International standards certification and exports from developing countries: firm level evidence Micheline Goedhuys1 and Leo Sleuwaegen2 Abstract The paper tests if ISC certification has an extra signalling role to buyers in foreign markets and stimulates exports by firms in developing countries. The empirical testing controls for heterogeneity in productivity and skill intensity of the firm. The estimation results which are based on a sample of manufacturing firms from over 89 countries indicate that ISC certified firms are more likely to export and export at a larger scale. keywords: certification, export performance, institutional development, transaction costs JEL: D23, D24, O12, O17, O33 1 UNU-MERIT, Maastricht, the Netherlands; Goedhuys@merit.unu.edu; 2 Corresponding author : leo.sleuwaegen@econ.kuleuven.be Vlerick Business School and KU Leuven, University of Leuven, Belgium; 1 1. Introduction The role of International Standard Certification (ISC) in relation to the development of international trade has been the subject of recent research. Studies by Clougherty and Grajec (2008) and Potoski and Prakash (2009) who use macro data found that ISO diffusion has a positive effect on exports, particularly from developing countries, yet no effect in developed countries (Clougherty and Grajec, 2008). Yet, to date there are no detailed studies at the level of the individual firm, the level at which ISC should have its direct impact, to validate and deepen these findings. This paper studies the export performance of firms using firm level data from the World Bank Enterprise Survey, pooled from 89 countries, both developing and least developed countries. It explicitly tests if ISC certification enhances the export performance of firm in developing countries, controlling for other important determinants of export market participation and export intensity. In addition the novelty of this paper lies in that it systematically tests whether the effects of quality certification on firm exports is different in countries at different levels of institutional development, underscoring its strategic ‘signalling’ role in reducing transaction costs. The paper is structured as follows. Section two presents the findings of the literature and builds hypotheses for testing. Section three develops the empirical approach, presents the data, estimating model and variable construction. Section four presents the results. Section five discusses the findings and concludes. 2. The decision to export and export intensity: Conceptual model and hypotheses The international trade literature focusing on firm heterogeneity relates differences in firms’ export performance and export status to differences in firms’ productivity (Melitz, 2003; Bernard and Jensen, 1999; Aw et al., 2000; Chaney, 2008). The underlying assumption is that only the more productive firms are able to overcome the huge risk and sunk costs that are related to entering foreign markets. There is indeed mounting evidence that firms wishing to export not only face variable costs such as transport costs and tariffs, but also critically face 2 some significant fixed costs that do not vary with export volume (Das, Roberts, and Tybout, 2001). These include costs to convince foreign buyers about the product, to research the foreign regulatory environment and adapt the product to foreign standards, to set up trade relationships and distribution channels in the foreign country and to conform to all the shipping rules specified by the foreign customs agency. Although some of these costs cannot be avoided, others are often manipulated by governments in order to erect non-tariff barriers to trade (Melitz, 2003; Helpman et al., 2008) and thus differ countrywise. Taking these sunk costs into account, theoretical and empirical models contend that more productive firms self-select into becoming exporters (Melitz, 2003; Helpman et al., 2008, Bernard and Jensen, 2004). The self-selection hypothesis has been largely supported by empirical evidence (Clerides and Lach, 1998; Aw et al., 2000; Arnold and Hussinger, 2005; Delgado et al., 2002; Damijan and Kostevc 2006). Bernard and Wagner (2001) find that higher levels of productivity positively affect the probability of becoming an exporter. Bernard and Jensen (1999) find similar effects for plant characteristics, with larger, highwage, more productive plants being more likely to export. Yet another set of empirical studies shows that there are substantial differences in export performance of equally productive firms, due to heterogeneity in firms’ ability to produce quality. Entry into foreign markets thus seems to be conditional upon firms’ ability to attain high levels of product quality (Hallak 2006, Brooks, 2006, Hallak and Sivadasan, 2013; Verhoogen 2008). Therefore, to take part in global trade, developing country firms are challenged to improve both “process productivity” and “product productivity” or quality of products and processes (Maskus et al., 2005, Brooks 2006; Hallak and Sividasan, 2013). They invest in high-quality labour (Verhoogen, 2008) and develop new products and processes to meet the quality requirements of the international market (Iacovone and Javorcik, 2010, Alvarez and Lopez, 2005). Likewise, the participation in export markets is equally positively influenced by mechanisms that reduce the fixed entry cost thereby decreasing the productivity threshold required to become exporter. Several studies find that firms benefit from the importing of goods and services from abroad in setting up their export operations. Sunk-cost complementarity (Kasahara and Lapham, 2013) is a mechanism through which previous importing experience positively impacts the probability of becoming an exporter. Empirical evidence has shown 3 that if the sunk cost associated with importing and exporting to the same market is shared, having importing activity can increase the likelihood that a firms is a two-way trader (e.g. Kasahara and Lapham, 2013; Muuls and Pisu, 