L* of them become trained lowers the must be below that the foreign workers do not correctly anticipate the imposition of first than demand for w + h and long as the tariff Y. Thus, the is wage for the market to on imports of Y tzo-iff of foreign trained workers will therefore Y and its output when they reduction in demand h and the number of workers is the standard optimal tariff argument. mcike their training decisions. Since they correctly anticipate the that will follow the imposition of the tariff, fewer of them obtain price charged abroad equals that obtain training w+ h. If the ex post tariff is wages r, Since the price charged abroad domestic residents lose from the to the foreign firms is tariff. (13) thus independent of the anticipated Domestic consumption falls tariff rate, and the imit price paid unchanged. Domestic residents would be better could commit never to levy a off if the country tariff. These conclusions are similar when is the is: MU'-'^(w + h] + MU'-'^ ({1 + t){w + h + t)Y that will lowers the price charged by the foreign firms, small tariffs training. Indeed, the nimiber of foreigners that obtains training adjusts until their w+ still that workers in the foreign region do correctly anticipate the imposition of the tariff equal on ako be not too large, so that the wage for trained workers helps the domestic region. This Now suppose tariff the equilibrium price cleao" the skilled workers will prefer to be employed producing not change. Because the A production of Y. for the to, though stronger, thain Lapan 's. Lapan (1988) shows the production of output occurs before a government can levy a 26 t£a-iff, the incentive to raise tariffs larger ex post than ex ante. is where countries trade because they are small tariff is However, intrinsically different. desirable even ex ante. Here, by contrast, As a all tariffs his framework result, in his one is model a are imdesirable ex ante BO countries are sure to gain by committing themselves never to levy a tariff in the future. One reaison to stress these results that they differ radically from those of the standard is models that explain trade among similar countries. Standard models of increasing returns and monopolistic competition as motives for trade can be seen in What we have shown 4. among regions. As Gros (1987), Venables (1987) and Helpman and Krugman (1989), under these assumptions tariffs are generally desirable even in this type stress is when they are correctly anticipated. that Lapan's (1988) case against tariffs applies even more strongly a model where identical countries trade with each other. o Antitrust Policy In the models we have presented the perfectly competitive outcome emerges even there are only two competing rivals. In practice, however, a paucity of competitors endow the if may firms in the industry with market power over their customers and suppliers. In particular, the firms may be able to restrict their consumption of inputs and thereby reduce the amount they pay to their input suppliers. This can occur, for example, when firms interact repeatedly and implicitly collude. Suppose in particular that after entrepreneurs training, prices are set and demeind That norm may be sustainable will lead to a breakdown in if realized over is be able to implement a collusive norm have entered many which wages are aind workers have obtained periods. Then the firms may below the competitive level. firms fear that any unilateral deviation from the norm in set cooperation in which wages return to the competitive Each firm would then weigh the short term gain from offering a slightly higher level.^ wage while others keep their wages at the collusive level, with the future loss that results from the elimination of the collusive gain. The result too large, they obtain an outcome that discussion manageable we will is is that, as long as the n\miber of firms similar to that of perfect collusion. assume that as long as no more than **S«c Friedman (1971) for a thecry along these Unei for colluiion in output 27 prices. N firms is not To keep the are present w they achieve the fully collusive outcome; the pay their workers by (4). We By contrast, if there are N more than firms, the competitive chairge a price given outcome are interested in examining the effect of a strong antitrxist policy. peirticular on the vigor with which merger that, initially, there are N > N policy an industry to The more vigorous firms. ^ /x. competition will characterize the industry and (1 collude perfectly and drive the suppose that the at eflBcient scale enforcement We and enforced.