Rational Speculators And Equity Volatility as a Measure of Ex Ante Risk Amir Kia Emory University, Department of Economics Atlanta, GA 30322-2240 U.S.A. E-mail: akia@emory.edu Tel.: (404) 727-7536 Fax: (404) 727-4639 March 2001 Rational Speculators And Equity Volatility as a Measure of Ex Ante Risk Abstract: A macro-determinant model of stock return volatility using monthly data on Canadian and U.S. markets is estimated. If volatility is a measure of risk, one should verify whether the estimated volatility is a measure of future (ex ante) risk or realized (ex post) risk. When speculators are rational the volatility created by their activities can be a measure for ex ante risk. It is found that the growth of commodity price, which was ignored in this literature, is also a factor in the equity return volatility. Furthermore, 71% of the volatility of Canadian stock returns is explained by the behavior of rational speculators. Key words: stock return, forward-looking agents, superexogeneity, ex post and ex ante risk JEL classification = G120, G140 and G190 Rational Speculators And Equity Volatility as a Measure of Ex Ante Risk 1. Introduction High volatility implies higher capital costs and may also increase the value of the “option to wait”, hence delaying investments. When making decisions, investors incorporate information pertaining to price movements and volatility in the asset they are trading. Since risk is directly related to volatility it is interesting to verify how much of the estimated risk reflects the behavior of rational speculators who use, e.g., observable fluctuations of macro-variables to forecast future volatility of dividend payments. If an essential part of return volatility is due to activities of rational (i.e., forward-looking) speculators then the estimated volatility can be a measure of future (ex ante) risk. Alternatively, if speculators are backward looking then clearly the volatility created by their activities can be a measure of the realized (ex post) risk. Unless we assume the volatility of the return remains the same in the next holding period we cannot use the estimated volatility as a measure of risk for the current holding of stocks or any other assets. Let us define rational speculators in equity markets as those investors whose investment activities are based on changes in the fundamental economic factors (e.g., macro-variables) that are used in the formation of their expectations on the future stream of dividend payments, and so, are forward looking. All other speculators in equity markets are then mostly noise traders. Thus the volatility generated by the rational (i.e., forward-looking) speculative activities is a measure of the future risk of holding equities (ex ante) and not realized risk (ex post). Realization of the ex ante risk is important to 2 both portfolio managers and policy makers. The investment decision of portfolio managers depends on the (ex ante) expected risk-adjusted return of different assets. If a major part of the volatility of equity return is due to rational speculative activities then monetary policies, e.g., aimed to keep the inflation rate within a target band, will also help to provide both stable and less volatile macroeconomic conditions as well as asset prices. Namely, these monetary policies, if successful, can also help to avoid, or at least to reduce, the historically relevant risk that a bubble, once out of its norm, can easily degenerate into a panic. However, if movements in the equity return can be explained mostly by waves of irrational optimism and pessimism, “fads”, noise trading or feedback trading then such monetary policies help to provide stable macroeconomic conditions, but not stable asset prices. In a world of efficient capital market and without regulatory distortion, and in the absence of excessive speculative activities, movements in equity prices simply reflect changes in underlying economic fundamentals. In such world equity prices would be of interest to central bankers to the extent that they provide useful information about the current and future states of the economy if the estimated volatility reflects the behavior of rational speculators. Consequently, central bankers would have no reason to concern themselves with equity price volatility per se if a dominant part of the observed volatility in equity return is due to rational speculative activities. However, as also mentioned by Bernanke and Gertler (1999), matters would change if (i) “nonfundamental” factors dominate asset market volatility and (ii) changes in asset prices unrelated to fundamental factors have potentially significant impacts on the rest of the economy. If these two conditions are satisfied, then equity price volatility becomes an important source of 3 economic instability of which policy makers should take account. In sum, it is very important to verify whether the dominant part of the estimated volatility reflects the behavior of rational speculators. Such information is useful to portfolio managers in their estimation of risk-adjusted expected return and the policy makers in the estimation of the future state of the economy. To the best of my knowledge no attention has been given so far to these important facts. For instance, Schwert (1989) and Culter, Poterba, and Summers (1989) find that unexpected volatility in current macroeconomic variables explains only about one-fifth of the variance in monthly stock returns. Fama (1990) and Schwert (1990) show real and financial variables explain about half of the variance in annual returns; Gallant, Rossi and Tauchen (1992) find a positive and non-linear relationship between volume and volatility of the S&P 500-stock index; Kearney (1998) finds 38% of the conditional volatility of Irish stock return can be explained by the conditional volatility of macro-variables. Kearney and Daly (1998) find 35% of the variation in the conditional volatility of Australian stock market is explained by the financial and business cycle variations. Kearney (2000) examines how volatility is transmitted to national stock markets from their international counterparts as well as from domestic business cycles variables for Britain, France, Germany, Japan and the U.S. He finds the national stock market indices are multivariate cointegrated with their domestic business cycle variables. None of these studies investigates if the dominant part of the observed volatility constitutes the activity of the forward-looking rational agents in the market, namely, if the equities volatility can be a measure for future (ex ante) risk rather than a realized (ex post) risk. 4 Furthermore, to the best of my knowledge, not much attention was given to resource-dependent internationally integrated stock markets volatility. For example, in none of the existing literature, the impact of the volatility of commodity prices is incorporated. Commodity price is an important determinant of the stock price in resource-dependent internationally integrated markets. The purpose of this paper is, taking into consideration the above facts, to extend the literature in the following way. Monthly data on Canadian and U.S. stock markets for the period 1975(Jan.)1999(Dec.) are used. A macro-determinant stock price model for a small and open-resource-oriented country is developed. The model is used to derive a conditional stock volatility model, capable to incorporate the volatility of macro-variables, including commodity price, which are used to forecast the volatility of future dividend payments. The model is estimated and the superexogeneity tests are used to examine whether the estimated volatility reflects the behavior of speculators who are forward looking and so their expectations are formed rationally, i.e., if the estimated volatility can be a measure of future (ex ante) risk or it is only a measure of realized (ex post) risk. It is found that the conditional volatility of growth of commodity price index, along with other conditional volatility of macro-determinants, is in fact an important component of the conditional volatility of stock return determination. Furthermore, it was found that 71% of the volatility of Canadian stock returns is explained by the behavior of forward-looking rational speculators which, consequently, can be used to estimate ex ante risk. Namely, noise traders’ participation in Canadian stock return volatility is only about one-fourth of the variation in monthly stock returns. 5 The following section deals with the development of the theoretical model as well as superexogeneity and invariance hypothesis for conditional volatility of stock returns. Section 3 describes the data and empirical methodology and results. Section 4 is devoted to marginal models as well as superexogeneity results. The final section provides some concluding remarks. 2. The theoretical model In an exchange-economy asset-pricing model, Lucas (1978) finds the equilibrium price of an asset is the expected, discounted, present value of its real dividend stream, conditional on current information. A close approximation of the model is Pt = Et [(1+rt)-1(Pt+1 + Dt+1)], (1) where Pt is the stock price at time t, Dt+1 is the dividend paid to the shareholders between t and t+1, 0<(1+rt)-1<1 is the discount factor and E denotes the mathematical expectation operator for information at time t. If the transversality condition, i.e., limn→∞ Et[(1+rt-n)-n (Pt+n)]=0, holds then the unique solution to Equation (1) is ∞ Pt = Et [ ∑ (1 + rt+i-1 ) -i (Dt+i) ] . i=1 (2) Future dividends as well as discount rates are not observable. Following Lucas (1978) and under rational expectations assumption, the market clearing price Pt is a fixed function of the state of the economy, yt, where yt is assumed to summarize all relevant information on the current and future physical state of the economy. If macroeconomic data provide all relevant information on the current and future physical state of the economy, we can assume that in a small, open and financially 6 integrated economy, the discounted expected value of future payments has the following function: ∞ Et [ ∑ (1 + rt+i-1 ) -i (Dt+i) ] = f(yt) = F(SPt, IPt, EXt, COMPt, PLt, Rt, PREMt, i=1 Rt-FRt, PLt/FPLt, IPt/FIPt, zt), (3) where SPt is the foreign country stock price, IPt is the level of total industrial production, EXt is the level of exchange rate (domestic currency value of a unit of foreign currency), COMPt is the commodity price index (commodities produced in the domestic country and sold abroad), PLt is the domestic price level, Rt is the domestic overnight interest rate, PREMt is a measure for the risk premium (corporate paper minus Treasury Bill rates), Rt-FRt is the domestic and foreign interest rates differential, PLt/FPLt is the ratio of domestic to foreign price levels, IPt/FIPt is the ratio of domestic to foreign levels of total industrial production, and zt includes past values of Pt and above-mentioned macroeconomic variables as well as current and past values of other valid conditioning variables.1 Substituting (3) in (2) yields Pt = F(SPt, IPt, EXt, COMPt, PLt, Rt, PREMt, Rt-FRt, PLt/FPLt, IPt/FIPt, zt).