2009). Aristei et al. (2013) find that prior importing experience has a positive effect on the decision to start exporting. Empirical evidence suggests that there is a positive effect associated with engaging in both importing and exporting activities: two-way traders appear to perform better and to be more productive (Muuls and Pisu, 2009; Aristei et al., 2013). Through imports companies can gain knowledge about foreign markets, increase their productivity by having access to cheaper inputs and reach the productivity threshold necessary to become exporters (Kasahara and Lapham, 2013; Blalock and Veloso, 2007; Bas and Strauss-Kahn, 2013). To raise productivity and quality of production, firms increasingly follow the requirements and specificities spelled out in internationally accepted quality standards and engage in the procedures necessary to obtain certification, indicating that the requirements of the international standards are met3. The implementation of internationally accepted standards has indeed become an increasingly important factor facilitating foreign market access for developing country firms. Czubala et al. (2009) show this for African textiles and clothing exports to the EU. Product standards have been developed defining technical specificities of products in all industries. In addition, generic process standards are equally developed, describing best-practice management systems more generally. The most widely diffused and adopted standards in this category are those developed by the International Standards Organisation, and known as the ISO 9000 and ISO 14000 series related to the implementations of quality assurance systems. The certification adoption is rising worldwide as more and more developing country firms adhere to the standards. In studies that empirically explain the role of quality in export performance, various scholar proxy the ability to produce quality by the possession of international quality certificates (Hallak and Sivadisan, 2013, Verhoogen, 2008). A number of papers show that ISO 9000 certification is correlated with direct measures of product quality (e.g. Carlsson and Carlsson 1996, Brown et al. 1998, and Withers and Ebrahimpour 2000) and customer satisfaction (Buttle, 1997). 3 For firm implementing the standards, certification can be obtained after an external audit confirms that the requirement of the standards are met. 4 A vast literature developed in parallel, describing the motivations for firms to obtain certification and its advantages for firm performance. A major motivation for firms to implement standards appear to be the resulting benefits and improvements in operational performance, as firms experience cost reductions resulting from better managed and codified production procedures (Sampaio et al., 2009). However, the certificate is also used strategically, to ‘signal’ to external parties that the firm is a high-performer on quality management issues, reinforcing its credentials in the market place. Firms with a certificate are more easily viewed as a reliable supplier committed to quality (see Sampaio et al., 2009 for an overview), facilitating foreign market entry. This explains why firms not only implement good management practices, but also try and obtain certification despite the considerable financial investment it implies (Guler et al., 2002). Signalling becomes important when information asymmetries exist between sellers and buyers in vertical relationships, when important characteristics of the firm or product are not directly observable, thereby increasing uncertainty, raising transaction costs and potentially inhibiting economic exchange. This view is strongly embedded in the New Institutional Economics perspective, which builds on the influential work of Coase (1937) - who identified transactions costs as a factor why some transactions do not take place between firms but rather within firms – and Williamson (1975, 1985) who identified bounded rationality and individual opportunism as factors potentially raising those transaction costs. To reduce uncertainty in transactions, institutions are the important ‘rules of the game’ that shape economic interactions (North, 1991) and they can be either formal institutions – including laws, regulations, property rights - or informal rules, such as norms and values, habits and practices, social conventions, reputations and trust. Some authors view certification as a decentralised institution, where the certificate represents a low-cost instrument capable of signalling a firm’s superior but unobserved quality performance (King, Lenox, Terlaak, 2005; Terlaak and King, 2006, Clougherty and Grajek, 2008; Potoski, Prakash, 2009). It is therefore an important instrument not only to raise efficiency levels but also to reduce foreign market entry costs. In view of the arguments above, we hypothesize: Hypothesis 1. Controlling for productivity, firms with an international standards certificate are more likely to be engaged in export transactions 5 The benefits from implementing standards and certification should be more important for firms in developing countries where markets are missing or institutions are weak. Firms operating in institutionally weak countries are disproportionately hampered by information asymmetries and negative reputations effects. When contract law is weak or less enforceable in settling conflict situations and rules and regulations lacking or less respected, transaction cost may turn out to be very substantial. The cost of convincing trading partners about reliability and trustworthiness in respecting formal and informal contractual agreements will then be higher. Problems of adverse selection and moral hazard may withhold foreign buyers to engage in deep trading relationships with firms in countries characterized by strong institutional deficiencies. It seems logical that under such circumstances firms will take own initiatives to convince foreign buyers of their reliability and use ISC certification not only