What Can the Price Gap Between Branded and Generic Tell Us About Markups? Robert Barsky, University of Michigan and NBER Mark Bergen, University of Minnesota Shantanu Dutta, University of Southern California Daniel Levy, Emory University Very Preliminary Draft For Presentation at the Conference on Income and Wealth, Scanner Data and Price Indexes. September 15-16, 2000 The authors would like to thank Ning Liu for her outstanding research assistance, Susanto Basu, Kai-Uwe Kuhn, Jim Levinsohn, Steve Salant, Mathew Shapiro for many helpful discussions, and Steve Hoch for access to his survey on national brand/private label quality differences, and both the University of Chicago for access to the data. Abstract In this paper we investigate the size of markups for nationally branded products sold in the U.S. retail grocery industry. Our approach to estimating these markups is to treat the price of the comparable private label product as an upper bound for the marginal costs faced by the branded manufacturer. Using scanner data from a large Midwestern grocery chain we estimate the markup ratios for over 200 products in 19 categories. This data includes not only the prices and quantities sold by UPC, but also the retailers’margins on each product, which allows us to measure the markup ratios for national brands based on wholesale rather than retail prices. We find that markup ratios measured this way range from 2.5 for crackers and 2.3 in the analgesics category to 1.2 in canned tuna, with the majority of categories in the range 1.4 to 1.7. These data also allow us to measure retailer’s markups over wholesale costs. We find that retailer’s markups are generally lower for nationally branded products than for private labels. The net effect of this is that markup ratios measured using only retail price data will understate the markups for nationally branded products. I. Introduction The magnitude of marginal costs and markups over marginal cost are empirical questions of considerable general interest in economics. Microeconomists are interested in markups because they bear on such questions as the relevance of alternative models of imperfect competition, the welfare consequences of market power, and the benefits of new product introduction. In recent macroeconomic research as well, markups play a central role. Although macroeconomic discourse most often focuses on the cyclicality rather than the level of markups, the degree of cyclicality is often limited by the absolute size of the markup (Rotemberg and Saloner 1986). The estimation of markups is difficult because of the unobservability of marginal cost. There are essentially two ways in which inference about markups and marginal cost is approached in the econometric literature. One approach is via the cost function, which is either inferred directly from engineering data or estimated from cross-sectional or time series market data. The other is to estimate consumer demand functions, and compute the markup based on estimated demand elasticities. This paper takes a quite different approach to the estimation of marginal costs and markups. We take the price of a “private label” equivalent or near-equivalent product as a proxy for marginal cost. Since the private label product would not be sold at less than its marginal cost, and if the two products are produced under sufficiently similar conditions, then the ratio of the price of the branded product to that of the private label would serve as a lower bound for the markup ratio for the branded product1. Roughly speaking, the story we tell is the following. Private label products are physically identical to nationally branded products, but because “brands” appears in the utility function, the branded product commands a higher market price. At the same time, however, many of the promotional expenses which vertically differentiate the branded product from its private label counterpart appear largely as sunk or at least fixed costs, marginal production costs of private label products are therefore not systematically lower 1 This appraoch has been used informally in the past. The text by Carlton and Perlof (1994) and a recent paper by Nevo (1997) applies this method in passing for breakfast cereals, although its principal content lies elsewhere. than marginal costs for branded products. The high ratio of branded price to private label price is thus indicative of substantial markups. On average, markups estimated in this manner are on the high side of, though consistent with, those found in previous studies. For the national brands with the highest visibility or brand capital, markups are particularly large, on the order of 100%. We apply this approach to products in the grocery industry. This is an appropriate place to apply this measure because there are many “private label” products in a wide variety of categories. Perhaps it is best to begin with a brief historical account of private labels in this industry. Fitzell (1998), in his book on private labels, recounts that "private labels in the grocery segment evolved out of bulk commodity staples, first into packaged teas, sugar, flour, spices, etc. Early in this century, private label development was expanded further into canned vegetables and fruits, frozen foods, and bakery and dairy products. Other product categories followed: paper products, detergents, deli items, soft drinks, health and beauty care products, general merchandise, and perishables such as meats, poultry and produce … With few exceptions, the packaged goods product mix has been the central focus of private label business in the retail store … The parameters for private label have been extended virtually into every product category found in retail outlets. Private label has tapped into untouchable product categories of the recent past: cosmetics, baby food, natural health products, gourmet delicacies, etc." It is important to note that the products sold under the private label of Dominick’s finer foods are not generics, and are in fact labeled in a way which provides some, but not all, of the functions of branding. The particular version of branding that Dominick’s offers substantially reduces uncertainty about the quality of the product, in particular concerns that the store brand may exhibit physical inferiority. Further, there are reasons to believe that private labels make a reasonable proxy for the marginal costs of nationally branded products. First, we were able to access a survey of quality assurance managers at the top 50 retail grocery chains from retailers where they rate the quality comparability of private labels and national brands. Although this varies by category, this survey suggests that on the whole private labels are fairly comparable. This is consistent with the prevailing wisdom in consumer reports and other sources in the business and trade press. Second, in discussions with private label managers it was their belief that the production costs of nationally branded products would be the same or higher for comparable private label products. This was due to the size and scale advantages national brands have in terms of packaging, production and input prices. Third, private labels have the same sources of marginal costs as national brands, and differ in areas that are related to more fixed costs, in this industry. Specifically private labels do not spend as significantly on R&D and advertising as national brands do. Their costs are almost completely made up of production, packaging and distribution costs. We compute this mark ups using scanner data.2 The grocery industry has scanner data available to make these estimates for a wide variety of products and categories. Additionally, the Dominick’s dataset we use in this paper has the unique feature of incorporating retail margins as used by managers making the pricing decisions at this chain. Thus, we are able to report markups based on the wholesale prices received by nationally branded manufacturers as well as the markups retailers receive on both nationally branded and private label products. This allows us to decompose the markups that can be calculated from retail prices into the different participants in the channel of distribution. In section V we report these markups for over 200 nationally branded products in 19 product categories (see tables 1 - 23). The paper is structured as follows. In the next section introduces our data and empirical methods. We proceed to present “markup” data, at both the wholesale and retail levels, for a wide range of products for which both national brand and private label prices are available. We discuss the implications of these results in the conclusion. II. Inferring Marginal Cost and Markups From Private Labels Our method to measure