(4) Equation (4) is an extension of the literature in the sense that it includes the commodity price index, the domestic price level relative to the foreign price level as well as a measure for the risk premium, which reflects, among other things, attitudes of 1 Note that, as Koutoulas and Kryzanowski (1996) also mention, there is no generally accepted theory for linking stock returns to the economy. Consequently, general economic theory and intuition have been the main inputs in the selection of macro-variables. 7 investors toward risk. In a small, open and financially integrated economy one would expect stock markets to rally as stock markets in the rest of the world or its largest trading partner rallies. For example, Canadian equity prices may move with U.S. equity prices as economic news in the U.S. may also affect Canadian equity markets.2 Furthermore, market psychology and speculative activities could lead stock markets in Canada to move with the stock markets in the U.S. For example, a rally in the U.S. stock markets and so higher equity prices will increase expectations of a higher demand for Canadian exports through the wealth effect in the U.S. Expectations of higher demand for Canadian exports lead to expectations of higher corporate profits in Canada. This will increase demand for equity in Canada and result in higher equity prices. Consequently, one would expect theoretically the sign of SPt in Equation (4) to be positive. It should be noted that it is more appropriate for the foreign stock price to be adjusted for the exchange rate. However, to avoid the introduction of an extra stochastic variable in the system, I follow Kearney (1998) and Koutoulas and Kryzanowski (1996) and allow the exchange rate to appear as a separate variable in the equation.3 Moreover, in a small open economy with high capital mobility, cash flows, Dt+i, as mentioned and shown by Kearney (1998) and others (see reference list given in Kearney, 1998), are influenced by developments in the domestic macroeconomic variables like the total level of industrial production, the price level, the exchange rate and interest rates. For instance, a higher level of industrial production is associated with 2 Note that the U.S. is Canada’s major trading partner. For example, in 1998, about 82% of Canadian exports were sent to the U.S. while about 78% of Canadian imports originated from the U.S. 3 This argument is also applicable for variables Rt-FRt, PLt/FPLt and IPt/FIPt. 8 higher corporate profits and cash flows. Consequently, it is expected for the industrial production theoretically to have a positive relationship with the price of equity. Furthermore, a higher exchange rate, which is associated with a lower foreign currency price of the exports, results in an appreciation of the balance of trade, which leads to higher corporate profits and cash flows. Consequently, a higher exchange rate is expected to lead to a higher equity price. It should, of course, be mentioned that exchange rate appreciation could result in an improvement of the balance of trade if the MarshallLerner condition, a long-run condition, is satisfied. However, in the short term, investors associate the deterioration of the domestic currency with a higher likelihood that the central bank would raise the interest rate to defend the currency. Consequently, the short run impact of the exchange rate appreciation on the equity price may be negative. The weakness in the commodity price does hurt stock markets of a highly open economy like Canada.4 Such a weakness can reduce corporate profits and lower expectations of future cash flows. Consequently, one would expect a positive relationship between the commodity and the stock prices. To the best of my knowledge, no study so far incorporated the commodity price index in the determination of stock price or return. 4 Note that Canada’s reliance on resource-based exports has declined from 80% to 40% of total exports during the past quarter century, but its dependence remains high compared with most advanced countries. Furthermore, about one-fifth of the Toronto Stock Exchange 300 Composite Index is made up of commodity related companies and as much as 35% of Canada’s exports are raw materials. It should, of course, be mentioned that global commodity price weakness is offset by Canadian dollar weakness, but the offset is only partial. However, in this paper the impact of exchange rate on the commodity price is already incorporated, see the description of the commodity price in Table 1. 9 Moreover, while a higher price level increases expectations of a future hike in interest rates, it may also lead to higher offsetting cash flows. However, cash flows may not rise at the same rate as the inflation rate; see Mukherjee and Naka (1995) and references therein. Consequently, one would expect a negative relationship between the level of price and the stock price. Furthermore, if stocks hedge against inflation, at least in the long run, as it was shown by Ely and Robinson (1997), Kaul (1986) and Kia (1997a, 1997b), then a positive relationship between stock price and the level of domestic price can be expected. A higher domestic interest rate as well as the level of interest rate relative to foreign interest rate is expected to have a positive impact on the investors’ subjective discount rate. Furthermore, a higher interest rate is associated with expectations of lower corporate profits. Both a higher subjective discount rate and expectations of lower corporate profits result in a fall of the equity price. Furthermore, the more risk averse investors are the higher risk premium they will require and, therefore, the higher their subjective discount rate will be. Consequently, we would expect the domestic level of interest rate, and the domestic rate relative to foreign rate (interest rate differential) as well as risk premium to have negative relationships with the stock price. Cash flows are also influenced by the above macro-variables relative to their foreign counterparts. For example, a higher domestic price relative to its international level in a small open economy results in a deterioration of balance of trade and expectations of a lower cash flow and, therefore, a lower stock price. Finally, if the industrial production in the domestic country continuously outgrows its foreign 10 counterpart, rational investors expect a higher cash flow relative to the cash flow of foreign stocks and a higher stock price. Let us define gt the actual equity return (excluding dividends) between time t-1 and t, and let get = Et [gt│It-1] denote its expected return conditional on the available information set at time t-1, i.e., It-1. Furthermore, define vgt (= Et [gt - get]2) conditional volatility of the equity return. According to Equation (4), the conditionally expected equity return is a function, g, of the conditionally expected macro-variables used to forecast the future stream of dividend payments. Namely, we will have get = Et [gt│It-1] = g {Et [F(spt, indpt, ext, compt, cpict, onrt, premt, ronfft, rindpcust, rcpt, zzt) │It-1]}. (5) The variable spt is the monthly return of S&P 500-stock index, indpt is the monthly growth of total industrial production, ext is the monthly growth of the exchange rate, compt is the monthly growth of commodity price index, cpict is the monthly growth of the Consumer Price Index in Canada, onrt is the Canadian overnight rate, premt is the monthly corporate rate less T-bill rate, ronfft is the difference between the Canadian overnight and Fed Fund rates, rindpcust is the monthly growth of the ratio of industrial production in Canada and U.S., rcpt is the monthly change of the log of the ratio of Canada to U.S. consumer price indexes, and zzt includes past values of gt and above-mentioned macroeconomic variables as well as current and past values of other valid conditioning variables. Following Kearney (1998), Kearney and Daly (1998) and Kearney (2000) and using Equation (5), the standard asymptotic approximation of the conditional variance of 11 the stock return, vgt (= Et [gt - get]2), depends on the volatility of macro-variables included in yt (Equation 3), assuming these macro-variables are independent. This implies that vgt = vtset = vg(vspt, vindpt, vext, vcompt, vcpict, vonrt, vpremt, vronfft, vrindpcust, vrcpt, vzt), (6) where vtset is the conditional volatility of monthly return of TSE 300, vspt is the conditional volatility of monthly return of S&P 500-stock index, vindpt is the conditional volatility of the monthly growth of total industrial production, vext is the conditional volatility of the monthly growth of the exchange rate, vcompt is the conditional volatility of the monthly growth of commodity price index, vcpict is the conditional volatility of the monthly growth of the Consumer Price Index in Canada, vonrt is the conditional volatility of the Canadian overnight rate, vpremt is the conditional volatility