as a proof of efficiency but also as a signaling device of trustworthiness in respecting rules and procedures, including seller-buyer contractual agreements (Terlaak and King, 2006; Potoski and Prakash, 2009). Hence, Hypothesis 2: The impact of quality certification on the probability of being an exporter is stronger in institutionally weak countries Success in global markets - measured by total export sales– is to a large extent determined by the same factors that make firms start exporting. Higher levels of productivity are associated with better export performance. However, once active on foreign markets, there appear in addition to be some feedback mechanisms which enable exporting firms to better realize economies of scale and through which firms learn from interacting with sophisticated and demanding buyers, so called learning-by-exporting hypothesis. Various scholars find supportive evidence for learning-by-exporting (Bigsten et al., 2004; Blalock and Gertler, 2004; Kraay, 1999; Girma et al., 2005; Van Biesebroeck, 2005; Yasar et al., 2006), though the evidence is more mixed than for the self-selection hypothesis (Clerides and Lach, 1998, Castellani, 2002, Delgado et al., 2002, Arnold and Hussinger, 2005, Damijan and Kostevc, 2006). In a survey paper on the issue, Wagner (2007) summarises the debate and concludes that ‘the more productive firms self-select into export markets, while exporting does not necessarily improve productivity’. 6 But, besides productivity, both fixed and variable transaction costs influence the export intensity. Helpman et al. (2008) develop a model that explains the export volumes between pairs of countries by the productivity of firms and the existing differences in fixed and variable costs in setting up and sustaining trade relationships in these countries. Only the more productive firms find it profitable to export. However, the profitability of exports varies by destination; it is higher to countries with higher demand levels, lower variable export costs, and lower fixed export costs. Along these lines, Lawless and Whelan (2008) observe a limited role for productivity in explaining firm exporting behaviour, but find that past exporting to a particular market has a strong impact on the current exports there. In a similar way, Das et al. (2007) find that the existence of entry costs makes firms exports dependent on their previous exporting status: firms that already export can increase their volumes at marginal production costs, while those that do not, must bear the sunk cost of entry into foreign markets and establishing relationships with foreign buyers. Yoshino (2008) finds that technological factors such as new vintage capital and internet access reduce export costs and raise export intensity of African manufacturing firms. Also foreign ownership is a significant factor in characterizing the intensity of global exports. Using data on Colombian firms, Brooks (2006) finds that in addition to plant size, factor intensities, location, ownership structure and heterogeneity in product quality and better skilled workforce need to be taken into account to explain the observed export sales distribution. Clougherty and Grajek (2008) argue and find supporting macro-evidence at the country level that a widespread use of ‘ISO 9000 helps standardise practices and terminology, mobilise resources, and structure efforts across organisations. The quality-signal, common-language, and conflict-settling properties lower the transaction costs and information asymmetries involved with business-to-business relations across borders, thus making arm’s length trading relations less costly.’ Additional to the productivity and quality differences, quality certificates can therefore be an efficient instrument to reduce the cost of sustaining relations with international clients and for signalling producer quality. Firms have an incentive to use quality standards to signal their commitment to continuously deliver a reliable product and provide the necessary sales service. Clearly, for firms who sell their products to wider markets, the information problems that raise transaction costs may be more serious, as spatial, 7 cultural, and linguistic barriers complicate the buyers’ capability to assess product quality (King, Lenox and Terlaak, 2005; Potoski and Prakash, 2009). Testing these arguments at the level of the individual firm, We therefore hypothesise: Hypothesis 3. Controlling for productivity, firms with an international standards certificate export more Clougherty and Grajek (2008) find a wide diffusion of ISO certifications to ‘‘push’’ exports to hold only for developing countries. They interpret this finding that the signaling role of a quality certificate matters more for firms based in countries where institutions are weakly developed. While they could show evidence for export sales at the country level, our data allows us to refine the testing of this argument with firm level data. Next, to hypothesizing that a quality certificate increases the likelihood to engage in exporting more in institutionally weak countries, we test: Hypothesis 4: The effect of certification on the total export sales of a firm will be higher in countries with weak institutional quality In the next section we empirically test these hypotheses against a large data set on manufacturing firms operating in 89 developing and transition countries. 3. Empirical approach 3.1. Data For studying these relationships at the micro-level, we use firm level data from the World Bank Enterprise Surveys (WBES) from 89 countries which were surveyed between 2006 and 2013. For countries which were surveyed more than once in this period, the data of the last survey round are used for the analysis. The WBES data are the most important source of harmonised firm-level survey data comparable across countries, covering the factors that affect the performance of firms in developing countries. The samples of firms in the WBES 8 are drawn from national business registers following a stratified random sampling based on location, size and industry (for more details on methodology of the http://www.enterprisesurveys.org/Methodology). The data are cross-section data and contain key information on indicators of the performance of the firm, including their exposure to foreign competition and their export performance. For the purpose of this analysis, the data set also contains information on productivity, the international standards certification (ISC) status of the firm, human capital, industry of activity, technological efforts and other relevant aspects. After pooling the various country data sets, we retained only firms active in manufacturing, while firms in services and retail were dropped. This was done because the questionnaire used for retail and services firms missed information on the capital stock and skill level of the work force. In addition, a number of firms dropped out because they had missing information on variables crucial to our analysis. This resulted in a firm level data set of over 18000 firms active in the following major sectors: food processing and beverages (20%), machinery and metal (16%), garments (13%), non-metallic and plastic materials (11%), textiles (8%), chemicals (8%), wood and furniture (4%) , electronics (2%), auto components (1%), other manufacturing (13%). The sample is presented in table 1. Insert table 1 here Table 1 presents the countries included in the sample and the number of observations in each country. To test hypotheses 2 and 4 – that ISC is more important for firms in institutionally weak countries- we need a measurement of institutional quality of the countries. For this, we use the World Bank Ease of Doing Business (EDB) index corresponding to the respective year of the survey. The EDB-index measures the regulations directly affecting businesses and is a composite index based on the average of 10 sub-indices including starting a business; dealing with construction permits; employing workers; registering property; getting credit; protecting investors; paying taxes; international trading; contract enforcement; closing a business (for more details see World Bank, 2005). 9 On average 28% of the sampled firms have an internationally accepted quality certificate. There are however large differences across countries, ranging from as high as 73% in the Czech Republic, 71% in China and 64% in Hungary to a low of 3% to 7% in Guinea Bissau, Burundi and conflict-affected states like Iraq and Côte d’Ivoire. Interestingly, splitting the countries by level of institutional quality, the average proportion of certified firms is 38% in the upper half of countries with better institutional quality, against 19% in the lower half of countries with weaker institutional quality. 3.2. Econometric model Since we are interested in explaining both the probability of being an exporter as well as the export intensity, i.e. the amount of sales coming from exporting for those who export, we develop an econometric model and estimation strategy that accounts for the zero values in the export intensity equation for the non-exporting firms. We therefore estimate a two-step model, inspired by Heckman (1979) for cross-section data, which estimates in the first stage the likelihood that a firm is exporting. In the second stage, an export intensity equation is estimated for the exporting firms only, with selection bias correction. Indeed it is likely that unobservable factors that affect export participation are equally influencing the export intensity. Formally, the first step would estimate, using a Probit model, the following equation Pi (Export=1)= γZ i + ε i (1) This is the selection equation, where Pi is the probability that a firms is exporting or not and Zi is a vector of relevant explanatory variables. In line with the arguments developed above, the key variables of interest included in Zi are measures of firm productivity and the possession of an ISC. Based on equation (1), estimates of the inverse Mill’s ratio will be obtained for each firm as: λ1i (γ Z i ) = φ(γ Z i ) / Φ (γ Z i ) for the exporting firms and λ0i (γ Z i ) = - φ(γ Z i ) / (1- Φ (γ Z i )) for the non-exporting firms 10 where φ(.) is the density function and (.) Φ is the cumulative distribution function of the standard normal distribution N(0, 1). The inverse Mill’s ratio is the instrument that will be used to correct the selection bias in the second stage. In the second step we estimate using OLS: Log(Exports)= X i + λ1 i + ε i Again, the key variables of interest included in Xi are measures of firm productivity and the possession of an ISC for testing hypotheses 1 and 3. By interacting certification with institutional quality variables of the country where the firm is active, we test whether certification has a different impact on exports depending on the level of development of the country (hypotheses 2 and 4). 3.3.Variables The variables used in the estimations are defined and their summary statistics are presented in table 2. Insert table 2 here The main variable relates to the possession of an Internationally recognised Standards Certificate (ISC). Firms were asked in the survey if they ‘possess an internationally recognised quality certificate (some examples are ISO 9000, 9002, ISO 14000, HACCP (for food) and AATCC (for textiles)’. We constructed a binary variable equalling one if the firm answered yes to the question. Productivity is measured as the normalized sales per employee in the last book year. Given the large number of countries in the sample, and the fact that sales are expressed in local currency unit and related to different years for different countries, the variable was normalised with a min-max normalisation4, where the industry and country minimum and maximum values were used. 4 Min-max normalization is the process of taking data and transforming it to a value between 0 and 1. The lowest (min) value is set to 0, the highest (max) value is set to 1. This provides 11 We used a