^ focus in We assume the antitrust enforcement, the or fewer. Let the probability that the ajititrust authorities will prevent such an increase in concentration be given by training they established is obtains. that a set of mergers will be tolerated which reduce the nimiber of firms in less likely it is We and when initial the price must expect is lax, wage down number is u; to earn they must earn + w+ w + h/n as well —A*) of firms, /i. For it is n denotes the probability that the probability that the firms will N, \s such that they csm there all operate to be worthwhile for workers to obtain h on average. Since they earn w + h/n when when is, to w. antitrust enforcement when the wage and price are equal in equilibriimi the price equals That w when is antitrust vigorous. Since firms are competing, this implies that effective competition. is In order for the trained workers to be fully employed in the event that antitrust policy is vigorous, the nimaber of workers that seek training must equal the nimiber of workers who obtain training policy enables the firms to collude, [l — fi): fewer workers obtain training. In the limit, h/fi). Therefore, decreasing in the probability that antitnist is A if D{w + higher probability of collusion means that the probability of collusion is one (so that n equals zero), no worker becomes trained. When sales equal the firms collude they set a wage of D{w + w and hire all the trained workers. h/n) and the price must again equal w+ h/n. Thus So the potential for collusion raises the price whether collusion takes place or not. We now consider international trade. Suppose that, as in the model of Section 2.1 there are two regions but only one high wage good. Suppose that in the domestic region '^In the U.S., for «x&mplc, the Deputraent of Juiticc hu coniidersble latitude in deciding which mercen It will challenge and bai set out 'Guidelinei* it uiei in reaching thote deciiioni. The guideline* are lubject to reviiion and thoee in effect at any time leave lubetantial room for interpretation. Accordingly merger policy can fluctuate lubitantially from adminiitration to adminiitration. 28 the probability of collusion competition is less fi zero. is than one i.e., By contrast, in the foreign region the probability of weak the foreign region has a for a sufficiently small (but strictly positive) foreign antitrust policy. Then, the foreign region fi must become the importer of good Y. This can be seen as follows. Suppose of y. h/fi Then the + t] which total is this find it fi. abroad U So, for sufficiently low profitable to become trained two firms do enter and the foreign wage foreign firms compete. from obtaining fi: at home two firms enter here. if below falls w + h/n even when antitrust policy tolerated. This simple rules, particularly in industries region, with is tough wage good. Thus the country with the vigorous is the only producer M\U'~^{w + h/fi)-\-U'~^{w + The only equilibrium has the domestic training. which collusion is is But, this means that in this case foreign workers do not benefit antitrust stance, exporting the high in that the foreign region of trained workers decreasing in Then, 2S workers Knowing number first is better off than the coimtry example suggests that relaxation of antitrust where human capital accumulation important, can well is be detrimental to a region's welfare. Insofar as cooperation between firms allows them to exploit workers more ex post, fewer workers will obtain training This concern for a strong antitrust policy in and the region will suflFer. order to ensure vigorous competition between purchasers of inputs echoes that of Porter (1989) who makes this argument strongly for similar reasons. may appear This result cooperation among firms is surprising because in the iisual models of extemzJ returns beneficial. When the externality is technological, so that increased output by one firm reduces the inputs needed by another, an agreement between the firms is beneficial since socially desirable it allows the firms to internalize the externality, leading to a output expansion. Similarly, in the case of localized knowledge research joint ventures joint venture to benefit may improve social welfare. By enabling from the research carried out by them externality from research is mitigated. Indeed, this 29 is all the spillovers, members of the in the joint venture, the precisely the argument used by Jorde and Teece (1988).^* Our paper serves as a warning that the appearance of external returns is not enough to justify cooperation among firms. In particular, although very large research consortia might lead to greater sharing of the fruits of the research, they may also reduce the compensation of their employees, acquire the knowledge and the 5. and thus reduce needed to conduct the research. skills Conclusions We have presented a model of regional agglomeration in the goods where the principal motor behind a region's exports among many if their incentive to is production of specific the healthy competition suppliers located there. Competition ensures that workers earn high wages they acquire industry-specific human makes human capital which, in turn, capital accu- mulation attractive and the industry viable. The main message