of the monthly corporate rate less T-bill rate, vronfft is the conditional volatility of the difference between the Canadian overnight and Fed Fund rates, vrindpcust is the conditional volatility of the monthly growth of the ratio of industrial production in Canada and U.S, vrcpt is the conditional volatility of the monthly growth of the ratio of Canada to U.S. consumer price indexes and vzt includes past values of vtset and above-mentioned volatilities of macroeconomic variables as well as current and past values of other valid conditioning volatilities. It is extremely important to mention that Equation (6) reflects the theoretical behavioral Equation (2) if and only if it is a forward-looking relationship. Equation (6) represents agents’ expectations on volatility of future dividend payments. Namely, it estimates an ex ante measure of risk. Consequently, its parameters are no longer invariant 12 to the process of forcing variables as was mentioned by Lucas (1976). Namely, at least one of the parameters varies with changes in the expectation process. This requires that at least one of the variables in (6) fails to be superexogeneous in the sense of Engle, Hendry and Richard (1983) and Engle and Hendry (1993). This important fact, to the best of my knowledge, was ignored in this literature. To formulate superexogeneity and invariance hypothesis associated with conditional model (6), assume a linear approximation relationship of Equation (6) is: vtset = Γ1 vspt + Γ2 vindpt + Γ3 vext + Γ4 vcompt + Γ5 vcpict + Γ6 vonrt + Γ7 vpremt + Γ8 vronfft + Γ9 vrindpcust + Γ10 vrcpt + vz t’Γ + εt, (6)’ where Γ1,...,Γ10 and Γ are constant parameters. The disturbance term εt is assumed to be normally, identically and independently distributed. Let the set of variables Zt include all contemporaneous macroeconomic volatilities in the conditional model and assume the information set It includes the past values of vtset and Zt as well as the current and past values of other valid conditioning variables (volatilities) included in vzt. Define, respectively, the conditional moments of vtset and Zt as ηPt=E(vtset │It), ηZt=E(Zt│It), σtPP=E[(vtset – ηPt)2│It] and σtZZ=E[(Zt – ηZt )2│It], and let σtPZ=E[(vtset – ηPt) (Zt - ηZt )│It]. Consider the joint distribution of vtset and Zt conditional on information set It to be normally distributed with mean ηt=[ηPt, ηZt] and a non-constant error covariance PP PZ σ σ . Then following Engle, Hendry and Richard (1983), Engle and matrix ∑ = ZP ZZ σ σ Hendry (1993) and Psaradakis and Sola (1996) we can write the relationship between vtset and Zt as: 13 vtset = α0 + ψ0 Zt + (δ0 - ψ0) (Zt - ηZt) + δ1 σtZZ (Zt - ηZt) + ψ1 (ηZt)2 + ψ2 σtZZ + ψ3 σtZZ ηZt + ψ4 σtZZ (ηZt)2 + vz’tγ + ut, (7) where α0, ψ0, ψ1, ψ2, ψ3, ψ4, δ0 and δ1 are regression coefficients of vtset on Zt conditional on z’tγ, and term ut is assumed to be, as before, white noise, normally, identically and independently distributed. Note that Zt includes volatilities of some control/target variables (i.e., the volatility of interest, exchange and inflation rates) that are subject to policy interventions. Under the null of weak exogeneity, δ0-ψ0=0. Under the null of invariance, ψ1=ψ2=ψ3= ψ4 =0 in order to have ψ0 = ψ. Finally, if we assume that σtZZ has distinct values over different, but clearly defined regimes, then under the null of constancy of δ, we need δ1=0. If these entire hypotheses are accepted the equation will be reduced to Equation (6)’. However, in such a case Equation (6)’ will no longer reflect a volatility model associated with Equation (2). Namely, the estimated volatility is a measure for a realized (ex post) risk and it is not a measure for risk (ex ante) for currently holding equity. It must, of course, be emphasized that in this case Equation (6)’ can be used for future prediction of the volatility of stock returns conditional on expected future values of Z and vz. Furthermore, “superexogeneity is sufficient but not a necessary condition for valid inference under intervention” (Engle, Hendry and Richard, 1983, p. 284). This is due to the fact that estimable models with invariant parameters, but with no weakly exogenous variables are easily formulated. 14 3. Data, empirical methodology and results I will test the model on monthly Canadian and U.S. data. All observations are for the last day of the month. The sample period is January 1975-December 1999. All data are obtained from Statistics Canada CANSIM database. Domestic stock markets are represented by all stocks traded on the Toronto Stock Exchange, and so the TSE 300 Composite Index is considered to be the price of domestic stock markets. The Standard and Poor 500 Index is a representative of the price of foreign stock markets. To empirically implement the model, we must obtain monthly estimates of the standard deviations of the relevant variables. Following, among many, Schwert (1989), Koutoulas and Kryzanowski (1996), Kearney (1998), Kearney and Daly (1998) as well as Kearney (2000) the methodology developed by Davidian and Carroll (1978) was used. Let vector Xt = [gt, spt, indpt, ext, compt, cpict, onrt, premt, ronfft, rindpcust, rcpt], and estimate equations (8a) for gt and spt: Xt = 12 12 i =1 i =1 ∑α ix X t-i + ∑ µ ix M it + β1 Oct87 + β2 AS97 + uxt, (8a) and Equation (8b) for the rest of the variables in vector X. Xt = 12 12 i =1 i =1 ∑α ix X t-i + ∑ µ ix M it + uxt. uxt ~niid(0, Σ), t = 1, …,N (8b) M’s are monthly seasonal dummy variables, Oct87 is a dummy variable used to capture the impact of the October 87 stock market crisis. It is equal to one in October 87 and zero otherwise. AS97 is a dummy variable, which is equal to one for October and 15 November 1997 observations, and is zero, otherwise.5 The parameters αx’s and µx’s are assumed to be constant. The monthly dummy variables capture seasonal variations in the means and standard deviations of the variables while Oct87t, and AS97t dummy variables capture the shock on stock prices during the October 87 and the recent Asian crises. Furthermore, a 12th-order autoregression for the absolute values of errors from equations (8a) and (8b), including monthly dummy variables to allow for different monthly standard deviations, should be estimated: |ûxt |= σ tx = 12 12 i =1 i =1 ∑ δ ixσ tx-i + ∑ηix M it + vt (9) where δ ix and η ix , for i = 1 to 12 are constant parameters. The absolute value of the fitted value of uxt (i.e., |ûxt |) is the standard deviation of X. However, as it was mentioned by Schwert (1989), since the expected error is less than the standard deviation from a normal distribution, following Schwert (1989), all absolute errors are multiplied by the constant 1.2533. 5 The TSE 300 Composite Index hit a record high on October 7, 1997, just 10 days before the crisis. Up to January 12, 1998 the index fell 13.45%. However, the index hit a record high on March 9, 1998 and by the end of March 1998 it hit 10 record highs. Consequently, if the Asian crisis had any impact on Canadian stock markets, the impact would have been completely dissipated by the end of February 1998. However, from the end of September 1997 till the end of November 1997 the TSE 300 Composite Index fell by 7.79% and rebounded after. This implies that for our monthly observations the appropriate dummy variable, which may reflect the Asian Crisis, is a variable that is one for the October-November period and zero, otherwise. This dummy variable is also relevant for the S&P500 index. The S&P500 index closed at 947.28 on the last day of September 1997 and fell by 3.45% and closed at 914.62 on the last day of October 1997. But the index rebounded and increased by 4.46% and closed at 955.40 on the last day of November 1997. 16 As it was also mentioned by Kearney and Daly (1998), the conditional volatility in Equation (9) represents a generalization of the 12-month rolling standard estimator used by Officer (1973), Fama (1976) and Merton (1980). This is due to the fact that the conditional volatility estimated by Equation (9) allows the conditional mean to vary over time in equations (8a) and (8b), while it also allows different weights to be applied to the lagged absolute unpredicted changes in stock market returns and macroeconomic variables in equations (8a) and (8b), respectively. Note that here I also allow the conditional mean of stock returns to vary with the stock crisis of 1987 and the Asian crisis of 1997. Furthermore, the merit of this measure of volatility is reviewed, among others, by Engle (1993) and Diebold and Lopez (1995). This measure of volatility, as also indicated by Kearney and Daly (1998), is similar to the autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity (ARCH) model of Engle (1982), which, in its various forms, has been widely used in the finance literature. Davidian and Carroll (1987) argue that the specification in Equation (9) based on the absolute value of the prediction errors is more robust than those on the squared residuals in equations (8a) and (8b). However, in estimation equations (6)’, (9) as well as superexogeneity Equation (7), the dependent variables are generated regressor and their t-statistic should be interpreted with caution (Pagan (1984) and (1986)). To cope with this problem, following Pagan (1984 and 1986), Kearney and Daly (1998) as well as Kearney (2000), the equation for the conditional volatility (i.e., Equation (6)’) is estimated jointly with the equations determining the conditional volatilities of all variables included in the model using the generalized least squares (GLS) estimation procedure. 