markups relies on the assumption that we can use the price of private labels to infer the marginal production cost of national brands. Since the generic would not be sold at less than its marginal cost, the price gap can thus be seen as a lower bound on the markup on the brand-name version. The natural question that arises is when 2 This data set has been used to study economic issues by authors including (Chevalier et. al. 2000; Muller et. al 2000; Bergen et. al. 1998; Dutta et. al 1999). is it okay to treat the brand and the generic as equivalent products, for the sake of inferring marginal cost. At a broad level, we know these are different goods by virtue of their carrying a different brand name and that customers pay different prices for them. Thus, the principal issues involve finding out how the branded products are different from the private labels. To the degree that there are not substantial differences in terms of variable costs, and the differences relate to fixed costs, we are on safe ground using our measure of markups. To the degree that the differences are in terms of variable costs borne by branded manufacturers, then our measure may be overestimating markups and would be less appropriate. In this industry there are two major sources of differences that could be variable cost in nature: 1) private label goods are inferior products produced by lower cost methods (the “physical quality” issue) and 2) even if the private label product is physically comparable to the nationally branded version, the expense of advertising, and otherwise promoting the national brand must be taken account of, and these may create additional marginal costs for national brands (the “marketing cost” objection). In this section we present the evidence we have found which suggests that, in fact, it is reasonable to assume that the differences between national brands and private labels are not likely to be variable costs for many products sold in this industry. We are still in the process of gathering additional evidence at the level of particular product categories or national brand/private label pairs to better understand exactly where this assumption is appropriate in this industry. Finally, we should mention that this is a conservative assumption for many nationally branded products in this context because private label manufacturers also have a markup that is not considered in our analysis, which will only cause our measure to understate markups. With these caveats in mind, we now turn to each issue in more detail. A. The Physical Quality Issue We began our process by going to the field and interviewing a number of industry experts on private labels. Their sense was that for products of equal quality, the costs of producing private labels were likely to be the same, or perhaps higher, than for national brands. One manager put it best when he said, "national brands should be able to physically produce at a lower cost … they are able to negotiate lower costs on components and vertically integrate to do processes themselves rather than having to buy at higher marginal costs." (VP private label food broker) Quality This suggests that the first thing we have to find out is whether private labels in this industry are indeed of similar quality, and if so which ones are more reasonable to use in our study. Hoch and Banerji (1993), noting the absence of secondary data source on private label quality comprehensive enough to cover all the SAMI product categories3, undertook a survey of quality assurance managers at the fifty largest supermarket chains and grocery wholesalers in the United States (according to Thomas Food Industry Register). The companies were widely dispersed across the country. These managers typically have graduate education in food science and have wide experience testing numerous product categories. Hoch and Banerji contacted each of these managers by telephone to solicit their participation, and followed up with a questionnaire. Thirty-two people (64%) returned the survey, resulting in twenty-five usable sets of responses (50%). The results reported are the average of these responses. For each of the original SAMI categories the experts were asked: “How does the quality of the best private label supplier compare to the leading national brands in the product category?”4 The respondents gave a rating on a five point scale where using a one suggests that private labels are much worse in quality than the national brands while using a 5 suggests that these experts think that the private label quality is comparable to that of the national brand. Since their primary focus lay elsewhere, Hoch and Banerji did not report the raw data from the quality survey. However, these authors graciously supplied us with the means of 3 For example, Consumer Reports typically review consumer packaged goods less than once per issue, therefore it does not have quality ratings of all the products that we have in the data set. 4 The experts received a one-page set of instructions explaining what we meant by each question and how to use the scales. The question on quality measures the retailer's ability to procure high-quality private labels. This was meant to capture "objective" quality rather than quality as perceived by customers. their survey-based quality rating for each of the categories that we examine in the Dominick’s data, and we report these in Exhibit 1. Exhibit 1: Product Category Ratings by Category* Product Category Ratings on quality of Private Label Analgesics 4.8 Toothbrushes 4.7 Frozen Juices 4.7 Cereals 4.7 Oatmeals 4.7 Crackers 4.6 Cheeses 4.6 Frozen Entrees 4.6 Canned Tuna 4.5 Fabric Softeners 4.5 Bottled Juices 4.5 Laundry Detergents 4.4 Snack Crackers 4.4 Cookies 4.3 Grooming Products 4.3 Dish Detergents 4.2 Toothpastes 4.2 Canned Soup 4.1 Bathroom Tissues 4.1 Soft Drinks 4.0 *We thank Steve Hoch for providing us this data. At the same time, the survey does have some limitations. Hoch and Banerji (1993) mention that “it is most likely that the experts were partisan to private labels” since “one aspect of their jobs involves monitoring and improving private label quality”. In order to check whether there was any serious bias in the ratings they received, they went through each issue of consumer reports for the past 6 years and found evaluations of 36 of the same product categories rated by the quality control experts. For each of these categories the consumer report provides rank order quality information for leading national brands and some selected private labels. They find that the ratings from the managers were highly correlated to those in the consumer report where available. Thus the ratings seem to be a reasonable indicator of the private label quality relative to the national brands. Hoch and Banerji’s (1993, p. 62) own evaluation of the evidence is that “the over riding sentiment of these experts was that quality of the best private label was quite close to that of the national brands”. This is consistent with industry observers (e.g. Quelch 1996; Fitzell 1998) who suggest that while over the long haul private label products have not consistently exhibited the uniformly high quality standards as national brands, in recent years private label products have significantly improved in quality and packaging enhancements, making them comparable to the national brands. The comparability of private label quality in these categories is also reinforced by another survey that asks consumers about their perception of quality premium that national brands offer relative to private labels (Sethuraman and Cole 1997). This study finds consumers are willing to pay a price premium for national brands even though they are aware that the price premiums do not reflect corresponding quality differences. It is important to stress that the label “Dominick’s Finer Foods” is in itself a kind of branding which differentiates the supermarket chain’s products from true generics. The very particular sort of branding Dominicks and other supermarket chain makes no attempt to provide the utility-yielding associations that is the object of much national advertising. It may, however, do a very good job of assuring physical quality. Fitzell( 1998, p. 126), states that “Private label owners did not compromise on quality because they could not afford to put a store name or their own brand name on a product that would be noted as inferior”. The private label manufacturers association web site also echoes this sentiment. It states, “Store brands consist of the same or comparable ingredients as the national brands and because the store's name or symbol is on the package, the consumer is assured that the product is manufactured to the store's quality standards and specifications.” Use