Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Kinetic models of economy. The conservative case Giuseppe Toscani Department of Mathematics University of Pavia, Italy Orleans, March 15 2007 KTASEEM Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Outline 1 Formation of Pareto tails Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades 2 Kinetic models The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples 3 Conclusions Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Outline 1 Formation of Pareto tails Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades 2 Kinetic models The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples 3 Conclusions Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Outline 1 Formation of Pareto tails Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades 2 Kinetic models The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples 3 Conclusions Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades 1 Formation of Pareto tails Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades 2 Kinetic models The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples 3 Conclusions Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades The goal Introduce kinetic models of Boltzmann type to study the evolution of the distribution of wealth in a simple market economy. In most of these models, the market is represented as an ideal gas, where each molecule is identified with an agent, and each trading event between two agents is considered to be an elastic – or rather money conserving – collision between two molecules. The founding idea is that a trading market composed of a sufficiently large number of agents can be described using the laws of statistical mechanics as it happens in a physical system composed of many interacting particles. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades The goal Introduce kinetic models of Boltzmann type to study the evolution of the distribution of wealth in a simple market economy. In most of these models, the market is represented as an ideal gas, where each molecule is identified with an agent, and each trading event between two agents is considered to be an elastic – or rather money conserving – collision between two molecules. The founding idea is that a trading market composed of a sufficiently large number of agents can be described using the laws of statistical mechanics as it happens in a physical system composed of many interacting particles. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades The goal Introduce kinetic models of Boltzmann type to study the evolution of the distribution of wealth in a simple market economy. In most of these models, the market is represented as an ideal gas, where each molecule is identified with an agent, and each trading event between two agents is considered to be an elastic – or rather money conserving – collision between two molecules. The founding idea is that a trading market composed of a sufficiently large number of agents can be described using the laws of statistical mechanics as it happens in a physical system composed of many interacting particles. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades The steady states The knowledge of the large-wealth behavior of the steady state density is of primary importance since it determines a posteriori if the model fits data of real economies. More than a hundred years ago, the Italian economist Vilfredo Pareto [V.Pareto, Cours d’Economie Politique, (1897)] first quantified the large-wealth behavior of the income distribution in a society and found it to follow a power-law distribution. If f (w ) is the probability density function of agents with wealth w , and w is sufficiently large, Z ∞ F (w ) = f (w∗ ) dw∗ ∼ w −µ . w Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades The steady states The knowledge of the large-wealth behavior of the steady state density is of primary importance since it determines a posteriori if the model fits data of real economies. More than a hundred years ago, the Italian economist Vilfredo Pareto [V.Pareto, Cours d’Economie Politique, (1897)] first quantified the large-wealth behavior of the income distribution in a society and found it to follow a power-law distribution. If f (w ) is the probability density function of agents with wealth w , and w is sufficiently large, Z ∞ F (w ) = f (w∗ ) dw∗ ∼ w −µ . w Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades The steady states The knowledge of the large-wealth behavior of the steady state density is of primary importance since it determines a posteriori if the model fits data of real economies. More than a hundred years ago, the Italian economist Vilfredo Pareto [V.Pareto, Cours d’Economie Politique, (1897)] first quantified the large-wealth behavior of the income distribution in a society and found it to follow a power-law distribution. If f (w ) is the probability density function of agents with wealth w , and w is sufficiently large, Z ∞ F (w ) = f (w∗ ) dw∗ ∼ w −µ . w Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades The steady states II Pareto mistakenly believed that power laws apply to the whole distribution with a universal exponent µ approximatively equal to 1.5. Later, Mandelbrot proposed a weak Pareto law that applies only to high incomes [B.Mandelbrot (1960)]. The exponent µ, usually called the Pareto index, was initially found to have a value between 1 and 3 . Considerable investigations with real data during the last ten years revealed that the tail of the income distribution indeed follows the above mentioned behavior and the value of the Pareto index is generally seen to vary between 1 and 2.5 (USA ∼ 1.6, Japan ∼ 1.8 − 2.2) [A.Drǎgulescu, V.M.Yakovenko (2000-2001)] Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades The steady states II Pareto mistakenly believed that power laws apply to the whole distribution with a universal exponent µ approximatively equal to 1.5. Later, Mandelbrot proposed a weak Pareto law that applies only to high incomes [B.Mandelbrot (1960)]. The exponent µ, usually called the Pareto index, was initially found to have a value between 1 and 3 . Considerable investigations with real data during the last ten years revealed that the tail of the income distribution indeed follows the above mentioned behavior and the value of the Pareto index is generally seen to vary between 1 and 2.5 (USA ∼ 1.6, Japan ∼ 1.8 − 2.2) [A.Drǎgulescu, V.M.Yakovenko (2000-2001)] Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades The steady states II Pareto mistakenly believed that power laws apply to the whole distribution with a universal exponent µ approximatively equal to 1.5. Later, Mandelbrot proposed a weak Pareto law that applies only to high incomes [B.Mandelbrot (1960)]. The exponent µ, usually called the Pareto index, was initially found to have a value between 1 and 3 . Considerable investigations with real data during the last ten years revealed that the tail of the income distribution indeed follows the above mentioned behavior and the value of the Pareto index is generally seen to vary between 1 and 2.5 (USA ∼ 1.6, Japan ∼ 1.8 − 2.2) [A.Drǎgulescu, V.M.Yakovenko (2000-2001)] Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades The steady states II Pareto mistakenly believed that power laws apply to the whole distribution with a universal exponent µ approximatively equal to 1.5. Later, Mandelbrot proposed a weak Pareto law that applies only to high incomes [B.Mandelbrot (1960)]. The exponent µ, usually called the Pareto index, was initially found to have a value between 1 and 3 . Considerable investigations with real data during the last ten years revealed that the tail of the income distribution indeed follows the above mentioned behavior and the value of the Pareto index is generally seen to vary between 1 and 2.5 (USA ∼ 1.6, Japan ∼ 1.8 − 2.2) [A.Drǎgulescu, V.M.Yakovenko (2000-2001)] Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades Consequences The main consequence is that typically less than 10% of the population in any country possesses about 40% of the total wealth of that country and they follow the above law. The rest of the low income population, in fact the majority (90% or more), follow a different distribution which is debated to be either Gibbs [A.Drǎgulescu, V.M.Yakovenko (2000-2001)] or log-normal [T. Di Matteo, T. Aste, S.T. Hyde (2004)]. It is possible to reproduce these results by means of a kinetic approach? Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades Consequences The main consequence is that typically less than 10% of the population in any country possesses about 40% of the total wealth of that country and they follow the above law. The rest of the low income population, in fact the majority (90% or more), follow a different distribution which is debated to be either Gibbs [A.Drǎgulescu, V.M.Yakovenko (2000-2001)] or log-normal [T. Di Matteo, T. Aste, S.T. Hyde (2004)]. It is possible to reproduce these results by means of a kinetic approach? Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades Consequences The main consequence is that typically less than 10% of the population in any country possesses about 40% of the total wealth of that country and they follow the above law. The rest of the low income population, in fact the majority (90% or more), follow a different distribution which is debated to be either Gibbs [A.Drǎgulescu, V.M.Yakovenko (2000-2001)] or log-normal [T. Di Matteo, T. Aste, S.T. Hyde (2004)]. It is possible to reproduce these results by means of a kinetic approach? Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades A typical picture Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades The cooling of a granular gas A well–known phenomenon in the large–time behavior of the Boltzmann equation with dissipative interactions is the formation of overpopulated tails [Bobylev, A. V.; Gamba, I. M.; Panferov, V. A. (2004)]. Exact results on the behavior of these tails have been obtained for simplified models, in particular for a gas inelastic Maxwell particles. In one dimension f (w ) = 2 π(1 + v 2 )2 [Baldassarri A., Marini Bettolo Marconi U., Puglisi A. (2002)] Analogous results (with no explicit self-similar solution) hold in higher dimensions [Bobylev A.V., Cercignani C. (2003)]. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades The cooling of a granular gas A well–known phenomenon in the large–time behavior of the Boltzmann equation with dissipative interactions is the formation of overpopulated tails [Bobylev, A. V.; Gamba, I. M.; Panferov, V. A. (2004)]. Exact results on the behavior of these tails have been obtained for simplified models, in particular for a gas inelastic Maxwell particles. In one dimension f (w ) = 2 π(1 + v 2 )2 [Baldassarri A., Marini Bettolo Marconi U., Puglisi A. (2002)] Analogous results (with no explicit self-similar solution) hold in higher dimensions [Bobylev A.V., Cercignani C. (2003)]. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades The cooling of a granular gas A well–known phenomenon in the large–time behavior of the Boltzmann equation with dissipative interactions is the formation of overpopulated tails [Bobylev, A. V.; Gamba, I. M.; Panferov, V. A. (2004)]. Exact results on the behavior of these tails have been obtained for simplified models, in particular for a gas inelastic Maxwell particles. In one dimension f (w ) = 2 π(1 + v 2 )2 [Baldassarri A., Marini Bettolo Marconi U., Puglisi A. (2002)] Analogous results (with no explicit self-similar solution) hold in higher dimensions [Bobylev A.V., Cercignani C. (2003)]. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades Fast diffusion equations A further example of a PDE with a self-similar solution with overpopulated tails is represented by fast diffusion equations. The logarithmic diffusion [J.A. Carrillo, J.L. Vázquez (2003)]. ∂f ∂ 2 log f = , ∂t ∂w 2 t≥0 has the Cauchy distribution as self-similar solution fs (w ) = 1 π(1 + v 2 ) The connection between the fast diffusion equation and classical kinetic theory relies in a result of McKean on the central limit theorem for Carleman model [H.P. McKean (1975)]. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades Fast diffusion equations A further example of a PDE with a self-similar solution with overpopulated tails is represented by fast diffusion equations. The logarithmic diffusion [J.A. Carrillo, J.L. Vázquez (2003)]. ∂f ∂ 2 log f = , ∂t ∂w 2 t≥0 has the Cauchy distribution as self-similar solution fs (w ) = 1 π(1 + v 2 ) The connection between the fast diffusion equation and classical kinetic theory relies in a result of McKean on the central limit theorem for Carleman model [H.P. McKean (1975)]. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades Fast diffusion equations A further example of a PDE with a self-similar solution with overpopulated tails is represented by fast diffusion equations. The logarithmic diffusion [J.A. Carrillo, J.L. Vázquez (2003)]. ∂f ∂ 2 log f = , ∂t ∂w 2 t≥0 has the Cauchy distribution as self-similar solution fs (w ) = 1 π(1 + v 2 ) The connection between the fast diffusion equation and classical kinetic theory relies in a result of McKean on the central limit theorem for Carleman model [H.P. McKean (1975)]. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades Fast diffusion equations A further example of a PDE with a self-similar solution with overpopulated tails is represented by fast diffusion equations. The logarithmic diffusion [J.A. Carrillo, J.L. Vázquez (2003)]. ∂f ∂ 2 log f = , ∂t ∂w 2 t≥0 has the Cauchy distribution as self-similar solution fs (w ) = 1 π(1 + v 2 ) The connection between the fast diffusion equation and classical kinetic theory relies in a result of McKean on the central limit theorem for Carleman model [H.P. McKean (1975)]. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades Common features Economic and dissipative systems have much in common. Pareto tails In a strong economy the mean wealth m(t) is increasing (only mass conservation). A time-independent density profile is obtained with the normalized density fn (w ) = m(t)f (m(t)w , t) of unit mean wealth. Giuseppe Toscani Granular gases In a gas with dissipative interactions the temperature E (t) is decreasing (mass and momentum are conserved). In this case one refers to a normalized density p p fn (w ) = E (t)f ( E (t)w , t) of unit energy. Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades Common features Economic and dissipative systems have much in common. Pareto tails In a strong economy the mean wealth m(t) is increasing (only mass conservation). A time-independent density profile is obtained with the normalized density fn (w ) = m(t)f (m(t)w , t) of unit mean wealth. Giuseppe Toscani Granular gases In a gas with dissipative interactions the temperature E (t) is decreasing (mass and momentum are conserved). In this case one refers to a normalized density p p fn (w ) = E (t)f ( E (t)w , t) of unit energy. Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades Common features Economic and dissipative systems have much in common. Pareto tails In a strong economy the mean wealth m(t) is increasing (only mass conservation). A time-independent density profile is obtained with the normalized density fn (w ) = m(t)f (m(t)w , t) of unit mean wealth. Giuseppe Toscani Granular gases In a gas with dissipative interactions the temperature E (t) is decreasing (mass and momentum are conserved). In this case one refers to a normalized density p p fn (w ) = E (t)f ( E (t)w , t) of unit energy. Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades Common features Economic and dissipative systems have much in common. Pareto tails In a strong economy the mean wealth m(t) is increasing (only mass conservation). A time-independent density profile is obtained with the normalized density fn (w ) = m(t)f (m(t)w , t) of unit mean wealth. Giuseppe Toscani Granular gases In a gas with dissipative interactions the temperature E (t) is decreasing (mass and momentum are conserved). In this case one refers to a normalized density p p fn (w ) = E (t)f ( E (t)w , t) of unit energy. Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades Common features Economic and dissipative systems have much in common. Pareto tails In a strong economy the mean wealth m(t) is increasing (only mass conservation). A time-independent density profile is obtained with the normalized density fn (w ) = m(t)f (m(t)w , t) of unit mean wealth. Giuseppe Toscani Granular gases In a gas with dissipative interactions the temperature E (t) is decreasing (mass and momentum are conserved). In this case one refers to a normalized density p p fn (w ) = E (t)f ( E (t)w , t) of unit energy. Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades A reasonable conjecture It can be reasonably conjectured that the formation of overpopulated tails depends mainly on two facts: The kinetic system is based on binary collisions that generate convolution-like collisional operators. The collision is such that some conservation law in the kinetic system is missed at a microscopic level. The classical elastic Boltzmann equation is pointwise conservative, and the steady state is a gaussian function (the Maxwellian) Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades A reasonable conjecture It can be reasonably conjectured that the formation of overpopulated tails depends mainly on two facts: The kinetic system is based on binary collisions that generate convolution-like collisional operators. The collision is such that some conservation law in the kinetic system is missed at a microscopic level. The classical elastic Boltzmann equation is pointwise conservative, and the steady state is a gaussian function (the Maxwellian) Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades A reasonable conjecture It can be reasonably conjectured that the formation of overpopulated tails depends mainly on two facts: The kinetic system is based on binary collisions that generate convolution-like collisional operators. The collision is such that some conservation law in the kinetic system is missed at a microscopic level. The classical elastic Boltzmann equation is pointwise conservative, and the steady state is a gaussian function (the Maxwellian) Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades A reasonable conjecture It can be reasonably conjectured that the formation of overpopulated tails depends mainly on two facts: The kinetic system is based on binary collisions that generate convolution-like collisional operators. The collision is such that some conservation law in the kinetic system is missed at a microscopic level. The classical elastic Boltzmann equation is pointwise conservative, and the steady state is a gaussian function (the Maxwellian) Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades Trades I The goal of a kinetic model of a simple market economy, is to describe the evolution of the distribution of wealth by means of microscopic interactions among agents or individuals which perform exchange of money. Each trade can be interpreted as an interaction where a fraction of the money changes hands. One generally assumes that this wealth after the interaction is non-negative, which corresponds to impose that no debts are allowed. From a microscopic view point, we will consider in the following binary interactions described by the rules v ∗ = p1 v + q1 w ; Giuseppe Toscani w ∗ = p2 v + q2 w . Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades Trades I The goal of a kinetic model of a simple market economy, is to describe the evolution of the distribution of wealth by means of microscopic interactions among agents or individuals which perform exchange of money. Each trade can be interpreted as an interaction where a fraction of the money changes hands. One generally assumes that this wealth after the interaction is non-negative, which corresponds to impose that no debts are allowed. From a microscopic view point, we will consider in the following binary interactions described by the rules v ∗ = p1 v + q1 w ; Giuseppe Toscani w ∗ = p2 v + q2 w . Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades Trades I The goal of a kinetic model of a simple market economy, is to describe the evolution of the distribution of wealth by means of microscopic interactions among agents or individuals which perform exchange of money. Each trade can be interpreted as an interaction where a fraction of the money changes hands. One generally assumes that this wealth after the interaction is non-negative, which corresponds to impose that no debts are allowed. From a microscopic view point, we will consider in the following binary interactions described by the rules v ∗ = p1 v + q1 w ; Giuseppe Toscani w ∗ = p2 v + q2 w . Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades Trades II (v , w ) denote the (positive) money of two arbitrary individuals before the trade and (v ∗ , w ∗ ) the money after the trade. We will not allow agents to have debts, and thus the interaction takes place only if v ∗ ≥ 0 and w ∗ ≥ 0. The transaction coefficients pi , qi , i = 1, 2 can be either given constant or random quantities, with the obvious constraint to be nonnegative. The total amount v + w of wealth involved in the trade changes into v ∗ + w ∗ = (p1 + p2 )v + (q1 + q2 )w , Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades Trades II (v , w ) denote the (positive) money of two arbitrary individuals before the trade and (v ∗ , w ∗ ) the money after the trade. We will not allow agents to have debts, and thus the interaction takes place only if v ∗ ≥ 0 and w ∗ ≥ 0. The transaction coefficients pi , qi , i = 1, 2 can be either given constant or random quantities, with the obvious constraint to be nonnegative. The total amount v + w of wealth involved in the trade changes into v ∗ + w ∗ = (p1 + p2 )v + (q1 + q2 )w , Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades Trades II (v , w ) denote the (positive) money of two arbitrary individuals before the trade and (v ∗ , w ∗ ) the money after the trade. We will not allow agents to have debts, and thus the interaction takes place only if v ∗ ≥ 0 and w ∗ ≥ 0. The transaction coefficients pi , qi , i = 1, 2 can be either given constant or random quantities, with the obvious constraint to be nonnegative. The total amount v + w of wealth involved in the trade changes into v ∗ + w ∗ = (p1 + p2 )v + (q1 + q2 )w , Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades Trades II (v , w ) denote the (positive) money of two arbitrary individuals before the trade and (v ∗ , w ∗ ) the money after the trade. We will not allow agents to have debts, and thus the interaction takes place only if v ∗ ≥ 0 and w ∗ ≥ 0. The transaction coefficients pi , qi , i = 1, 2 can be either given constant or random quantities, with the obvious constraint to be nonnegative. The total amount v + w of wealth involved in the trade changes into v ∗ + w ∗ = (p1 + p2 )v + (q1 + q2 )w , Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades Trades III Unless both p1 + p2 = 1, q1 + q2 = 1, the total wealth put into the trade is not conserved. Condition relaxed in presence of random coefficients. In this case, the total wealth put into the trade, even if not pointwise conserved, can be conserved in the mean hp1 + p2 i = 1, hq1 + q2 i = 1 These conditions define conservative trades. These interactions are such that the mean wealth in the kinetic model is a conserved quantity. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades Trades III Unless both p1 + p2 = 1, q1 + q2 = 1, the total wealth put into the trade is not conserved. Condition relaxed in presence of random coefficients. In this case, the total wealth put into the trade, even if not pointwise conserved, can be conserved in the mean hp1 + p2 i = 1, hq1 + q2 i = 1 These conditions define conservative trades. These interactions are such that the mean wealth in the kinetic model is a conserved quantity. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades Trades III Unless both p1 + p2 = 1, q1 + q2 = 1, the total wealth put into the trade is not conserved. Condition relaxed in presence of random coefficients. In this case, the total wealth put into the trade, even if not pointwise conserved, can be conserved in the mean hp1 + p2 i = 1, hq1 + q2 i = 1 These conditions define conservative trades. These interactions are such that the mean wealth in the kinetic model is a conserved quantity. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades Chakraborty - Chakrabarthi model In [A. Chakraborti, B.K. Chakrabarti (2000)] the agents taking part in trading change their money according to the rule v ∗ = v + ∆(v , w ); w ∗ = w − ∆(v , w ), where ∆(v , w ) represents the amount of money to be exchanged. The realization of ∆(v , w ) takes into account the basic fact that the agents always keep some money in hand when trading. The ratio of saving to all of the money held (usually denoted by λ or s) is called the saving rate. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades Chakraborty - Chakrabarthi model In [A. Chakraborti, B.K. Chakrabarti (2000)] the agents taking part in trading change their money according to the rule v ∗ = v + ∆(v , w ); w ∗ = w − ∆(v , w ), where ∆(v , w ) represents the amount of money to be exchanged. The realization of ∆(v , w ) takes into account the basic fact that the agents always keep some money in hand when trading. The ratio of saving to all of the money held (usually denoted by λ or s) is called the saving rate. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades Chakraborty - Chakrabarthi model In [A. Chakraborti, B.K. Chakrabarti (2000)] the agents taking part in trading change their money according to the rule v ∗ = v + ∆(v , w ); w ∗ = w − ∆(v , w ), where ∆(v , w ) represents the amount of money to be exchanged. The realization of ∆(v , w ) takes into account the basic fact that the agents always keep some money in hand when trading. The ratio of saving to all of the money held (usually denoted by λ or s) is called the saving rate. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades C-C model II The amount of money to be exchanged is ∆(v , w ) = (1 − λ) [( − 1)v + w ] , 0 ≤ ≤ 1 is a random fraction, or even = 12 . Mixing parameters (λ saving rate) p1 = 1 − (1 − λ)(1 − ), p2 = (1 − λ)(1 − ), q1 = (1 − λ) q2 = 1 − (1 − λ). The trade is pointwise conservative. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy (1) Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades C-C model II The amount of money to be exchanged is ∆(v , w ) = (1 − λ) [( − 1)v + w ] , 0 ≤ ≤ 1 is a random fraction, or even = 12 . Mixing parameters (λ saving rate) p1 = 1 − (1 − λ)(1 − ), p2 = (1 − λ)(1 − ), q1 = (1 − λ) q2 = 1 − (1 − λ). The trade is pointwise conservative. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy (1) Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades C-C model II The amount of money to be exchanged is ∆(v , w ) = (1 − λ) [( − 1)v + w ] , 0 ≤ ≤ 1 is a random fraction, or even = 12 . Mixing parameters (λ saving rate) p1 = 1 − (1 − λ)(1 − ), p2 = (1 − λ)(1 − ), q1 = (1 − λ) q2 = 1 − (1 − λ). The trade is pointwise conservative. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy (1) Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades Chatterjee - Chakrabarti - Manna model In [A. Chatterjee, B.K. Chakrabarti, S.S. Manna (2004)] Chakrabarthi research group introduced random saving rate for the agents p1 = 1 − (1 − λv )(1 − ), q1 = (1 − λw ) p2 = (1 − λv )(1 − ), q2 = 1 − (1 − λw ), The random quantities λv and λw model the individual saving rates of agents with wealth v and w , respectively. Model still pointwise conservative. Agents with high saving propensity tend to become richer than individuals with lower saving rate. