THE BILLION-TON SOLUTION Europe’s Chance to Lead on Climate Action through International Mitigation Partnerships Andreas Dahl-Jørgensen | February 2015 The Billion-Ton Solution | Dahl-Jørgensen Executive Summary Never has the momentum for global climate action been stronger. For the first time, a global agreement is within reach that includes climate action by all countries. China has agreed to peak its carbon emissions by 2030 at the latest, and also to cap coal use by 2020 and achieve 20% clean energy by 2030. The United States has pledged to reduce emissions 26–28% below 2005 levels by 2025, and the European Union has agreed to cut its internal emissions by “at least 40%” by 2030. However, though all three pledges are arguably more ambitious than previous goals, they are still not ambitious enough to put the international community on a path toward stabilizing the climate. Given these three pledges, and with reasonable assumptions about the forthcoming pledges from other key countries, Climate Advisers has estimated that the gap between the collective national pledges and the emissions level required to limit the global average temperature rise to 2°C relative to the preindustrial level will likely increase. In fact, the sum of the most ambitious national pledges considered likely to be included in the Paris global climate agreement next year will only amount to about half the reductions required to get on a 2°C path. In contrast to previous climate mitigation pledges, most countries are currently focused purely on pledging domestic mitigation. But this approach will not enable the numbers to add up. Moreover, it will miss out on a large portion of the world’s most achievable and cost-effective emission reductions. Paradoxically, out of mathematical necessity most of these reductions will need to happen in the developing countries, whose capacity and historical responsibility are lower, but where all the growth in emissions is currently happening. Leaving the developing countries to take sufficient action by themselves would not only be unjust; it would also not realistically deliver the needed reductions. Therefore, it is in the advanced economies’ interest to help the developing countries do more. This paper argues that the most promising and politically realistic way to further increase climate ambition in 2015 is for Europe and other advanced economies to make additional pledges for mitigation that they intend to secure outside their borders. Doing so would reduce more emissions at a lower cost, unlock large emission cuts in developing countries that would otherwise not occur, help ensure a global climate agreement, facilitate the linking of regional systems and carbon markets, and deliver significant development benefits. The European Union’s goal of at least 40% internal emission reductions was a hard-fought political compromise at a time of considerable economic difficulty. However, it is not compatible with climate science. EU leaders should seek an internal agreement to go beyond 40% at home, but this will be politically challenging. Leaders should also pursue a supplementary strategy: to pledge to reduce emissions abroad — for example, up to 1 billion tons of CO2 per year in 2020-30 as part of a global effort to narrow the mitigation gap. By pledging such “dual contributions” that not only highlight what the EU will do at home but also how much mitigation it would help other nations achieve through international mitigation partnerships, the EU would again demonstrate global climate leadership. Through Germany’s chairmanship of the G7 this year Europe has an opportunity to encourage similar pledges from other developed countries. If this is not feasible, the EU chould make its pledge conditional on commitments from others in Paris. Once the U.S. EPA’s Clean Power Plant gets finalized just before Paris, President Obama could be in a position to join a Europe-led initiative and make an international mitigation pledge. Although he is unlikely to pledge large amounts of finance with a hostile Republican Congress, he and the next president hold executive authorities that can mobilize U.S. efforts to secure mitigation abroad. Similarly, Japan’s Prime Minister Abe is looking for new ways to lead on climate change internationally following the Fukushima nuclear disaster. 2 The Billion-Ton Solution | Dahl-Jørgensen Although the international mitigation pledge should be sector neutral to mobilize innovation in all sectors, efforts to slow tropical forest loss through payments for verified emission reductions (so-called REDD+) could meet a large portion of the EU’s international “1 billion tons pledge,” and would be a preferred option if considering (1) cost-effectiveness, (2) the opportunity to leverage action by other countries and the private sector, (3) development benefits, and (4) the EU’s own contributions to tropical deforestation through commodity imports. The mitigation potential from REDD+ is substantial. Although net forest loss accounts for about 12% of global emissions, the mitigation potential from simultaneously addressing forest loss and forest restoration is much larger. In September 2014, the EU endorsed the New York Declaration on Forests, pledging to “put in place economic incentives commensurate with the challenge”—to halve natural forest loss by 2020 and eliminate it by 2030, and restore an area the size of India by 2030. Meeting these goals would reduce 4.5–8.8 billion tons of CO2 per year in 2030, more than the EU’s total emissions today. Never before has such a vision seemed feasible. The last year has seen a cascade of private sector commitments to eliminate commodity-driven deforestation. The Consumer Goods Forum—whose collective revenues exceed the GDP of France—has called for a climate agreement that includes REDD+ incentives, to help achieve the governance changes in forest-rich countries that are necessary for them to meet their ambitious corporate pledges. Tropical forest countries are increasingly prepared to foot a large portion of the bill on their own, as a contribution to global climate mitigation efforts and to pursue the many local and national benefits. Still, REDD+ incentives, brought to scale, will be key to unlocking all these forces. REDD+ incentive payments may be even more cost-effective than previously thought. Rather than compensating for the forgone profits of individual landowners abstaining from agricultural expansion, REDD+ payments should be viewed as a “political transition incentive” to mobilize the political will to implement law enforcement and sustainable land use policies, replicating the success of Brazil. This lower financial cost, combined with the many development benefits for forest-rich countries, suggests that the EU should seek ways to avoid overpaying for REDD+ reductions whose price in a global market would be set at the marginal cost of expensive energy reductions. This could be done by negotiating bilateral deals—for example, at $5 per ton of CO2—while still finding ways for the European private sector to pay for the emission reductions. A separate international mitigation pledge that includes REDD+ on top of the already agreed-on domestic goal would overcome ideological opposition from nongovernmental organizations that fear REDD+ would otherwise compromise ambitious domestic action. It could be implemented in ways that would enable a group of ambitious EU member states to take the lead. It is fully consistent with the emerging “bottom-up” global climate framework. Most fundamentally, it would make the EU’s climate policy compatible with a 2°C pathway. 3 The Billion-Ton Solution | Dahl-Jørgensen Contents Executive Summary ......................................................................................................................................2 Contents .......................................................................................................................................................4 Acknowledgments ........................................................................................................................................4 Introduction ..................................................................................................................................................5 Part I: The Case for a European Pledge for International Mitigation ............................................................5 1. Increasing Momentum – 2015 Is a Critical Year for Climate Action ....................................................5 2. Europe’s Opening Bid .........................................................................................................................6 3. The Widening Climate Ambition Gap ..................................................................................................8 4. Narrowing the Gap ..............................................................................................................................9 5. Europe’s Second Bite of the Apple: An International Mitigation Pledge ...........................................12 6. Conclusion.........................................................................................................................................18 Part II: The Case for International Forest Mitigation ...................................................................................19 1. The Importance of Forest Mitigation .................................................................................................19 2. What Would It Take to Stop Deforestation? ......................................................................................21 3. The Ongoing Supply Chain Revolution .............................................................................................23 4. The Role of REDD+ Payments ..........................................................................................................25 5. Ready for What? The Moving Goalpost of REDD Demand ...............................................................26 6. The EU’s Opportunity to Lead on Forests .........................................................................................27 Part III: Options for Inclusion in the EU’s Policy and Legal Frameworks ...................................................29 Conclusion..................................................................................................................................................31 Bibliography ...............................................................................................................................................32 Acknowledgments This paper was made possible with the general support of the Blue Moon Fund and the Climate and Land Use Alliance. Its individual sections have benefited from comments by several colleagues. At Climate Advisers, I thank Michael Wolosin, Nigel Purvis and Maria Belenky. Outside Climate Advisers, I thank William Boyd, Jonah Bush, Donna Lee, Ruben Lubowski, Daniel Nepstad, Frances Seymour, and Charlotte Streck. All views, and errors, are my own. 4 The Billion-Ton Solution | Dahl-Jørgensen Introduction This paper makes the case that the European Union should lead the world in an effort to raise global climate ambition further by announcing a commitment to international climate mitigation on top of its internal climate mitigation target. Part I takes stock of the recent climate goals announced by the EU, China, and the United States and examines the expected global mitigation gap that will remain after all the major economies have announced their post-2020 goals for reducing carbon emissions. It discusses options for narrowing this gap, and lays out the benefits of a European pledge to reduce emissions abroad. Part II examines the potential to reduce emissions in the forest sector, arguing that international mitigation through payments for reduced forest emissions in developing countries (REDD+) offers a unique opportunity to deliver a large amount of mitigation at a relatively low cost, and that it thus should be a core part of an EU international mitigation pledge. Finally, part III presents a range of options for incorporating an international mitigation pledge into European policy frameworks. It focuses particularly on those options that will allow the most ambitious European nations to take on most of the new pledge. Part I: The Case for a European Pledge for International Mitigation 1. Increasing Momentum – 2015 Is a Critical Year for Climate Action Never before has the momentum been stronger for global climate action. Climate science is more conclusive than ever. News coverage of the climate issue is on the rise, and a majority of people in most countries now strongly favor increased climate action. The cost of renewable energy is falling faster than experts had predicted, despite weak climate policies. New technology and business models for solar power, battery technology, energy storage, and energy efficiency are making a low-carbon future seem more feasible than ever before. Despite weak or lacking policy signals in most economies, companies are increasingly coming forward with ambitious climate actions voluntarily, and many are pricing in more stringent climate regulations as part of their financial planning and investment decisions. New evidence shows that climate action will be cheaper than previously thought, and only have a negligible additional investment cost over business as usual. In addition, climate action brings substantial co-benefits beyond avoided climate damages, such as improved public health, increased fuel savings, and strengthened energy security.1 However, thus far most national climate policies have been insufficiently stringent to ensure that this growing momentum is brought to bear at a scale that adequately addresses the problem of climate change. This is even truer for global climate policy, which tends to reflect rather than influence the ambition of national climate policies. The next few months will set the global climate ambition for the next 10 to 15 years. By mid-2015, in preparation for the new climate agreement to be adopted later this year at the UN climate change conference in Paris and to take effect starting in 2020, all countries that are “ready to do so” are supposed to put forward their climate goals for the period starting in 2020. Some countries have already 1 Global Commission on the Economy and Climate, Better Growth, Better Climate (London: Global Commission on the Economy and Climate, 2014). 