of name such as Dominick’s serves a bonding function: if one good (or the services of one store) proves to be dangerous or unpalatable, there is a spillover on the credibility of all goods and all stores carrying that label. Finally, we can use Hoch and Banerji’s private label quality ratings to identify categories where quality differences are more likely so that we can learn whether the quality differences are likely to be related to lower variable costs or not. To that end we did further study of the two product categories that were lowest on Hoch and Banerji’s survey that were also available from the Dominick’s data, toilet paper and soft drinks. Toilet Paper This was one of the lowest rated categories in terms of quality comparability. Thus the higher markups may, in this category, represent true input quality differences and therefore differences in marginal costs. We were fortunate enough to have a recent consumer reports on toilet paper, and a recent economic article by Hausman (1999) on the category as well. Both of these, as well as a survey of consumer perceptions by Sethuraman and Cole (1997), reinforced the belief that this category does indeed have significant quality variation. The consumer reports article reported studies of many products that ranged broadly from ultra plush Charmin to low quality private labels products and Scott tissue. Hausman (1999) echoes the claim that some brands are of low quality while others are of high quality. And Sethuraman and Cole (1997) find that consumers rate toilet paper as one of the two product categories for which the quality gap as perceived by consumers is highest. Further, Hausman (1999) suggests that this is due to real differences in input quality in the pulp used to make the paper, which is likely to lead to higher costs for higher quality branded manufacturers in this category. We thought this might allow us to compare the private label Scott, but Scott turns out to have many more sheets per role than the private label, making it possible that Scott faces higher costs because of the additional sheets, even if the input costs are the same or lower. In the end this additional information led us to drop the toilet paper category from our paper (even though the markups in the category averaged above 2.0). We were not able to find national brand/private label pairs that were of comparable quality and were sure to be the same or lower cost for the national brand to produce. Soft Drinks According to our quality experts, soft drinks are one of the least comparable in terms of quality based on quality control manger’s perceptions. To the degree that the quality differences relate to cost savings for the private label, this would inflate our markup estimates. Yet to the degree that the differences in quality are in terms of taste or other inputs into the syrup to make the soft drinks, then it is unlikely to relate to substantial differences in costs. Unlike toilet paper, we decided to keep soft drinks in this paper because we felt the sources of quality differences we not likely to be related to the marginal costs faced by soft drinks manufacturers. In this category the majority of the costs are bottling and distribution. The cost of the syrup is only a very small proportion of the cost of producing soft drinks. Types of Private Label Manufacturers The second issue our field work suggested was that national brand manufacturers would be able to produce similar quality products at the same or lower prices than private label manufacturers. To check this we started at the web page of the Private Labels Manufacturers Association asserts that private label manufactures fall into four classifications. They are: 1) Large national brand manufacturers that utilize their expertise and excess plant capacity to supply store brands. 2) Small, quality manufacturers who specialize in particular product lines and concentrate on producing store brands almost exclusively. Often these companies are owned by corporations that also produce national brands. 3) Major retailers and wholesalers that own their own manufacturing facilities and provide store brand products for themselves. 4) Regional brand manufacturers that produce private label products for specific markets. Clearly in (1) the branded manufacturer has similar variable costs because it uses the same production facilities and comparable products. To the degree that private labels come from sources like (1), branded manufacturers using the same plant, and they produce essentially identical products with the same inputs, it seems reasonable to assume that the variable costs are likely to be the same. This is not uncommon in the grocery industry. The first firm to do this was Borden in the pasta category (Fitzell, 1998). There are many branded manufacturers doing this with products in our sample as well. The scanner data set does not identify them, and at the present time we have not been able to identify which national brand/private label pairs are produced by the same manufacturer. But if we are able to identify such products we will report them as such in future drafts of the paper. In (2), those smaller manufacturers who are owned by corporations that also produce national brands are likely to share the same productions expertise and processes making it reasonable to assume similar production costs for comparable products. In (3) the costs of production are likely to be the same or higher for private label producers because they do not produce the product in the same scale as nationally branded products. Supermarket chains in the United States are regional, limiting the size and scale they can achieve relative to “national” brands that sell in all of the major supermarket chains. That leaves us with (4) the regional brands and some of (2) manufacturers who are not owned by nationally branded manufacturers. Essentially because of the scale and negotiation power of branded manufacturers, they are able to produce the products at the same, or more likely lower prices than store brands. National brands have purchasing power for raw ingredients, packaging materials, etc. In general, private label manufacturers are smaller, more regional and more fragmented than their nationally branded counterparts. For example, Fitzell (1998, p.126) states that “In the evolution of private label into different product categories, the trend in the United States was more toward smaller manufacturers/processors, leaving the national brand business, with its high costs of product development and marketing, to the larger manufacturers.” As another example consider a TOPCO pamphlet which describes its buying programs [TOPCO handles distribution for what is perhaps the largest generics program in the country] states that although some of its “sources are large enough to produce and market products successfully under their own brands In many cases, however, they are small and medium sized producers who do not have the financial strength or organization to market their own brand products effectively in competition with giant competitors.” (Fitzell 1998). This value of size for national brands has been noted in academic research studies as well. For example, Schmalensee (1978) has shown that national brands benefit from the substantial economies of scale in production and advertising that accrue through national distribution in the cereal category. Likewise Brown (199?) has shown that larger buyers can receive substantial quantity discounts on their purchases. B. The Marketing Cost Issue The second major source of differences between national brands and private labels is in terms of marketing costs. Industry sources indicate that in general private label manufacturers do far less in terms of R&D, advertising, trade promotion and consumer promotion than national brands. For example, Fitzell (1998, p.126) states that national brand businesses have “high costs of product development and marketing” This leaves us with the remaining question of how large these costs are and whether they are fixed or variable costs in nature. We argue that R&D is a fixed cost, and that national advertising is predominantly a fixed cost. This leaves trade promotion spending and consumer promotion spending as possible variable cost differences we must consider. Notice that the largest effect of both trade promotions and consumer promotions is the reduced price the manufacturer receives from the promotions. Thus they aren’t marginal cost differences, but adjustments to the prices the manufacturer receives that we must consider. There are additional costs of implementing the promotional programs that we should also consider. Research & Development R&D is one area where private labels and national brands differ substantially. Fitzell (1982) states that “private label manufacturers budgets for research and development, however, usually fall far short of the national brand manufacturers”. While managers of national brands see these kinds of expenditures as critical to maintaining their brand equity. Quelch and Harding state that "Brand equity – the added value that a brand-name gives to the underlying product – must be carefully nurtured by each successive brand manager. Managers must continually monitor how consumers perceive the brand. Consistent, clear positioning – supported by periodic product improvements that keep the brand contemporary without distorting its fundamental promise – is essential. For example, Proctor and Gamble Company has made 70 separate improvements to Tide laundry detergent since its launch in 1956, but the brand's core promise that it will get clothes cleaner than any other product has never been compromised. Consistent investment in product improvements enhances a brand's perceived superiority … ". Clearly R&D spending for new product development is not marginal for products being sold in grocery chains. According to Monroe (1990), as well as many other authors, research and development costs "do not vary with the (sales) activity level" and are "not easily traceable to a product or segment" and thus should be treated as fixed from our perspectives. Advertising Advertising spending is another major difference between national brands and private labels. National brands invest substantial amounts of money in advertising. For example, in the Survey of Leading National Advertisers in Advertising Age magazine (2000), they report that advertising spending for major brands is substantial. Futher, many brands have been doing this for many years. "The strongest national brands have built their consumer equities over decades of advertising … " (Quelch and Harding, 1996). In fact, these authors go on to state that restrictions on television advertising help explain the strength of private labels in Europe relative to in the United States - “Of course, the reasons for the strength of private labels in Europe are partly structural. First, regulated television markets mean that cumulative advertising for name brands has never approached U.S. levels" (Quelch and Harding, 1996). This has not been true for most private labels. "Private label owners could not afford the expense of building their own brand equity through multi-million dollar advertising campaigns”(Fitzell 1998). In particular, for the retailer we are studying they did not invest anywhere near these amounts, even on a per unit sold or sales basis, on advertising to build brands. The question then is whether it is more reasonable to treat advertising expenditures by manufacturers as a fixed cost or variable cost. If we suppose for a moment that the branded variant is heavily advertised while the private label version is not, the average cost of a unit sold (which includes costs incurred by the "marketing department" in addition to those of the "production department") would be higher for the branded product. The question then becomes whether advertising should be seen as a marginal cost (as opposed to a fixed or sunk cost). The best evidence we could find on this question in the literature is from the Cox Annual Survey of Promotional Practices (1996). It surveys consumers, packaged goods manufacturers and grocery retailers on issues on promotion practice and usage. Specifically "the packaged goods manufacturer questionnaire was sent to 136 executives, yielding thirty-two usable replies, for a completion rate of 24%. Fact gathering was conducted from September 5, 1995 through November 17, 1995. The distribution of the packaged goods manufacturer responses, based on self-reported major company product category, is as follows: foods, 59%; household products, 3%; soft drinks and candy, 6%; health and beauty care, 21%; drug and remedies, 3% and other 8%. Of the respondents, 34% represent larger firms/divisions (annual sales = $1 billion plus) and 66% are smaller firms/divisions (annual sales = less than $1 billion)." When asked about national advertising, they state that they view their advertising expenses as mostly aimed at building brand equity, which is more of a fixed or long run cost. In 1995 packaged goods manufacturers believe that at least 66% of their advertising spending was meant to build their brand equity only. Of the remaining 34%, 14% was both brand equity and consumer promotions, 7% was both brand equity and trade promotions, and the remaining 13% was brand equity, trade and consumer promotions. So we might be able to argue that up to 80% of advertising is related to brand equity (since it is part of all answers). Specifically they asked packaged goods manufacturers the "share of media advertising programs used to support/build brand equity, consumer and trade promotions". There are academic authors in this area who also believe that advertising by national brands is a fixed, rather than variable, cost. Morton and Zettelmeyer (2000) state that there is a "difference in fixed costs between national and store brands. The advertising required to support national brands implies that national brand manufacturers have average costs that are substantially higher than their marginal costs of production." Trade Promotions Manufacturers also invest heavily in trade promotions. In the Cox survey they report some industry averages on how firms in the grocery industry allocate their promotional dollars. It looks to be about 50% trade promotions, 25% national advertising and 25% consumer promotions. So trade promotions are the largest component of manufacturer spending. Private label manufacturers do not undertake nearly as much trade spending, so this is another major difference between national brands and private labels. Fortunately the Dominick’s data already incorporates some of the trade spending in its wholesale prices, so we have already taken part of manufacturer’s trade promotion spending into account in our estimates of national brand markups. It is likely that there are trade promotions that are not captured in the wholesale prices in our data. These are most likely lumpy payments such as slotting allowances, cooperative advertising allowances, and various case discounts and spiffs the manufacturer gives to the retailer. To the degree that they are lumpy, and not incorporated into the wholesale price that retailers are using in their pricing decisions, however, it is not clear that these expenses are truly variable. So these unreported trade expenditures may not be as relevant as the trade promotions incorporated into the data we use in this paper. But to the degree that the unreported trade spending is variable, and substantial, our measure of markups will be overstated. Consumer Promotions This is also a major difference between national brands and private labels. Private labels tend to not coupon or promote to consumers. While branded manufacturers spend, on average, 25% of their promotional expenses on consumer promotions. That is about on par with the amount spent on national advertising. These activities are likely to be either reductions in the price manufacturers receive (as with redeemed coupons) or variable expenses to run the promotion. Although scanner data sets often include measures of coupon use, that is not true in this data set. Thus our data has not taken these price reductions or expenditures into account at this time. We are trying to get information on consumer promotions by category or product wherever possible so that we can factor this into our measures of markup. To give the reader some sense of how important these may be by category, we report the percentage of sales made using a coupon for all the product categories in our paper in exhibit 2. Exhibit 2 Product Category % Dollars with Manufacturers Coupon Analgesics 10.6 Toothbrushes 12.5 Frozen Juices 1.7 – 5.9 Cereals 16.5 Oatmeals 9.9 Crackers 0.8 – 5.3 Cheeses 2.6 – 6.6 Frozen Entrees 2.5 – 16.5 Canned Tuna 0.6 Fabric Softeners 14.2 – 16.3 Bottled Juices 0.7-2.1 Laundry Detergents 14.0 Snack Crackers 6.4 Cookies 3.9 Grooming Products 9.4 Dish Detergents 12.3 Toothpastes 13.6 Canned Soup 6.5 Bathroom Tissues 4.8 Soft Drinks 2.2 th *From Supermarket Business 16 Annual Product Preference Study In sum, we believe there is enough evidence to suggest that using private label prices to infer national brand costs is a reasonable assumption in this industry. We are in the process of gathering additional evidence at a category and product level to check this assumption further, but there is reason to believe that this measure of markup can be appropriate for at least some categories and products in