from to obtain the same the model is that even where it technologically possible is allocation with trade as without trade, trade serves a useful role. It allows industries to operate on a sufficiently large scale that same goods firms producing the it is possible to have several one location and thereby reap the benefits that flow in from regional agglomeration. While we have focused on the of monopsony power, there salutziry eff^ect of regional may be htiman capital accumulation. That which having several other reasons is, it is local firms creates why agglomeration on the abuse regional agglomeration enhances an open question whether the mechanism by an incentive for human capital accumulation is through the increased competition they generate. For example, a some assurance change diff"erent advantage of regional agglomeration may be that to workers that they will remain employable in the industry in the future. That is, workers may prefer it if there in the sirea that use their industry specific skills in case is if it conditions a diverse range of demand provides activities conditions or production techniques change in a way that eliminates the activity they choose to be employed This preference for diversity might exist even if in. long-term wage contracts can be written '* *[W]c point out thkt our uititruit policy ... impoaet unneoeuary reitrictioni on high technology ioduttri** ... In our view, trict antitrust enforcement i« generaily not needed in the circumitance* we contemplkte, because international competition and new and unexpected entry it est>ecially itrong.* 30 specifying the power is wage that the worker will receive in a particular activity, so that monopsony not an issue. Consider just three specific examples. Workers employed in the production of midsized automobiles case may want demand shifts to be located near plants that produce small automobiles in in the direction of Or workers employed producing computers the latter. based on a proprietary operating system, but whose system, may prefer it if skills are not specific to that operating plants producing computers bzised on alternative operating systems are located nearby in case theirs becomes obsolete. Finally, worker is concerned that he know that if it could simply be that the not get on with his supervisor or co-workers, and will he becomes unhappy in his job that he can easily shift to another. While the existence of such diversity may be important to workers making ing decisions, it is not clezir why it and if if when workers are concerned about the possibility of bankruptcy rolled into one. about the "corporate culture" and that arate divisions within the is, divisions. Multiple two firms somehow have a combined probability of bankruptcy that those firms would have their train- cannot be achieved within a single enterprise. That one firm could encompaiss a range of technologies, products, plants, and firms might have an advantage like to it is Or it lower than might be that workers are concerned difficult to same company. Such is maintain several "cultures" in sep- rationales for regional agglomeration must be highly speculative for the moment. Sorting out which of them, or others not suggested here, can survive the scrutiny of formal modeling Another open area for research is with high wages, extensive industry in practice, is it b hard to is a question that awaits future research. the extent to which competition specific training gauge when am industry b is actually associated and exports. One problem is relatively competitive. Nonetheless worth providing some anecdotal examples which appear to support the model. centrally planned economies have firms and are notorious little that, it First, actual competition for workers between the various for their inability to export high wage goods. Second, consider the automobile industry. Japan, the most successful exporter of high quality mass-produced cars, has a relatively large number of firms in this industry. Similarly, Italy has several producers of high performance cars which are very successful exporters. In contrast, Italy 31 manufacturer, FIAT, whose exports to the has only one large mass-production auto are minimal. cars performance Italian Interpreted within the context of our model, the high and the mass-produced Japanese cars can be thought use relatively skilled workers while who employs US less skilled FIAT can be thought of as high quality goods of as a lower quality producer workers. These anecdotes suggest that a of the empirical validity of the model is warranted. 32 which more careful exploration References Bhagwhati, Jagdish and V. K. Ramaswami: "Domestic Distortions, Tariffs and the Theory of Optimum Subsidy," JournaJ of PoUtica.