dichotomous variable to indicate the ‘institutional quality’ of a country. The variable takes the value one if the firm is active in a country belonging to the upper half of institutional quality ranking following the Ease of Doing Business’ measure compiled by the World Bank. Control variables As control variables we include a human capital variable measuring the skills level of the labour force (%Skilled). We also control for firm size, measured by the log of capital (lcapital). In accordance with the literature section, we include in the estimations the percentage of foreign inputs to measure the possible effect of sunk cost complementarity on the exporting status and performance. In the export sales equation which we run on the exporting firms, we equally include the number of years since they first started exporting, as suggested by Das et al., 2007. Finally, sector and country dummies are included to capture country and industry specific effects such as exchange rate differences and technological conditions determining the existence of scale economies. 4. Results 4.1 Who is exporter? Before turning to the estimation, we first look at the descriptive statistics presented in table 3. About one third of the entire sample of firms is actually exporting. When we look at the subgroup of firms without an ISC, this proportion reduces to 23.7%. By contrast, for the group of firms possessing an ISC, more than half of the firms, or 56.8% is an exporter, suggesting a strong correlation between the two variables. Also the institutional quality of the country reveals some differences: of the firms located in countries with better institutional quality, the proportion of exporters is 41%. In institutionally weaker countries, only 27% of the firms export. Since we are interested in the interaction of ISC and the institutional quality of the country, we also present the proportions along these two variables combined. It can be an easy way to compare values that are measured using different scales. The normalised value is defined as : ( the value – the minimum )/(the range of values). 12 seen from the table that in institutionally weaker countries, there is a large gap in the proportion of firms exporting between the ISC holders and the other firms: 19% versus 57%. In other words, the probability of being an exporter is very low in institutionally weak countries if the firm has no ISC. On the contrary, when the firm has an ISC, the chances of being an exporter come close, or even exceed, those of ISC holders in highly developed countries. In the latter countries, nevertheless, not-having an ISC seems to be less harmful for the export status: still 31% of the firms are exporting without possessing an ISC. Firms relative productivity position within the own industry and country is also different and superior for exporting firms. The low mean value of the productivity variable indicates that there is a large heterogeneity in productivity across firms, resulting in a skewed distribution of productivity. Clearly, as suggested in the literature section, holding an ISC is correlated with higher productivity levels. The values of the productivity variable for ISC holders versus other firms are 0.13 versus 0.09 respectively. It therefore remains an interesting question whether, controlling for productivity, ISC will still show up as a significant determinant of export performance. Insert table 3 here To tease out the mechanisms and interactions between the various variables explaining to the export decision, we present in table 4, column one and two, the results of the probit estimation. The table reports marginal effects, with for dummy variables the change in the probability of having a quality certificate from a discrete change of the dummy from zero to one. The results confirm what was already suggested from the bivariate presentation. More productive firms are more likely to be exporter. Controlling for this, the possession of a quality certificate still raises the likelihood of being an exporter by 23%, underscoring the signalling role of certification and the importance of quality performance in international trade and providing support for hypothesis one. It is also more likely to be an exporter when the firm operates from a country with solid institutions, that are instrumental in reducing or overcoming high sunk cost related to entering foreign markets. In column two, the interaction term between ISC and InstitutionalQ is added to the equation. For firms in countries with higher institutional quality, the negative coefficient for the interaction terms with ISC points at a downward correction of the ISC effect. The coefficient suggests that the effects from certification are strongest for firms located in low institutional quality countries and less strong in high institutional quality countries. This implies that in 13 countries with good institutions, the signalling role of ISC is less important. Alternatively in weakly developed markets, the obtention of an ISC is more important in distinguishing between exporting and non-exporting firms, indicating that ISC act as substitutes in deficient markets. This grants support for hypothesis 2. Interestingly, the additional control variable %Foreigninputs also turns out to be a significant determinant for the decision to export. Foreign market knowledge acquired through import activities also facilitates the development of export activities. The positive coefficient for Lcapital (capital assets) reflects the fact that large firms can more easily incur and overcome the large sunk costs associated with exporting. Somewhat remarkably, the skill intensity of the labour force found in many empirical studies from developed economies is not significant here. Important industry and country differences are equally observed (but not reported in detail). Insert table 4 here 4.2 Export sales Columns three and four show the results explaining the (logarithmic) value of exports. Higher productivity levels