5 The Billion-Ton Solution | Dahl-Jørgensen come forward with their targets. In October 2014, European leaders were the first ones to do so, as they finally reached a compromise on the European Climate and Energy Package, which aims to cut the EU’s internal emissions by at least 40% below 1990 levels by 2030.2 Then, in a landmark joint announcement by presidents Xi and Obama, China agreed for the first time to peak its emissions by a specific date—by 2030 at the latest, while seeking to do so sooner. It also announced that it would cap its coal use by 2020, and have 20% clean energy by 2030. Of these three goals, the coal use peak seems to be the most ambitious. Analysts indicate that meeting the coal peak goal by 2020 implies peaking emissions by 2025 at the latest.3 At the same time, the United States pledged to reduce its emissions 26–28% below 2005 levels by 2025, doubling the annual de-carbonization rate compared with the period before 2020.4 All three pledges are more ambitious than previous goals. Yet, as described further below, they are still not ambitious enough to put the world on a path to avoid dangerous climate change. Although domestic political processes and pressure are the most important factors determining national climate ambitions, the international process can help at the margin. For the first time, a global agreement is within reach that will apply equally to all countries. The agreed-on timeline for putting forward national climate targets will mobilize new commitments from some countries that have not previously had national climate goals. Although the UN principle of “common but differentiated responsibilities and respective capabilities” will still apply, it will now be up to each country to define for itself what climate mitigation contribution it deems adequate and equitable, given its domestic politics and level of development. Despite what some countries and most environmentalists would prefer, the national targets will likely not be legally binding internationally but will instead be reflected in nonbinding national annexes to the international agreement. Only the procedural elements, such as an obligation to regularly update national climate goals and policies and to report on climate action, seem likely to become internationally binding. There will likely be a very light-touch review by the international community of the national offers, but it seems unlikely at this stage that agreement can be reached on a clear process for closing the mitigation gap to limit global average warming to 2°C. 2. Europe’s Opening Bid The European Union has a proud legacy of global climate leadership. Through its participation in the Kyoto Protocol, the EU adopted an internationally legally binding climate target through 2012 (and later extended until 2020). In Copenhagen in 2009, the EU took a leadership position by pledging to reduce emissions 20% below 1990 levels by 2020 regardless of other countries’ efforts, and by offering to increase its pledge to 30% in the context of an ambitious agreement. It put in place ambitious policies to meet its 2020 goal, with the flagship EU Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS) at the core (covering about half the EU’s emissions), complemented with separate targets for renewable energy deployment and energy efficiency. Recently, however, the EU’s leadership has been subsiding. The lack of an ambitious and binding global climate agreement in Copenhagen in 2009 made it politically impossible for the EU to raise its 2020 target to 30%, as it had planned to do, and it got stuck with the 20% target even as circumstances changed. The worldwide economic recession reduced the EU’s energy consumption and emissions, making it easier and cheaper than anticipated to meet the 20% target. According to the European 2 See http://ec.europa.eu/clima/policies/2030/index_en.htm. See http://switchboard.nrdc.org/blogs/jschmidt/china_evolving_to_coal_consump.html. 4 White House, “President to Attend Copenhagen Climate Talks,” http://www.whitehouse.gov/the-­‐press-­‐office/president-­‐ attend-­‐copenhagen-­‐climate-­‐talks. 3 6 The Billion-Ton Solution | Dahl-Jørgensen Commission’s own analysis in 2013, the EU is on track to reach 24% by 2020 without new policies, and to reach 32% by 2030.5 The ETS suffered from a large oversupply of allowances driven by the recession and mandatory energy targets for renewables. As a consequence, the price signal created by the ETS became too weak to change investment decisions. One could make the case that the market worked exactly as intentioned, and that the plummeting carbon price might have been necessary for the ETS to survive the politics of a recession, in a way a fixed carbon tax could actually not have been. But the sustained low carbon price – currently trading at about €7 per ton CO2 – is evidence that Europe could pursue more ambitious targets at an affordable cost. The EU failed to adapt to these changing circumstances by tightening its climate policies. (At the moment, the EU Parliament is discussing options for reducing the oversupply through a market stability reserve to start sometime between 2017 and 2021). Although this may help avoid similar mistakes in the future and increase the European carbon price in the medium term, it is unlikely to help much in the short term.) In recent years, the United States has reduced its emissions more rapidly than the EU. This is partly due to the shale gas revolution in the United States, which Europe has—at least so far—chosen not to replicate at scale. Also, because Europe started taking serious climate action decades earlier, the United States still has almost twice the emissions per capita as the EU, and therefore a much bigger reduction potential today. The EU’s new goal of a 40% reduction by 2030 is an important first step. It is slightly more ambitious than the current path. The implied annual de-carbonization rate through 2030 (1.9%) is higher than the U.S. annual rate through 2025 (1.6%).6 More important, the 2030 goal is an important sign of political will at a time when many EU countries are in the midst of economic hardship. Getting a clear and early policy signal for European business through 2030 was in itself an achievement. By being the first out of the gate to set a goal for the post-2020 period, and by leaving room for this goal to be strengthened before Paris, Europe also set an example. China and the United States did follow suit just weeks later, though not as a consequence of the European announcement. (Indeed, the political establishment in both China and the United States increasingly view the climate problem as a “Group of Two” issue.) However, though the EU may not have triggered commitments from China and the United States, a lack of leadership from the EU, as the traditional climate leader, would have had a negative influence on other key countries. The EU must go beyond 40% to do its fair share of an effort to limit global warming to 2°C. Clearly, the 2030 goal of at least 40% domestic reductions was a hard-fought and carefully crafted political compromise between ambitious countries (mostly Western European ones) on one hand, and coaldependent, less affluent Eastern European countries on the other hand. This internal battle for ambition is continuing. German chancellor Angela Markel was quoted as saying that the compromise provides flexibility to increase the EU’s ambition in Paris.7 The UK had advocated a 50% reduction target. 8 The UK took the lead in creating a powerful coalition of 14 EU countries, called the “Green Growth Group,” had also called for deeper targets. The members of this group—which comprises the EU’s 7 largest 5 European Union, “EU Energy, Transport and GHG Emissions: Trends to 2050, Reference Scenario 2013,” 2013, http://ec.europa.eu/clima/policies/2030/docs/eu_trends_2050_en.pdf. 6 Michael Wolosin and Maria Belenky, “Gap Analysis with Paris Pledges,” 2014, http://www.climateadvisers.com/wp-­‐ content/uploads/2014/12/Climate-­‐Advisers-­‐Paris-­‐Analysis-­‐Mind-­‐the-­‐Gap.pdf. 7 This comment was not reported widely, but was picked up by the journalist Dave Keating (@Dave Keating) on Twitter on October 23, 2014. 8 See https://www.gov.uk/government/speeches/written-­‐ministerial-­‐statement-­‐by-­‐edward-­‐davey-­‐uk-­‐negotiating-­‐position-­‐on-­‐ the-­‐eu-­‐2030-­‐climate-­‐and-­‐energy-­‐framework 7 The Billion-Ton Solution | Dahl-Jørgensen economies and represents 88% of its GDP and 76% of its population—are still seeking even more ambitious climate action. Following the Lima climate talks in December 2014, they stated: We should be ready to consider raising the ambition of the [greenhouse gas] reduction target and the level of EU action, including through the use of international carbon market mechanisms, in the context of securing an ambitious, global and comprehensive international climate agreement at the Paris Conference.9 There is a clear opening for the EU to increase its ambition before Paris. It is worth emphasizing the difference between the EU’s 2020 and 2030 pledges. Before the Copenhagen climate talks in 2009, the EU pledged to reduce emissions by 20% below 1990 levels by 2020, or 30% as part of an ambitious climate agreement, with both targets including the use of international offsets. This time, learning the lesson from Copenhagen, the EU has started out with an internal-only goal, leaving the door open to increase its ambition in Paris either by strengthening its internal goal and/or through international mitigation on top of its 40% (or more) reduction at home. European negotiators are advocating that the new climate agreement include provisions for international carbon markets and partnerships, a clear sign that they are at least considering the option of adding an international mitigation pledge.10 In the emerging bottom-up international framework, whereby pledges are nationally determined rather than globally negotiated, this strategy makes sense. Several elements of this framework go against longstanding European positions. For example, the EU has favored legally binding national targets negotiated in a top-down fashion guided by science, with punishment for non-compliance. Yet, the EU is widely expected to go along with the less-binding, bottom-up framework, given that this is the only solution likely to maximize participation from key polluters like the United States, China, and India. It is indeed in the EU’s interest to accept a relatively weaker legal agreement in order to make some progress, and to focus its efforts on increasing global ambition over time within this politically feasible international framework. Its primary tool for doing so is through the strategic design of the EU’s own mitigation pledge. After describing the widening global ambition gap, the next sections propose how this can be done. 3. The Widening Climate Ambition Gap The EU and the rest of the international community have endorsed the global scientific consensus on the need to limit global warming to at most 2°C relative to the preindustrial level to avoid unmanageable climate impacts.11 The EU and all industrialized countries have also jointly recognized that meeting the 2°C goal will require a 50% reduction in global emissions and an 80% reduction in emissions from developed nations by 2050.12 The EU aims to reach 80–95% reductions by 2050, and President Obama has endorsed the 80% reduction goal for the United States.13 Unfortunately, even if implemented fully, the domestic climate plans that nations have put forward so far for the period up to 2020 only total about 40% of the climate action needed to place the world on a 9 See https://www.gov.uk/government/news/green-­‐growth-­‐group-­‐ministers-­‐statement-­‐on-­‐2030-­‐energy-­‐climate-­‐policy-­‐ framework. 10 See http://www.consilium.europa.eu/uedocs/cms_data/docs/pressdata/en/envir/145508.pdf. 11 See http://unfccc.int/key_steps/cancun_agreements/items/6132.php. 12 See http://www.g8italia2009.it/static/G8_Allegato/G8_Declaration_08_07_09_final,0.pdf. 13 See http://elections.nytimes.com/2008/president/issues/climate.html and http://www.whitehouse.gov/the-­‐press-­‐ office/president-­‐attend-­‐copenhagen-­‐climate-­‐talks. 8 The Billion-Ton Solution | Dahl-Jørgensen trajectory to limit global warming to 2°C.14 Regrettably, the gap between what science requires and what nations plan is soon likely to grow even larger. By the first half of 2015, most major economies will have followed the example of the EU, China, and the United States and have instituted new climate goals for the period starting in 2020. Based on what is known today about the new emission reduction pledges, and based on best estimates of upcoming pledges from others, Climate Advisers estimates that the emissions mitigation gap will likely continue to grow through 2030 in absolute terms, and that even pledges at the stronger end of what is expected would only deliver 50% of the mitigation required (see figure 1).15 In short, though nations are finally poised to take stronger climate action than ever before, they are not moving quickly enough to achieve the 2°C goal. Figure 1. Expected Mitigation Gap Based on Known and Expected National Pledges Source: Michael Wolosin and Maria Belenky, “Paris Analysis: Mind the Gap,” 2014, www.climateadvisers.com/mindthegap. 14 United Nations Environment Program, The Emissions Gap Report 2013: A UNEP Synthesis Report (New York: United Nations Environment Program, 2013), http://www.unep.org/publications/ebooks/emissionsgapreport2013/. 15 Michael Wolosin and Maria Belenky, “Paris Analysis: Mind the Gap,” 2014, www.climateadvisers.com/mindthegap. 