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades Chatterjee - Chakrabarti - Manna model In [A. Chatterjee, B.K. Chakrabarti, S.S. Manna (2004)] Chakrabarthi research group introduced random saving rate for the agents p1 = 1 − (1 − λv )(1 − ), q1 = (1 − λw ) p2 = (1 − λv )(1 − ), q2 = 1 − (1 − λw ), The random quantities λv and λw model the individual saving rates of agents with wealth v and w , respectively. Model still pointwise conservative. Agents with high saving propensity tend to become richer than individuals with lower saving rate. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades Chatterjee - Chakrabarti - Manna model In [A. Chatterjee, B.K. Chakrabarti, S.S. Manna (2004)] Chakrabarthi research group introduced random saving rate for the agents p1 = 1 − (1 − λv )(1 − ), q1 = (1 − λw ) p2 = (1 − λv )(1 − ), q2 = 1 − (1 − λw ), The random quantities λv and λw model the individual saving rates of agents with wealth v and w , respectively. Model still pointwise conservative. Agents with high saving propensity tend to become richer than individuals with lower saving rate. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades Cordier - Pareschi - Toscani model In [S. Cordier, L. Pareschi, G. Toscani (2005)] the trade is v ∗ = λv + (1 − λ)w + ηv w ∗ = (1 − λ)v + λw + η̃w . λ is the constant saving rate, while η and η̃ are independent centered random variables. The random term contains the effects of an open economy describing the risks (or returns) of the market Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades Cordier - Pareschi - Toscani model In [S. Cordier, L. Pareschi, G. Toscani (2005)] the trade is v ∗ = λv + (1 − λ)w + ηv w ∗ = (1 − λ)v + λw + η̃w . λ is the constant saving rate, while η and η̃ are independent centered random variables. The random term contains the effects of an open economy describing the risks (or returns) of the market Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades Cordier - Pareschi - Toscani model In [S. Cordier, L. Pareschi, G. Toscani (2005)] the trade is v ∗ = λv + (1 − λ)w + ηv w ∗ = (1 − λ)v + λw + η̃w . λ is the constant saving rate, while η and η̃ are independent centered random variables. The random term contains the effects of an open economy describing the risks (or returns) of the market Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades Cordier - Pareschi - Toscani model II If η, η̃ ≥ −λ, the random coefficients pi , qi , i = 1, 2 are nonnegative. p1 = λ + η, q1 = 1 − λ p2 = 1 − λ, q2 = λ + η̃. (2) The trade is conservative only in the mean, since hp1 + p2 i = 1, but p1 + p2 = 1 + η 6= 1 with probability one. Pointwise conservative (CC and CCM models) and conservative in the mean trades (CPT model) have different behaviors! Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades Cordier - Pareschi - Toscani model II If η, η̃ ≥ −λ, the random coefficients pi , qi , i = 1, 2 are nonnegative. p1 = λ + η, q1 = 1 − λ p2 = 1 − λ, q2 = λ + η̃. (2) The trade is conservative only in the mean, since hp1 + p2 i = 1, but p1 + p2 = 1 + η 6= 1 with probability one. Pointwise conservative (CC and CCM models) and conservative in the mean trades (CPT model) have different behaviors! Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades Cordier - Pareschi - Toscani model II If η, η̃ ≥ −λ, the random coefficients pi , qi , i = 1, 2 are nonnegative. p1 = λ + η, q1 = 1 − λ p2 = 1 − λ, q2 = λ + η̃. (2) The trade is conservative only in the mean, since hp1 + p2 i = 1, but p1 + p2 = 1 + η 6= 1 with probability one. Pointwise conservative (CC and CCM models) and conservative in the mean trades (CPT model) have different behaviors! Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades Slanina model Non-conservative models have been considered by F. Slanina [F. Slanina (2004)] p1 = λ, q1 = 1 − λ + p2 = 1 − λ + , q2 = λ. (3) is a fixed positive constant, so that the total money put into the trade increases, and v ∗ + w ∗ = (1 + )(v + w ). This type of trade intends to introduce (artificially) the effects of a strong economy, which is such that the total wealth is increasing in time. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades Slanina model Non-conservative models have been considered by F. Slanina [F. Slanina (2004)] p1 = λ, q1 = 1 − λ + p2 = 1 − λ + , q2 = λ. (3) is a fixed positive constant, so that the total money put into the trade increases, and v ∗ + w ∗ = (1 + )(v + w ). This type of trade intends to introduce (artificially) the effects of a strong economy, which is such that the total wealth is increasing in time. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades Slanina model Non-conservative models have been considered by F. Slanina [F. Slanina (2004)] p1 = λ, q1 = 1 − λ + p2 = 1 − λ + , q2 = λ. (3) is a fixed positive constant, so that the total money put into the trade increases, and v ∗ + w ∗ = (1 + )(v + w ). This type of trade intends to introduce (artificially) the effects of a strong economy, which is such that the total wealth is increasing in time. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades A remark on non conservative models A non conservative trade can be obtained in a more natural way simply allowing the random variables in CPT-trade to assume values on the whole space, and at the same time discarding the trades for which the post-trade wealths are non positive. Same property for the original transfer model proposed by A. Drǎgulesku and V. Yakovenko [A.Drǎgulescu, V.M.Yakovenko (2000-2001)], where ∆(v , w ) is decided by the following trading rule ∆(v , w ) = (v + w ). 2 is a random number, 0 ≤ ≤ 1. If the payer can not afford the money to be exchanged, the trade does not take place. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades A remark on non conservative models A non conservative trade can be obtained in a more natural way simply allowing the random variables in CPT-trade to assume values on the whole space, and at the same time discarding the trades for which the post-trade wealths are non positive. Same property for the original transfer model proposed by A. Drǎgulesku and V. Yakovenko [A.Drǎgulescu, V.M.Yakovenko (2000-2001)], where ∆(v , w ) is decided by the following trading rule ∆(v , w ) = (v + w ). 2 is a random number, 0 ≤ ≤ 1. If the payer can not afford the money to be exchanged, the trade does not take place. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades A remark on non conservative models A non conservative trade can be obtained in a more natural way simply allowing the random variables in CPT-trade to assume values on the whole space, and at the same time discarding the trades for which the post-trade wealths are non positive. Same property for the original transfer model proposed by A. Drǎgulesku and V. Yakovenko [A.Drǎgulescu, V.M.Yakovenko (2000-2001)], where ∆(v , w ) is decided by the following trading rule ∆(v , w ) = (v + w ). 2 is a random number, 0 ≤ ≤ 1. If the payer can not afford the money to be exchanged, the trade does not take place. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples 1 Formation of Pareto tails Introduction Other systems with overpopulated tails Market and trades 2 Kinetic models The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples 3 Conclusions Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples The Boltzmann equation f (v , t) denotes the distribution of agents with wealth v ∈ IR + at time t ≥ 0. A Boltzmann-like equation for f (v , t) can be derived by standard methods of kinetic theory. A useful way of writing this equation is to use the so-called weak form Z Z d Q(f , f )(v )φ(v ) dv , f (v )φ(v ) dv = dt IR + IR + the right-hand side 1 2 Z Z ∗ ∗ (φ(v ) + φ(w ) − φ(v ) − φ(w ))f (v )f (w )dv dw IR + IR + Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy . Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples The Boltzmann equation f (v , t) denotes the distribution of agents with wealth v ∈ IR + at time t ≥ 0. A Boltzmann-like equation for f (v , t) can be derived by standard methods of kinetic theory. A useful way of writing this equation is to use the so-called weak form Z Z d Q(f , f )(v )φ(v ) dv , f (v )φ(v ) dv = dt IR + IR + the right-hand side 1 2 Z Z ∗ ∗ (φ(v ) + φ(w ) − φ(v ) − φ(w ))f (v )f (w )dv dw IR + IR + Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy . Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples The Boltzmann equation f (v , t) denotes the distribution of agents with wealth v ∈ IR + at time t ≥ 0. A Boltzmann-like equation for f (v , t) can be derived by standard methods of kinetic theory. A useful way of writing this equation is to use the so-called weak form Z Z d Q(f , f )(v )φ(v ) dv , f (v )φ(v ) dv = dt IR + IR + the right-hand side 1 2 Z Z ∗ ∗ (φ(v ) + φ(w ) − φ(v ) − φ(w ))f (v )f (w )dv dw IR + IR + Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy . Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples The Boltzmann equation II The kinetic equation is the analogous of the Boltzmann equation for Maxwell molecules, where the collision frequency is assumed to be constant. Higher order R nmoments can be evaluated recursively, since the integrals v f (v , t) dv obey a closed hierarchy of equations. Fix the initial density to satisfy Z Z vf0 (v ) dv = M. f0 (v ) dv = 1 ; IR + IR + Conditions are propagated in time. For all t > 0 Z Z f (v , t) dv = 1 ; vf (v , t) dv = M IR + IR + Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples The Boltzmann equation II The kinetic equation is the analogous of the Boltzmann equation for Maxwell molecules, where the collision frequency is assumed to be constant. Higher order R nmoments can be evaluated recursively, since the integrals v f (v , t) dv obey a closed hierarchy of equations. Fix the initial density to satisfy Z Z vf0 (v ) dv = M. f0 (v ) dv = 1 ; IR + IR + Conditions are propagated in time. For all t > 0 Z Z f (v , t) dv = 1 ; vf (v , t) dv = M IR + IR + Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples The Boltzmann equation II The kinetic equation is the analogous of the Boltzmann equation for Maxwell molecules, where the collision frequency is assumed to be constant. Higher order R nmoments can be evaluated recursively, since the integrals v f (v , t) dv obey a closed hierarchy of equations. Fix the initial density to satisfy Z Z vf0 (v ) dv = M. f0 (v ) dv = 1 ; IR + IR + Conditions are propagated in time. For all t > 0 Z Z f (v , t) dv = 1 ; vf (v , t) dv = M IR + IR + Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples The Boltzmann equation II The kinetic equation is the analogous of the Boltzmann equation for Maxwell molecules, where the collision frequency is assumed to be constant. Higher order R nmoments can be evaluated recursively, since the integrals v f (v , t) dv obey a closed hierarchy of equations. Fix the initial density to satisfy Z Z vf0 (v ) dv = M. f0 (v ) dv = 1 ; IR + IR + Conditions are propagated in time. For all t > 0 Z Z f (v , t) dv = 1 ; vf (v , t) dv = M IR + IR + Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples The Boltzmann equation III The existence of a solution to Boltzmann equation can be seen easily using the same methods available for the elastic Kac model. A Boltzmann-like equation with constant kernel easily studied by means of Fourier transform [A.V. Bobylev (1988)]. The Fourier version ∂b f (ξ, t) b b =Q f ,b f (ξ, t), ∂t where E 1 Db b b Q f ,b f (ξ) = f (p1 ξ)b f (q1 ξ) + b f (p2 ξ)b f (q2 ξ) − b f (ξ). 2 Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples The Boltzmann equation III The existence of a solution to Boltzmann equation can be seen easily using the same methods available for the elastic Kac model. A Boltzmann-like equation with constant kernel easily studied by means of Fourier transform [A.V. Bobylev (1988)]. The Fourier version ∂b f (ξ, t) b b =Q f ,b f (ξ, t), ∂t where E 1 Db b b Q f ,b f (ξ) = f (p1 ξ)b f (q1 ξ) + b f (p2 ξ)b f (q2 ξ) − b f (ξ). 2 Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples The Boltzmann equation III The existence of a solution to Boltzmann equation can be seen easily using the same methods available for the elastic Kac model. A Boltzmann-like equation with constant kernel easily studied by means of Fourier transform [A.V. Bobylev (1988)]. The Fourier version ∂b f (ξ, t) b b =Q f ,b f (ξ, t), ∂t where E 1 Db b b Q f ,b f (ξ) = f (p1 ξ)b f (q1 ξ) + b f (p2 ξ)b f (q2 ξ) − b f (ξ). 2 Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples The Boltzmann equation IV Introduce a metric ds (f , g ) = sup ξ∈IR |b f (ξ) − gb(ξ)| |ξ|s s = m + α, m integer and 0 ≤ α < 1. Theorem Let f1 (t) and f2 (t) be two solutions of the Boltzmann equation, corresponding to initial values with the same mean. Assume that ds (f1,0 , f2,0 ) is bounded for some positive constant s. Then, for all times t ≥ 0, ! ) ( 2 1X s ds (f1 (t), f2 (t)) ≤ e hpi + qis i − 1 t ds (f1,0 , f2,0 ). 2 i=1 Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples The Boltzmann equation IV Introduce a metric ds (f , g ) = sup ξ∈IR |b f (ξ) − gb(ξ)| |ξ|s s = m + α, m integer and 0 ≤ α < 1. Theorem Let f1 (t) and f2 (t) be two solutions of the Boltzmann equation, corresponding to initial values with the same mean. Assume that ds (f1,0 , f2,0 ) is bounded for some positive constant s. Then, for all times t ≥ 0, ! ) ( 2 1X s ds (f1 (t), f2 (t)) ≤ e hpi + qis i − 1 t ds (f1,0 , f2,0 ). 2 i=1 Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples The Boltzmann equation V In particular there exists a unique weak solution f (t) of the Boltzmann equation. Corollary Let f1 (t) and f2 (t) be two solutions of the Boltzmann equation, corresponding to initial values with the same mean. Assume that ds (f1,0 , f2,0 ) is bounded for some positive constant s. In case ! 2 1X s hpi + qis i − 1 < 0 2 i=1 the distance ds of f1 and f2 decays exponentially in time. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples The Boltzmann equation V In particular there exists a unique weak solution f (t) of the Boltzmann equation. Corollary Let f1 (t) and f2 (t) be two solutions of the Boltzmann equation, corresponding to initial values with the same mean. Assume that ds (f1,0 , f2,0 ) is bounded for some positive constant s. In case ! 2 1X s hpi + qis i − 1 < 0 2 i=1 the distance ds of f1 and f2 decays exponentially in time. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples A noticeable quantity The large-time behavior of the solution to the kinetic equation depends of the quantity 2 S(s) = 1X s hpi + qis i − 1. 2 i=1 The sign of this quantity, in fact, is related both to the number of moments of the solution which remain uniformly bounded in time, and to the possibility to conclude the existence and uniqueness of a steady state. Let s > 1 be such that Z Ms = v s f0 (v ) dv < ∞, IR + and assume further that S(s) is finite, but is not zero. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples A noticeable quantity The large-time behavior of the solution to the kinetic equation depends of the quantity 2 S(s) = 1X s hpi + qis i − 1. 2 i=1 The sign of this quantity, in fact, is related both to the number of moments of the solution which remain uniformly bounded in time, and to the possibility to conclude the existence and uniqueness of a steady state. Let s > 1 be such that Z Ms = v s f0 (v ) dv < ∞, IR + and assume further that S(s) is finite, but is not zero. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples A noticeable quantity The large-time behavior of the solution to the kinetic equation depends of the quantity 2 S(s) = 1X s hpi + qis i − 1. 2 i=1 The sign of this quantity, in fact, is related both to the number of moments of the solution which remain uniformly bounded in time, and to the possibility to conclude the existence and uniqueness of a steady state. Let s > 1 be such that Z Ms = v s f0 (v ) dv < ∞, IR + and assume further that S(s) is finite, but is not zero. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples A noticeable quantity II Define 1 K(s) := hp1s−1 q1 + p2s−1 q2 + p1 q1s−1 + p2 q2s−1 i 2 1 ≤ hp1s + p2s + q1s + q2s i 2 ≤ (S(s) + 1) . If S(s) is a finite number, then so is K(s). The main result on S(s) gives its relationship with moments. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples A noticeable quantity II Define 1 K(s) := hp1s−1 q1 + p2s−1 q2 + p1 q1s−1 + p2 q2s−1 i 2 1 ≤ hp1s + p2s + q1s + q2s i 2 ≤ (S(s) + 1) . If S(s) is a finite number, then so is K(s). The main result on S(s) gives its relationship with moments. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples A noticeable quantity II Define 1 K(s) := hp1s−1 q1 + p2s−1 q2 + p1 q1s−1 + p2 q2s−1 i 2 1 ≤ hp1s + p2s + q1s + q2s i 2 ≤ (S(s) + 1) . If S(s) is a finite number, then so is K(s). The main result on S(s) gives its relationship with moments. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples Main result on moments Theorem The weak solution to the Boltzmann equation satisfies the following estimates: 1 If S(s) > 0, then, as t → ∞, R s s θs K(s) Θs K(s) R+ v f (v , t) dv 1/s s ·M ≤ ·M Ms + ≤ Ms + S(s) e{t · S(s)} S(s) 2 If S(s) < 0, then the s-th moment is bounded for all times. Moreover, as t → ∞, Z θs K(s) Θs K(s) s s s ·M ≤ v f (v , t) dv ≤ · Ms. |S(s)| |S(s)| R+ Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples Properties of steady states Theorem Suppose there exists s such that S(s) < 0, and let f∞ (v ) be the unique stationary solution to the Boltzmann equation. Let f (v , t) be the weak solution. Then, if the initial density f0 satisfies Z v σ f0 (v ) dv < ∞, IR + where σ = max{1, s}, f (v , t) converges exponentially fast in Fourier metric towards f∞ (v ), and the following bound holds ds (f (t), f∞ ) ≤ ds (f0 , f∞ )e {−|S(s)|t} . Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy (4) Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples Consequences Consider a conservative trade v ∗ = p1 v + q1 w ; w ∗ = p2 v + q2 w . Introduce the quantity 2 1X s S(s) = hpi + qis i − 1. 2 i=1 The large-time behavior of the solution to the kinetic equation depends of the knowledge of the sign of the function S(s). Both the existence and uniqueness of a solution and the existence of a steady distribution depend on the microscopic details of the binary interaction. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples Consequences Consider a conservative trade v ∗ = p1 v + q1 w ; w ∗ = p2 v + q2 w . Introduce the quantity 2 1X s S(s) = hpi + qis i − 1. 2 i=1 The large-time behavior of the solution to the kinetic equation depends of the knowledge of the sign of the function S(s). Both the existence and uniqueness of a solution and the existence of a steady distribution depend on the microscopic details of the binary interaction. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples Consequences Consider a conservative trade v ∗ = p1 v + q1 w ; w ∗ = p2 v + q2 w . Introduce the quantity 2 1X s S(s) = hpi + qis i − 1. 