} Economy, 71, February 1963. J.: "Decreasing Costs in International Trade and Frank Grahaim's Argximent for Protection," Econometrica., 50, 1243-69, 1982. Ethier, Wilfred Joseph and Garth Saloner: "Standardization, Compatibility, and Innovation," Rajid JournaJ of Economics, 16, Spring 1985, 70-83. FaLTTell, Feenstra, Robert C: "Monopsony Distortions in an Analysis," Journal of Internationa] Economics, 10, Open Economy:A May James W.: "A Non-Cooperative Equilibrium Economic Studies, 38, January 1971, 1-12. Friedmaji, Theoretical 1980, 213-35. for Supergzones," Review of Gros, Dajiiel: "A Note on the Optimal Tariff, Retaliation and the Welfzo-e Loss from Tariff Wars in a Frajnework of Intra-Industry Trade", Journal of International Economics, 23, 1987, 357-67. Graham, Frank: "Some Aspects of Protection Further Reconsidered," Quarteriy Journal of Economics, 37, 199-227, 1923. Eagen, Everett E.: "An Economic Justification for Protectionism," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 72, November 1958, 496-514. Helpman, Elhanan and Paul R. Krugman: Market Structure and Foreign Trade, Press, Cambridge, 1985 :7>ade Policy and Market Structure, Jorde, Thomas M. and David titrust," UC Berkeley, J. MIT MIT Press, Cambridge, 1989. Teece, "Innovation, Strategic Alliances, and An- November 1988, mimeo. Katz, Lawrence F. and Lawrence H. Summers: "Industry Rents :Evidence and Implications," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1989, 209-90 Krugman, Paul R: "Import Protection (ed.), as Export Promotion," in Henryk Kierkowski Monopolistic Competition and Internafionai IVade, Blackwell, Oxford, 1984. Lapan, Harvey E.: "The Optimal Tariff, Production Lags and Time Inconsistency", Americim Economic Review, 78, June 1988, 395-401 33 Lucas, Robert E. Jr.: "On the Mechajiics of Economic Development", Journal of Monetary Economics, 22, July 1988, 3-42. Markusen, Jaimes R. ajid Arthur J. Robson: "Simple General Equilibrium and Trade with a Monopsonized Sector," Canadian Journai of Economics, 13, 668-82, 1980. and James R. Melvin: "Trade, Factor Prices and the Gains from Trade with Increasing Returns to Scale," Canadian Journal of Economics, 14, 450-69, 1981. Marshall, Alfred -.Principles of Economics, London, Macmillan, 1920. McCulloch, Rachel and Janet L. Yellen: "Factor Market Monopsony and the Allocation of Resources," Journa/ of International Economics, 10, May 1980, 237-47. Melvin James R.: "Increasing Returns to Scale as a Determinzint of Trade," Canadian Journal of Economics, 2, 389-402, 1969. , Shleifer and Robert W. Vishny: "Industrialization and the Big Push,"JournaJ of Political Economy, 97, October 1989, 1003-26. Murphy, Kevin M., Andrei Porter, Michael E.: The Competitive Advantage of Nations, The Free Press, New York, Forthcoming. Romer, Paul M.: "Increasing Returns and Long Run Growth", Journal of Economy, 94, October 1986, 1002-37. Political Venables, Anthony J.: "Trade and Trade Policy with Differentiated Products: Chamberlinian-Ricardian Model," Economic Journal, 97, 1987, 700-17. A Williamson, Oliver E.,: Mariets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Imp/icafions, New York: The Free Press, 1975. 34 (D) (C) (B) (A) (F) (E) ^ Bqm. exists without trade Eqm. exists with trade but is not robust Eqm. exists with trade and is robust No eqm. exists with positive production P.O. involves production ar -> no trade P.O. involves production and trade P.O. involves no product! oi L* (I4A) S s s Figure 1; Eqiiilibriun and Pareto Optinality KEY: (A) No production in Pareto Optimum or in equilibrium (B) P.O. involves production amd trade but there is no production in equilibrium (C) Aut-arky is the P.O., but there is no production in equilibrium (D) Autarky is the P.O. (E) Autarky is the P.O. (F) Autarky is the P.O. and the unique equilibrium outcome. , but equilibrixom requires regional agglomeration and trade There are multiple equilibria: An agglomeration equilibrixun (which is not robust) and an autarkic equilibrium / .. Appendix Existence of we prove In this appendix when exists < 2 The subgame wages that firms finns sets If < iV offer are: (a) If = tZ^,- = £>"^(L). is D~^{L); and L<5 all and the others h) there are and the remaining firms set Wi the assertion in Section 1 that a competitive equilibrium equilibrium strategies are as follows: L* workers obtain training. 25 < L < D[w + the firms set The Competitive Equilibrium TV. = D{L) + j tD, A (ii) set their (e) If firms set set tD, = tDj = D{L) + y — c two cases to consider: N > N': D{w) < L (i) N' Jn his case wage equal 0; (b) If to 0; (d) If firms set ty,- = N 5 < L < 25 one < N' = -i- h) int j: In this case tli, = D-'^{L) < L < D{w), In case (e) a ty. of the for c arbitrarily small; (c) firms set D{w The + ^ firms all minor modification required for the rule that workers use in allocating themselves across firms since there are too many workers L — D{w) to be employed at workers elect to work wage w in other industries. industry distribute themselves uniformly across the We first Case (a): Since here fewer than (b): Since the 5 Thus they that remain