9 The Billion-Ton Solution | Dahl-Jørgensen 4. Narrowing the Gap The primary objective of international climate diplomacy should be to eliminate or at least significantly narrow the global mitigation gap by 2030, rather than locking in a scenario that would actually make it larger and the climate crisis more unmanageable. At the moment, neither international nor European climate policy is aligned with this goal. As figure 2 shows, the developed countries’ emissions may already have peaked and begun declining, though this progress is the combined result of both policy action and economic contraction, and thus is fragile and potentially reversible. In contrast, the developing countries’ emissions are increasing rapidly, making up all the current and future growth in global annual emissions. Even if rich countries brought their emissions to zero, the world would still exceed 2°C warming without significant new climate action by developing countries. In order to limit warming to 2°C, global emissions will need to peak in the next few years, plummet 40–70% from 2010 levels by 2050, reach net zero by 2055–70, and become negative by 2100.16 Figure 2. Global Emissions by Region Source: United Nations Environment Program, The Emissions Gap Report 2014: A UNEP Synthesis Report (New York: United Nations Environment Program, 2014), http://www.unep.org/publications/ebooks/emissionsgapreport2014/portals/50268/pdf/EGR2014_LOWRE S.pdf. 16 Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC), Fifth Assessment Report: Summary for Policymakers (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2014), https://www.google.com/?gws_rd=ssl#q=IPCC+AR5+%282014%29%2C+Summary+for+Policy-­‐Makers; United Nations Environment Program, The Emissions Gap Report 2014: A UNEP Synthesis Report (New York: United Nations Environment Program, 2014), http://www.unep.org/publications/ebooks/emissionsgapreport2014/portals/50268/pdf/EGR2014_LOWRES.pdf. 10 The Billion-Ton Solution | Dahl-Jørgensen Deepening countries’ pledges to get on this trajectory will be extremely challenging. In simple conceptual terms, as sketched in figure 3, there are three ways to narrow the global gap: (1) The developed countries could pledge to do more at home; (2) the developing countries could pledge to do more on their own; or (3) the developed and developing countries could pledge to do more together through international partnerships and mechanisms whereby the developing nations would agree to do more as long as the developed nations were willing to shoulder a portion of the additional costs. Figure 3. Three Ways to Reduce the Global Emissions Gap Source: Climate Advisers analysis. Few countries are expected to deepen their domestic post-2020 goals in the next year before Paris. The EU may be the best candidate to do so, given the way it formulated its current goal, and the clear signal from key European leaders that they would consider doing so. Both the United States and China signaled that they would try to overdeliver, but it is unclear whether this would be reflected in deeper targets. The United States could, for example, say that it would aim for the higher end of its announced 26–28% goal, while China could pledge to move its peak year forward to 2025 to be consistent with its 2020 coal peak year. It should be noted that the United States has signaled clearly that it does not intend to increase its target before Paris, and has encouraged all nations to put forward their best bid this year, rather than expecting international pressure to increase national ambitions. It seems possible that some countries could be able to increase their post-2020 ambitions by modest amounts over the next five years, as the current momentum in the real economy continues and lowcarbon opportunities continue to seem more feasible, and political pressure for climaet action increases. But given the large mitigation gap, it is unrealistic to expect that the pledges would be strengthened sufficiently to get on a 2°C pathway. Securing significantly deeper and faster emission reduction pledges from the developed countries could be costly, and politically very challenging. With the right policy tools, some additional reductions seem possible at a moderate cost. Going much deeper would in some cases require explicit or implicit carbon pricing up to and beyond $100 per ton of CO2, far beyond the current political will. Similarly, expecting the developing countries to unilaterally pledge do more than they will have already determined is in their self-interest and to assume responsibility for a dramatically larger share of global 11 The Billion-Ton Solution | Dahl-Jørgensen emission reductions seems unrealistic, given their level of development, limited capacity for action, and still relatively lower (though rapidly increasing) historical emissions. This would be politically unrealistic in any case, but even more so in the absence of far deeper pledges from the rich countries. The most politically realistic way to significantly narrow the gap in the near to medium term, therefore, is through international partnerships, in which rich countries see that it is in their selfinterest to help reduce emissions in poor and emerging economies, where emissions are growing and low-cost mitigation opportunities are abundant. The EU’s climate policy and diplomacy need to be aligned with this insight in order to ensure that the world and the EU are doing what needs to be done over the next decades. 5. Europe’s Second Bite of the Apple: An International Mitigation Pledge As stated above, the EU has two ways to increase its climate mitigation ambition and to align its climate policy with the global 2°C goal. It could seek to reach an agreement among its leaders in 2015 to go beyond 40% internally. The EU can and should do even more than 40% at home, and could potentially do so at limited additional cost. 17 Given the political horse-trading that preceded the “at least 40%” compromise, however, it will be challenging to deliver more than a few additional percentage points before Paris. As a complimentary and additional strategy – on top of whatever mitigation ambition EU member states can agree to do internally – the EU should commit to reduce up to 1 billion tons of CO2 per year outside its borders in 2020-30. Increasing mitigation ambition through such a “dual commitment” could be politically more realistic, especially if it could be done in a way that allows the most ambitious EU member states take on more of the additional ambition. It is not a question of either or, but of maximizing European political will on both fronts. Why 1 billion tons? This number is suggested as a reasonable EU contribution to the effort to narrow the global mitigation gap. The UN Environment Program estimates the gap to be about 8–10 billion tons per year by 2020.18 Climate Advisers’ recent analysis—which takes into account the recent post-2020 pledges by the EU, the United States, and China—estimates that the 2030 mitigation gap will increase to 7–14 billion tons per year by 2030, depending on the strength of the yet-to-be-announced national post2020 climate pledges.19 The average gap during the decade is 7.5–12 billion tons per year. Halving the mitigation gap would require about 4–6 billion tons per year in additional mitigation. An additional 1 billion tons from the EU, as the world’s largest economy, is therefore not unreasonable. The EU could, as part of its pledge, set a maximum carbon price to limit the financial liability and uncertainty. As we will see in part II, mitigation from REDD+ is highly cost-effective, probably even more so than assumed so far. It seems reasonable to assume that the EU could set a fixed price at, say, €5 per ton, and still get up to 1 billion tons of credible supply from REDD+. alone. At a price of € 5 per ton, the total cost to the EU would be €5 billion per year, or less than €10 per EU citizen per year to keep the 2°C option alive, and if REDD+ is includded, to save most of the world’s remaining tropical forests, at 17 The EU’s Low Carbon Roadmap from 2013 estimated that 40-­‐44% reductions by 2030 was the lowest cost trajectory to a pathway to 79-­‐82% reductions by 2050. See https://www.gov.uk/government/publications/analysis-­‐of-­‐eu-­‐2030-­‐greenhouse-­‐ gas-­‐emission-­‐reduction-­‐target-­‐options. 18 United Nations Environment Program, Emissions Gap Report 2014. 19 Wolosin and Belenky, “Paris Analysis.” 12 The Billion-Ton Solution | Dahl-Jørgensen a direct benefit to the EU that would likely far exceed the cost. A total of €5 per ton would be about onethird the price paid for Certified Emission Reductions under the Clean Development Mechanism in 2008, when the price of EU allowances was high enough to stimulate fuel-switching away from coal in the EU. Politically within the EU, the focus needs to be on the results, not the finance. Certainly, some would see €5 billion as a lot of money to transfer abroad. It is about twice the annual “fast-start finance” provided by the EU in 2010–12. Given the magnitude of the climate impact and the additional benefits, however, this sum is arguably very small. The fast-start finance was meant to provide initial funding to prepare for much larger amounts of climate finance to come. In contrast, the €5 billion per year for the international mitigation commitment would drive large-scale global mitigation, and could be designed to come from both public and private sources. It should therefore be regarded as a purchasing commitment required to (1) contribute to narrowing the global mitigation gap, and (2) to getting a deal in Paris. It should be framed politically—accurately—as a precondition for the EU to regain global leadership on climate change and make EU policy consistent with a 2°C goal. Given that the EU holds 25% of the world’s GDP, this would not be an unreasonable contribution from the EU—in particular, given the $100 billion a year that the developed countries have pledged to “mobilize” international climate financing by 2020. The political focus should be on “1 billion tons” (and the additional mitigation it would trigger), not on the €5 billion. This pledge should be conditioned upon the conclusion of a meaningful climate agreement in Paris, and—of course—on the environmental integrity of the tons available for purchase. The proper perspective is “what would it cost to achieve this ambition, which is given, through other means,” not “how does this compare with previous climate-related ODA flows.” The impact of the international mitigation pledge would likely far exceed 1 billion tons. It is reasonable to assume that large-scale carbon demand from the EU would help developing countries do more self-financed emission reductions. Though the EU would of course not be in a position to formally take credit for this additional self-financed effort by developing countries, it would be credited as the indispensable partner in a global partnership leading to possibly the most significant contribution to increased global climate ambitions in the next two decades. A demand signal for the period 2020–30 delivered in 2015 would likely also lead to significant additional emission reductions before 2020, at no additional cost. A clear forward demand signal would be a major boost to current mitigation efforts, and give countries time to prepare for large-scale demand. Current official development assistance (ODA) programs could be used to kick-start the “market” through various mechanisms (perhaps even rheoufh advance market commitments, auctioning of put options, reverse auctions, or open tenders). A “dual commitment” is likely most politically realistic, while also offering the largest climate benefits. Pledging to mitigate 1 billion tons might be preferable to a pledge of, say, 10% additional mitigation below 1990 levels. The latter would be a lower volume (approximately 0.5 billion tons per year in 2030, and lower initially), yet is—perhaps ironically—likely to trigger even more political resistance among the EU’s member states. Some countries that were opposed to do 40% at home would feel threatened by the ambitious 10% number (because 10% at home—the natural association—is a very significant effort). At the same time, many NGOs would see a 10% pledge as a premature step toward the inclusion of REDD in the ETS. A “dual commitment” could garner broad support from stakeholders. A separate international mitigation commitment not linked to the EU’s internal mitigation target would avoid the ideological resistance to carbon markets and offsets. By being truly additional to domestic efforts, it would get the full support of the environmental NGO community. There is significant ideological opposition, in 13 The Billion-Ton Solution | Dahl-Jørgensen particular when it comes to linking REDD+ to carbon markets, most of which is arguably misguided. But there are practical reasons for keeping a REDD+ commitment out of the ETS, or at most testing a partial and gradual inclusion. Including REDD+ in the ETS at this stage, with a large oversupply of credits for the foreseeable future, would probably be ill advised—even setting aside the ideological opposition. But a separate commitment to pay for international emission reductions, including from REDD+, would have broad support. In fact, it would be almost identical to the proposal made by Greenpeace’s of a “Tropical 20 Deforestation Emission Reduction Mechanism” ahead of the Copenhagen talks. The critical aspect for delivering international mitigation generally, and REDD+ particularly, is predictable and significant demand, measured in tons of CO2 rather than euros. It is less important whether it is linked to an offsets program. In essence, a separate international mitigation pledge would create a separate market for REDD+ and other international mitigation credits. An international mitigation pledge would generate additional benefits that domestic action would not. It would achieve a higher level of ambition from the EU at a relatively lower cost; mobilize more action from both the developed and developing countries; mobilize climate finance and secure a robust global climate agreement; facilitate future linking of carbon markets; deliver tremendous development benefits; and serve the EU’s foreign policy interests. The additional benefits are elaborated further below: • Achieving a higher EU ambition at a lower average cost. Although more climate action could have been undertaken within Europe at a reasonable cost, a significant increase in ambition—of, say, 10–20%—would likely entail a significant additional cost, at least in the short and medium term. The EU Commission already estimates that carbon prices of €50–60 per ton in 2030 and €100–370 per ton in 2050 will be needed to meet the EU’s climate goals.21 In contrast, there are abundant cost-effective emission reductions to be achieved in developing countries that could support such an ambition. The UK has estimated that for a 50% reduction target, access to 5% through international offsets would reduce costs by 32%, while 10% would reduce costs by 44% compared to purely internal mitigation.22 As is shown in the forest sector analysis below, the EU could potentially secure a large portion of an international commitment at a cost as low as $5 per ton. Given the strain on public budgets and the recent agreement to generously compensate the Eastern European countries for accepting the goal of reducing the EU’s internal emissions by at least 40% by 2030, achieving political acceptance