this industry. Further, since the private label will have some markup, and the nationally branded products have advantages on size and scale in production, packaging and negotiation on input prices we believe the use of private labels may actually be a conservative measure of these costs. III. Data The scanner data come from Dominick's Finer Food (DFF), which is one of the largest retail supermarket chains in the larger Chicago metropolitan area operating 94 stores. Large multi store U.S. Supermarket chains of this type made up about $310,146,666,000 in total annual sales in 1992, which was 86.3% of total retail grocery sales (Supermarket Business, 1993). In 1999 the retail grocery sales has reached $435 billion (Chevalier, Kashyap, and Rossi, 2000). Thus the chain we study is a representative of a major class of the retail grocery trade. Moreover, Dominick’s type multistore supermarket chains’sales constitute about 14 percent of the total retail sales of about $2,250 billion in the US. Thus the market we are studying has a quantitative economic significance as well. ((Since retail sales account for about 9.3 percent of the GDP, our data set is a representative of as much as 1.28 percent of the GDP, which seems substantial.)) The data consist of up to 400 weekly observations of actual transaction prices in 29 different categories, covering the period from September 14, 1989 to May 8, 1997. The data come from the store scanner data base which contain actual retail transaction prices of the products along with profit margin the supermarket makes on each one of them. From the information on retail prices and the profit margin, we have constructed the weekly time series of wholesale prices. The retail prices are the actual transaction prices: the price customers paid at the cash register each week. If the item was on sale, then the price data we have reflects the sale price. Although the retail prices are set on a chain-wide basis at the corporate headquarters of Dominick’s, there may still be some price variation across the stores depending on the competitive market structure in and around the location of the stores. For example, if a particular store of the chain is located in the vicinity of a Cub Food store, then the store may be designated a “Cub-fighter” and as such, it may pursue a more aggressive pricing policy in comparison to the stores located in other zones. The data we use are averaged across the stores of this chain.5 The wholesale price series, which measure the direct cost to the retailer, are computed by combining the retail price data with the information provided by the retailer on their weekly gross margins for each product and using the relation, wholesale price = (1 – gross margin %) multiplied by the retail price. The wholesale price DFF uses for computing their gross margin series is constructed by the retailer as a weighted average of the amount the retailer paid for all their inventory. For example, a profit margin of *25.3 means that DFF makes 25.3 cents on the dollar for each item sold which yields a cost of good sold of 74.7 cents. If the retailer bought its current stock of a Kellog’s Corn Flakes, 18oz, in two transactions, then its wholesale price is computed as the average of these two transaction prices (no FIFO or LIFO accounting rules are used in these computations).6 For the purpose of this study, we had to go through the entire DFF’s data set and identify pairs of national brand and private label products. Of the approximately 350 pairs we were able to locate in the 29 product categories, we have eliminated a portion of them because of substantial size differences. For example, if, say, in cereals category we compare Kellog’s Corn Flakes to DFF’s Corn Flakes, but the national brand comes in 32 oz box (which is a family size) while DFF’s product comes in 18 oz box, then this is not a good comparison since the two products are not really comparable as they are targeted to two different kinds of customers, and computing prices per oz would not eliminate this fundamental problem. Other pairs were eliminated because many non-private label brands 5 Our retail prices reflect any retailer’s coupons or discounts, but do not include manufacturer coupons. Further, none of these product categories are not used by Dominick’s as loss-leaders. 6 Thus, the wholesale costs in the data do not correspond exactly to the replacement cost or the last transaction price. Instead we have the average acquisition cost (ACC) of the items in inventory. So the supermarket chain sets retail prices for the next week and also determines AAC at the end of each week, t, according to the formula AAC(t+1) = (Inventory bought in t) Price paid(t) + (Inventory, end of t-l-sales(t)) AAC(t) There are two main sources of discrepancy between replacement cost and AAC. The first is the familiar one of sluggish adjustment. A wholesale price cut today only gradually works itself into AAC as old, higher priced inventory is sold off. The second arises from the occasional practice of manufacturers to inform the buyer in advance of an impending temporary price reduction. This permits the buyer to completely deplete inventory and then "overstock" at the lower price. In this case AAC declines did not really qualify as national brand products as these products are marketed only regionally (and some even locally only) or they did not have substantial market share. Still other pairs were eliminated because of our uncertainty about equality of their quality. Thus, the results we are reporting in the paper are for product pairs, such that (1) the national brand product is clearly marketed nationally, (2) the national brand products are widely recognized, (3) the national brand products have non-trivial market share, and (4) the pair of national brand – private label products are comparable in size and quality, as much as possible. The product pairs that pass these criteria represent 19 categories which include Analgesics, Bottled Juices, Cereals, Cheeses, Cookies, Crackers, Canned Soups, Dish Detergent, Frozen Entrees, Frozen Juices, Fabric Softeners, Grooming Products, Laundry Detergent, Oatmeal, Soft Drinks, Snack Crackers, Toothbrush, Tooth Pastes, and Canned Tuna.7 To compute the average markup figures for each category , which are reported in Tables 1–3, we had to compress the data by three different procedures of averaging. First, we have averaged all weekly price series across all the chain's stores to get a single weekly wholesale and retail price series for each of the national brand and private label products chosen for the analysis. This averaging was done by weighing the national brand and private label price series from each store according to the store's sales share in the total DFF's sale where the sales are measured by the weekly sales figures of the specific national brand and private label products, respectively. Since the scanner database does not include information on the quantities purchased at the wholesale level, we used the retail sales figures as its proxy. This procedure likely introduces a noise in the generated series because the retail sales are more spread over time in comparison to wholesale purchases which likely occur with lower frequency. The noise, however, will mostly affect the weekly volatility properties of the price series, but the average values are unlikely to be precipitously to the lower price and stays there until the large inventory acquired at that price runs off. Thus, the accounting cost shows the low price for some time after the replacement cost has gone back up. 7 Thus, in the remaining ten categories, which include Bath Soap, Beer, Cigarettes, Front-EndCandies, Frozen Dinners, Paper Towels, Refrigerated Juices, Shampoos, Soaps, and Bathroom Tissues, we were unable to find comparable national brand-private label pairs. affected from this procedure in a significant way. The purpose of the weighing procedure we have implemented is to ensure that the price series coming from the stores that sell proportionally more than others, receive higher weight. Next, we computed the weighted average weekly values of the above across-store weighted averaged series by taking each price series for the sample period it was available and computing its weekly average value by weighing each weekly observation according to the share of that week’s quantity sold in the total quantity sold over the entire sample period. As before, the purpose of this weighing is to give higher weight to observations (i.e., weeks) that represent higher sales volume measured in terms of products’quantity (such as oz’s). In each case the prices of national brand products were weighed using the sales volume of that specific national brand product while the price