are associated with higher export levels. Controlling for this, having an ISC significantly raises the value of exports, in support of hypothesis 3. We indeed find evidence in support of a significant micro-level export bonus for certificate holders, which at the more aggregate level may lead to a healthy contribution to the export performance of developing countries, as found by Potoski and Prakash (2009). On the contrary, we do not find that the interaction term of ISC and the institutional quality of the country is significant. Hence, hypothesis 4 is not supported. To account for longer term influences of the exposure to international market knowledge we also added the years of experience in exporting to the equation, also including the quadratic term to allow for non-linearities in the relationship. We find an inverted U-shaped relationship between the duration in exporting and the amount of exports. It is calculated that at the sample means the amount of exports go up by 4% with an additional year of export experience. Also the skill level of the labour force is positive and significant in the equation here, as is the percentage of inputs of foreign origin. 14 Altogether, these variables indicate that, while the decision to export is largely determined by variables related to overcoming initial sunk cost of starting to export, export performance measured through export sales is explained by firm specific knowledge and skills about the export market, built up over time. Finally, the significance of the inverse mill’s Ratio, denoted by λ1, shows that there are unobservable characteristics that affect both the decision to export and the export intensity. 4.3 Local versus foreign firms Finally we examined differences in ISC impact for local firms (column 5) versus foreign firms (column 6). The traditional export determinants – capital intensity and productivity- are significant and with the expected sign. Certification positively affects export sales in both subsamples but the effect appears to be larger for local firms than for foreign firms. 6. Discussion and conclusions This study presents original evidence on the relationship between certification and export performance at the micro level of the firm, and on the effects of quality certification by firms located in countries differentiated by the quality of institutions. Against a large dataset of manufacturing firms operating in 89 countries we test the basic hypotheses that international quality certification has a major impact on the decision to export and the intensity of exports, as measured by the value of exports. We argue that firms implement internationally accepted standards to improve the efficiency of their operations and quality of their products and services, two factors that are found to be key determinants for the export performance of firms. In addition, firm apply for a certificate of conformity with the international standards to signal to buyers and other stakeholders their commitment concerning quality of governance and reliability in commercial transactions. This is an important instrument to reduce both variable and fixed transaction costs, which in environments characterised by uncertainty and asymmetric information, can be very high and hampering international trade. A number of recent studies investigate such effects of certification as a signalling device. Global standards, including the widely used ISO 9000, are seen as transaction supporting institutions by themselves and considered as a substitute for 15 missing or deficient national institutions. Recent empirical studies have argued that firms located in developing countries face the difficulties that consumers in global markets, deciding under information asymmetry, associate their product with the generally poor reputation of its country of origin (Potoski, Prakash, 2009). They infer that these producers face greater difficulty in signalling their product quality and that international standards act as a mechanism to mitigate information asymmetries and stimulate international trade. Macro evidence was found to support this idea. Our empirical results support the importance of quality certification for both the export status and the level of export sales by individual firms. Controlling for productivity of the firm, ISC raises the likelihood of exporting – in line with argument that it helps to overcome sunk cost of establishing relations with foreign buyers and facilitates entry. An interesting finding is that this effect goes up for firms located in institutionally less developed countries, thereby providing micro evidence for the specific role of international quality certificates as a substitute institution for reducing transaction costs. Consistent with its impact on the decision to start exporting, ISC raises export sales by reducing transaction costs and by sustaining the firm’s competitive edge in international trading relations. 16 References Alvarez, R. and López, R. A. (2005) Exporting and performance: Evidence from chilean plants. Canadian Journal of Economics 38(4): 1384-1400. Aristei, D., Castellani, D. and Franco, C. (2013) Firms' exporting and importing activities: Is there a two-way relationship? Review of World Economics 149(1): 55-84. Arnold, J. M. and Hussinger, K. (2005) Export behavior and firm productivity in german manufacturing: A firm-level analysis. Review of World Economics 141(2): 219-243. Aw, B. Y., Chung, S. and Roberts, M. J. (2000) Productivity and turnover in the export market: Micro-level evidence from the republic of korea and taiwan (china). World Bank Economic Review 14(1): 65-90. Bas, M. and Strauss-Kahn, V. (2013) Does importing more inputs raise exports? Firm-level evidence from france. Review of World Economics: 1-35. Bernard, A. B. and Jensen, J. B. (1999) Exceptional exporter performance: Cause, effect, or both? Journal of International Economics 47(1): 1-25. Bernard, A. B. and Jensen, J. B. (2004) Why some firms export. Review of Economics and Statistics 86(2): 561-569. Bernard, A. B. and Wagner, J. (2001) Export entry and exit by german firms. Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv 137(1): 105-123. Bigsten, A., Collier, P., Dercon, S., Fafchamps, M., Gauthier, B., Gunning, J. W., Oduro, A., Oostendorp, R., Pattillo, C., Söderbom, M., Teal, F. and Zeufack, A. (2004) Do african manufacturing firms learn from exporting? Journal of Development Studies 40(3): 115-141. Blalock, G. and Gertler, P. J. (2004) Learning from exporting revisited in a less developed setting. Journal of Development Economics 75(2 SPEC. ISS.): 397-416. Blalock, G. and Veloso, F. M. (2007) Imports, productivity growth, and supply chain learning. World Development 35(7): 1134-1151. Brooks, E. L. (2006) Why don't firms export more? Product quality and colombian plants. Journal of Development Economics 80(1): 160-178. 17 Brown, A., van der Wiele, T. and Loughton, K. (1998) Smaller enterprises’ experiences with iso 9000. International Journal of Quality & Reliability Management 15(3): 273-285. Buttle, F. (1997) Iso 9000: Marketing motivations and benefits. International Journal of Quality & Reliability Management 14(9): 936-947. Carlsson, M. and Carlsson, D. (1996) Experiences of implementing iso 9000 in swedish industry. International Journal of Quality & Reliability Management 13(7): 36-47. Castellani, D. (2002) Export behavior and productivity growth: Evidence from italian manufacturing firms. Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv 138(4): 605-628. Chaney, T. (2008) Distorted gravity: The intensive and extensive margins of international trade. The American Economic Review 98(4): 1707-1721. Clerides, S. K., Lach, S. and Tybout, J. R. (1998) Is learning by exporting important? Microdynamic evidence from colombia, mexico, and morocco. Quarterly Journal of Economics 113(3): 903-947. Clougherty, J. A. and Grajek, M. (2008) The impact of iso 9000 diffusion on trade and fdi: A new institutional analysis. Journal of International Business Studies 39(4): 613-633. Coase, R. H. (1937) The nature of the firm. in 4 economica, 386-405. Damijan, J. e. P. and Kostevc, Ä. (2006) Learning-by-exporting: Continuous productivity improvements or capacity utilization effects? Evidence from slovenian firms. Review of World Economics 142(3): 599-614. Das, S., Roberts, M. J. and Tybout, J. R. (2007) Market entry costs, producer heterogeneity, and export dynamics. Econometrica 75(3): 837-873. Delgado, M. A., Farinas, J. C. and Ruano, S. (2002) Firm productivity and export markets: A non-parametric approach. Journal of International Economics 57(2): 397-422. Girma, S., Kneller, R. and Pisu, M. (2005) Exports versus fdi: An empirical test. Review of World Economics 141(2): 193-218. Guler, I., Guillén, M. F. and Macpherson, J. M. (2002) Global competition, institutions, and the diffusion of organizational practices: The international spread of iso 9000 quality certificates. Administrative Science Quarterly 47(2): 207-232. Hallak, J. C. (2006) Product quality and the direction of trade. Journal of International Economics 68(1): 238-265. 18 Hallak, J. C. and Sivadasan, J. (2013) Product and process productivity: Implications for quality choice and conditional exporter premia. Journal of International Economics 91(1): 53-67. Iacovone, L. and Javorcik, B. S. (2010) Multi-product exporters: Product churning, uncertainty and export discoveries. Economic Journal 120(544): 481-499. Kasahara, H. and Lapham, B. (2013) Productivity and the decision to import and export: Theory and evidence. Journal of International Economics 89(2): 297-316. King, A. A., Lenox, M. J. and Terlaak, A. (2005) The strategic use of decentralized institutions: Exploring certification with the iso 14001 management standard. Academy of Management Journal 48(6): 1091-1106. Kraay, A. (1999) Exportations et performances économiques: Étude d'un panel d'entreprises chinoises. Revue d'économie du développement (Paris) (1-2): 183-207. Lawless, M. and Whelan, K. (2008) Where do firms export, how much, and why? in Working Paper Series, UCD Centre for Economic Research 08/21: University College Dublin (UCD). Maskus, K. E., Otsuki, Y. and Wilson, J. S. (2005) The cost of compliance with product standards for firms in developing countries: An econometric study. in World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3590. Washington: World Bank, 35. Melitz, M. J. (2003) The impact of trade on intra-industry reallocations and aggregate industry productivity. Econometrica 71(6): 1695-1725. Muûls, M. and Pisu, M. (2009) Imports and exports at the level of the firm: Evidence from belgium. World Economy 32(5): 692-734. North, D. C. (1991) Institutions. Journal of Economic Perspectives 5(1): 97-112. Potoski, M. and Prakash, A. (2009) Information asymmetries as trade barriers: Iso 9000 increases international commerce. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 28(2): 221-238. Sampaio, P., Saraiva, P. and Rodrigues, A. G. (2009) Iso 9001 certification research: Questions, answers and approaches. International Journal of Quality and Reliability Management 26(1): 38-58. 19 Terlaak, A. and King, A. A. (2006) The effect of certification with the iso 9000 quality management standard: A signaling approach. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 60(4): 579-602. Van Biesebroeck, J. (2005) Exporting raises productivity in sub-saharan african manufacturing firms. Journal of International Economics 67(2): 373-391. Verhoogen, E. A. (2008) Trade, quality upgrading, and wage inequality in the mexican manufacturing sector. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 123(2): 489-530. Wagner, J. (2007) Exports and productivity: A survey of the evidence from firm-level data. World Economy 30(1): 60-82. Williamson, O. E. (1975) Markets and hierarchies: Analysis and antitrust implications. New York: Free Press. Williamson, O. E. (1985) The economic institutions of capitalism. New York: Free Press. Withers, B. and Ebrahimpour, M. (2000) Does iso 9000 certification affect the dimensions of quality used for competitive advantage? European Management Journal 18(4): 431443. WorldBank (2005) Doing business indicators. Washington D.C.: World Bank. Yasar, M., Nelson, C. H. and Rejesus, R. (2006) Productivity and exporting status of manufacturing firms: Evidence from quantile regressions. Review of World Economics 142(4): 675-694. Yoshino, Y. (2008) Domestic constraints, firm characteristics, and geographical diversification of firm-level manufacturing exports in africa. in World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 4575 World Bank.Adams, M., 1999, Determinants of ISO accreditation in the New Zealand manufacturing sector, Omega, 27, 285-292. 20 Table 1: composition of the sample, by country and incidence of certification Country survey Afghanistan2014 Albania2007 Angola2010 Argentina2010 Armenia2009 Azerbaijan2013 Bangladesh2013 Belarus2013 Bolivia2010 Bosnia and Herzegov.. Botswana2010 Brazil2009 Bulgaria2007 BurkinaFaso2009 Burundi2006 Cameroon2009 Chile2010 China2012 Colombia2010 Costarica2010 Croatia2007 Czech Republic2009 DRC2010 DominicanRepublic2010 Ecuador2010 Elsalvador2010 Estonia2009 Ethiopia2011 Fyr Macedonia2009 Gambia2006 Georgia2013 Ghana2007 Guatemala2010 Guinea2006 GuineaBissau2006 Honduras2010 Hungary2009 Indonesia2009 Iraq2011 Ivory Coast2009 N 17 45 116 577 62 8 1,088 57 38 73 53 975 379 34 88 81 602 1,391 572 202 230 55 72 80 92 80 71 106 91 27 48 269 202 96 42 44 81 619 471 110 %ISC Country survey 0.47 0.33 0.28 0.37 0.35 0.00 0.22 0.16 0.21 0.44 0.21 0.18 0.37 0.24 0.05 0.27 0.36 0.71 0.33 0.19 0.37 0.73 0.13 0.24 0.33 0.23 0.46 0.18 0.36 0.19 0.21 0.07 0.14 0.06 0.05 0.32 0.64 0.11 0.03 0.06 LaoPDR2012 Latvia2009 Lithuania2009 Madagascar2009 Mali2010 Mauritania2006 Mauritius2009 Mexico2010 Moldova2013 Mongolia2009 Montenegro2009 Mozambique2007 Namibia2006 Nepal2013 Nicaragua2010 Nigeria2007 Pakistan2007 Panama2010 Paraguay2010 Peru2010 Philippines2009 Poland2009 Romania2009 Russia2012 Senegal2007 Serbia2013 Slovak Republic2009 Slovenia2009 SouthAfrica2007 SriLanka2011 Swaziland2006 Tajikistan2008 Tanzania2013 TrinidadandTobago2010 Turkey2008 Uganda2013 Ukraine2008 Uruguay2010 Uzbekistan2008 Venezuela2010 21 N 36 60 63 142 16 73 106 1,015 36 126 19 263 95 181 23 870 125 13 69 504 463 67 69 439 214 69 46 71 652 237 61 67 49 73 465 63 201 168 116 44 %ISC 0.19 0.38 0.22 0.10 0.06 0.08 0.16 0.23 0.22 0.19 0.11 0.14 0.28 0.16 0.39 0.09 0.46 0.31 0.25 0.27 0.33 0.28 0.42 0.17 0.07 0.54 0.43 0.52 0.37 0.14 0.26 0.18 0.20 0.26 0.51 0.22 0.20 0.25 0.21 0.18 Jamaica2010 Kazakhstan2013 Kenya2013 Kosovo2009 Krygyz Republic2013 75 46 190 62 44 0.27 0.26 0.31 0.10 0.18 22 Vietnam2009 Yemen2010 Zambia2013 Zimbabwe2011 635 112 135 348 0.28 0.09 0.19 0.32 TOTAL 18,460 0.28 Table 2: Definition of variables Variable name Definition Mean (STD) Dependent variables EXPORT =1 if the firm exports (in the last fiscal year prior to the survey) 0.14 (0.29) LEXPORT Value of those exports, in log. 17.12 (3.53) 0.12 (0.22) ISC lcapital Productivity, measured by sales per employee, in the last fiscal year prior to the survey, normalised, using the country-industry specific range =1 if firm has internationally recognized quality certification Net book value of the capital stock, in log. D-Foreign InstitutionalQ %Skilled =1 if the firm is foreign owned =1 if the firm is active in a country with high institutional quality Proportion of skilled production workers in total production workers %Foreigninputs Percentage of inputs of foreign origin Yearsexporting Number of year of experience in exporting Explanatory variables Productivity 23 0.27 15.98 (3.38) 0.11 0.41 0.50 (0.28) 28.19 (35.19) 3.81 (8.67) Table 3: Firm and country characteristics and the export status of the firm: summary statistics Non-exporting Exporting Total Number of firms Full sample With ISC InstitutionalQ=0 InstitutionalQ=1 12,377 2,209 7,997 4,380 6,083 2,920 2,994 3,089 18,460 5,129 10,991 7,469 % of firms all Without ISC With ISC InstitutionalQ=0 InstitutionalQ=1 67.05 76.27 43.07 72.76 58.64 32.95 23.73 56.93 27.24 41.36 100.00 100.00 100.00 100.00 100.00 80.04 42.41 19.96 57.59 100.00 100.00 68.79 43.54 31.21 56.46 100.00 100.00 0.102 0.170 0.124 In InstitutionalQ=0: Without ISC With ISC In InstitutionalQ=1: Without ISC With ISC Productivity 24 Table 4: Results of the probit and OLS regressions explaining the export decision and value OLS VARIABLES Productivity ISC InstitutionalQ PROBIT All firms EXPORTa PROBIT All firms EXPORTa OLS Exporters only lexport OLS Exporters only lexport OLS Local firms lexport OLS Foreign firms lexport 0.078*** (0.020) 0.227*** (0.010) 0.223* (0.121) 2.281*** (0.125) 0.608*** (0.048) 2.549*** (0.902) 0.054*** (0.002) -0.006 (0.014) 0.002*** (0.000) 0.079*** (0.020) 0.251*** (0.013) 0.235* (0.121) -0.044*** (0.016) 0.054*** (0.002) -0.006 (0.014) 0.002*** (0.000) 0.345*** (0.019) 0.292*** (0.092) 0.003*** (0.001) 0.039*** (0.004) -0.000*** (0.000) -1.109*** (0.122) 9.807*** (0.568) 2.280*** (0.125) 0.588*** (0.068) 2.530*** (0.898) 0.039 (0.089) 0.345*** (0.019) 0.293*** (0.092) 0.003*** (0.001) 0.039*** (0.004) -0.000*** (0.000) -1.111*** (0.122) 9.817*** (0.568) 2.439*** (0.160) 0.537*** (0.078) 1.654** (0.676) 0.093 (0.101) 0.305*** (0.022) 0.169* (0.102) 0.001* (0.001) 0.042*** (0.005) -0.000*** (0.000) -1.210*** (0.134) 9.708*** (0.634) 1.917*** (0.201) 0.339** (0.137) -0.882 (0.619) 0.039 (0.189) 0.383*** (0.040) 0.752*** (0.193) 0.002 (0.001) 0.041*** (0.012) -0.001** (0.000) -0.522* (0.283) 10.529*** (1.200) 18,451 18,451 6,051 0.788 6,051 0.788 4,653 0.779 1,398 0.815 ISC*InstitutionalQ lcapital %Skilled %Foreigninputs Yearsexporting Yearsexporting^2 λ1 Constant Observations R-squared Robust standard errors in parentheses; *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1; a Marginal effects reported, with for dummy variables the change in the probability of having a quality certificate from a discrete change of the dummy from zero to one. 25