among a group of front-runners to also pledge mitigation internationally will surely be a challenge. Conversely, the European leaders are more likely to be favorable to additional policies framed as a concrete and measurable solution to narrow the global mitigation gap rather than as a proposal for additional public finance. What is more, as is shown in the final section, there are ways to pass on the cost of an international mitigation pledge to the private sector, in accordance with the polluter-pays principle. • Unlocking the large mitigation potential of the developing countries. Most emission reductions to meet the 2°C goal will need to take place in the emerging and developing countries. Although they are increasingly taking on commitments and responsibility for action, 20 See http://www.greenpeace.org/international/Global/international/planet-­‐2/report/2008/3/tropical-­‐deforestation-­‐ emissio.pdf. 21 EU Commission, Summary of the Impact Assessment: A Roadmap for Moving to a Competitive Low-­‐Carbon Economy in 2050 (Brussels: European Union, 2011), http://eur-­‐lex.europa.eu/legal-­‐content/EN/TXT/PDF/?uri=CELEX:52011SC0289&from=EN. 22 UK Department of Energy and Climate Change, Analysis of EU 2030 greenhouse gas reduction target options, 28 October 2013, https://www.gov.uk/government/publications/analysis-­‐of-­‐eu-­‐2030-­‐greenhouse-­‐gas-­‐emission-­‐reduction-­‐target-­‐options 14 The Billion-Ton Solution | Dahl-Jørgensen they will need massive support to meet their full cost-effective mitigation potential. They cannot be reasonably expected to cover the full cost of their maximum effort. This is not just a question of fairness, but of feasibility. At the 2014 climate talks in Lima, 14 developing countries came forward with a joint “Lima Challenge,” where they committed to coming forward in 2015 with a combination of unconditional (self-financed) and conditional emission reduction targets, whose conditional portion indicates the level of ambition they would offer on top of their maximum domestic efforts, if sufficient economic incentives were to be made available.23 These conditional reductions would be left on the table unless they were matched by a commitment from the developed countries to help finance them. As an example, in 2009 Indonesia pledged to reduce its emissions 26% compared with its business-as-usual trajectory by 2020 on its own, or 41% with support. The conditional portion of this pledge amounted to almost half a billion tons of CO2. The EU could help create a “race to the top” by deciding that only countries or jurisdictions that pledge ambitious mitigation on their own would be eligible to receive payments for verified emission reductions through international mitigation partnerships with the EU, EU member states, or EU-regulated entities. When countries pledge ambitious self-financed action, there will always be a risk that pledges will not be met. If provided with an incentive to go beyond those targets, countries are more likely to also deliver on their unconditional target. Similarly, if they expect international incentives to become available after 2020, they are also likely to take more concerted action before 2020, to prepare for such incentives. Hence, international mitigation commitments can mobilize even more mitigation from the developing countries than the portion directly supported. • Securing higher ambition from the United States and Japan. If the EU were to establish a norm that climate leadership must be demonstrated not only through a country’s domestic climate ambition but also through its contribution to mitigation abroad, it is possible that other developed countries could be convinced to follow suit and adopt an international mitigation pledge of their own. The United States, for example, is unlikely to change its domestic emissions reduction goal before Paris—President Obama’s pledge to reduce U.S. domestic emissions 2628% by 2025 from 2005 levels.. And with Republican majorities in both the Senate and the House of Representatives, President Obama has limited capacity to make new pledges for additional U.S. government funding for international emissions mitigation in developing nations. President Obama, however, does control a range of tools that—assuming he had the will to do so—could create new financial incentives from the U.S. private sector for international mitigation relying solely on the President’s existing executive authorities.24 President Obama, therefore, could pledge that the United States would adopt new greenhouse gas regulations that would incentivize U.S. companies to mitigate emissions outside the United States on top of the 2628% U.S. domestic goal. President Obama’s primary climate legacy and number one environmental priority for the remainder of his term is formalizing the Clean Power Plan, which would regulate emissions from existing power plants and will only be finalized just before Paris. 23 Andreas Dahl-­‐Jørgensen, “Forest Countries Challenge World to Increase Climate Ambition,” December 9, 2014, http://www.climateadvisers.com/forest-­‐countries-­‐challenge-­‐world-­‐to-­‐increase-­‐climate-­‐ambition/. 24 For an elaboration of U.S. options see forthcoming paper by Dahl-­‐Jørgensen, Purvis and Wolosin, Increasing U.S. Climate Ambition Through International Mitigation Partnerships. 15 The Billion-Ton Solution | Dahl-Jørgensen Once that important regulation is finalized late in the year, President Obama might be convinced to join a European-led effort to articulate new pledges for emission cuts outside developed countries. Other developed countries could also be convinced to adopt an international mitigation pledge. For some, it would make sense to keep domestic and international commitments separate, as the EU would. Others would perhaps want to use international mitigation as a way of increasing their overall ambition while keeping the share of each flexible. For example, Japan is facing significant uncertainty about its future energy mix while all its nuclear plants are going through safety reviews, and it would likely maximize the flexibility to take action abroad. Indeed, ambitious pledges for international mitigation is likely the primary option for Prime Minister Abe to show international leadership on climate change. • Mobilizing climate finance and securing a robust global climate agreement. A commitment to international mitigation by the EU would help seal a meaningful global climate agreement, by increasing mitigation ambition, providing credible commitments to high-quality climate finance, and possibly getting concessions on other aspects of the agreement. Key parts of the Paris agreement are already coming into view. To some degree, there is no longer a deal to be lost, in the sense that the ambition question is being formally kept out of the agreement, while negotiations are centering on the legal form, how to differentiate between countries at various stages of development, and the provision of finance. The one remaining sticking point that could derail the Paris agreement is the level of international climate finance from rich to poor countries, both for mitigation and adaptation. In Copenhagen in 2009, the EU joined the other developed countries in pledging that they would jointly mobilize—from both public and private sources—$100 billion per year in climate finance to the developing countries by 2020. If the EU were to secure 1 billion tons of CO2 a year abroad—at a cost of around €5 per ton, for example—this would provide around €5 billion per year to the developing countries for climate mitigation. Depending on how this is mobilized (see part III), this could potentially free up more of the scarce public foreign assistance finance to be spent on adaptation and resilience in some of the poorest and most vulnerable countries, which is a high political priority for a large number of countries in the climate negotiations. Critically, a pledge to international mitigation—measured in tons rather than euros—would deliver quantified results in ways that other types of climate finance (e.g., through the Green Climate Fund) would likely not do. At the moment, climate finance is seen by most developed countries as a political problem—as a necessary concession to “get a deal”—rather than as a strategic tool to deliver the policy reforms and investmetns needed to solve the climate crisis. An international mitigation pledge could create sectorial or even economy-wide price signals in developing countries that mobilize and redirect private investments on a large scale toward lowcarbon opportunities, in a way that a fund seeking up-front cofinancing from the private sector for specific projects will not be able to do. • Advancing international carbon pricing. The EU has led the way globally on emissions trading, and countries all over the world—and increasingly, developing countries—are now replicating the EU’s early leadership. Already, 39 countries and 23 subnational governments have 16 The Billion-Ton Solution | Dahl-Jørgensen implemented or are scheduled to introduce carbon pricing.25 China has piloted regional regulations and aims to have a national carbon market operational by 2016. Recently, 73 countries and more than 1,000 companies signed up to support strong carbon pricing policies.26 Evidence suggests that the developing nations that participated in international carbon markets have been more likely to adopt their own domestic carbon prices and markets.27 Hence, by committing to pay for emission reductions from developing countries now, the EU could help spread carbon pricing and advance the convergence of global price signals to the long term benefit of both the European and global economies. This would also help create a level playing field for European companies and safeguard their global competitiveness. • Promoting EU’s Foreign Policy and Development Objectives. An international mitigation pledge would support broader EU foreign policy objectives, including through significant sustainable development impacts in poor countries resulting from a wide variety of interventions. For example, expanding access to clean, renewable energy will raise millions of people out of energy poverty and reduce the estimated 7 million annual premature deaths that are due to air pollution, both indoors from biomass and outdoors from coal power.28 Reduced global demand for oil will reduce the geopolitical clout of some nations that are politically antagonistic to the EU. Energy efficiency measures will save costs, freeing up resources for countries to invest in infrastructure or development priorities. Promoting sustainable agriculture and the preservation of the remaining tropical forests can enhance food security, create livelihoods, promote the rule of law, protect indigenous peoples and local communities against human rights abuses, and protect the world’s most valuable biodiversity. Finally, increasing the demand for low-carbon technology—for energy efficiency, renewable energy, or carbon capture and storage—will benefit European firms that specialize in those products, and thus will create jobs in Europe. The EU could condition its pledge on others doing more, or making policy concessions. An international mitigation contribution is fully consistent with the emerging bottom-up international climate framework. It could be done completely unilaterally, and would not depend on reaching a consensus within the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change. However, offering such a commitment could be used strategically to get concessions from other countries in the international climate negotiations. The European pledge could be conditioned upon one or a combination of outcomes, such as similar contributions from other developed countries, sufficient self-financed mitigation pledges by developing countries, sufficient “supply” of additional high-quality emission reductions from developing countries – perhaps below a set maximum price, or aspects of the climate agreement less directly related to mitigation ambition, such as a clear process for reviewing and “ratcheting up” national climate goals. Although it may be politically tempting – or even necessary – to add such conditions to a European pledge, Europena leaders are wise to consider the lessons from Copenhagen and weigh the value of such additional “concessions” from others against the likelihood of them happening. 25 World Bank, “State & Trends Report Charts Global Growth of Carbon Pricing,” May 28, 2014, http://www.worldbank.org/en/news/feature/2014/05/28/state-­‐trends-­‐report-­‐tracks-­‐global-­‐growth-­‐carbon-­‐pricing. 26 World Bank, “73 Countries and Over 1,000 Businesses Speak Out in Support of a Price on Carbon,” September 22, 2014, http://www.worldbank.org/en/news/feature/2014/09/22/governments-­‐businesses-­‐support-­‐carbon-­‐pricing. 27 Nigel Purvis, Samuel Grausz, and Andrew Light, Carbon Market Crossroads: New Ideas for Harnessing Global Markets to Confront Climate Change (Washington: Center for American Progress, 2013), http://www.americanprogress.org/issues/green/report/2013/04/29/61655/carbon-­‐market-­‐crossroads/. 28 World Health Organization, “7 Million Premature Deaths Annually Linked to Air Pollution,” press release, March 25, 2014, http://www.who.int/mediacentre/news/releases/2014/air-­‐pollution/en/. 17 The Billion-Ton Solution | Dahl-Jørgensen 6. Conclusion The most promising and most politically realistic way for the EU to further increase its global climate ambition in 2015 is to make an additional international mitigation pledge—a “dual contribution”—on top of the 40% (or higher) goal it sets internally. Specifically, the EU should pledge to reduce 1 billion tons of CO2 per year abroad after 2020, as part of a global effort to narrow the mitigation gap. This will set a norm for other developed countries to follow, opening up a new front in the climate battle. International mitigation partnerships have the potential to substantially increase global ambition, without requiring proportionate increases in any nation’s political will to act. Developing countries will be willing to do more with support than they could achieve by themselves, at a relatively low cost. Leaving those emission reductions on the table would be a poor political and environmental strategy for those — like the EU — that seek a global climate framework that can narrow the remaining mitigation gap. Although an international mitigation pledge could be designed in many ways, and could pursue emission reductions from any number of sectors and countries, part II analyzes the potential for the forest sector (REDD+) to deliver a significant portion of the European pledge for international mitigation. 