series of the private label products were correspondingly weighed by sales volume of the private label products. These series then were used to compute various markup measures reported in Tables A1.1–A19.2. It should be noted that an alternative way of computing these weekly average markup values for each national brand-private label product pair is to first compute weekly markup series for the entire sample period covered by each product pair and then compute their weekly weighted average using the procedure outlined above. Preliminary calculations performed using this procedure has so far yielded similar quantitative results in terms of average markup figures. This procedure, however, has the advantage that by first computing markups, that is, first computing ratios and then averaging them over time (instead of first averaging them over time and then computing the ratios) makes it possible to explore the time series variability in each individual markup series and perhaps also to provide some measure of over time variability associated with the markup. We are currently performing these calculations and the next revision of the manuscript will report the results. Finally, we have taken the above-calculated average markup figures for each product pair and computed the average markup for each of the 19 product categories included in our sample. As before, these category averages were also calculated as weighted averages. However, unlike the previous steps, here the weighing was done according to the share of the dollar value of the sales for each product pair in the dollar value of the total sales in the category. For example, if in the analgesics category we have 22 national brand-private label product pairs, to compute the category average markup, we took the markup figures for the 22 product pairs (listed in Table A1.1) and computed their weighted average, where the weights are the ratios of the total dollar sales of the pair to the total dollar sales in the category. The weights here use dollar sales rather than unit sales in order to avoid the problem of “adding apples to oranges.” The resulting category averages figures are reported in Tables 1–3. IV. Results The most unique aspect of our findings is that we can back out the wholesale prices paid by the retailer to manufacturers. This allows us to get a measure of markups for national brands based on the wholesale prices they receive from retailers. We report the results from these studies first in section IV.1. Then we report the retail markups on both national brands and private labels in section IV.2. Finally, in section IV.3 we present the markups for national brands had we used final retail prices, and discuss the advantages and disadvantages of using this as an estimate of markups based on lessons from our study. IV.1 Markup Ratios based on wholesale prices As seen by Table 1, the markups based on wholesale prices are generally large. These markup ratios are calculated by dividing the wholesale price of the national brands with the wholesale price of the comparable private label. For the product categories of analgesics, toothbrushes, and crackers the markups are higher than 2. This pushes the markup ratios to the range of substantial market power for national brands in these categories by Hall's (1986) definition. There are also a couple of product categories that are near 2, grooming products and fabric softeners. The rest of the product categories fall in the range of 1.4 to 1.6, which is some market power according to Hall (1986). These include oatmeal, cereals, bottled juices, cookies, frozen juices, canned soups, snack crackers, laundry detergents, soft drinks, dish detergents, and toothpaste. The remaining four categories cheeses, canned tuna, laundry detergent and frozen entrees are in the range of 1.2 to 1.3. It is interesting to note that our estimates for ready-to-eat breakfast cereals are very close to the price-cost margin of 50% found by Hausman (1997) using a sophisticated demand elasticity approach. Evidence from private label prices is consistent with the interpretation of branded breakfast cereals, along with a number of other heavily promoted products, as highly differentiated products with low demand elasticities. There are examples of large markups by brand within some categories that are interesting to consider. Tables A1 to A19 give the results by national brand/private label pair we report in the study. For example, looking at the specific markups by brand and type of soda we observe some interesting patterns. In the cola category we find that Coke and Pepsi both have markups near 2, averaging 1.9. While Royal Crown Cola has markups averaging 1.7, which is closer to the category average of 1.68. Thus, the more heavily branded and well known products are receiving higher markups in the category. Similarly for brands in the tonic water types of products, Schweppes, Seagrams and Canada Dry has markups of 1.82, 1.9 and 2.48 respectively. In analgesics we found the highest markups for children’s aspirin. In the Toothbrush category we see the highest markups for Reach and Crest, which are leading national brands. Followed by Pepsodent and Johnson & Johnson which are the next strongest brands, also receiving markups over 2, but still less than the Reach and Crest. Taken as a whole we see a great deal of evidence that there can be substantial wholesale markup ratios for nationally branded products in this industry. In category after category, brand after brand, we tend to find markups at least as high as 1.3 and more often in the 1.4 to 1.6 range. And we find many brands that are able to command markups of nearly 100% in many categories. IV.2 Retail markup ratios for private labels and national brands Table 2 shows the retailer’s markups for the private labels and national brands by category. We measured retail markup as the retail price of the product divided by the wholesale price of the product. Two themes seem to emerge from this table. First, in almost every category the retail markups are higher for private labels than national brands. Second, retail markups are generally lower for nationally branded products than nationally branded markups based on our estimates. An examination of Table 2 shows that the retailer’s markups for national brands range from 1.03 (cereals and laundry detergent) to 1.38 (toothbrushes). There are many products with markups less than 1.1, including the categories of analgesics, fabric softeners, dish detergents, and oatmeal. Most of the other categories fall below markups of 1.2, including the categories of bottled juice, cheese, cookies, crackers, toothpaste grooming products, frozen entrees, and canned tuna. The retailer’s markups for private label products are substantially higher, ranging from 1.07 in laundry detergents to 3.83 in toothbrushes. Only dish detergents, cereals and frozen entrees are below 1.2, the rest are higher and tend to be in the range of 1.2 to 1.5. Comparing the rows in Table 2 we see that the retailer’s markups for private labels are higher than their markups for national brands in every category except frozen entrees. In most categories the markup is higher by somewhere between .1 and .2. In some categories it is even higher, about .3 in analgesics and crackers, and much larger for toothbrushes. Thus we offer clear evidence that retailer’s markups are higher for private labels than national brands. This fact is well known in the trade. "The gap between marginal and average cost of national brands allows retailers to achieve higher price-cost margins than those earned with national brands. Industry observers, the popular press and academic work all indicate that this effect can be quite large" (Morton and Zettelmeyer, 2000). Hoch and Banerji (1993) state that "Industry sources suggest that retailer gross margins on private labels are 20% to 30% higher than on national brands." This is also consistent with differences between the United States and Europe. "In European supermarkets, higher private-label sales result in higher average pretax profits. U.S. supermarkets average only 15% of sales from private labels, they average 2% pre-tax profits from all sales. By contrast, European grocery stores such as Sainsbury's, with 54% of its sales coming from private labels, and Tesco, with 41%, average 7% pretax profits." (Quelch and Harding, 1996) Comparing Table 2 with Table 1 we see that the retailer’s markups in each category are lower than the manufacturer’s markups in every instance. For example, even in the case where nationally branded markups are low, such as canned tuna (1.23) and cheese (1.31), the corresponding retail markups are 1.14 and 1.17 respectively. The contrasts can be very large, with nationally