17 In our GLS system, two equations are generated by Equation (8a), nine equations are generated by Equation (8b), eleven equations are generated by Equation (9), and including Equation (6)’ a system of 23 equations with 300 observations will be estimated. The GLS estimator incorporates the possibility of cross-equation correlation among the error terms. As it was also mentioned by Kearney and Daly (1998), in the current context of estimating volatilities of financial and economic variables, the potential for efficiency gain by estimating the system using GLS is considerable. Table 1 about here Table 1 reports the description of variables and data sources. Tables 2 and 3 reports the OLS result of the estimation of equations (8a) and (8b) and diagnosis tests on these estimations, respectively. Tables 4 and 5 report the OLS estimation results on Equation (9) and diagnosis test on the estimation, respectively. In the estimation process whenever the errors exhibit heteroskedasticity I used the robust-error regression estimation technique (White (1980) and Hansen (1982)) to correct for heteroskedasticity. In tables 3 and 5, White is the White’s (1980) general test for heteroskedasticity, ARCH is five-order Engle’s (1982) test, Godfrey is five-order Godfrey’s (1978) test, RESET is the Ramsey (1969) misspecification test. According to Godfrey’s test result in Table (3) none of the equations suffers from autocorrelation while according to White and ARCH test results, TSE return, the growth of industrial product, U.S.-Canada industrial production growth rates differential, the Canadian overnight rate, Canada-U.S. overnight rates differential, premium rate and Canada-U.S. inflation rates differential suffer from heteroskedasticity. The robust-error regression estimation technique (White (1980) and Hansen (1982)) was, therefore, used to 18 correct the standard errors. According to R2 test result reported in Table 2 the equations explain between 9% (for the growth of the commodity price) and 98% (for the Canadian overnight interest rate) of the variation in the dependent variables. The lagged dependent variables, according to the F-test result (column 2), are jointly significant for all equations except for the S&P 500-stock index and the growth of the commodity price index. Furthermore, the F-test for joint exclusion of monthly seasonal dummy variables is significant only for the rate of return on the TSE 300 index, the growth of industrial production, premium, inflation rate and Canada-U.S. inflation rates differential. Since there is no study of this sort for Canada it is not possible to confirm these results with other studies. Studies on other countries did ignore commodity price and premium variables, but as far as other variables are concerned, the result on the lagged dependent variable on the Canadian stock market confirms, e.g., the result of Kearney and Daly (1998) for the Australian stock market. Tables 2 and 3 about here According to Godfrey’s test results in Table 5, none of the error term in volatility equations suffers from autocorrelation. The error terms in volatility equation of stock return, growth of industrial production, U.S.-Canada industrial production growth rate differential, Canadian overnight rate, Canada-U.S. overnight rates differential, premium and Canada-U.S. inflation differential, however, suffers from heteroskedasticity. As before, the robust-error regression estimation technique (White (1980) and Hansen (1982)) was, therefore, used to correct the standard errors. According to Ramsey’s (1969) RESET test result, the conditional volatility equation for S&P 500-stock index return, U.S.-Canada industrial production growth rates differential, growth of exchange rate, 19 premium, Canadian inflation rate and Canada-U.S. inflation rates differential are not misspecified. According to the F-test result reported in Table 4 the lagged values of conditional volatilities (column 2 of Table 4), except the growth of commodity price, U.S.-Canada industrial production growth rate differential and growth of the exchange rate, should be included in all models. This result confirms, among others, findings of Kearney and Daly (1998) for the Australian stock market, growth of Australian industrial production, interest rate, inflation and exchange rates, namely, all our common macro-variables. According to the F-test result, column 3 of Table 4, the seasonal dummy variables of the conditional volatility of domestic stock return, as well as the growth of industrial production, Canadian overnight rate and premium are jointly significant, indicating that these conditional volatilities are time varying. This result confirms earlier findings of Koutoulas and Kryzanowski (1996), who also used Canadian data, on macro-variables like the growth of industrial production and exchange rate. Furthermore, the result also confirms other work on other countries. For instance, Kearney (1998) finds a strong monthly seasonality effect for British stock markets as well as Irish interest rate, Irish-U.K. exchange rate, Irish industrial production and inflation rate. Furthermore, our result also confirms Kearney and Daly’s (1998) findings for seasonality effect on the conditional volatility of Australian stock return and the growth of industrial production. Tables 4 and 5 about here Table 6 reports the summary statistics from the OLS estimates of Equation (9). All of the conditional volatility variables have low standard deviation relative to their means. Except for the conditional volatility of the return of the S&P 500-stock index, of 20 the differential between the growth of the Canadian and U.S. industrial production and of the growth of the exchange rate, there is evidence of non-normality in the conditional volatility variables. This result is consistent with the existing literature, e.g., Koutoulas and Kryzanowski (1996), Kearney (1998) and Kearney and Daly (1998). Tables 6 and 7 about here As stationary test results reported in Table 7 indicate all conditional volatility variables are integrated of degree zero (stationary). Given all conditional volatility variables are stationary, assuming a lag length of six, to capture two-quarter impact, a parsimonious GLS was obtained by engaging in general-to-specific-modeling procedure. The general-to-specific-modeling procedure is common in this literature, e.g., Koutoulas and Kryzanowski (1996), Kearney (1998) and Kearney and Daly (1998). Table 8 reports GLS estimation result of conditional volatility model (6)’. In Table 5, the R 2, σ and DW, respectively, denote the adjusted squared multiple correlation coefficient, the residual standard deviation and the Durbin-Watson statistic. Hansen’s (1992) stability L test for the null hypothesis that the estimated coefficient is stable (5% critical value=0.47, Table 1, Hansen (1992)) denotes all of the coefficients are stable. Table 8 about here Furthermore, the joint Hansen’s (1992) stability Lc test result for the null hypothesis that the estimated coefficients as well as the error variance are jointly constant is 3.39 (<4.14 for 18 degrees of freedom), which indicates we can not reject the null of joint stability of the coefficients together with the estimated variance. I also estimated recursively computed ‘break point’ Chow test (not reported, but available upon request) which also indicated all coefficients are stable. Consequently, the conditional volatility 21 Equation (6)’appears to be constant over the sample period. In Table 8 White is the White’s (1980) general test for heteroskedasticity, ARCH is five-order Engle’s (1982) test, Godfrey is five-order Godfrey’s (1978) test, RESET is the Ramsey (1969) misspecification test, Normality is Jarque-Bera (1987) normality statistic. None of these diagnostic checks is significant. According to the R 2 statistics the model explains 71% of the variation in the conditional variance of the Canadian stock market with the standard error of the estimate being one-fifth of the mean of the dependent variable. This result compares extremely well with related existing work of, for instance, Schwert (1989) on U.S. data (i.e., R2 = 0.208 for the 1900-1987 period, the standard error of the estimate not reported), Kearney (1998) on Irish stock market (i.e., R2 = 0.38, with the standard error of the estimate being 0.011, the mean of the dependent variable not reported), Kearney and Daly (1998) on Australian stock market (i.e., R2 = 0.35, with the standard error of the estimate being one-third of the mean of the dependent variable) and Kearney (2000) on British stock (i.e., R2 = 0.46, with the standard error of the estimate being one-fifth of the mean of the dependent variable), on French stock (i.e., R2 = 0.48, with the standard error of the estimate being 18% of the mean of the dependent variable), on German stock (i.e., R2 = 0.43, with the standard error of the estimate being 31% of the mean of the dependent variable) and on Japanese stock (i.e., R2 = 0.63, with the standard error of the estimate being 35% of the mean of the dependent variable) . As the results in Table 8 indicate, while the intercept is zero in nine months of the year, it is positive in February and April and negative in December indicating no January effect on the conditional volatility of the stock return. December’s tax loss selling could 22 be a factor in a lower volatility in December. As it would be expected for a small open economy under perfect capital mobility the conditional volatility of stock return is instantaneously affected by the conditional volatility of the exchange rate and Canada-U.S. interest rates differential. The estimated coefficient of the conditional volatility of the exchange rate is 0.52 and statistically significant (t-statistic of 3.06), indicating that, everything else being constant, more than half of the exchange rate volatility is instantaneously transmitted to the stock market volatility. The instantaneous and positive sign of the exchange volatility on the conditional volatility of stock return confirms the finding of Kearney and Daly (1998) and Kearney (2000) for French stock market. The coefficient of the volatility of interest rate differential is also positive and statistically significant (t-statistic = 3.37) implying an instantaneous impact on the conditional volatility of the stock return.6 Furthermore, the impact lasts for four months with an overall impact (the sum of the coefficients) of 0.51% for a one-percent increase of the conditional volatility of the interest rate differential. The conditional volatility of the other macro-variables influences the conditional volatility of stock return with lags. The volatility of the growth of the industrial production influences positively the conditional volatility of stock return after a one-month lag length and it lasts for two months. The overall impact is 1.24, indicating that an increase of one percent in the volatility of the growth of industrial production results in an increase of 1.24% in the volatility of stock return within two months.7 This result is consistent with the finding of Schwert (1989) on U.S. data for the period 6 To the best of my knowledge no study of this sort incorporated interest rate differential. 