18 The Billion-Ton Solution | Dahl-Jørgensen Part II: The Case for International Forest Mitigation The launch of the New York Declaration on Forests at the UN Climate Summit in September 2014 represented an unprecedented momentum to stop harmful forest loss.29 As of December 2014, 177 national and regional governments, companies, indigenous peoples’ organizations and NGOs had endorsed the declaration, with its goals of (1) at least halving natural forest loss globally by 2020, and strive to end it by 2030; (2) eliminating deforestation from the production of agricultural commodities such as palm oil, soy, paper and beef by no later than 2020; (3) restoring 150 million hectares of degraded landscapes and forestlands by 2020, and at least 350 million hectares by 2030; and (4) ensuring that strong, large-scale economic incentives are in place commensurate with the challenge. How can the momentum we are seeing today in the private sector be continued, broadened, and implemented? And what is the relationship between efforts to reduce emissions from supply chains and payments for verified reductions in forest emissions in developing countries (REDD+)? How can the EU best contribute to reducing tropical deforestation? This part of the paper starts by recapping the mitigation potential from forests, what it would take to stop deforestation, and the role of REDD+ payments. It then makes the case for the EU to consider REDD+ as an important component of an international mitigation commitment. 1. The Importance of Forest Mitigation Without large-scale mitigation in the forest sector, a two-degree path is most likely beyond reach. The most recent report from the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change states—with the highest possible degree of certainty and agreement among scientists—that leveraging the climate change mitigation potential from land use is “extremely important in meeting emission reduction targets.” Depending on the level of mitigation achieved in other sectors, land-based mitigation can make up 20–60% of the global cuts needed by 2030 (depending on cuts in other sectors, and with the upper bound assuming large-scale 30 bioenergy), and 15–45% through 2050. According to the latest emissions gap report from the UN Environment Program, global emissions must be net zero by 2055–70. In other words, carbon sequestration through forest Figure 4. Small Change in Gross Deforestation/Restoration Leads To Large Mitigation 29 United Nations Development Program, UN Climate Summit: New York Declaration on Forests (New York: United Nations Development Program, 2014), available at http://www.undp.org/content/undp/en/home/presscenter/events/2014/september/23-­‐september-­‐united-­‐nations-­‐climate-­‐ summit/Land-­‐Use-­‐and-­‐Forest-­‐Action-­‐Area-­‐Online-­‐Pressroom.html. 30 IPCC, Fifth Assessment Report, WG3, chap. 11. 19 The Billion-Ton Solution | Dahl-Jørgensen growth or carbon capture and storage will have to cancel out all gross emissions from all sectors.31 Due largely to the rapid increase in fossil fuel emissions, net carbon emissions from tropical forests are now down to about 10% of global emissions. But this net emissions number conceals the outsized share of net emission reductions that tropical forests can provide by simultaneously slowing deforestation and enhancing reforestation and restoration. Deforestation and forest degradation have been estimated to cause some 9.5 billion tons of greenhouse gas emissions (19% of the global total), while restoration and reforestation remove some 4.4 billion tons from the atmosphere (a negative 9% of 32 global net emissions). Reducing tropical deforestation and forest degradation by a modest 25%, while simultaneously increasing restoration and reforestation by 25%, would deliver 3.5 billion tons per year in emission reductions (see figure 4). This is a modest ambition. The EU goal of a 50% reduction in gross deforestation (i.e., halving the red column in figure 4) would bring the net emissions (the blue column) close to zero, even before adding any new restoration effort. If restoration is doubled, net emission reductions jump to a whopping 13.5 billion tons per year, or about 30% of today’s global emissions. Reaching the goals of the New York Declaration on Forests—ending forest loss by 2030 and restoring 350 million hectares—is estimated to reduce 4.5–8.8 billion tons of CO2 per year in 2030.33 Forest mitigation is a largely untapped mitigation strategy, and a dwindling opportunity. Despite important progress in some countries, notably Brazil, tropical deforestation is not being reduced quickly enough to stay within reach of the 2°C target. And despite progress on REDD+ under the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC) negotiations and ambitious mitigation commitments from countries like Brazil and Indonesia, total global efforts are far short of the mitigation potential. 34 REDD+ promotes sustainable development. The multiple benefits of REDD+ are well documented. Beyond the climate benefits from carbon sequestration, it preserves global biodiversity and global rainfall patterns that are critical for some of the world’s most important agricultural belts. Locally, REDD+ secures a resource base for both timber and nontimber forest products, ensures pollination, preserves soils, and provides clean and steady flows of water. The governance reforms required to implement REDD+ are critical to secure livelihoods and protect the rights of indigenous peoples and local communities. Healthy forests also make communities and nations more resilient to impacts of climate 35 change, thereby protecting the hard-fought development gains of the last few decades. Although many of these benefits are seen as “co-benefits,” REDD+ has in some cases proven to be more effective at bringing about these additional benefits than interventions that have them as their primary goal. For example, indigenous peoples and local communities in Indonesia have suffered human rights abuses and a lack of customary land recognition for decades, and many aid organizations have tried to support these efforts. With the emerging “One Map” initiative that seeks to put indigenous lands off limits for new 31 United Nations Environment Program, Emissions Gap Report 2014. Gross and net emissions from deforestation taken from Richard A. Houghton, “The Emissions of Carbon from Deforestation and Degradation in the Tropics: Past Trends and Future Potential,” Carbon Management 4, no. 5 (2013): 539–46. This is within the IPCC number of net emissions at 4.3–5.5 gigatons (Gt). However, the IPCC report does not include gross flows. To calculate the share of global emissions, the IPCC’s number of 49Gt CO2e global emissions was used, taken from IPCC, Fifth Assessment Report, WG3, chap. 11. 33 Michael Wolosin, “Quantifying the Benefits of the New York Declaration on Forests,” 2014, http://www.climateadvisers.com/quantifying-­‐the-­‐benefits-­‐of-­‐the-­‐new-­‐york-­‐declaration-­‐on-­‐forests/. 34 United Nations Environment Program, Building Natural Capital: How REDD+ Can Support a Green Economy (New York: United Nations Environment Program, 2014). 35 IPCC, Fifth Assessment Report, WG3, chap. 11. 32 20 The Billion-Ton Solution | Dahl-Jørgensen developers, as well as other related initiatives as part of the government’s REDD+ program, attention to indigenous rights to land has been significantly increased. 2. What Would It Take to Stop Deforestation? We know what it would take to stop deforestation. Although Brazil is unique in many respects, its experience offers critical lessons for other forest-rich nations, including those countries with much less capacity to act. Brazil has reduced deforestation in the Amazon by more than 75% below the 10-year historical average (1996–2005). Applying conservative estimates, this translates into an emission reduction of 2.6 billion tons over 7 years and a 1.6% reduction in global emissions in 2012.36 In comparison, the EU reduced its annual emissions by about 400 million tons from 2006 to 2011.37 Even more impressively, this all happened during a period of rapid agricultural growth. Figure 5 shows the dramatic “decoupling” between deforestation and the production of soy and beef in the Brazilian Amazon. What caused Brazil’s decoupling? No expert predicted in 2004 that Brazil could reduce deforestation in the Amazon by more than 75% in less than a decade, given the severe governance challenges that still prevailed in the Amazon at the time Figure 5. Brazil’s Decoupling of Deforestation and (much like the situation in many Agricultural Production developing countries today). What caused the decline? Many factors contributed, but first among them was political will. Under president Lula and ministers of environment Marina Silva and later Carlos Minc, Brazil launched an ambitious law enforcement effort (guided by real-time satellite monitoring), which entailed sending in the military to arrest thousands of illegal loggers. The government protected vast areas by designating them as national parks and indigenous Source: PRODES, FAOSTAT, cited by Why Forests Why Now territories, and it linked the provision of (Washington: Center for Global Development, forthcoming), available billions of dollars in agricultural credit to via http://www.cgdev.org/page/why-forests-why-now-bookcounties’ performance in deforestation, and-paper-series, even blacklisting laggard counties to 38 encourage peer compliance. Spurred by international NGO campaigns and demands from commodity buyers, soy producers agreed to a voluntary “deforestation moratorium.” Active Brazilian NGOs, using the government’s transparent satellite deforestation data, supported the process. Finally, Brazil established its Amazon Fund—with contributions from Norway, Germany, and Petrobras—which helped 36 Daniel Nepstad, Silvia Irawan, Tathiana Bezerra, William Boyd, Claudia Stickler, João Shimada, Oswaldo Carvalho, Katie MacIntyre, Alue Dohong, Ane Alencar, Andrea Azevedo, David Tepper, and Sarah Lowery, “More Food, More Forests, Fewer Emissions, Better Livelihoods: Linking REDD+, Sustainable Supply Chains, and Domestic Policy in Brazil, Indonesia, and Colombia,” Carbon Management 4, no. 6 (2013): 639–58, http://earthinnovation.org/publications/more-­‐food-­‐more-­‐forests-­‐ fewer-­‐emissions-­‐better-­‐livelihoods/. 37 Wolosin and Belenky, “Paris Analysis.” 38 Juliano Assunção, Clarissa C. e Gandour, and Rudi Rocha, Deforestation Slowdown in the Legal Amazon: Prices or Policies? (Rio de Janeiro: Climate Policy Initiative, 2012), http://climatepolicyinitiative.org/wp-­‐content/uploads/2012/03/Deforestation-­‐ Prices-­‐or-­‐Policies-­‐Working-­‐Paper.pdf. 21 The Billion-Ton Solution | Dahl-Jørgensen lock in and create international attention arounf the country’s international commitment, while making available resources for local implementation. For example, a $40 million contribution from the Amazon Fund is enabling the state of Pará to roll out its successful Green Municipalities Program to 100 municipalities throughout the state, to sustain the impressive results achieved, and to catalyze further progress. Will Brazil’s deforestation stay low? It seems highly unlikely that Brazil will revert to the record high deforestation rates of the 1990s and early 2000s. Too much progress has been made on monitoring, legal frameworks, law enforcement, and private sector commitments and practices. Yet there is a real risk of a partial reversal. In 2013, deforestation increased for the first time in many years (though from a record low baseline, and still vastly below the previous levels), causing many experts to worry that the gains could not be sustained. Then, in 2014, deforestation fell again to levels close to 2012’s record low.39 Continued success will depend on political will and international support. Experts stress that though most of the early and easiest reductions were achieved through a “stick approach,” maintaining and continuing this progress will be difficult unless farmers on the ground start benefiting from real incentives to protect forests.40 What would it take to stop global deforestation? Doing what Brazil has done is hard, and has significant short- and medium-term financial and political costs. Doing so in countries with less capacity in Brazil is harder still. But a concerted global public–private effort to stop deforestation would have many similarities to the Brazil experience. It would require a three-pronged strategy: 1. Countries with tropical forests would need to implement sustainable land use policies and governance reforms. Sustainable land use planning typically includes (1) policies to conserve high-carbon forests; (2) freeing up degraded lands for agricultural expansion and forest restoration; and (3) sustainable intensification of production on existing agricultural lands. Other fundamental governance reforms typically part of REDD+ strategies include a recognition of customary land rights, strengthening law enforcement, and aligning fiscal and sector growth policies. This again requires robust coalitions for change, and an "all-of-government" approach. 2. Private companies would need to implement zero-deforestation policies. A growing number of companies are pledging to not buy commodities tainted by deforestation, and are seeking third-party verification by NGOs such as the Tropical Forest Trust and Greenpeace to comply. More companies must follow suit, and they should cover a broader set of commodities. There is also increasing interest among commodity buyers in helping to stimulate reforms by aligning their purchasing power, investments, and ability to offer long-term market access with REDD+ incentives at the jurisdictional level. More analysis is needed to promote this idea. 3. Developed countries would need to create economic incentives, including REDD+ demand. Large-scale systems to reward countries for reducing forest emissions through REDD+ will be critical to stimulate the necessary public policies in forest-rich countries, yet they have not yet been tested at scale. Norway’s bilateral pledges, though too small to pose as a fair test of the potential of REDD+ incentives, still demonstrate a track record in stimulating forest governance improvements. The relatively modest pledge of $1 billion to Indonesia—the country with the largest deforestation problem—has already initiated processes that if continued would mark a fundamental change in the political economy of land use. Anticorruption and law 39 Associated Press, “Deforestation Drops 18 Percent in Brazil’s Amazon,” November 26, 2014, http://bigstory.ap.org/article/27662c4b95ee4e75adbdb02bba82f05e/deforestation-­‐drops-­‐brazils-­‐amazon. 