in this N firms. workers obtain training, no firm is able to operate at refuse to hire workers (set w^ = 0). all nimiber of workers only one firm can op>erate at in being the The D{w) workers demonstrate that the firms' wage strategies are equilibrium strategies. rnin iTTnim eflScient scale. Case Here we assume that in this industry. minimum who obtain training exceeds efficient scale. Since one who hires the worker derives utility of v, 5 but is less the entreprenexir that succeeds they are each prepared to bid v to the workers, or y Lf each, for the right to be their employer. (Note that since e cost at this stage it is winning firm is irrelevant). willing to pay than 25, is a simk Since the mairket clearing price will be I>~^(L), the D~^{L) +y to each worker to be the sole producer. Since Lf the losing firms will not attract any workers in equilibrixim, they are prepared to tiny amount less than the wage of the "Svinning firm" . (c(i)): If w + h. Since the all a Doing so keeps the winning firm "honest" and eliminates an incentive for him to shave his wage Case offer offer. L workers are hired the market clearing price will be D[L) which exceeds N firms can produce at minimum efficient scale in this case, they will bid the wage Case up to (c(ii)): minimum scale. D{L). Here there are efficient scale. A^* As Case in insuflBcient trained is the number workers for N all firms to operate at of firms that can operate at (b) the entrepreneurs are willing to pay t; minimum to be successful. Since there are -j^ workers per successful firm, the firms are willing to pay a "preniium" of worker to attract them to the firm and be successful. Once the workers are the market clearing price will be D~^{L). Thus the successful firms bid workers. Unsuccessful firms bid Case Here (d): all N efficient per employed all D~^{L) ^^ + ^^ for 0. firms can produce at minimima efficient scale. Once the workers are hired the market clearing price will be D~^{L). Firms therefore bid the wage up to this level. Case (e): If firms offer w, workers are indifferent between being employed in this industry and being employed elsewhere. Therefore D~^{w) workers if to take employment they are employed, will be Thus the firms are tv. in it is consistent with optimizing behavior for only thb industry. But then the market clearing Thus firms bid the wage up to w. any number of willing to carry out the proposed strategies for workers that become trained. Those strategies are therefore subgame perfect. now to the training strategy of workers. workers to obtain training. and the wage that is offered If that is price, The proposed equilibrium number obtains D~^{L*) = w + h. training. Case We turn strategy calls for L* (c(i)) is the relevant one Since they recoup their training expenses the workers are prepzu-ed to obtain training. No additional workers are prepared to obtain training, however. worker obtains training. Case D~^{L* + Similao-ly, 1) < w + h, (d) one additional becomes the relevant one. The wage that BO that the deviating worker is is h and earning w+h offered is unable to recoup his training costs. none of the L* workers has an incentive to deviate by not obtaining Each worker who obtains training at a cost If in equilibrium in indifferent training. between obtaining training and not obtaining training and earning w. Appendix B Uniqueness of the Competitive Equilibrium In this equal Appendix we show that the equilibrium + fc, u; is unique. The proof of this and the highest wage that {i) w < w+ trained workers is is charged in a candidate equilibrixmi by P* is offered in equilibrium by w. There cannot be an equilibrium where the highest wage h: less than w-\-h since at least w > w -^ w h and P* > h: In -\- off. an equilibrium like this it the entire pool of untrained workers becomes trained because untrained workers is sufficient to satisfy below w-\-h for the market to can make himself better (iii) w >w -\- off clear. demand when But then offered to one of the workers would be able to deviate by not obtaining training and make himself better (ii) where the price and wage proposition proceeds by contradiction for a series Denote the price that of exhaxistive cases. in Section 1, for v —e must be the case that w > w + h. Since the pool of + /i, the price must be the price is u; very small at least one entrepreneur by not entering. h and P* < tt; + workers lose money. But then for r When /i: —e the price is below the wage, firms that hire very small at least one entreprenexir could do better by not entering. (iv) vj w •\- h. =w •\- The reason > w+ h. and P* is that a firm can raise the wage infinitesimally, attract workers and increase its profits. h: Here a firm will deviate and offer a wage above all the trained Appendix C Uniqueness of Equilibrium with Sequential Training Decisions Appendix we consider the case where L* > 25 and workers get trained In this sequence. We show that, in this case, the one region while none get trained in outcome where L*{1 the other is + A) in workers get trained in The only not an equilibrium. equilibrium the autarkic one where L* workers get trained in each region. is Workers in each region are ordered from be given the option of becoming trained. After that, the first worker at home If M. The 1 to worker abroad and so on.