7 Note that standard deviation has the same unit as the variable. 23 1953-1987 with statistically significant coefficient of 0.18, Kearney (1998) on the Irish stock market with a statistically significant coefficient of 0.458. The conditional volatility of the commodity price index influences the stock volatility after a two-month lag length and it lasts for three months though the overall impact is a negative 0.08. Namely, a 1% increase in the volatility of the growth of commodity price index results in an increase of 0.21% in the conditional volatility of stock return after a lag length of two months, but after a three-month lag length, such an increase will reduce the volatility of stock return by 0.29%. To the best of my knowledge no study has included the commodity price in the analysis. The impact of the conditional volatility of interest rate on the conditional volatility of stock return is negative with a lag length of two months. This result is in contrast with Kearney and Daly (1998) who find the impact of the conditional volatility of interest rate on the conditional volatility of Australian stock return to be positive with a lag length of one month. Interestingly, while the conditional volatility of interest rate differential is found to influence instantaneously and positively the conditional volatility of stock return it takes two months for the volatility of interest rate to influence negatively the volatility of stock return. One possible explanation is that, if a higher volatility of interest rate differential is due to a higher volatility of Canadian overnight rate, given Fed Fund rate, then stock volatility will increase instantaneously as interest rate differential varies, but after two months when the market adjusts to the variations of interest rate differential the stock volatility will fall. 24 The estimated coefficient of the conditional volatility of the premium is positive while the estimated coefficient of conditional volatility of inflation rate is negative; both impacts take a lag length of one month. The estimated coefficient of the lagged dependent variable is statistically significant up to a six-month lag length indicating that the conditional volatility of stock return in Canada responds dynamically to the conditional volatility of the related macro-variables. In sum, this section adds to the existing literature by showing that in a small open economy with no restriction on the mobility of capital both volatility of commodity price and interest rate differential are important determinants, among the volatility of other macro variables, in the determination of the volatility of equity return. 4. Marginal models: Superexogeneity test result Having established in the previous section that a dynamic relationship to describe conditional volatility of stock return and conditional volatility of related macro-variables exists, we need to verify if our model is also forward looking, namely, if the estimated conditional volatility represents future volatility of dividend payments. This requires a superexogeneity test on the variables. For this test we need to establish the marginal models. 25 4.1. Marginal models There have been several potential regime changes over the sample period as follows: (i) The introduction of SPRA (the Special Purchase and Resale Agreements) and SRA (Sales Repurchase Agreements) in June 1985.8 (ii) The change of the Bank of Canada’s policy management approach (tight monetary policy) under Governor Crow, February 1987-February 1994.9 (iii) The implementation of a free trade agreement between Canada and the United States in January 1991. (iv) The implementation of NAFTA (North American Free Trade Agreement between Canada, the United States and Mexico in January 1994). (v) The introduction of inflation rate target band by the Department of Finance and the Bank of Canada in February 1991.10 8 With SPRA instrument, Bank of Canada is involved in the purchase of short-term Government of Canada securities under an agreement to sell them back on the following day. This temporary supply of funds can ease the market. SRA is the reverse of SPRA (Bank of Canada, 1989). 9 In this period Canada-U.S. overnight interest rate differential (overnight rate minus Fed Fund rate) went up from an average of 1.41% (standard deviation=2.39) during the 1975:01-1987:01 period to an average of 2.64% (standard deviation=1.33) during 1987:02 to 1994:02 period. 10 “… from 1982 to 1991, monetary policy in Canada was carried out with price stability as the longer-term goal and inflation containment as the shorter-term goal, but without intermediate targets or a specified path to the longer-term objective. In February 1991, explicit targets for reducing inflation were introduced through joint announcements by the Bank and the federal government. These announcements confirmed 26 (vi) The introduction of term deposit auction in April 1986.11 Dummy variables were created for step changes, i.e., (i) spra = 1 for June 1985 and after, zero otherwise, (ii) crow = 1 for February 1987-February 1994, zero otherwise, (iii) free = 1 for January 1991 and after, zero otherwise, (iv) nafta = 1 for January 1994 price stability as the appropriate long-term objective for monetary policy in Canada and specified a target path to low inflation….”(Thiessen, 1998-1999, p. 91). 11 In Canada, the day-to-day operations of monetary policy seek to influence the overnight financing rate, primarily through the management of the supply of settlement balances provided to the direct clearers. The direct clearers use their accounts at the Bank of Canada only to settle transactions between themselves or with the government. Currently, Bank of Canada influences the daily level of these balances, retroactively, through the drawdown/redeposit (D/R) mechanism. Even though the bank’s actions as fiscal agent of the government are not directly linked to the implementation of monetary policy, the two functions are related. Interactions occur principally on two major fronts. The use of the Receiver General deposits in the D/R mechanism changes the overall level of government balances every day. Consequently, treasury management decisions must take into account actual and potential monetary operations. The net investment of government balances in the overnight market can then be an important net source or use of funds for the market, influencing the evolution of the overnight financing rate and should, therefore, be taken into account by the Bank when determining the supply of settlement balances (Montador, 1995). A portion of Receiver General deposits has been auctioned among direct clearers since April 1986, and has become the largest component of the government’s cash balances. Furthermore, the auction for term deposits is now an important daily event for the overnight money market in Canada. Indeed, the yields on these deposits are one of the key indicators for the evolution of overnight rates during the course of a daily overnight funds cycle. The one-day funds won at the term deposit auctions are part of the pool of one-day resources available to the financial institutions to lend or meet their financing needs (Kia, 1996). 27 and after, zero otherwise, (v) inftar = 1 for February 1991 and after, zero otherwise, and (vi) term = 1 for April 1996 and after, zero otherwise. 12 Level and interactive combinations of these dummy variables were tried for the impact of these potential shift events in the marginal models for lspt, lext, lcompt and onrt and any first round significant effects were retained. The resulting marginal models took the form: 12 Dummies for other potential regimes were also created and used as regressors in marginal equations. However, none of these dummies was found to be significant in any of the marginal equations. These potential regime changes include: the revision to the reserve requirement in Canada in August 1983 (Bank of Canada, 1983) and the introduction of zero reserve requirements and operating band in July 1994. In compliance with the Bank Act, the statutory requirement on chartered banks to hold reserves against certain of their deposit liabilities was reduced to zero in July 1994, Bank of Canada, (1994, p. 80, Footnote 1). 