40 Nepstad et al., “More Food, More Forests.” 22 The Billion-Ton Solution | Dahl-Jørgensen enforcement measures mark the beginning of the end of decades of impunity for illegal activities. A forest clearing moratorium, and the related “One Map” initiative, have exposed massive amounts of overlapping and illegal forest concessions, and have made them publicly transparent for the first time. Meanwhile, and only partially a consequence of the bilateral REDD+ partnership, the involvement and empowerment of indigenous peoples and local communities led to a landmark constitutional court ruling that ruled that local communities’ should be allowed to formalise their customary claims to millions of hectares of land. Until now, such lands have been often been claimed by the state and doled out in various forms of concessions back to local communities. As in any complex national reform process, it is difficult to assess causality, but initial evaluations indicate that the agreement of international REDD+ incentives spurred important progress.41 REDD+ demand is not the only international strategy to slow deforestation. Trade policy and demandside measures on legality, market access, and public procurement can also help, and indeed play essential supplementary roles. Significant REDD+ demand will, however, be required to help alter the political and economic realities to bring about reform in most forest-rich countries. 3. The Ongoing Supply Chain Revolution While REDD+ demand has taken a long time to materialize, there is tremendous momentum to clean up agricultural supply chains. In 2010, the Consumer Goods Forum (CGF)—a collection of some 400 companies with $3 trillion in sales—pledged to help (in the context of a global public–private partnership) to eliminate deforestation from the supply chains of soy, beef, paper, and palm oil by 2020. Since then, commitments have accelerated. This movement toward deforestation-free commodity supply chains is playing out in three ways: 1. More companies are likely to come forward with new commitments over the next months. Just in the last 12 months, the share of the global palm oil trade covered by companies with commitments to zero deforestation has increased from 5% to about 96%.42 As the CGF pledge has been translated into individual corporate commitments from large consumer goods companies, agricultural traders have started making commitments. And as they have made these commitments, even more producers and consumers have made commitments of their own. This domino effect has fundamentally disrupted the global palm oil industry in a very short period. With announcements from agribusiness giants such as Wilmar’s and Cargill’s that they will be going deforestation free across all their commodities, it seems clear that other commodities will see a similar development. Commitments from producers, traders, and consumer companies are now also starting to trickle into finance. The Banking Environment Initiative – a collection of about 10 international banks – has pledged to introduce zerodeforestation banking standards that match the metrics used by CGF.43 As the market share 41 Norad (2014) Considerable progress for Norway’s International Climate and Forest Initiative (NICFI), http://www.norad.no/en/evaluation/news/considerable-­‐progress-­‐for-­‐norways-­‐international-­‐climate-­‐and-­‐forest-­‐initiative-­‐nicfi 42 Chain Reaction Research: “96% of Global Palm Oil Trade Covered by Zero-­‐Deforestation”, December 8, 2014, http://chainreactionresearch.com/2014/12/08/the-­‐chain-­‐96-­‐of-­‐global-­‐palm-­‐oil-­‐trade-­‐covered-­‐by-­‐zero-­‐deforestatio-­‐plus-­‐ jokowi-­‐brazil-­‐kl/ 43 Cambridge Institute for Sustainability Leadership, “Banking Environment Initiative,” http://www.cisl.cam.ac.uk/Business-­‐ Platforms/Banking-­‐Environment-­‐Initiative.aspx. 23 The Billion-Ton Solution | Dahl-Jørgensen covered by zero-deforestation commitments grows, more buyers and financiers will gain confidence that there will be enough sustainable supply. 2. The new commitments are helping to change the political economy in producer countries. An increasing share of the private sector is now calling for, rather than actively opposing, governance reforms related to REDD+. The Indonesia case is illustrative. In 2011, the Indonesian private sector actively lobbied against the deforestation moratorium. In 2013, it was largely silent when the moratorium was extended. But today—following the Wilmar announcement, which affects 45% of global palm oil production and 80% of the palm oil producers—the Indonesian private sector is actively calling for governance reforms. Asia Pulp and Paper, long regarded one of the world’s least sustainable companies, is now on record asking for ramped-up law enforcement and a review of overlapping concessions.44 At the UN Climate Summit in September 2014, the Indonesian Chamber of Commerce along with leading companies issued a statement requesting that the government of Indonesia incorporate all elements of their zerodeforestation pledges into Indonesian law.45 The CEO of Wilmar International, Kuok Khoon Hong, conveyed similar arguments at the World Economic Forum in January 2014. 3. Leading Consumer Goods Forum member companies are now explicitly asking for a global REDD+ mechanism to help meet its goal. Through the Tropical Forest Alliance 2020, the CGF has called on governments to establish the enabling environment necessary for the CGF to meet its goal. (A goal which when set in Cancun in 2010, was to help eliminate commodity deforestation, in the context of emerging climate negotiations for a global REDD+ mechanism.) Increasingly, the CGF is seeing REDD demand as the most important contribution developed countries can make to stimulate the governance reforms businesses need. This makes business sense: Unless there are policy reforms, CGF members will be undercut by unsustainable producers, and will find it challenging to abide by their commitments. The three strategies – green growth policeis supported by REDD+ incentives and corporate commitments – cannot succeed in isolation. They depend on and reinforce each other. First, green growth policy reforms will in most places not be possible or sustainable without the financial support and political cover that comes from REDD+ and global commodity markets. Second, support from the developed countries will not by itself change the land use calculus and transform markets unless countries and companies see a development or business case for taking action. And third, voluntary private sector commitments cannot transform entire markets without land use governance reform in producer countries that create a level playing field, and ensure access to nonforested lands for agricultural production. The most important way voluntary supply chain commitments reduce land use emissions may in fact be indirect, through its impact on policy. With strong and growing commodity demand from domestic and emerging markets, there will always be new companies willing to step in to supply those markets unsustainably unless producer countries implement land use reforms. Largescale incentives for REDD+ constitute the most important lever developed countries have to stimulate forest and land use reforms in countries with tropical forests and to thereby close that loophole. REDD+ is also critical for addressing the almost 50% of forest emissions not driven by international trade in commodities. 44 Rhett Butler, “APP, Environmentalists Talk Future of Indonesia’s Forests,” Mongabay, February 20, 2014, http://news.mongabay.com/2014/0220-­‐app-­‐fcp-­‐debate.html#evK62zDQwDj6Fowl.99. 45 See http://www.undp.org/content/undp/en/home/presscenter/events/2014/september/23-­‐‑september-­‐‑united-­‐‑ nations-­‐‑climate-­‐‑summit/Land-­‐‑Use-­‐‑and-­‐‑Forest-­‐‑Action-­‐‑Area-­‐‑Online-­‐‑Pressroom.html 24 The Billion-Ton Solution | Dahl-Jørgensen 4. The Role of REDD+ Payments Emission reductions from REDD+ are highly cost-effective—perhaps even more than previously thought. REDD+ was always estimated to be highly cost-effective. Indeed, REDD+ was ironically excluded from large-scale mitigation policies due to its very ability to deliver large volumes of inexpensive emission reductions, as this would risk flooding carbon markets, depress prices, and slow the energy transition in advanced economies. Yet even those estimates were overstating the cost. The most frequently cited cost estimate, the 2008 Eliasch report, indicated that a 50% reduction in 46 deforestation by 2030 would cost $17–34 billion per year. This seems too high, by several orders of magnitude, for three key reasons. First, too often REDD+ is depicted as a choice between food production and conservation rather than as a new framework for sustainable, productive land use. Many studies have estimated the levels of REDD+ payments necessary to compensate private landholders—on a hectare-by-hectare or project-by-project basis—for the private opportunity cost of land use change. (In other words, pay landowners or agribusinesses not to convert specific forests areas to farms.) In reality, the farmer could be offered alternative, nonforested lands, or be supported to intensify production on existing lands. Similarly, stopping illegal loggers with law enforcement has a lower financial cost than paying them off (which, of course, would also be unjust). REDD+ incentives provided at the national or jurisdictional level against a set “reference level,” as agreed on under the UNFCCC, would need to be sufficiently large to make a difference politically by strengthening the reformers’ ability to implement sustainable land use policies and law enforcement. Part of the money would be needed to cover their budgetary/implementation costs, including the programmatic and transaction costs of providing benefits on the ground, and a part could be used for other green growth investments. But there would be no need to match the total of foregone private profits from every hectare of potentially converted land. The trade-offs of REDD+ should be made through national land use planning processes, not by individual farmers and firms weighing the advantages of production versus protection. The actual financial resources needed to achieve REDD+ results at the national or jurisdictional level is substantially lower than the opportunity costs faced by private decision-makers. The concept of REDD+ has long suffered from this confusion, partly because many pilot activities have been at the project level, rendering them unable to make an impact on broader policy change. Second, previous estimates assumed that rich countries would need to pay for most reductions. In 2009, it became clear that this would not be the case, with Brazil, Indonesia, and other countries pledging substantial mitigation without international support. As the next climate agreement takes effect in 2020, most forest-rich countries will be willing to undertake some forest mitigation without support, both to contribute to climate action and because reducing deforestation is increasingly understood to be in their medium- and long-term interest (notwithstanding the significant short-term financial and political costs). As discussed in part 1, the Lima Challenge demonstrated this commitment and leadership from important tropical forest countries. The commitment to self-finance a significant share of the emission reductions will be reflected in countries’ reference levels and a lower share of the overall reductions to be paid for through REDD+. Similarly, corporate zero-deforestation commitments increase the incentive for governments and producers to change their practices beyond the incentive from REDD+ payments alone, potentially achieving greater reductions at a given level of REDD+ payments. 46 Johan Eliasch, Climate Change: Financing Global Forests—The Eliasch Review (London: Earthscan, 2008). 25 The Billion-Ton Solution | Dahl-Jørgensen Third, cost estimates were inflated based on the assumption that REDD+ would be fully integrated into global carbon markets. This would imply paying a high and increasing carbon price determined by the global marginal abatement cost. However, since REDD+ can be achieved at a far lower cost than other mitigation actions, one can avoid paying excessive “REDD+ rents” by keeping REDD+ separate from other sectors. This also has the added benefit of lowering price volatility risk in carbon markets like the European ETS, and of creating a broad coalition of environmental and social NGOs supportive of large-scale REDD+ payments because REDD+ reductions would come in addition to rather than replacing climate action to transition out of fossile fuels in advanced economies. The power of REDD+ payments lies not in their direct financial impact but in their ability to redirect economic activity and existing agricultural investment flows. The Food and Agriculture Organization recently estimated global annual investment in agriculture at about $328 billion, of which 47 about half is private and half is public. REDD+ obviously cannot succeed if it tries to financially outcompete food production. But it can make a significant difference on the margins, by keeping those existing investment flows away from forest areas and direct them to degraded land and existing farms. By so doing, REDD+ can help bring about the transition from extensive to more productive agriculture that will be needed to secure food security and long-term economic development. 