branded markups being double or triple the markups of retailers for the same product. IV.3 Markup Ratios Based on Retail Prices Our original inspiration for using scanner data to study markups was based on the idea of using retail prices to infer markups for national brands. Anyone who walks the aisles of a supermarket and looks at the prices of national brands and private labels is sure to see some combinations which suggest that national brands must have substantial markups. Our most vivid example had one author buying cold remedies at the grocery store and being stunned by the markups for chemically identical offerings. Further, the authors who had suggested this approach in the past (Scherer 1980; Carlton and Perloff 1994) had focused on using retail prices to infer markups. The value of these estimates of markups is that retail prices are becoming more and more available with new technologies in computers, software, scanning and other systems being developed. Any markets where prices are posted or price data is systematically collected offers the possibility of using these kinds of measures to infer markups for nationally branded products. Further, this kind of price data is already public, so it is easier to gain access to. To get wholesale prices requires that the retailers give information on their costs or margins. Usually, wholesale price information is not part of publicly available scanner data sets. Most firms prefer to keep their margins private and proprietary. One of the unique advantages of the Dominick’s dataset is that the retailer in willing to share their margin, and therefore cost, data. Given the proprietary nature of costs and margins, it is important to assess how well markup estimates based on posted prices work as estimates of markups. Table 3 shows the markups for national brands in 19 categories based on the retail prices of nationally branded products and private labels. The markup estimates range from a high of 2.36 in toothbrushes to a low of 1.16 for canned tuna. The majority of the markups are below 1.4, with the only exceptions being cereal (1.45), razors (1.58), analgesics (1.64), fabric softeners, crackers (1.71) and cookies as well as the aforementioned toothbrushes. Overall, based on Hall’s ratings (1986), we would suggest there was some market power but not substantial market power in this data based on markups estimated from retail price data alone. In Figure 1 we report the markups in Table 1 and Table 3 together. Two insights emerge from figure 1. First, the markups based on wholesale prices are significantly larger than the markups based on retail prices. In general the markups increase by about .2 or more, depending on the product category. The increase is even larger in analgesics, crackers, grooming, and toothbrushes. The reason this occurs is that the retailer takes larger markups on private labels than on national brands, so that the retail prices understate the manufacturer markups in this industry by combining the pricing decision of both the retailer and the manufacturers in this measure. This suggests that one criterion for using retail prices to infer markup is that retailers have small markups in general to minimize this bias. Or that retailers have more uniform policies for markups on both national brands and private labels than in this industry. Also notice that the general order of which category has the highest markups is maintained estimating markups using retail prices rather than using wholesale prices. The highest markup categories such as analgesics are high using both measures. To the extent that the research question is about variation between markups rather than the absolute size of markups, this suggests that using retail prices may be appropriate for studying those questions. Overall, to the degree that the private label products are comparable, the differentiation between them and nationally branded products are based on fixed costs such as advertising or R&D, and the retail markups are small these may be a very useful proxy for markups in an industry. But the researcher should keep in mind that the retail markups are lower, so they may understate the markups in this industry. VI. Discussion and Conclusions In this paper we have investigated the size of markups for nationally branded products sold in the U.S. retail grocery industry. Our approach, which we hope will serve as a complement to more structural econometric approaches, treats the wholesale price of the comparable private label product as an upper bound on the marginal costs faced by the branded manufacturer. Using scanner data from a large Midwestern grocery chain, we have estimated the markup ratios for over 200 products in 19 categories. We found that markup ratios measured this way range from 2.5 for crackers and 2.3 in the analgesics category to 1.2 in canned tuna, with the majority of categories in the range 1.4 to 1.7. Our numbers are on the high side of, though consistent with, those in the existing literature. Our approach offers several benefits. Because it involves only a simple computation (once the data have been assembled), the method permits calculation of markups for a large variety of products. It is transparent and intuitive, and it offers a benchmark comparison for more structural approaches. Particularly in light of the importance of markups in recent macroeconomic discourse, one might ask whether the finding of high markups for heavily advertised differentiated products generalizes to the economy at large. In this direction, it is worth noting that even some “commodity” products such as aluminum and other producers’goods come in both branded and generic versions, and that the price gap for those products is comparable to that for the supermarket goods we have studied. This is also true for other consumer goods sold outside the supermarket industry, home and office supply products would be one example. References Bergen, Mark, Shantanu Dutta, and Daniel Levy (1998), “Heterogeneity in Price Rigidity: Evidence from Primary Micro-Level Data,” Working Paper, Emory University. Carlton, Dennis W. and Jeffrey M. Perloff (1994), Modern Industrial Organization (Harper Collins, NY). Chevalier Judith, Anil K. Kashyap and Peter E. Rossi (2000), “Why Don’t Prices Rise During Periods of Peak Demand ? Evidence From Scanner Data” Working Paper University of Chicago. Cox Eighteenth Annual Promotional Practice (1996) Dutta, Shantanu, Mark Bergen, and Daniel Levy (1998), “Price Flexibility in Channels of Distribution: Evidence From Scanner Data,” Working Paper. Fitzell, Philip (1982) Private Labels: Store Brands and Generic Products, AVI Publishing Company, Inc., Westport, Connecticut. Fitzell, Philip (1998) The Explosive Growth of Private Labels in North America, Global Books, LLC, New York. Hall, Robert E. (1988), “The Relation Between Price and Marginal Cost in U.S. Industry” Journal of Political Economy”, 96, 921-947. Hausman, Jerry A. (1997) “Valuation of New Goods Under Perfect and Imperfect Competition”, Timothy Bresnahan and Robert J. Gordon ed., The Economics of New Goods. Hausman, Jerry A. and Leonard Gregory K. (1999), “The Competitive Effect of a New Product Introduction: A Case Study”, MIT Working Paper Hoch, Steve, J. S. Kim, Alan Montgomery and Peter Rossi (1995) "Determinants of Store-Level Price Elasticity", Journal of Marketing Research, 32, February. Hoch and Banerji (1993) "When Do Private Labels Succeed?", Sloan Management Review, Summer. Hoch (1995) "How Should National Brands Think About Private Labels", Working Paper, University of Chicago. Monroe, Kent, E. (1990), A Guide to Strategic Pricing, Morton, Feona Scott and Florian Zettelmeyer (2000), “The Strategic Use of Store Brand In Retailer-Manufacturer Bargaining”, Working Paper, U.C. Berkeley Muller,Georg, Mark Bergen, Shantanu Dutta and Daniel Levy (2000), “Price Rigidity During Holiday Periods: The Role of Menu Costs,” Working Paper Nevo, Aviv (1997), “Demand For Ready to Eat Cereal and Its Implications For Price Competition, Merger Analysis and Valuation of New Brands” Harvard University PhD dissertation. Quelch, John A. and David Harding (1996) Harvard Business Review, Jan.