^^ Let s^ denote the strategy we equal one let 8 for the t'th if the first to it is for the t'th given to the second worker at home while These strategies can take only one of two s- denotes the j'th foreign worker's strategy. values; is he declines he cannot later become trained. given the option, then is worker first the worker becomes trained and zero otherwise. The strategy worker depends only on the number of workers that have decided to become trained before him. Thus: m=l Suppose that at trained at Xf b home least X^ two firms enter n=l each region and that in there b no region. t, then the price at trade. If it home greater than t, is showed equilibriimi is +t home and as Y flows would be undimnged - U'{Xf) 17' (X') and from the foreign to the domestic if the equilibrium many as (1 + + h) + b of the former type if when 2S X)L* workers get trained abroad, the U'~^{w + h If 2S workers become + t)]-2S become trained abroad. On the other hand, 25 workers are anftlyiii U'{X^) bigger than U'{X^) while the equilibritmi price unique. So, consider the latter equilibria. home, then no more than M\U'~^{w **The If and b smaller than U'{X^). in section 2.1.1 that workers get trained at workers become U'{X^) while the price abroad b good The equilibrium price abroad P^ b home, P^ equals P^ We b X^ workers become trained abroad. Given our interest, assume that exceeds X^. Then the equilibrium prices can be of two forms. smaller than at while m=l n=l trained at workers are willing to willing to become trained the flnt deciiicn on training were taken by the flnt worker at home. at home h) number as long as the + U'~^{w + — f)] — 25, /i of foreign trained workers does not exceed which The discrepancy comes from larger. is K^ = M\U'~^{w + the existence of transport costs whose presence ensures that the price abroad must be below to equal + lo We now at least K^ /i that, if trained. Consider first subgames workers ever become trained abroad. Then, 25 workers or more trained 25 — if will enter see this note that the 25 — 2 workers exactly if M'th domestic worker is if it is M— I'st perfect, which fewer than become trained will By doing so got trained before him. in strictly better off workers got trained before him. Similarly, the 1 /i subgame the strategies followed by foreign workers are 25 domestic workers become To + home. at show at home. ti; by becoming domestic worker he, just like the last worker, recoups his training cost and lowers the equilibrium price. This reasoning extends M — 25'th worker backwards so that the sure to become trained is if other workers did not get trained before him. We now argue that Suppose there to exists a become trained K^ = M[U'-'^{w U'~^{w -\- h — t)] subgame where the /i) + K good Y of Y — 1 and recoups » — there are only So — far K K°' — + /i + t 01 - (^^ - home if = 25 + 1 + M\U'-'^{w 1) worker there were -\-h-\-t)- would definitely — even if his decision to Similarly, the if there he does not become trained, t — become trained triggers further 2'th domestic worker will get trained if 2 workers trained before him. This argument extends backwards so I'th domestic we If become trained (By the definition of K^^. By entering, he lowers the price his training cost we have argued entry of two firms that the + I'th domestic worker training of domestic workers. t /i K'Wi from acquiring training domestic workers already trained before him. will cost u; that the + refrain worker becomes the domestic workers already trained. In equilibrium, such a number will always be present. The were U'-'^{w workers ever to become trained abroad. I'th foreign That worker would there. + K^ impossible for it is worker becomes trained. that the initially home region produces at least 25 which justifies the assumed. In fact the argument can be strengthened to show region produces L* and the autarkic equilibrium prevails. Suppose that, on the contrary, the foreign region produces L* +x which is less than K' where x is positive. For X sufficiently leirge the home region will import Y. implies that the domestic region will then produce (L* + i) = MU'~^{w + h - t) - X which But, then, the price and wage abroad equal exceeds h) + U'~^{w 25 because L* + x M[U'~^{w w+h—t BuflBciently small that the foreign region does The backwards induction argument which -\- is is h— + less t)] ~ than K^. impossible. So x must be not export the good. But, then, x must be zero for otherwise the foreign price and wage would again be below w+ h. q-^'^-'^o C^OBO 0^ s^e^ SV3 Date Due DEC c li^u 3-33li Lib-26-67