5. Ready for What? The Moving Goalpost of REDD Demand Current REDD+ pilot efforts are suffering from a lack of carbon demand signals. Some developing countries have made important progress, driven by a combination of government leadership, international partnerships, and strengthened market pressure through international commodity supply chains. But in the absence of global REDD+ demand signals, too few nations are addressing the direct and underlying drivers of deforestation withh the resolve needed. Most countries with tropical forests have taken preliminary steps on “REDD+ readiness,” such as strategy formulation and capacity building, with very limited support or certainty of future funding. The policy change expected from REDD+ is simply too fundamental to be triggered by small, up-front “readiness” grants with cumbersome procedures and without a clear path to future results-based payments. “Readiness” alone is therefore unlikely to deliver REDD= results, except in those countries that have already mustered the political will to take serious action. Conversely, readiness has so far progressed most rapidly where it has been coupled with results-based pledges from the start. REDD+ is essentially a development choice; and to succeed, it needs to be chosen at the highest political levels and with support across line ministries. It involves significant up-front costs—political as well as financial. Its benefits, however, though real, will tend to materialize beyond the electoral cycle. A few million dollars for readiness has proven to be insufficient to make this development choice a realistic option. The failure to create demand for REDD+ leaves billions of tons of cost-effective mitigation unexploited pre-2020. The EU decided against the inclusion of forest mitigation in its ETS, and failed to find alternative ways to create demand. The United States came close to creating massive demand for REDD+ through the Waxman-Markey Bill in 2009, which passed the House of Representative but died in the Senate. In the UNFCCC process, REDD+ was held back by the broader decision in Durban in 2011 to postpone the start of a new climate agreement from 2013 till 2020, despite the REDD+ rule set having been largely agreed upon at that time (and later finalized in Warsaw in 2013). 47 Sarah Lowery, David Tepper, and Rupert Edwards, Bridging Financing Gaps for Low-­‐Emissions Rural Development through Integrated Finance Strategies (Washington: Forest Trends, 2014), http://www.forest-­‐ trends.org/documents/files/Bridging%20Financing%20Gaps%20English.pdf. 26 The Billion-Ton Solution | Dahl-Jørgensen Forest-rich nations have been preparing for REDD+ for almost a decade now, and are losing faith that serious willingness to pay will ever materialize. The stakes cannot be overestimated. Decisions made by countries during the next 12 months will determine whether REDD+ will ever become a reality. Not including large-scale REDD+ incentives in the international framework to apply through 2025 or 2030 would be tantamount to giving up on the goals of the New York Declaration on Forests only a year after it was launched. If credible willingness to pay is within reach, forest-rich nations could be convinced to put forward not only ambitious and unconditional mitigation pledges of own action, but also additional mitigation subject to international financial support. However, a failure in 2015 to include provisions for large-scale REDD+ demand in countries’ mitigation contributions for the post-2020 agreement would likely close the REDD+ window of opportunity and even leave the 2°C target out of reach. REDD+ is the only agreed-upon sectorial mechanism under the UNFCCC. To date, there has been very slow progress in developing a “new market mechanism” (as established at the UNFCCC’s 17th Conference of the Parties in Durban) that scales up from projects to sectorial approaches. REDD+ has a rule set that was agreed to under the UNFCCC to do exactly that, in a way that deals with “additionality” without creating perverse incentives for countries not to enact ambitious climate policies. Technical concerns about monitoring, “permanence,” and “leakage” can be dealt with. Leakage is best dealt with through jurisdictional and national approaches, and through the participation of many countries. Permanence can be dealt with through continued carbon payments in the short term, and reformed land use policies in the long term. Both can also be dealt with through simple measures such as discounts and buffers. The agreed-on “Warsaw Framework” for REDD+ contains robust social and environmental safeguards, and despite initial ideological opposition in the negotiations, the developing countries have accepted that strong safeguards are not only a precondition for financial support, but also an integral part of effectively and sustainably reducing forest emissions. Many financing channels are up and running, ranging from national funds like the Brazilian development bank’s Amazon Fund, to bilateral funds like Germany’s innovate REDD+ Early Movers to multilateral funds like the World Bank’s Forest Carbon Partnership Facility’s Carbon Fund. These can be scaled up or replicated, and more are already being put in place. 6. The EU’s Opportunity to Lead on Forests In 2008, the EU promised to “take a leading role to shape the global policy response to deforestation.” It even articulated the goals of reducing gross tropical deforestation by 50% by 2020 48 and achieving zero net deforestation by 2030. In large part emboldened by the EU’s signals that it would mobilize significant demand for REDD+ credits, the developing countries accepted ambitious language to “reduce, halt, and reverse” forest and forest carbon loss, but with clear caveats that significant international incentives would be required to succeed.49 The EU considered options for mobilizing REDD+ demand, but did not deliver on them. In 2010, the EU Commission included REDD+ purchases as one of several options to be considered as part of a strategy to ramp up the EU’s 2020 target from 20% to 30% below 1990 levels. But this target was never 48 For a good review of the EU’s policy process on REDD+, see Moritz von Unger, Charlotte Streck, and Donna Lee, “Options for Financing REDD+ in the Context of EU Climate Policy: Status and Opportunities,” TNC and Climate Focus, http://www.climatefocus.com/documents/files/options_for_financing_redd.pdf. 49 United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change, “Cancun Agreements,” 2010, http://unfccc.int/resource/docs/2010/cop16/eng/07a01.pdf#page=2. 27 The Billion-Ton Solution | Dahl-Jørgensen raised, despite the fact that reaching the 30% target is now estimated to be cheaper than the 20% target was expected to be when it was set in 2008. The Commission also discussed testing compliance demand for REDD+ by governments through the “Effort Sharing Decision” (for those sectors not covered by the ETS) in the pre-2020 period, which also has not happened. The EU’s only adopted policy on REDD+ demand has been a nonbinding encouragement to its member states to use revenues from auctioned ETS allowances on REDD+. Though, in theory, these EU allowances are a promising source of predictable and large-scale demand, in practice their the low prices dramatically reduced the available funding. Germany has used this source of funding to finance its innovative bilateral REDD Early Movers program, but at a lower scale than initially hoped for, due to falling auctioning revenues as EU carbon prices fell. Although some member states—notably, Germany and the U.K.—have started piloting REDD+ payments through their development budgets, the EU as a whole has yet to create the sizable demand for forest carbon pre- or post-2020 that forest countries were expecting. Trade measures can support but not replace the need for positive incentives. In the last few years, the EU as a whole has largely moved away from REDD+ and instead focused on its Forest Law Enforcement, Governance, and Trade program (FLEGT). Through this program, forest countries are supported with technical assistance to implement “Voluntary Partnership Agreements” with the EU, to allow continued imports of forest products into the EU from those countries that are in compliance with the EU’s new timber regulations. The motivation behind FLEGT is to reduce the EU’s global forest footprint, recognizing that EU members’ demand for forest and agricultural products is a highly significant driver of deforestation. Although FLEGT is making a positive contribution, it is hard to see how this program will fundamentally change the land use policies of forest-rich nations and level the playing field among local producers that serve domestic markets or export markets beyond the EU. In short, there is a mismatch between the EU’s policy goals and its current policies. To reinvigorate REDD+ the EU should prioritize REDD+ as a core component of its international mitigation commitment. The commitment itself would be sector neutral, but accompanying political statements could highlight REDD+ as a core strategy to deliver the commitment. Not all of the international mitigation commitment would need to be from REDD+, of course. When assessing options in terms of cost-effectiveness, the ability to mobilize own efforts from developing countries, and positive development effects, REDD+ would in any case emerge as a very high priority. A pledge of 1 billion tons with a strong focus on REDD+ would make the EU’s policy consistent with its stated goals. Since Copenhagen and Cancun in 2009-10, when the EU pushed for and got a commitment from developing countries to “slow, halt and reverse forest carbon and cover loss”, they have struggled to come up with a credible response. Until last year, the world had almost stopped waiting for the EU to create large-scale demand for REDD+. Then, in September 2014, the EU endorsed the New York Declaration, which committed to “ensure that strong, large-scale economic incentives are in place commensurate with the challenge”. The time to deliver on that commitment is in 2015, when the EU’s climate targets are set for the next 15 years. A dual pledge focused on forests would fit well within the EU’s negotiating position. It would stimulate increased ambition from developing countries, and even competition among them to put forward the most ambitious climate goals (or forest “reference levels”). It would allow the EU to distinguish between countries at different levels of development by requiring a larger portion of own effort (i.e. stricter reference levels) from middle-income countries. It would stimulate the private sector to deliver the low-carbon economy by redirecting the large capital flows currently driving deforestation. It would do so not through direct cofinance and the often creative mathematics of “leverage” claimed by the aid community, but by getting prices right and letting the private sector innovate and create value. 28 The Billion-Ton Solution | Dahl-Jørgensen Part III: Options for Inclusion in the EU’s Policy and Legal Frameworks Several options exist for incorporating an international mitigation pledge into EU climate policy. The legal and technical aspects of integrating the commitment into EU climate policy could be elaborated and fine-tuned during the five-year window after the pledge is made and before it takes effect in 2020. To start mobilizing the supply side, it is important that the pledge be made explicit in 2015, with the caveat that the legal predictability following formal inclusion in EU policy would come later.The following options, along with others, could be considered, some of which could be combined: 1. Decentralized purchases through the Effort-Sharing Decision. This option would simply add a legally binding commitment to purchase/pay for international credit purchasing to member states, on top of the internal mitigation required under the Effort-Sharing Decision (ESD)—that is, the cuts EU member states are committed to achieve in sectors not covered by the ETS, such as transportation, buildings, agriculture, and waste. Each EU member state could then decide whether to procure the additional tons from government budgets or to impose additional regulations on those industries that are not covered by the ETS to purchase international carbon units (that are not fungible with the ETS). The EU Commission could suggest dedicated funding streams for member states to mobilize for this purpose (e.g., ETS auctioning revenues or dedicated environmental taxes). Alternatively, this could be left to member states. 2. Political coalition. Some committed EU member states could take on the additional international mitigation commitment without sharing it across all the member states. This may not require EU regulation, and could potentially be more of a political pledge. For it to count as an EU commitment to mitigation in the UNFCCC, it would probably still require coordination among the member states and with the EU Commission about the rules and structures for the carbon transactions. This option may be politically more feasible than agreement under the ESD, because one would not need to convince all the EU member states. However, it would make it obvious to domestic constituencies in the countries that take on the extra burden that others are not contributing. For that reason, the contributing countries may prefer to take on the additional effort on behalf of the EU, but still do so as part of the ESD negotiations. An arguably more important disadvantage of the “political pledge” approach is that it may be perceived more like a “fast-start financing” pledge than a rules-based “compliance pledge” measured in tons of CO2. It may therefore become a continuation or scaling up of ODA programs, with all the related procedures and limitations, than a purchasing commitment (that may typically fall under a different ministry with a different mandate, like the Ministry of Finance or ministries covering climate change. To mitigate this risk, the pledge should include language about creating legal predictability as part of the operationalization of the effort toward 2020, and that the tons will be verified according to established rules (or rules to be clarified by 2020). 3. Centralized purchases at the EU level. EU-wide procurement of international carbon credits could potentially save on cost and strengthen the EU’s bargaining power with sellers by acting at scale as a monopsonist buyer. It could also allow for the use of potentially efficiencyenhancing purchasing methods, such as large-scale global tenders. Centralized purchases would require the EU Commission be given the resources needed, which is always a challenge vis-à-vis the member states. Options for mobilizing the revenues would need to be sorted out before 2020. (This could include, for example, ETS auction revenues (currently delegated to member states, with “recommendations” from the Commission to spend it on climate finance, 29 The Billion-Ton Solution | Dahl-Jørgensen including REDD+), dedicated set-asides from certain taxes (at the national or EU level), as a budget item in the overall EU budget or as a separate climate budget stemming from the EUinternal Effort Sharing Decision). 