28 vext = 0.07 - 0.18 vext-1 - 0.50 vext-2 - 0.42 vex t-3 - 0.53 vex t-4 [SE]→[0.005] [0.05] [0.05] [0.05] [0.06] - 0.45 vext-5 - 0.38 vext-6 - 0.48 vex t-7 - 0.15 vex t-8 [SE]→ [0.06] [0.05] [0.06] [0.06] - 0.52 vext-9 - 0.16 vext-10 - 0.22 vex t-11 - 0.12 (vex t-7)(crowt-7) [SE]→ [0.04] [0.05] [0.05] [0.04] + 0.73 vrcpt-2 - 0.81 vrcpt-4 - 0.51 (vrcpt-9)(naftat-9) [SE]→ [0.14] [0.13] [0.15] - 0.07 vronfft-5 + 0.11 (vronfft-3)(freet-3) [SE]→ [0.02] [0.03] - 0.08 (vronfft-9)(crowt-9) + 0.10 (vronff t-12)(crowt-12) + 0.06 vonrt-4 [SE]→ [0.02] [0.03] [0.02] + 0.09 vonrt-11 - 0.18 (vonrt-2)(freet-2) -0.13 (vonrt-9)(freet-9) [SE]→ [0.02] [0.04] [0.04] + 0.20 (vonrt-2)(crowt-2) + 0.12 (vonrt-11)(crowt-11) [SE]→ [0.05] [0.04] - 0.19 vindpt-3 - 0.28 vindpt-4-0.17 vindpt-5 [SE]→ [0.06] [0.06] [0.06] + 0.28 (vindpt-1)(sprat-1) +0.22 (vindpt-6)(zerot-6) [SE]→ [0.07] [0.06] + 0.15 (vindpt-2)(naftat-2) -0.27 (vindpt-1)(inftart-1) [SE]→ [0.05] [0.07] + 0.21 (vindpt-3)(inftart-3) + 0.14 (vindpt-4)(inftart-4) [SE]→ [0.06] [0.08] - 0.18 (vindpt-8)(inftart-8) + 0.13 (vindpt-11)(inftart-11) [SE]→ [0.07] [0.06] + 0.11 (vindpt-8)(crowt-8) - 0.004 sprat – 0.003 AS97t [SE]→ [0.05] [0.001] [0.001] (10) 29 2 R =0.73, σ=0.002, DW=1.93, Godfrey(5)=0.53 (significance level=0.78), White=234 (significance level=1.00), ARCH(5)=22.17 (significance level=0.04), RESET=0.83 (significance level=0.47), Normality(χ2=2)=0.07 (significance level=0.97), and vronfft = 0.36 vronfft-1 + 0.23 vronfft-5 + 0.48 vronfft-7- 0.15 vronff t-11 [SE] [0.07] [0.07] [0.08] [0.07] - 0.25 (vronfft-2)(sprat-2) - 0.33 (vronfft-7)(sprat-7) - 0.18 (vronfft-8)(sprat-8) [SE]→ [0.07] [0.09] [0.06] + 0.18 (vronfft-9)(sprat-9) + 0.47 vex t-1 + 0.23 (vex t-8)(spra t-8) [SE]→ [0.06] [0.07] [0.08] - 0.30 vindpt-12 - 0.43 (vindpt-10)(sprat-10) + 0.77 vrcp t-1 - 1.28 vrcp t-7 [SE]→ [0.10] [0.10] [0.36] [0.32] + 0.77 (vrcpt-6)(sprat-6) + 0.81 (vrcp t-11)(sprat-11) [SE]→ [0.22] [0.25] (11) 2 R =0.71, σ=0.004, DW=1.85, Godfrey(5)=1.67 (significance level=0.13), White=168.68 (significance level=0.51), ARCH(5)=77.53 (significance level=0.00), RESET=0.02 (significance level=0.99), Normality(χ2=2)=145.88 (significance level=0.00), Equations (10) and (11) pass the diagnostic checks for residual autocorrelation test and the RESET test. However, both equations’ residual suffers from heteroskedasticity in ARCH sense. To cope with heteroskedasticity problem the robusterror regression estimation technique (White (1980) and Hansen (1982)) was used to correct the standard errors. Furthermore, Equation (11) fails for the normality of the residual. The failure of the residual normality is common in the estimation of marginal equations, e.g., Hurn and Muscatelli (1992) and Metin (1998). Overall, equations (10) and (11) seem reasonable marginal models for the analogues of ηz, especially since the standard errors are very small, i.e., σ respectively is 30 0.002 and 0.004. Clearly there is evidence of the structural break in all these equations, i.e., possible break points are due to the introduction of Free Trade, NAFTA, overnight repoes (spra and sra), Bank of Canada’s auctions of the Government of Canada funds (term), the introduction of inflation target (inftar), the appointment of Governor Crow (crow), the elimination of reserve requirements and the Asian Stock Market Crisis. Note that non-constancy of the marginal models is related to the concept of superexogeneity, which implies that the parameters of conditional model remain constant if agents are not forward looking. In Equation (10) the ‘crow’,‘free’, ‘nafta’, ‘spra’, ‘zero’, ‘inftar’ and ‘AS97’ dummy variables are significant. Dummy variable ‘AS97’affects only the intercept while dummy variable ‘spra’ affects the intercept and the slope. Dummy variables ‘crow’,‘free’, ‘nafta’, ‘zero’, and ‘inftar’ influence only the slope. According to the estimated results the conditional volatility of growth of the exchange rate fell during the Asian crisis. After the introduction of NAFTA a higher conditional volatility of Canada-U.S. inflation differential, after a lag length of nine months, reduces the conditional volatility of the exchange rate while an increase in the conditional volatility of the growth of the industrial production, after a lag length of two months, increases the volatility of the growth of the exchange rate. Before the introduction of Free Trade Agreement between U.S. and Canada, the conditional volatility of Canadian-U.S. interest rate differentials had a negative impact on the conditional volatility of the growth of the exchange rate while the conditional volatility of overnight interest rate had a positive impact on the volatility of the growth of the exchange rate. The introduction of free trade reversed the impact of these variables. 31 Furthermore, during the period of tight monetary policy of John Crow the positive impact of the conditional volatility of overnight rate on the conditional volatility of the growth of the exchange rate was overemphasized. During this period the negative impact of the conditional volatility of interest rate differential on the growth of the exchange rate was reduced after a lag length of twelve months. The negative impact of the conditional volatility of industrial production on the conditional volatility of the growth of the exchange rate was reduced after the introduction of SPRA, zero reserve requirement and inflation target policy. Such an observation is also evidenced during the period of tight monetary policy of John Crow. It should, of course, be mentioned that according to the estimation result there are different lag lengths in the above procedure. In Equation (11), as it would be expected, the ‘spra’ dummy variable is only significant. This dummy variable influences only the slope. The equation suggests that while a higher conditional volatility of the growth of the exchange rate and Canada-U.S. inflation rates differential increases the conditional volatility of Canada-U.S. interest rates differential after a one-month lag length, the conditional volatility of the growth rate of the industrial production reduces the interest rates differential after a 12-month lag length. The introduction of SPRA emphasized these impacts. 4.2. Superexogeneity test results From marginal models 10 and 11, estimates of ηZ, and σtZZ, for Z = vex and vronff were calculated. As for σtZZ, since the error for vex and vronff variables at the conventional level is heteroskedastic according to ARCH test, a five-period ARCH error, therefore, was estimated. I also constructed DevZ (for Z=vex and vronff) as differences 32 between the variance of the error term in (10) and (11) and the variance constructed by ARCH estimation. All of these constructed variables were then included in Equation (6)’ reported in Table 8. The estimation results on these constructed variables are given in Table 9. Table 9 about here The individual F-test is on the null hypothesis that each variable is zero. The F-test on the null hypothesis that all constructed variables are jointly zero is given in the last row of the table. The F-test, given in the third to last row in Table 9, is on the hypothesis that only the constructed variables related to each contemporaneous variable while all other constructed variables are included, are jointly zero. I also included only the constructed variables related to each contemporaneous variable and tested whether these constructed variables are jointly zero. The F-test result is given in the second to last row in Table 9. As the estimation result in Table 9 shows the joint F-test on the null hypothesis that coefficients of these constructed variables are jointly zero is significant, indicating that these variables together should be included. This result immediately implies that the contemporaneous variables in the conditional model, reported in Table 8, are not jointly superexogenous, i.e., agents are forward looking and Equation (6)’ reflects a volatility model associated with Equation (2) and, consequently, the estimated volatility can be a measure of future risk for holding equity in Canada. Since the coefficient of (Z-ηZ) of both contemporaneous variables vex and vronff is statistically insignificant, both of these variables are weakly exogenous. However, the coefficient of σZZ(Z-ηZ) of vronff variable is significant implying that the null of constancy is rejected for this variable. 33 The coefficient of σZZ ηZ and σZZ (ηZ)2 of both variables vex and vronff is significant. Furthermore, the coefficient of σZZ of vex is significant. These results together imply that the null of invariance with respect to policy changes is rejected for both of these variables. Consequently, we reject the null of constancy and invariance, while accepting weak exogeneity conditions for vronff variable, and reject the null of invariance for the contemporaneous variable vex while accepting weak exogeneity condition. Note that constancy and invariance are different concepts. Parameters could vary over time, but be invariant with respect to policy changes. However, as it was mentioned by Engle and Hendry (1993), we need all three conditions to be satisfied in order to ensure superexogeneity. The failure of the constancy and invariance conditions, therefore, justifies the result of the joint F-test on the null hypothesis that all coefficients of the constructed variables are jointly zero. Namely, in general, we reject the null hypothesis that variables vex and vronff are superexogenous. Note that Fed Fund rate is exogenous to Canadian financial markets. Hence, the above result means that, for a given Fed Fund rate, the monetary policy which alters the conditional volatility of interest rate differential and/or the growth of the exchange rate will affect investment decisions made by the economic agents in Canadian stock markets. Namely the agents in equity markets are forward looking. It should be noted that, instead of marginal models 10 and 11, one could simply estimate the DGP (data generating process) of each contemporaneous variable in the volatility model (6)’, while allowing level and interactive combinations of the above dummy variables to reflect potential shifts events. The estimated equations, of course, would not have any economic interpretation, but would be valid marginal equations for 34 the superexogeneity test, see Engle and Hendry (1993). In fact, I also tried this approach and found no materially different result with what is reported. For the sake of brevity this result is not reported, but available upon request. It should be mentioned that since both contemporaneous variables vex and vronff in the agents’ model (Equation (6)’) are weakly exogenous the inferences on the parameters of agents’ model are efficient. In sum, it was found in this section that the conditional volatility of the stock return represented by Equation (6)’can be a measure of the ex ante risk for holding equities in Canada. The agents in the stock markets in Canada are forward looking. Furthermore, agents form expectations by using non-constant parameter models. This result also implies that Canadian investors in equity markets form rational (or near rational) expectations. Namely, they incorporate expectations of future economic changes in determining their investment decisions in equity markets. 