2 i=1 The large-time behavior of the solution to the kinetic equation depends of the knowledge of the sign of the function S(s). Both the existence and uniqueness of a solution and the existence of a steady distribution depend on the microscopic details of the binary interaction. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples Consequences Consider a conservative trade v ∗ = p1 v + q1 w ; w ∗ = p2 v + q2 w . Introduce the quantity 2 1X s S(s) = hpi + qis i − 1. 2 i=1 The large-time behavior of the solution to the kinetic equation depends of the knowledge of the sign of the function S(s). Both the existence and uniqueness of a solution and the existence of a steady distribution depend on the microscopic details of the binary interaction. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples The sign of S(s) Differentiating twice with respect to s 2 1X s 2 d 2 S(s) = hpi ln pi + qis ln2 qi i > 0. 2 ds 2 i=1 S(s) is convex on IR + . S(0) = 1, and S(1) = 0 Only three possible scenarios for the qualitative behavior of S. Characterized by the sign of S0 (1). S0 (1) = 0 by convexity implies S(s) ≥ 0 for all s > 0. In this case, it does not exist any s̄ ∈ IR + such that S(s̄) < 0, and all the conclusions fail. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples The sign of S(s) Differentiating twice with respect to s 2 1X s 2 d 2 S(s) = hpi ln pi + qis ln2 qi i > 0. 2 ds 2 i=1 S(s) is convex on IR + . S(0) = 1, and S(1) = 0 Only three possible scenarios for the qualitative behavior of S. Characterized by the sign of S0 (1). S0 (1) = 0 by convexity implies S(s) ≥ 0 for all s > 0. In this case, it does not exist any s̄ ∈ IR + such that S(s̄) < 0, and all the conclusions fail. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples The sign of S(s) Differentiating twice with respect to s 2 1X s 2 d 2 S(s) = hpi ln pi + qis ln2 qi i > 0. 2 ds 2 i=1 S(s) is convex on IR + . S(0) = 1, and S(1) = 0 Only three possible scenarios for the qualitative behavior of S. Characterized by the sign of S0 (1). S0 (1) = 0 by convexity implies S(s) ≥ 0 for all s > 0. In this case, it does not exist any s̄ ∈ IR + such that S(s̄) < 0, and all the conclusions fail. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples The sign of S(s) Differentiating twice with respect to s 2 1X s 2 d 2 S(s) = hpi ln pi + qis ln2 qi i > 0. 2 ds 2 i=1 S(s) is convex on IR + . S(0) = 1, and S(1) = 0 Only three possible scenarios for the qualitative behavior of S. Characterized by the sign of S0 (1). S0 (1) = 0 by convexity implies S(s) ≥ 0 for all s > 0. In this case, it does not exist any s̄ ∈ IR + such that S(s̄) < 0, and all the conclusions fail. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples The sign of S(s) II Suppose now S0 (1) > 0. In this case, since S(0) = 1, while S(1) = 0, the convex function S(s) has a minimum in the interval 0 < s < 1. If the minimum is attained at the point s̄, S(s) < 0 at least in the interval s̄ < s < 1, and at the same time S(s) > 0 for s > 1. Theorems imply that the kinetic equation has a unique steady state that possesses moments bounded up to the order one, while all the moments of order bigger than one are infinite. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples The sign of S(s) II Suppose now S0 (1) > 0. In this case, since S(0) = 1, while S(1) = 0, the convex function S(s) has a minimum in the interval 0 < s < 1. If the minimum is attained at the point s̄, S(s) < 0 at least in the interval s̄ < s < 1, and at the same time S(s) > 0 for s > 1. Theorems imply that the kinetic equation has a unique steady state that possesses moments bounded up to the order one, while all the moments of order bigger than one are infinite. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples The sign of S(s) II Suppose now S0 (1) > 0. In this case, since S(0) = 1, while S(1) = 0, the convex function S(s) has a minimum in the interval 0 < s < 1. If the minimum is attained at the point s̄, S(s) < 0 at least in the interval s̄ < s < 1, and at the same time S(s) > 0 for s > 1. Theorems imply that the kinetic equation has a unique steady state that possesses moments bounded up to the order one, while all the moments of order bigger than one are infinite. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples The sign of S(s) II Suppose now S0 (1) > 0. In this case, since S(0) = 1, while S(1) = 0, the convex function S(s) has a minimum in the interval 0 < s < 1. If the minimum is attained at the point s̄, S(s) < 0 at least in the interval s̄ < s < 1, and at the same time S(s) > 0 for s > 1. Theorems imply that the kinetic equation has a unique steady state that possesses moments bounded up to the order one, while all the moments of order bigger than one are infinite. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples The sign of S(s) III Suppose S0 (1) < 0. The presence of tails in the steady distribution depend whether lim S(s)< (>)0, s→∞ In the < case, S(s) < 0 for s > 1. The kinetic equation has a unique steady state that possesses all moments bounded. In the > case, since S(1) = 0, the convex function S(s) has a minimum attained at some point s̃ > 1, and at the same time there exists s̄ > s̃ in which S(s̄) = 0. The kinetic equation (4) has a unique steady state that possesses moments bounded only up to the order s̄ (excluded) Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples The sign of S(s) III Suppose S0 (1) < 0. The presence of tails in the steady distribution depend whether lim S(s)< (>)0, s→∞ In the < case, S(s) < 0 for s > 1. The kinetic equation has a unique steady state that possesses all moments bounded. In the > case, since S(1) = 0, the convex function S(s) has a minimum attained at some point s̃ > 1, and at the same time there exists s̄ > s̃ in which S(s̄) = 0. The kinetic equation (4) has a unique steady state that possesses moments bounded only up to the order s̄ (excluded) Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples The sign of S(s) III Suppose S0 (1) < 0. The presence of tails in the steady distribution depend whether lim S(s)< (>)0, s→∞ In the < case, S(s) < 0 for s > 1. The kinetic equation has a unique steady state that possesses all moments bounded. In the > case, since S(1) = 0, the convex function S(s) has a minimum attained at some point s̃ > 1, and at the same time there exists s̄ > s̃ in which S(s̄) = 0. The kinetic equation (4) has a unique steady state that possesses moments bounded only up to the order s̄ (excluded) Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples The sign of S(s) III Suppose S0 (1) < 0. The presence of tails in the steady distribution depend whether lim S(s)< (>)0, s→∞ In the < case, S(s) < 0 for s > 1. The kinetic equation has a unique steady state that possesses all moments bounded. In the > case, since S(1) = 0, the convex function S(s) has a minimum attained at some point s̃ > 1, and at the same time there exists s̄ > s̃ in which S(s̄) = 0. The kinetic equation (4) has a unique steady state that possesses moments bounded only up to the order s̄ (excluded) Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples The sign of S(s) III Suppose S0 (1) < 0. The presence of tails in the steady distribution depend whether lim S(s)< (>)0, s→∞ In the < case, S(s) < 0 for s > 1. The kinetic equation has a unique steady state that possesses all moments bounded. In the > case, since S(1) = 0, the convex function S(s) has a minimum attained at some point s̃ > 1, and at the same time there exists s̄ > s̃ in which S(s̄) = 0. The kinetic equation (4) has a unique steady state that possesses moments bounded only up to the order s̄ (excluded) Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples Pointwise conservative trades Consider models where 0 ≤ p1 , p2 , q1 , q2 ≤ 1 with probability one. hpi i = 6 0 hqi i = 6 0 for i = 1 or i = 2.. Each pointwise conservative model fits into this class. S(s) is negative for all s > 1, which guarantees boundedness of all moments in time. Among others, Chakraborty - Chakrabarthi model belongs to this class. The solution to Chakraborty - Chakrabarthi model does not develop tails. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples Pointwise conservative trades Consider models where 0 ≤ p1 , p2 , q1 , q2 ≤ 1 with probability one. hpi i = 6 0 hqi i = 6 0 for i = 1 or i = 2.. Each pointwise conservative model fits into this class. S(s) is negative for all s > 1, which guarantees boundedness of all moments in time. Among others, Chakraborty - Chakrabarthi model belongs to this class. The solution to Chakraborty - Chakrabarthi model does not develop tails. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples Pointwise conservative trades Consider models where 0 ≤ p1 , p2 , q1 , q2 ≤ 1 with probability one. hpi i = 6 0 hqi i = 6 0 for i = 1 or i = 2.. Each pointwise conservative model fits into this class. S(s) is negative for all s > 1, which guarantees boundedness of all moments in time. Among others, Chakraborty - Chakrabarthi model belongs to this class. The solution to Chakraborty - Chakrabarthi model does not develop tails. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples Pointwise conservative trades Consider models where 0 ≤ p1 , p2 , q1 , q2 ≤ 1 with probability one. hpi i = 6 0 hqi i = 6 0 for i = 1 or i = 2.. Each pointwise conservative model fits into this class. S(s) is negative for all s > 1, which guarantees boundedness of all moments in time. Among others, Chakraborty - Chakrabarthi model belongs to this class. The solution to Chakraborty - Chakrabarthi model does not develop tails. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples Pointwise conservative trades Consider models where 0 ≤ p1 , p2 , q1 , q2 ≤ 1 with probability one. hpi i = 6 0 hqi i = 6 0 for i = 1 or i = 2.. Each pointwise conservative model fits into this class. S(s) is negative for all s > 1, which guarantees boundedness of all moments in time. Among others, Chakraborty - Chakrabarthi model belongs to this class. The solution to Chakraborty - Chakrabarthi model does not develop tails. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples Conservative in the mean trades Consider models which are conservative in the mean only . In [S. Cordier, L. Pareschi, G. Toscani (2005)] the trade is of this type v ∗ = λv + (1 − λ)w + ηv w ∗ = (1 − λ)v + λw + η̃w . Assume that the probability variables η and η̃ are independent and identically distributed Under these assumptions, S(s) = hp1s + p2s i − 1 = (1 − λ)s − 1 + Z +∞ (λ + ω)s dρ(s), −λ where ρ(s) is the probability density of η and η̃ on [−λ, +∞). Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples Conservative in the mean trades Consider models which are conservative in the mean only . In [S. Cordier, L. Pareschi, G. Toscani (2005)] the trade is of this type v ∗ = λv + (1 − λ)w + ηv w ∗ = (1 − λ)v + λw + η̃w . Assume that the probability variables η and η̃ are independent and identically distributed Under these assumptions, S(s) = hp1s + p2s i − 1 = (1 − λ)s − 1 + Z +∞ (λ + ω)s dρ(s), −λ where ρ(s) is the probability density of η and η̃ on [−λ, +∞). Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples Conservative in the mean trades Consider models which are conservative in the mean only . In [S. Cordier, L. Pareschi, G. Toscani (2005)] the trade is of this type v ∗ = λv + (1 − λ)w + ηv w ∗ = (1 − λ)v + λw + η̃w . Assume that the probability variables η and η̃ are independent and identically distributed Under these assumptions, S(s) = hp1s + p2s i − 1 = (1 − λ)s − 1 + Z +∞ (λ + ω)s dρ(s), −λ where ρ(s) is the probability density of η and η̃ on [−λ, +∞). Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples Conservative in the mean trades Consider models which are conservative in the mean only . In [S. Cordier, L. Pareschi, G. Toscani (2005)] the trade is of this type v ∗ = λv + (1 − λ)w + ηv w ∗ = (1 − λ)v + λw + η̃w . Assume that the probability variables η and η̃ are independent and identically distributed Under these assumptions, S(s) = hp1s + p2s i − 1 = (1 − λ)s − 1 + Z +∞ (λ + ω)s dρ(s), −λ where ρ(s) is the probability density of η and η̃ on [−λ, +∞). Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples Conservative in the mean trades II Assume η only takes values ±µ, with probability where 0 ≤ µ ≤ λ. 1 2 each, By varying the parameters λ and µ, one encounters the whole variety of possible behaviors of the moments of f∞ . If λ + µ ≤ 1, then the trade is pointwise conservative and all moments are finite. Assume λ + µ > 1. Evaluate 1 1 S(s) = (1 − λ)s − 1 + (λ − µ)s + (λ + µ)s . 2 2 Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples Conservative in the mean trades II Assume η only takes values ±µ, with probability where 0 ≤ µ ≤ λ. 1 2 each, By varying the parameters λ and µ, one encounters the whole variety of possible behaviors of the moments of f∞ . If λ + µ ≤ 1, then the trade is pointwise conservative and all moments are finite. Assume λ + µ > 1. Evaluate 1 1 S(s) = (1 − λ)s − 1 + (λ − µ)s + (λ + µ)s . 2 2 Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples Conservative in the mean trades II Assume η only takes values ±µ, with probability where 0 ≤ µ ≤ λ. 1 2 each, By varying the parameters λ and µ, one encounters the whole variety of possible behaviors of the moments of f∞ . If λ + µ ≤ 1, then the trade is pointwise conservative and all moments are finite. Assume λ + µ > 1. Evaluate 1 1 S(s) = (1 − λ)s − 1 + (λ − µ)s + (λ + µ)s . 2 2 Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples Conservative in the mean trades II Assume η only takes values ±µ, with probability where 0 ≤ µ ≤ λ. 1 2 each, By varying the parameters λ and µ, one encounters the whole variety of possible behaviors of the moments of f∞ . If λ + µ ≤ 1, then the trade is pointwise conservative and all moments are finite. Assume λ + µ > 1. Evaluate 1 1 S(s) = (1 − λ)s − 1 + (λ − µ)s + (λ + µ)s . 2 2 Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples Tails in CPT model In region II, all moments remain bounded for all times, while in regions III and IV, sufficiently high or all moments above one, respectively, diverge. Notice that the parameter region I is excluded by the condition µ ≤ λ. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples A note on caution Easy to identify models for which all moments remain bounded for all times. In pointwise conservative trades the appearance of Pareto tails is excluded. Hard to decide from the output of numerical experiments on the nature of the tail – exponential or Pareto. If S is negative but very close to zero, the lower bounds for the moments become huge. The CC-model with constant exchange rate = very low or very high saving rates λ. S(s) = 1+λ 2 s Giuseppe Toscani + 1−λ 2 s − 1. Kinetic models of economy 1 2 and either Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples A note on caution Easy to identify models for which all moments remain bounded for all times. In pointwise conservative trades the appearance of Pareto tails is excluded. Hard to decide from the output of numerical experiments on the nature of the tail – exponential or Pareto. If S is negative but very close to zero, the lower bounds for the moments become huge. The CC-model with constant exchange rate = very low or very high saving rates λ. S(s) = 1+λ 2 s Giuseppe Toscani + 1−λ 2 s − 1. Kinetic models of economy 1 2 and either Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples A note on caution Easy to identify models for which all moments remain bounded for all times. In pointwise conservative trades the appearance of Pareto tails is excluded. Hard to decide from the output of numerical experiments on the nature of the tail – exponential or Pareto. If S is negative but very close to zero, the lower bounds for the moments become huge. The CC-model with constant exchange rate = very low or very high saving rates λ. S(s) = 1+λ 2 s Giuseppe Toscani + 1−λ 2 s − 1. Kinetic models of economy 1 2 and either Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples A note on caution Easy to identify models for which all moments remain bounded for all times. In pointwise conservative trades the appearance of Pareto tails is excluded. Hard to decide from the output of numerical experiments on the nature of the tail – exponential or Pareto. If S is negative but very close to zero, the lower bounds for the moments become huge. The CC-model with constant exchange rate = very low or very high saving rates λ. S(s) = 1+λ 2 s Giuseppe Toscani + 1−λ 2 s − 1. Kinetic models of economy 1 2 and either Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples A note on caution II For each fixed s > 2, this expression converges to zero for either λ → 0 (no saving) or λ → 1 (no trading). The time-uniform lower bound on the sth moment blows up like the inverse of S(s). Numerically one could mistake the dramatic temporal growth of moments for s > 2 (and most probably also for all s > 1) as convergence to a steady state f∞ with unbounded moments corresponding to a Pareto tail. Since the value of the first moment is fixed by the total wealth, but all the higher moments seemingly diverge, one would most likely “observe” a fat tail distribution with critical Pareto index ν = 1. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples A note on caution II For each fixed s > 2, this expression converges to zero for either λ → 0 (no saving) or λ → 1 (no trading). The time-uniform lower bound on the sth moment blows up like the inverse of S(s). Numerically one could mistake the dramatic temporal growth of moments for s > 2 (and most probably also for all s > 1) as convergence to a steady state f∞ with unbounded moments corresponding to a Pareto tail. Since the value of the first moment is fixed by the total wealth, but all the higher moments seemingly diverge, one would most likely “observe” a fat tail distribution with critical Pareto index ν = 1. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples A note on caution II For each fixed s > 2, this expression converges to zero for either λ → 0 (no saving) or λ → 1 (no trading). The time-uniform lower bound on the sth moment blows up like the inverse of S(s). Numerically one could mistake the dramatic temporal growth of moments for s > 2 (and most probably also for all s > 1) as convergence to a steady state f∞ with unbounded moments corresponding to a Pareto tail. Since the value of the first moment is fixed by the total wealth, but all the higher moments seemingly diverge, one would most likely “observe” a fat tail distribution with critical Pareto index ν = 1. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions The Boltzmann equation Formation of tails Examples A note on caution II For each fixed s > 2, this expression converges to zero for either λ → 0 (no saving) or λ → 1 (no trading). The time-uniform lower bound on the sth moment blows up like the inverse of S(s). Numerically one could mistake the dramatic temporal growth of moments for s > 2 (and most probably also for all s > 1) as convergence to a steady state f∞ with unbounded moments corresponding to a Pareto tail. Since the value of the first moment is fixed by the total wealth, but all the higher moments seemingly diverge, one would most likely “observe” a fat tail distribution with critical Pareto index ν = 1. Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Conclusions We discussed the large–time behavior of various kinetic models of conservative economies. It has been shown that the tails of the (unique) stationary solution depend on the details of the microscopic interaction. The main difference in the large-time evolution of the solution relies is related to the fact that the trade is or not pointwise conservative. Pointwise conservative trades produce a steady state which possesses all moments bounded. Pareto tails can appear only on conservative in the mean trades Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Conclusions We discussed the large–time behavior of various kinetic models of conservative economies. It has been shown that the tails of the (unique) stationary solution depend on the details of the microscopic interaction. The main difference in the large-time evolution of the solution relies is related to the fact that the trade is or not pointwise conservative. Pointwise conservative trades produce a steady state which possesses all moments bounded. Pareto tails can appear only on conservative in the mean trades Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Conclusions We discussed the large–time behavior of various kinetic models of conservative economies. It has been shown that the tails of the (unique) stationary solution depend on the details of the microscopic interaction. The main difference in the large-time evolution of the solution relies is related to the fact that the trade is or not pointwise conservative. Pointwise conservative trades produce a steady state which possesses all moments bounded. Pareto tails can appear only on conservative in the mean trades Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Conclusions We discussed the large–time behavior of various kinetic models of conservative economies. It has been shown that the tails of the (unique) stationary solution depend on the details of the microscopic interaction. The main difference in the large-time evolution of the solution relies is related to the fact that the trade is or not pointwise conservative. Pointwise conservative trades produce a steady state which possesses all moments bounded. Pareto tails can appear only on conservative in the mean trades Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Conclusions We discussed the large–time behavior of various kinetic models of conservative economies. It has been shown that the tails of the (unique) stationary solution depend on the details of the microscopic interaction. The main difference in the large-time evolution of the solution relies is related to the fact that the trade is or not pointwise conservative. Pointwise conservative trades produce a steady state which possesses all moments bounded. Pareto tails can appear only on conservative in the mean trades Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Conclusions Our analysis has been largely based on the possibility to apply Fourier transform techniques. This analysis is reminiscent of previous results for the Boltzmann equation for Maxwell molecules L. Pareschi, G. Toscani, Self-similarity and power-like tails in nonconservative kinetic models, J. Statist. Phys.124 747-779 (2006) D. Matthes, G. Toscani, On steady distributions of kinetic models of conservative economies, (preprint) (2006) http://www-dimat.unipv.it/toscani/ J.A. Carrillo, S. Cordier, G. Toscani, Steady distributions of conservative-in-mean Maxwell-type models of the Boltzmann equation (in preparation) (2007) Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Conclusions Our analysis has been largely based on the possibility to apply Fourier transform techniques. This analysis is reminiscent of previous results for the Boltzmann equation for Maxwell molecules L. Pareschi, G. Toscani, Self-similarity and power-like tails in nonconservative kinetic models, J. Statist. Phys.124 747-779 (2006) D. Matthes, G. Toscani, On steady distributions of kinetic models of conservative economies, (preprint) (2006) http://www-dimat.unipv.it/toscani/ J.A. Carrillo, S. Cordier, G. Toscani, Steady distributions of conservative-in-mean Maxwell-type models of the Boltzmann equation (in preparation) (2007) Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Conclusions Our analysis has been largely based on the possibility to apply Fourier transform techniques. This analysis is reminiscent of previous results for the Boltzmann equation for Maxwell molecules L. Pareschi, G. Toscani, Self-similarity and power-like tails in nonconservative kinetic models, J. Statist. Phys.124 747-779 (2006) D. Matthes, G. Toscani, On steady distributions of kinetic models of conservative economies, (preprint) (2006) http://www-dimat.unipv.it/toscani/ J.A. Carrillo, S. Cordier, G. Toscani, Steady distributions of conservative-in-mean Maxwell-type models of the Boltzmann equation (in preparation) (2007) Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Conclusions Our analysis has been largely based on the possibility to apply Fourier transform techniques. This analysis is reminiscent of previous results for the Boltzmann equation for Maxwell molecules L. Pareschi, G. Toscani, Self-similarity and power-like tails in nonconservative kinetic models, J. Statist. Phys.124 747-779 (2006) D. Matthes, G. Toscani, On steady distributions of kinetic models of conservative economies, (preprint) (2006) http://www-dimat.unipv.it/toscani/ J.A. Carrillo, S. Cordier, G. Toscani, Steady distributions of conservative-in-mean Maxwell-type models of the Boltzmann equation (in preparation) (2007) Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions Conclusions Our analysis has been largely based on the possibility to apply Fourier transform techniques. This analysis is reminiscent of previous results for the Boltzmann equation for Maxwell molecules L. Pareschi, G. Toscani, Self-similarity and power-like tails in nonconservative kinetic models, J. Statist. Phys.124 747-779 (2006) D. Matthes, G. Toscani, On steady distributions of kinetic models of conservative economies, (preprint) (2006) http://www-dimat.unipv.it/toscani/ J.A. Carrillo, S. Cordier, G. Toscani, Steady distributions of conservative-in-mean Maxwell-type models of the Boltzmann equation (in preparation) (2007) Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy Outlines Formation of Pareto tails Kinetic models Conclusions References Baldassarri A., Marini Bettolo Marconi U., Puglisi A. : Kinetic models of inelastic gases. Mat. Mod. Meth. Appl. Sci. 12 965–983 (2002). Ben-Avraham D., Ben-Naim E., Lindenberg K., Rosas A.: Self-similarity in random collision processes, Phys. Rev. E, 68, R050103 (2003). Ben-Naim E., Krapivski P. : Multiscaling in inelastic collisions. Phys. Rev. E, 61, R5–R8 (2000). A.V. Bobylev, The theory of the spatially Uniform Boltzmann equation for Maxwell molecules Sov. Sci. Review C 7, 112-229 (1988). Bobylev A.V., Cercignani C.: Self-similar asymptotics for the Boltzmann equation with inelastic and elastic interactions. J. Statist. Phys. 110, 333-375 (2003). Bobylev, A. V.; Gamba, I. M.; Panferov, V. A. Moment inequalities and high-energy tails for Boltzmann equations with inelastic interactions. J. Statist. Phys. 116 (2004) Bouchaud J.P., Mézard M.: Wealth condensation in a simple model of economy, Physica A, 282, 536- (2000). J.A. Carrillo, J.L. Vázquez, Fine asymptotics for fast diffusion equations. Comm. Partial Differential Equations 28 (2003), 1023–1056. A. Chakraborti, B.K. Chakrabarti, Statistical mechanics of money: how saving propensity affects its distributions, Eur. Phys. J. B., 17, 167-170 (2000). A. Chatterjee, B.K. Chakrabarti, S.S. Manna, Pareto law in a kinetic model of market with random saving propensity. Physica A 335 155-163 (2004) S. Cordier, L. Pareschi, G. Toscani, On a kinetic model for a simple market economy. J. Stat. Phys. 120 253-277 (2005). T. Di Matteo, T. Aste, S.T. Hyde, in The physics of complex systems (New advances and perspectives) F, Mallamace & H.E. Stanley eds., IOS press, Amsterdam, 2004 A.Dragulescu, V.M.Yakovenko, Statistical mechanics of money, Eur. Phys. Jour. B, 17, 723–729 (2000). A.Dragulescu, V.M.Yakovenko, Exponential and power law probability distribution of wealth and income in the United kingdom and the United states , Physica A, 299, 213-221 (2001). H.P. McKean, The central limit theorem for Carleman’s equation, Israel J. Math., 21 (1975) 54-92. B.Mandelbrot, The Pareto-Lévy law and the distribution of income, International Economic Review ,1, 79-106 (1960). V.Pareto, Cours d’Economie Politique, Lausanne and Paris, (1897). F. Slanina, Inelastically scattering particles and wealth distribution in an open economy, Phys. Rev. E 69, 046102 (2004). Giuseppe Toscani Kinetic models of economy