4. Hybrid approach—centralized mechanism with bilateral contributions. One could envisage a hybrid approach that combines the voluntary “political coalition” and a quasi–“centralized purchases” model. In this case, member states would agree to the overall ambition (e.g., 1 billion tons per year). A subset of member states would then make politically binding but nationally determined pledges splitting the responsibility of the overall additional EU mitigation pledge. Member states would then task the European Commission to set up a voluntary EU-wide mechanism and to negotiate bilateral framework agreements with forest-rich countries on their behalf. Purchasing member states would have the option to pay for forest reductions through the EU mechanism at EU’s agreed-on prices from the jurisdictions negotiated by the Commission. This approach would avoid the potential redundancies and confusion of having several EU member states negotiate bilateral agreements with the same forest-rich countries or jurisdictions and would ensure a consistent approach. At the same time, this flexible “opt-in” system would not require nations that lack the political will or financial resources to assume any purchasing obligation. In addition, this system would not require the transfer of any budgetary resources to the EU from Member States, as participating Member States would decide whether and when to pay for forest emission reductions via the EU mechanism. This system would also create transparency so that purchasing member states would receive political recognition for their international forest contributions. As with the "political coalition" model, it would be important that the tons be verified according to clear rules, either defined by the EU or taken from the UNFCCC where available. 5. “Compensation Credits.” The concept of “Compensation Credits” combines the classic offsetting with regulatory obligations outside emission trading by allowing entities with obligations under a range of EU climate and energy laws (e.g., energy efficiency, renewable targets, fuel standards, agriculture policy) to meet part of those obligations with compensation credits.50 It has many of the same pros and cons as traditional offsetting—for example, costeffective compliance for industry, protection against price shocks and global competition on one hand, and delayed domestic action within the relevant sector/policy energy transition and uncertainty of demand on the other. This option would likely trigger reactions from parts of the NGO community, much like the opposition to traditional offsetting. 6. Partial inclusion in the ETS. The EU could decide to allow some international credits into its ETS, its main climate policy instrument. This could likely only be a partial solution, given that the demand would be insufficient to add up to the EU’s international commitment (e.g., 1 billion tons a year). It would also be opposed by many NGOs, and even be opposed by some policymakers for technical reasons (e.g., in the case of REDD+, the “leakage” and “permanence” of credits, both of which can be accommodated for through buffers or discounting of credits). Conversely, the ETS is the EU’s main policy tool to meet its mitigation targets, and has a track record of mobilizing private capital for international mitigation. Partial inclusion up to a defined cap would require the EU Commission or the member states to find a way to guarantee both that sufficient mitigation occurs in the EU to meet the internal goal and that sufficient tons are paid for to meet 50 Conway, Streck and Unger, “REDD+ Finance in the European Union: Options for Scaling-­‐up Near Term Support”, August 2014 30 The Billion-Ton Solution | Dahl-Jørgensen the additional 1 billion tons per year. This could be done with a combination of a cap on the volume of credits to be allowed into the ETS and a commitment among the governments or the EU Commission to be the purchaser of last resort if the ETS demand is insufficient to pick up the maximum allowed supply (on top of the share that the EU member states were in any case planning to procure outside the ETS through one or more of the other options presented above). In any circumstance, even a partial inclusion in the ETS would not be an option until the EU has found a permanent solution to its current oversupply of existing allowances through the emerging Market Stability Reserve. Conclusion The EU contributes only about 11% of global emissions but has the world’s largest economy, at about 25% of the global GDP. It has an explicit ambition to take—and a proud history of having taken—the lead on climate change. To continue to lead, the EU should not only reduce its own carbon emissions by at least 40% below 1990 levels by 2030 but also establish an international norm that all major economies should contribute to significant emission reductions abroad. Thus, it should pledge an additional 1 billion tons CO2 outside its borders. While the pledge should be sector neutral, REDD+ can deliver a significant portion of the reductions. It is the only developed sectorial mechanism. Some 60 countries are actively preparing for full implementation—and need international incentives to deliver on their potential. REDD+ can demonstrably deliver large-scale and near-term mitigation, with unmatched additional development benefits. And it can do so at a cost several orders of magnitude lower than other sectors abroad, and at a fraction of the cost of delivering similar mitigation contributions at home. A commitment from the EU before the Paris climate talks in December 2015 to mitigate 1 billion tons CO2 per year starting in 2020 would mobilize significant additional mitigation efforts from developing countries—and likely from the other developed countries—with positive spillovers to the broader climate negotiations on ambition and finance. As the European Union faces a seemingly intractable contradiction between its eagerness to lead on climate change and its fiscal challenges at home, international mitigation and REDD+ offer a unique opportunity to regain global climate leadership and get the climate negotiations on track to narrow the global mitigation gap. 31 The Billion-Ton Solution | Dahl-Jørgensen Bibliography Associated Press. “Deforestation Drops 18 Percent in Brazil’s Amazon.” November 26, 2014. http://bigstory.ap.org/article/27662c4b95ee4e75adbdb02bba82f05e/deforestation-­‐drops-­‐brazils-­‐ amazon. Assunção, Juliano, Clarissa C. e Gandour, and Rudi Rocha. Deforestation Slowdown in the Legal Amazon: Prices or Policies? Rio de Janeiro: Climate Policy Initiative, 2012. http://climatepolicyinitiative.org/wp-­‐ content/uploads/2012/03/Deforestation-­‐Prices-­‐or-­‐Policies-­‐Working-­‐Paper.pdf. Butler, Rhett. “APP, Environmentalists Talk Future of Indonesia’s Forests.” Mongabay, February 20, 2014. http://news.mongabay.com/2014/0220-­‐app-­‐fcp-­‐debate.html#evK62zDQwDj6Fowl.99. Cambridge Institute for Sustainability Leadership. “Banking Environment Initiative.” http://www.cisl.cam.ac.uk/Business-­‐Platforms/Banking-­‐Environment-­‐Initiative.aspx. Chain Reaction Research. “96% of Global Palm Oil Trade Covered by Zero-Deforestation”, December 8, 2014, http://chainreactionresearch.com/2014/12/08/the-­‐chain-­‐96-­‐of-­‐global-­‐palm-­‐oil-­‐trade-­‐covered-­‐by-­‐zero-­‐deforestatio-­‐ plus-­‐jokowi-­‐brazil-­‐kl/ Eliasch, Johan. Climate Change: Financing Global Forests—The Eliasch Review. London: Earthscan, 2008. Conway, Darragh, Charlotte Streck, Moritz von Unger, “REDD+ Finance in the European Union: Options for Scalingup Near Term Support”, Climate Focus, August 2014, http://www.climatefocus.com/documents/redd_finance_in_the_european_union Dahl-Jørgensen, Andreas. “Forest Countries Challenge World to Increase Climate Ambition.” December 9, 2014. http://www.climateadvisers.com/forest-­‐countries-­‐challenge-­‐world-­‐to-­‐increase-­‐climate-­‐ambition/. European Commission. 2030 Framework for Climate and Energy Policies. Brussels: European Commission, 2014. http://ec.europa.eu/clima/policies/2030/index_en.htm. ———. Summary of the Impact Assessment: A Roadmap for Moving to a Competitive Low-Carbon Economy in 2050. Brussels: European Union, 2011. http://eur-­‐lex.europa.eu/legal-­‐ content/EN/TXT/PDF/?uri=CELEX:52011SC0289&from=EN. European Council. “Council Conclusions, 28 October 2014.” 2014. http://www.consilium.europa.eu/uedocs/cms_data/docs/pressdata/en/envir/145508.pdf. European Union. “EU Energy, Transport and GHG Emissions: Trends to 2050, Reference Scenario 2013.” 2013. http://ec.europa.eu/clima/policies/2030/docs/eu_trends_2050_en.pdf. Global Commission on the Economy and Climate. Better Growth, Better Climate. London: Global Commission on the Economy and Climate, 2014. Available at http://newclimateeconomy.report/. Greenpeace. “Tropical Deforestation Emission Reduction Mechanism: Executive Summary.” http://www.greenpeace.org/international/Global/international/planet-­‐2/report/2008/3/tropical-­‐ deforestation-­‐emissio.pdf. Group of Eight. “Responsible Leadership for a Sustainable Future.” 2009. http://www.g8italia2009.it/static/G8_Allegato/G8_Declaration_08_07_09_final,0.pdf. Houghton, Richard A. “The Emissions of Carbon from Deforestation and Degradation in the Tropics: Past Trends and Future Potential,” Carbon Management 4, no. 5 (2013): 539–46. Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Fifth Assessment Report: Summary for Policymakers. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2014. https://www.google.com/?gws_rd=ssl#q=IPCC+AR5+%282014%29%2C+Summary+for+Policy-­‐Makers. Lowery, Sarah, David Tepper, and Rupert Edwards. Bridging Financing Gaps for Low-Emissions Rural Development through Integrated Finance Strategies. Washington: Forest Trends, 2014. http://www.forest-­‐ trends.org/documents/files/Bridging%20Financing%20Gaps%20English.pdf. Nepstad, Daniel, Silvia Irawan, Tathiana Bezerra, William Boyd, Claudia Stickler, João Shimada, Oswaldo Carvalho, Katie MacIntyre, Alue Dohong, Ane Alencar, Andrea Azevedo, David Tepper, and Sarah Lowery. “More Food, More Forests, Fewer Emissions, Better Livelihoods: Linking REDD+, Sustainable Supply Chains, and Domestic Policy in Brazil, Indonesia, and Colombia.” Carbon Management 4, no. 6 (2013): 639–58. http://earthinnovation.org/publications/more-­‐food-­‐more-­‐forests-­‐fewer-­‐emissions-­‐better-­‐livelihoods/. New York Times. “Election Guide 2008.” http://elections.nytimes.com/2008/president/issues/climate.html. Purvis, Nigel, Samuel Grausz, and Andrew Light. Carbon Market Crossroads: New Ideas for Harnessing Global Markets to Confront Climate Change. Washington: Center for American Progress, 2013. http://www.americanprogress.org/issues/green/report/2013/04/29/61655/carbon-­‐market-­‐crossroads/. Schmidt, J. “China Evolving to Coal Consumption Peak & Strong Climate Commitments.” 2014. http://switchboard.nrdc.org/blogs/jschmidt/china_evolving_to_coal_consump.html. 32 The Billion-Ton Solution | Dahl-Jørgensen United Kingdom, Department of Energy and Climate Change. Analysis of EU 2030 greenhouse gas emission reduction target options, 28 October 2013. https://www.gov.uk/government/publications/analysis-­‐of-­‐eu-­‐ 2030-­‐greenhouse-­‐gas-­‐emission-­‐reduction-­‐target-­‐option ———. Green Growth Group Ministers' Statement—Next Steps on the EU 2030 Climate and Energy Policy Framework, 18 December, 2014 https://www.gov.uk/government/news/green-­‐growth-­‐group-­‐ministers-­‐ statement-­‐on-­‐2030-­‐energy-­‐climate-­‐policy-­‐framework. ———.Written Ministerial Statement by Edward Davey: UK Negotiating Position on the EU 2030 Climate and Energy Framework, 4 June 2013, https://www.gov.uk/government/speeches/written-­‐ministerial-­‐statement-­‐by-­‐ edward-­‐davey-­‐uk-­‐negotiating-­‐position-­‐on-­‐the-­‐eu-­‐2030-­‐climate-­‐and-­‐energy-­‐framework. United Nations Development Program. UN Climate Summit: New York Declaration on Forests. New York: United Nations Development Program, 2014. Available at http://www.undp.org/content/undp/en/home/presscenter/events/2014/september/23-­‐september-­‐ united-­‐nations-­‐climate-­‐summit/Land-­‐Use-­‐and-­‐Forest-­‐Action-­‐Area-­‐Online-­‐Pressroom.html. United Nations Environment Program. Building Natural Capital: How REDD+ Can Support a Green Economy. New York: United Nations Environment Program, 2014. ———. The Emissions Gap Report 2013: A UNEP Synthesis Report. New York: United Nations Environment Program, 2013. http://www.unep.org/publications/ebooks/emissionsgapreport2013/. ———. The Emissions Gap Report 2014: A UNEP Synthesis Report. New York: United Nations Environment Program, 2014. http://www.unep.org/publications/ebooks/emissionsgapreport2014/portals/50268/pdf/EGR2014_LOWR ES.pdf. United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change. “Cancun Agreements.” 2010. http://unfccc.int/resource/docs/2010/cop16/eng/07a01.pdf#page=2. Von Unger, Moritz, Charlotte Streck, and Donna Lee. “Options for Financing REDD+ in the Context of EU Climate Policy: Status and Opportunities.” TNC and Climate Focus. http://www.climatefocus.com/documents/files/options_for_financing_redd.pdf. White House. “President to Attend Copenhagen Climate Talks.” http://www.whitehouse.gov/the-­‐press-­‐ office/president-­‐attend-­‐copenhagen-­‐climate-­‐talks. Wolosin, Michael. “The Climate Impact of Wilmar’s ‘No Deforestation No Peat No Exploitation Policy.’” March 14, 2014. http://www.climateadvisers.com/the-­‐climate-­‐impact-­‐of-­‐wilmars-­‐no-­‐deforestation-­‐no-­‐peat-­‐no-­‐ exploitation-­‐policy/. ———. “Quantifying the Benefits of the New York Declaration on Forests.” 2014. http://www.climateadvisers.com/quantifying-­‐the-­‐benefits-­‐of-­‐the-­‐new-­‐york-­‐declaration-­‐on-­‐forests/. Wolosin, Michael, and Maria Belenky. “Gap Analysis with Paris Pledges.” 2014. http://www.climateadvisers.com/wp-­‐content/uploads/2014/12/Climate-­‐Advisers-­‐Paris-­‐Analysis-­‐Mind-­‐ the-­‐Gap.pdf. ———. “Paris Analysis: Mind the Gap.” 2014. www.climateadvisers.com/mindthegap. World Bank. “73 Countries and Over 1,000 Businesses Speak Out in Support of a Price on Carbon.” September 22, 2014. http://www.worldbank.org/en/news/feature/2014/09/22/governments-­‐businesses-­‐support-­‐ carbon-­‐pricing. ———. “State & Trends Report Charts Global Growth of Carbon Pricing.” May 28, 2014. http://www.worldbank.org/en/news/feature/2014/05/28/state-­‐trends-­‐report-­‐tracks-­‐global-­‐growth-­‐ carbon-­‐pricing. World Health Organization. “7 Million Premature Deaths Annually Linked to Air Pollution.” Press release, March 25, 2014. http://www.who.int/mediacentre/news/releases/2014/air-­‐pollution/en/. th 33 1320 19 St. NW | Suite 400 | Washington, DC 20036 | 202.350.4650 | www.climateadvisers.com