5. Concluding remarks This paper extends the existing literature by developing a model of stock return volatility capable to capture whether the observed estimated equity return volatility can be a measure of the future (ex ante) risk or realized (ex post) risk. The monthly data on Canadian and U.S. stock markets for the period 1975-1999 are used. A macrodeterminant stock price model for a small and open-resource-oriented country is developed. The model is used to derive a conditional stock volatility model capable to incorporate the volatility of macro-variables, including commodity price, which are used to forecast the volatility of future dividend payments. The model is estimated and the superexogeneity tests are used to examine whether the estimated volatility reflects the behavior of agents who are forward looking and their expectations are formed rationally, 35 i.e., if the estimated volatility can be a measure of future (ex ante) risk or it is only a measure of realized (ex post) risk. It is found that the conditional volatility of both the growth of commodity price index and Canada-U.S. interest rate differentials, along with other conditional volatility of macro-determinants, are in fact important component of the conditional volatility of stock return determination. Furthermore, it was found that 71% of the volatility of the Canadian stock return is explained by the behavior of forward-looking rational speculators which, consequently, can be used to estimate ex ante risk. Namely, noise traders’ participation in Canadian stock return volatility is only about one-fourth of the variation in monthly stock returns. 36 References Bank of Canada, 1983. Overnight Financing in Canada: Special Call Loans, Bank of Canada Review, May, 4-13. Bank of Canada, 1989. Buy-back Techniques in the Conduct of Monetary Policy, Bank of Canada Review, July, 3-17. Bank of Canada, 1994. Bank of Canada Review, Autumn. Bernanke, Ben and Mark Gertler, 1999, Monetary Policy and Asset Price Volatility, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Fourth Quarter, 17-51. Culter, David M., James M. Poterba, and Lawrence H. Summers, 1989. What Moves Stock Prices? Journal of Portfolio Management 15, 4-12. Davidian, M. and R. J. Carroll, 1978. Variance Function Estimation Journal of the American Statistical Association 82, 1079-1091. Dickey, D. A. and W. A. Fuller, 1981. Likelihood Ratio Statistics for Autoregressive Time Series with a Unit Root, Econometrica 49, 1057-1072. Diebold, F. X. and J. A. Lopez, 1995. Modeling Volatility Dynamics, in Macroeconometrics; Developments, Tensions and Prospects, Ed. K. D. (Kluwer Academic Publisher Hoover, Boston). Ely, David P. and Kenneth J Robinson, 1997. Are Stocks a Hedge Against Inflation? International Evidence Using a Long-run Approach, Journal of International Money and Finance 16, 141-167. Engle, Robert F., 1982. Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity With Estimates of the Variance of United Kingdom Inflation, Econometrica 50, 987-1007. 37 Engle, Robert F., 1993. Statistical Models for Financial Volatility, Financial Analysts Journal 49, 72-78. Engle, Robert F., David F. Hendry and Jean-Francois Richard, 1983. Exogeneity, Econometrica 51, 277-304. Engle, Robert F. and David F. Hendry, 1993. Testing Superexogeneity and Invariance in Regression Models, Journal of Econometrics 56, 119-139. Fama, Eugene F., 1976. Forward Rate as Predictors of Future Rates, Journal of Financial Economics 3, 351-377. Fama, Eugene F., 1990. Stock Returns, Expected Returns, and Real Activity, Journal of Finance 45, 1089-1108. Gallant, A. Ronald, Peter E. Rossi and George Tauchen, 1992. Stock Prices and Volume, Review of Financial Studies 5, 199-242. Godfrey, Les G., 1978. Testing Against General Autoregressive And Moving Average Error Models When the Regressors Include Lagged Dependent Variables, Econometrica 46, 1293-1301. Hansen, Bruce E., 1992. Testing for Parameter Instability in Linear Models, Journal of Political Modeling 14, 517-533. Hansen, Lars P., 1982. Large Sample Properties of Generalized Method of Moments Estimators, Econometrica 50, 1029-1054. Hurn, A.S. and V.A. Muscatelli, 1992. Testing Superexogeneity: The Demand for Broad Money in the UK, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 54, 543-556. Jarque, Carlos M. and Anil K. Bera, 1987. A Test for Normality of Observations and Regression Residuals, International Statistical Review 55, August, 163-172. 38 Kaul, Gautam, 1986. Stock Returns and Inflation: the Role of the Monetary Sector, Journal of Financial Economics 18, 253-276. Kearney, Colm, 1998. The Causes of Volatility in a Small, Internationally Integrated Stock Market: Ireland, July 1975-June 1994, The Journal of Financial Research XXI, 85-104. Kearney, Colm and Kevin Daly, 1998. The Causes of Stock Market Volatility in Australia, Applied Financial Economics 8, 597-605. Kearney, Colm, 2000. The determination and international transmission of stock market volatility, Global Finance Journal 11, 31-52. Kia, Amir, 1996. Day-of-the-Week Effect and the Overnight Money Market Efficiency, Bank of Canada mimeograph. Paper presented at the annual meeting of the Canadian Economics Association, May 1996. Kia, Amir, 1997a. Inflation, Stock Returns and the Relative Performance of Equities and Bonds: A Brief Survey of Empirical Studies, Bank of Canada, Financial Markets Department Working Paper, FMD 97-110. Kia, Amir, 1997b. Hedging Against Inflation: The Best Investment Strategy in a Low Inflation Environment, Bank of Canada, Financial Markets Department Working Paper, FMD 97-195. Korkie, Bob, 1990. A Note on the TSE/Western Treasury Bill Returns, Canadian Journal of Administrative Sciences 7, 26-28. Koutoulas, George and Lawrence Kryzanowski, 1996. Microfactor conditional volatilities, time-varying risk premia and stock return behavior, The Financial Review 31, 169-227. 39 Lucas Jr., Robert E., 1976. Econometric Policy Evaluation: A critique in K. Brunner and A.H. Meltzer, eds., The Phillips Curve and Labor Markets (North-Holland, Amsterdam), 19-46. Lucas Jr., Robert E., 1978. Asset Prices in an Exchange Economy, Econometrica 46, 1429-1445. Merton, R.C., 1980. On Estimating the Expected Return on the Market: an Explanatory Investigation, Journal of Financial Economics 8, 323-361. Metin, Kivilcim, 1998. The Relationship Between Inflation and the Budget Deficit in Turkey, Journal of Business & Economic Statistics 16, No. 4, 412-422. Montador, Bruce, 1995. The Implementation of Monetary Policy in Canada, Canadian Public Policy XXX:1, 107-120. Mukherjee, Tarun K. and Atsuyuki Naka, 1995. Dynamic Relations Between Macroeconomic Variables and the Japanese Stock Market: An Application of A Vector Error Correction Model, The Journal of Financial Research XVIII, 223-237. Officer, R., R., 1973. The Variability of the Market Factor of the New York Stock Exchange, Journal of Business 46, 434-453. Pagan, Adrian, 1984. Econometric Issues in the Analysis of Regressions with Generated Regressors, International Economic Review 25, 221-247. Pagan, Adrian, 1986. Two Stage and Related Estimators and Their Applications, Review of Economic Studies 53, 517-538. Psaradakis, Zacharias and Martin Sola, 1996. On the Power of Tests for Superexogeneity and Structural Invariance, Journal of Econometrics 72, 151-175. 40 Ramsey, J.B., 1969. Tests for Specification Errors in Classical Linear Least-squares Regression Analysis, Journal of Royal Statistical Society 31 Series B, 350-371. Schwert, G. William, 1989. Why Does Stock Market Volatility Change Over Time?, The Journal of Finance XLIV, 1115-1153. Schwert, G. William, 1990. Stock Returns and Real Activity: A Century of Evidence, Journal of Finance 45, 1237-1257. Thiessen, Gordon, 1998-1999. The Canadian Experience with Targets for Inflation Control, Bank of Canada Review, winter, 89-107. White, Halbert, 1980. A Heteroskedasticity-Consistent Covariance Matrix Estimator and a Direct Test for Heteroskedasticity, Econometrica 48, 817-837. 41 Table 1 Description of Variables Of Which The Conditional Volatilities Are Used in the Analysis: CANSIM Number a. The commodity price index is a fixed-weight index of the spot or transaction prices of 23 commodities produced in Canada and sold in world markets. The weight of each commodity in the total index is based on the average value of the Canadian production over the 1982-90 period (Bank of Canada Review (1994)). Consequently, the data were converted to the Canadian dollar by multiplying it by the exchange rate and dividing it by the average of exchange rate for the period 1982-90 (i.e., 1.269193474994). b. Since corresponding data were not available the ratio was constructed by using the ratio of the log of real indexes plus the log of the ratio of Canadian and U.S. consumer price indexes: D360048 converted to 1992=100, D360061, I56010, P100000 and D139105. c. The overnight financing rate is the call loan rate. Call loans are money market instruments designed to finance the acquisition or holding of securities by investment dealers for short periods of time. These loans are callable and a wide range of collateral is accepted by their suppliers (Bank of Canada, 1983). d. Note that monthly T-bill rates are only available from 1989. We, consequently, followed Korkie (1990) and Koutoulas and Kryzanowski (1996) and calculated these rates for the 1975:1-1979:12 period as tbr1t=log(1+kt), where kt=1200[(1+(91/365)*tbr3t-1/100)30.4/91-1] and tbr3 is the three-month T-bill rate (B14060). g = Monthly return of the TSE 300 Composite Index, closing quotations at month-end: B4237 sp = Monthly return of the S&P 500-stock index, quotations at month-end: B4291 indp = Monthly growth of nominal (unadjusted) total industrial production= change of the log of real total industrial production: I57001 plus change of the log of Consumer Price (unadjusted) Index: P100000 comp = Monthly growth of commodity price index in Canadian dollars: B3300a rindpcus = Canadian (SA) and U.S. (SA) industrial production monthly growth rates differentialsb ex = Monthly growth of the exchange rate ($Canadian of one unit $US), the last day of the month: B3414 onr = Canadian overnight financing ratec: B14044 ronff = Canadian overnight rate less Fed Fund rate: B14044 and B54408 cpi = Monthly Canadian inflation rate (Consumer Price Index: P100000) rcp = Monthly Canadian-U.S. inflation rate differentials (Consumer Price indexes: P100000 and D139105) prem = Premium=Differences between monthly Canadian corporate paper and T-bill ratesd: B14039 and B14059 42 Table 2 The ARCH Models of Stock Market Returns and Macro-variables Sample Period:1975:1-1999:12 (Note the first two years were reserved for lags) *The robust-error regression estimation technique (White, 1980; and Hansen, 1982) was used to correct for heteroskedasticity. 12 Xt = ∑α ix X t-i 12 + i =1 ∑α ix X t-i x i M t -i + β1 Oct87 + β2 AS97 + uxt (8a) x i M t -i (8b) i =1 12 Xt = ∑µ 12 + i =1 X Return TSE: Eq(8a)* ∑µ + uxt i =1 F-test: (p-value) Null: t-stat. t-stat. α1x=...=α12x=0 F-test: (p-value) Null: µ1=...=µ12=0 on on β1 β2 R2 0.01 0.03 -22 -4 0.21 Return S&P: Eq(8a) 0.83 0.57 -5 - 0.21 Growth rate: total indus. prod.: Eq(8b)* Growth rate: commodity:Eq(8b) U.S.-Canada indus. prod. growth rate diff.: Eq(8b)* Growth of exchange rate: Eq(8b) Canadian overnight rate: Eq(8b)* Canada-U.S. overnight rate diff.: Eq(8b)* Premium: Eq(8b)* 0.00 0.00 - - 0.96 0.49 0.46 - - 0.09 0.00 0.05 - - 0.17 0.03 0.76 - - 0.10 0.00 0.39 - - 0.98 0.00 0.39 - - 0.74 0.00 0.00 - - 0.66 Inflation: Eq(8b) 0.00 0.00 - - 0.76 Canada-U.S. inflation diff.: Eq(8b)* 0.00 0.00 - - 0.25 43 Table 3 Diagnosis tests of the estimation of equations (8a) and (8b) Godfrey White ARCH RESET X (p-value) (p-value) (p-value) (p-value) Return TSE: Eq(8a) 0.54 0.02 0.00 0.98 Return S&P: Eq(8a) 0.92 0.47 0.89 0.01 Growth rate: total indus. prod.: Eq(8b) Growth rate: commodity: Eq(8b) U.S.-Canada indus. prod. growth rate diff.: Eq(8b) Growth of exchange rate: Eq(8b) Canadian overnight rate: Eq(8b)* Canada-U.S. overnight rate diff.: Eq(8b) Premium: Eq(8b) 0.09 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.89 0.41 0.13 0.96 0.99 0.07 0.01 0.39 0.99 0.80 0.77 0.87 0.99 0.00 0.00 0.32 0.96 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.21 0.00 0.10 0.40 Inflation: Eq(8b) 0.99 0.27 0.27 0.70 Canada-U.S. inflation diff.: Eq(8b) 0.81 0.00 0.69 0.73 44 Table 4 The ARCH Models of Volatility of Stock Market Returns and Macro-variables Sample Period: 1975:1-1999:12 (Note the first two years were reserved for lags). *The robust-error regression estimation technique (White, 1980; and Hansen,1982) was used to correct for heteroskedasticity. σ tx 12 = ∑ δ ixσ tx-i 12 + i =1 ∑η x i M t -i + vt (9) i =1 X F-test: (p-value) Null:δ1x=...=δ12x=0 F-test: ( p-value) Null:η1=...=η12 R2 Return TSE* 0.00 0.00 0.63 Return S&P 0.03 0.33 0.21 Growth rate: total indus. prod.* 0.00 0.00 0.61 Growth rate: commodity price 0.48 0.29 0.63 U.S.-Canada indus. prod. growth rate diff.* 0.33 0.39 0.61 Growth of exchange rate 0.74 0.27 0.59 Canadian overnight rate* 0.00 0.02 0.57 Canada-U.S. overnight rate diff.* 0.00 0.12 0.62 Premium* 0.00 0.00 0.58 Inflation 0.00 0.10 0.59 Canada-U.S. inflation diff.* 0.01 0.09 0.58 45 Table 5 Diagnosis tests of the estimation of Equation (9) Godfrey White ARCH RESET X (p-value) (p-value) (p-value) (p-value ) Return TSE 0.99 0.04 0.39 0.02 Return S&P 0.99 0.39 0.55 0.72 Growth rate: total indus. prod. 0.99 0.00 0.00 0.00 Growth rate: commodity 0.99 0.83 0.68 0.04 U.S.-Canada indus. prod. growth rate diff. 0.99 0.06 0.03 0.75 Growth of exchange rate 0.99 0.97 0.91 0.98 Canadian overnight rate 0.99 0.00 0.14 0.00 Canada-U.S. overnight rate diff. 0.99 0.00 0.00 0.00 Premium 0.99 0.01 0.99 0.18 Inflation 0.99 0.93 0.99 0.22 Canada-U.S. inflation diff. 0.99 0.00 0.73 0.08 46 Table 6 Summary of statistics of conditional volatility of the stock returns and macro-variables a. SK is skewness, KU is kurtosis and JB is Jarque-Bera normality test. Sample Period: 1975:11999:12 (Note the first two years were reserved for lags). ** vtse is the conditional volatility of monthly return of TSE 300, vsp is the conditional volatility of monthly return of S&P 500-stock index, vindp is the conditional volatility of the monthly growth of total industrial production, vcomp is the conditional volatility of the monthly growth of commodity price index, vrindpcus is the conditional volatility of the monthly growth of the ratio of industrial production in Canada and U.S., vex is the conditional volatility of the monthly growth of the exchange rate, vonr is the conditional volatility of the Canadian overnight rate, vronff is the conditional volatility of the difference between the Canadian overnight and Fed Fund rates, vcpic is the conditional volatility of the monthly change of the log of Consumer Price Index in Canada, vrcp is the conditional volatility of the monthly change of the log of the ratio of Canada to U.S. consumer price indexes and vprem is the conditional volatility of the monthly corporate rate less T-bill rate. Variable Mean Standard SKa KUa JBa Deviation (p-value for (p-value for (sig. lev.for SK=0) KU=0) JB=0) vtse 0.04 0.01 0.48 -0.11 11.13 (0.00) (0.71) (0.00) . vsp 0.04 0.01 vindp 0.01 0.00 vcomp 0.02 0.00 vrindpcus 0.01 0.00 vex 0.01 0.00 vonr 0.01 0.00 vronff 0.01 0.00 vcpic 0.002 0.00 vrcp 0.003 0.00 vprem 0.002 0.00 0.33 (0.02) 1.46 (0.00) 0.42 (0.00) 0.18 (0.23) 0.28 (0.06) 1.68 (0.00) 1.91 (0.00) 0.95 (0.00) 0.72 (0.00) 1.11 (0.00) 0.21 (0.47) 4.43 (0.00) -0.07 (0.83) 0.004 (0.99) -0.18 (0.55) 3.86 (0.00) 4.69 (0.00) 1.33 (0.00) 0.47 (0.11) 2.92 (0.00) 5.58 (0.05) 324 (0.00) 8.49 (0.01) 1.46 (0.48) 4.04 (0.13) 300 (0.00) 420 (0.00) 62.16 (0.00) 26.3 (0.00) 155 (0.00) 47 Table 7* Stationary Tests: 1975 (Jan.) - 1999 (Dec.) * All tests include constant and trend. The critical value for Augmented Dickey-Fuller τ test (lag-length = 5) and for Phillips-Perron non-parametric Z test (window size = 4) is 3.42 at 5% and 3.98 at 1%. ** vtse is the conditional volatility of monthly return of TSE 300, vsp is the conditional volatility of monthly return of S&P 500-stock index, vindp is the conditional volatility of the monthly growth of total industrial production, vcomp is the conditional volatility of the monthly growth of commodity price index, vrindpcus is the conditional volatility of the monthly growth of the ratio of industrial production in Canada and U.S., vex is the conditional volatility of the monthly growth of the exchange rate, vonr is the conditional volatility of the Canadian overnight rate, vronff is the conditional volatility of the difference between the Canadian overnight and Fed Fund rates, vcpic is the conditional volatility of the monthly change of the log of Consumer Price Index in Canada, vrcp is the conditional volatility of the monthly change of the log of the ratio of Canada to U.S. consumer price indexes and vprem is the conditional volatility of the monthly corporate rate less T-bill rate. Absolute Values Variables Augmented Dickey-Fuller τ-stat. Phillips-Perron Z-stat. 4.39 7.54 8.74 6.91 6.39 11.26 3.78 3.50 6.03 4.36 6.30 17.68 18.78 9.77 16.06 17.18 12.85 10.17 8.44 12.82 16.10 13.75 Volatilities:** vtse vsp vindp vcomp vrindpcus vex vonr vronff vcpic vrcp vprem 48 Table 8* GLS Estimation Results of Conditional Volatility Model * Period=1975(Jan.)-1999(Dec.), Mean of Dep. Variable=0.04, R 2=0.71, σ=0.008, DW=1.99, Godfrey(5)=1.25 (significance level=0.28), White=140 (significance level=0.09), ARCH(5)=15.27 (significance level=0.23), RESET=1.56 (significance level=0.20), and Normality(χ2=2)=7.00 (significance level=0.03). ** Feb, Apr and Dec are dummy variables for the month of February, April and December, respectively. For the description of the remaining mnemonics see notes of Table 7. Dependent Variable = vtset Variable** Coefficient Standard Error Hansen’s (1992) Stability Li test (5% critical value = 0.47) vindpt-1 0.68 0.21 0.09 vindpt-2 0.56 0.22 0.11 vext 0.52 0.17 0.09 vcompt-2 0.21 0.10 0.11 vcompt -3 -0.29 0.09 0.12 vonrt-2 -0.52 0.10 0.10 vpremt-1 2.18 0.54 0.09 vronfft 0.27 0.08 0.05 vronfft-4 0.24 0.08 0.02 vcpict-1 -1.75 0.56 0.04 vtset-2 0.41 0.05 0.11 vtset-3 0.20 0.04 0.06 vtset-4 0.18 0.05 0.04 vtset-6 -0.23 0.04 0.05 Feb 0.01 0.002 0.29 Apr 0.02 0.002 0.20 Dec -0.01 0.002 Hansen’s (1992) Stability Li test on Variance of the Equation Joint (coefficients and the error variance) Hansen’s (1992) Lc test (5% critical value=4.14 for degrees of freedom=18) 0.06 0.24 3.39 49 Table 9* GLS Estimation Results of Superexogeneity Tests * vex is the conditional volatility of the monthly growth of the exchange rate, vronff is the conditional volatility of the difference between the Canadian overnight and Fed Fund rates, ηZ is the conditional mean of Z, σZZ is the conditional variance of Z, and DevZ is the deviation of variance of the error term from a five-period ARCH error of Z. ** vtset = α0 + ψ0 Zt + (δ0 - ψ0) (Zt - ηZt) + δ1 σtZZ (Zt - ηZt) + ψ1 (ηZt)2 + ψ2 σtZZ + ψ3 σtZZ ηZt + ψ4 σtZZ (ηZt)2 +z’tγ + ut F-statistics (p-value) Variable (Z)** vex vronff Z- ηZ 0.60 2.53 (0.43) (0.11) σZZ (Z - ηZ) 0.19 333.31 (0.66) (0.00) (ηZ)2 0.09 0.78 (0.79) (0.38) σZZ 10.14 2.67 (0.00) (0.10) σZZ ηZ 13.62 12.51 (0.00) (0.00) σZZ (ηZ)2 15.55 15.17 (0.00) (0.00) DevZ 1.30 0.07 (0.26) (0.79) F-statistics on null hypothesis that coefficients of all constructed variables in this column are jointly zero. The equation includes the constructed variables related to other contemporaneous variables. 29.88 356.28 (0.00) (0.00) F-statistics on null hypothesis that coefficients of all constructed variables in this column are jointly zero. The equation excludes the constructed variables related to other contemporaneous variables. 14.72 326.43 (0.04) (0.00) F statistics on coefficients of all variables in rows and 386.27 columns (0.00)