-Feb., reprint #96109. Rotemberg, J. J., and Saloner G (1986), “A Supergame-Theoretic Model of Business Cycle and Price Wars During Booms”, American Economic Review, June, 76, 390-407. Scherer, F. M. (1980), Industrial Market Structure and Economic Performance, 2ed. Houghton-Mifflin, Boston. Schmalensee, Richard (1978), “Entry Deterrence In The Ready To Eat Breakfast Cereal Industry”, Bell Journal of Economics, 9, 305-327. Sethuraman, Raj and Catherine Cole (1997), “Why Do Consumers Pay More For National Brands than for Store Brands” Marketing Science Institute, Report # 97-126. Table 1. Average National Brand Markups Based on Wholesale Prices Product Category Average Markup Tooth Brushes 7.93 Crackers 2.53 Analgesics 2.34 Grooming Products 1.92 Fabric Softeners 1.77 Soft Drinks 1.68 Cookies 1.67 Oatmeals 1.55 Canned Soups 1.53 Cereals 1.49 Snack Crackers 1.49 Toothpastes 1.46 Dish Detergents 1.41 Frozen Juices 1.41 Bottled Juices 1.40 Cheeses 1.31 Laundry Detergents 1.26 Canned Tuna 1.23 Forzen Entrees 1.22 Table 2. Average Retailer Markups on National Brand and Private Label Average Markup on National Brand Average Markup on Private Label Tooth Brushes 1.38 3.83 Crackers 1.14 1.47 Analgesics 1.06 1.36 Grooming Products 1.12 1.37 Fabric Softeners 1.06 1.21 Soft Drinks 1.29 1.48 Cookies 1.13 1.30 Oatmeals 1.09 1.38 Canned Soups 1.29 1.43 Cereals 1.03 1.17 Snack Crackers 1.23 1.40 Toothpastes 1.12 1.28 Dish Detergents 1.07 1.14 Frozen Juices 1.31 1.46 Bottled Juices 1.13 1.23 Cheeses 1.17 1.29 Laundry Detergents 1.03 1.07 Canned Tuna 1.14 1.20 Forzen Entrees 1.18 1.15 Product Category Table 3. Average National Brand Markups Based on Retail Prices Product Category Average Markup Tooth Brushes 2.36 Crackers 1.98 Analgesics 1.72 Grooming Products 1.57 Fabric Softeners 1.56 Soft Drinks 1.45 Cookies 1.44 Oatmeals 1.24 Canned Soups 1.38 Cereals 1.32 Snack Crackers 1.24 Toothpastes 1.26 Dish Detergents 1.32 Frozen Juices 1.28 Bottled Juices 1.29 Cheeses 1.19 Laundry Detergents 1.20 Canned Tuna 1.16 Forzen Entrees 1.26 Table A1.1. Analgesics: National Brand Markup NB Markup Based on WP NB Markup Based on RP MOTRIN IB CAPLETS 1.61 1.46 MOTRIN IB 1.07 0.95 MOTRIN IB GELCAPS 1.89 1.63 TYLENOL INFANT DROPS 2.08 1.71 TYLENOL X/S CAPLET 2.75 2.19 TYLENOL X/S GELCAPS 1.90 1.73 CHILD CHEW GRAP TYLENOL 1.79 1.37 CHILD CHEW FRT TYLENOL 1.79 1.38 TYLENOL TABLETS REGULAR 2.35 1.86 TYLENOL X/S TABLETS 1.82 1.57 TYLENOL X/S TABLETS 1.16 1.01 TYLENOL X/S TABLETS 1.15 1.00 ADVIL 1.86 1.64 ADVIL CAPLETS 1.46 1.32 ANACIN-3 CHILDREN TABS 7.63 3.77 BAYER CHILD ASPIRIN 3.23 1.81 PANADOL CHILD TABS 6.73 3.51 EXCEDRIN IB TABS 50 1.94 1.67 EXCEDRIN IB TAB 100 1.51 1.39 EXCEDRIN IB CAPLETS 1.81 1.64 EXCEDRIN IB TABS 50 2.00 1.70 ALEVE CAPLETS 1.89 1.63 Weighted Average 2.34 1.72 Product Pair Table A1.2. Analgesics: Retailer’s Markup Retailer’s Markup on NB Retailer’s Markup on PL MOTRIN IB CAPLETS 1.02 1.12 MOTRIN IB 1.09 1.22 MOTRIN IB GELCAPS 1.04 1.21 TYLENOL INFANT DROPS 1.07 1.31 TYLENOL X/S CAPLET 1.06 1.32 TYLENOL X/S GELCAPS 1.02 1.12 CHILD CHEW GRAP TYLENOL 1.13 1.47 CHILD CHEW FRT TYLENOL 1.13 1.47 TYLENOL TABLETS REGULAR 1.02 1.28 TYLENOL X/S TABLETS 1.01 1.17 TYLENOL X/S TABLETS 1.03 1.19 TYLENOL X/S TABLETS 1.03 1.18 ADVIL 1.03 1.17 ADVIL CAPLETS 1.02 1.12 ANACIN-3 CHILDREN TABS 1.09 2.20 BAYER CHILD ASPIRIN 1.23 2.20 PANADOL CHILD TABS 1.14 2.20 EXCEDRIN IB TABS 50 1.06 1.24 EXCEDRIN IB TAB 100 1.03 1.13 EXCEDRIN IB CAPLETS 1.05 1.16 EXCEDRIN IB TABS 50 1.06 1.24 ALEVE CAPLETS 1.05 1.21 Weighted Average 1.06 1.36 Product Pair Table A2.1. Bottled Juice: National Brand Markup NB Markup Based on WP NB Markup Based on RP MOTTS APPLE JUICE 2.10 2.08 SENECA APPLE JUICE 1.88 1.42 GATORADE ORANGE DRIN 1.83 1.72 NORTHERN CRAN/RASP 1.64 1.50 FLAVOR FRESH APPLE J 1.58 1.14 NORTHERN CRAN/RASP 1.55 1.47 TREE TOP APPLE JUIC 1.47 1.14 MUSSELMAN APPLE JUIC 1.46 1.13 MM NATL. APPLE JUIC 1.45 1.10 O S RUBY RED GRAPEF 1.43 1.25 O S CRANRASPBERRY DR 1.42 1.33 O S PINK GRAPEFRUIT 1.41 1.31 O S GRAPEFRUIT JUICE 1.37 1.26 NORTHLAND CRANBERRY 1.35 1.38 NORTHLAND CRANBERRY 1.34 1.38 NORTHLAND CRANBERRY 1.33 1.37 SPEAS FARM APPLE JUI 1.31 1.08 WELCH'S GRAPE JUICE 1.24 1.22 O S CRANBERRY JUICE 1.23 1.21 SUNSWEET PRUNE JUICE 1.19 1.13 VERYFINE R/RED GRPF 1.17 1.12 VERYFINE CRANBERRY 1.13 1.16 DEL MONTE PRUNE JCE/ 1.00 1.08 Weighted Average 1.40 1.29 Product Pair Table A2.2. Bottled Juice: Retailer’s Markup Retailer’s Markup on NB Retailer’s Markup on PL MOTTS APPLE JUICE 1.43 1.44 SENECA APPLE JUICE 1.25 1.66 GATORADE ORANGE DRIN 1.26 1.34 NORTHERN CRAN/RASP 1.08 1.15 FLAVOR FRESH APPLE J 1.21 1.68 NORTHERN CRAN/RASP 1.07 1.18 TREE TOP APPLE JUIC 1.19 1.53 MUSSELMAN APPLE JUIC 1.16 1.49 MM NATL. APPLE JUIC 1.12 1.47 O S RUBY RED GRAPEF 1.04 1.20 O S CRANRASPBERRY DR 1.09 1.15 O S PINK GRAPEFRUIT 1.13 1.22 O S GRAPEFRUIT JUICE 1.12 1.22 NORTHLAND CRANBERRY 1.08 1.06 NORTHLAND CRANBERRY 1.09 1.06 NORTHLAND CRANBERRY 1.08 1.06 SPEAS FARM APPLE JUI 1.33 1.62 WELCH'S GRAPE JUICE 1.10 1.12 O S CRANBERRY JUICE 1.04 1.06 SUNSWEET PRUNE JUICE 1.23 1.29 VERYFINE R/RED GRPF 1.15 1.20 VERYFINE CRANBERRY 1.09 1.06 DEL MONTE PRUNE JCE/ 1.36 1.25 Weighted Average 1.13 1.23 Product Pair Table A3.1. Cereals: National Brand Markup NB Markup Based on WP NB Markup Based on RP TOTAL RAISIN BRAN 1.79 1.63 KELLOGGS CORN FLAKES 1.57 1.28 KELLOGGS NUT & HONEY 1.54 1.37 POST RAISIN BRAN 1.51 1.40 KELLOGGS RAISIN BRAN 1.48 1.34 APPLE CINNAMON CHERR 1.48 1.31 W.C. X-RAISIN BRAN C 1.46 1.39 KELLOGG'S FROSTED FL 1.44 1.27 KELLOGG FROSTED FLAK 1.41 1.24 KLLG LWFT GRANOLA W/ 1.40 1.25 HONEY NUT CHEERIOS 1.38 1.22 Weighted Average 1.49 1.32 Product Pair Table A3.2. Cereals: Retailer’s Markup Retailer’s Markup on NB Retailer’s Markup on PL KELLOGG’S CORN FLAKES 1.04 1.28 KELLOGG’S LWFT GRANOLA 1.09 1.22 KELLOGG’S NUT & HONEY 1.05 1.18 APPLE CINNAMON CHERRIOS 1.03 1.16 HONEY NUT CHEERIOS 1.02 1.16 KELLOGG’S FROSTED FLAKES 0.99 1.15 KELLOGG’S FROSTED FLAKES 1.03 1.15 W.C. X-RAISIN BRAN 1.09 1.15 POST RAISIN BRAN 1.06 1.14 TOTAL RAISIN BRAN 1.05 1.14 KELLOGG’S RAISIN BRAN 1.03 1.14 Weighted Average 1.03 1.17 Product Pair Table A4.1. Cheese: National Brand Markup NB Markup Based on WP NB Markup Based on RP KR SOFT PHILLY CREAM 1.82 1.53 KRAFT COLBY JACK CHU 1.00 0.93 KR PHILA CREAM CHEES 1.53 1.23 KR GRTD PARMESAN 1.32 1.26 $KRAFT SHRED MOZZARE 1.15 1.12 KR MILD COLBY 1.24 1.09 KR LT/NAT SWISS CHUN 1.33 1.21 KR KLN SLICED SWISS 1.30 1.17 KR LT NAT SHRED MOZZ 1.45 1.30 KRAFT HALFMOON MILD 1.24 1.14 ~KRAFT SHREDDED MOZZ 1.17 1.15 KR SL COLBY RESEALAB 1.40 1.24 KR SHRED MOZZARELLA 1.17 1.06 KR SL MUENSTER RESEA 1.40 1.28 KR SHRED MILD CHEDDA 1.29 1.17 KRAFT FINELY SHREDDE 1.24 1.13 Weighted Average 1.31 1.19 Product Pair Table A4.2. Cheese: Retailer’s Markup Retailer’s Markup on NB Retailer’s Markup on PL KR SOFT PHILLY CREAM 1.25 1.49 KRAFT COLBY JACK CHU 1.25 1.36 KR PHILA CREAM CHEES 1.20 1.49 KR GRTD PARMESAN 1.09 1.14 KRAFT SHRED MOZZARE 1.05 1.08 KR MILD COLBY 1.19 1.35 KR LT/NAT SWISS CHUN 1.15 1.26 KR KLN SLICED SWISS 1.14 1.27 KR LT NAT SHRED MOZZ 1.19 1.32 KRAFT HALFMOON MILD 1.13 1.23 KRAFT SHREDDED MOZZ 1.13 1.15 KR SL COLBY RESEALAB 1.17 1.31 KR SHRED MOZZARELLA 1.18 1.30 KR SL MUENSTER RESEA 1.18 1.29 KR SHRED MILD CHEDDA 1.19 1.31 KRAFT FINELY SHREDDE 1.18 1.29 Weighted Average 1.17 1.29 Product Pair Table A5.1. Cookes: National Brand Markup NB Markup Based on WP NB Markup Based on RP SALERNO BUTTER COOKI 1.27 1.08 SALERNO CHOC GRAHAMS 1.34 1.18 SALERNO MINT CREAM P 1.53 1.45 SALERNO ROYAL GRAHAM 1.48 1.29 SALERNO OATMEAL PNT 0.96 0.87 SALERNO VANLLA WAFER 1.75 1.44 MINI CHOCOLATE CHIP- 1.37 1.09 SALERNO CHOC CHOC CH 1.83 1.74 SALERNO CHOC CHIP W/ 1.83 1.75 SALERNO PREMIER CHOC 1.82 1.73 SUPER MARIO CHOCOLAT 1.43 1.25 KLBR SUGAR WAFERS-VA 1.74 1.40 ARCHWAY CHOC CHIP S 1.08 1.00 ARCHWAY CINN APPLE S 1.42 1.17 ARCHWAY CHOC CHIP & 1.25 1.10 ARCHWAY CHOCO CHIP& 1.56 1.29 ARCHWAY FF FIG BARS 1.41 1.29 ARCHWAY FATFREE AP 1.53 1.49 KEEBLER LF HONEY GRA 1.98 1.54 W.C.CHOC CHIP ALL B 1.78 1.30 HONEY MAID CHOCOLATE 1.29 1.23 ALMOST HOME CHOCOLAT 1.83 1.51 ALMOST HOME OATMEAL 1.78 1.44 NUTTER BUTTER PNT BT 3.40 2.75 CAMEO CREME SANDWICH 3.37 2.72 FAM AMOS CHOC CHIP W 1.98 1.71 FAM AMOS CHOC CHIP C 1.93 1.68 FAMOUS AMOS CHOC CHI 1.25 1.13 FAMOUS AMOS CHOC CRE 1.37 1.22 Weighted Average 1.67 1.44 Product Pair Table A5.2. Cookes: Retailer’s Markup Retailer’s Markup on NB Retailer’s Markup on PL SALERNO BUTTER COOKI 1.18 1.39 SALERNO CHOC GRAHAMS 1.15 1.31 SALERNO MINT CREAM P 1.18 1.24 SALERNO ROYAL GRAHAM 1.14 1.31 ~SALERNO OATMEAL PNT 1.25 1.38 SALERNO VANLLA WAFER 1.14 1.39 MINI CHOCOLATE CHIP- 1.08 1.35 SALERNO CHOC CHOC CH 1.13 1.19 SALERNO CHOC CHIP W/ 1.13 1.18 SALERNO PREMIER CHOC 1.13 1.19 SUPER MARIO CHOCOLAT 1.17 1.34 KLBR SUGAR WAFERS-VA 1.12 1.39 `ARCHWAY CHOC CHIP S 1.11 1.19 ARCHWAY CINN APPLE S 1.08 1.32 ARCHWAY CHOC CHIP & 1.19 1.35 ~ARCHWAY CHOCO CHIP& 1.11 1.35 ARCHWAY FF FIG BARS 1.06 1.16 ~ARCHWAY FATFREE AP 1.09 1.11 KEEBLER LF HONEY GRA 1.11 1.43 ~W.C.CHOC CHIP ALL B 1.01 1.37 HONEY MAID CHOCOLATE 1.11 1.16 ALMOST HOME CHOCOLAT 1.12 1.35 ALMOST HOME OATMEAL 1.12 1.39 NUTTER BUTTER PNT BT 1.11 1.38 CAMEO CREME SANDWICH 1.12 1.38 FAM AMOS CHOC CHIP W 1.16 1.35 FAM AMOS CHOC CHIP C 1.17 1.35 FAMOUS AMOS CHOC CHI 1.07 1.18 FAMOUS AMOS CHOC CRE 1.09 1.22 Weighted Average 1.13 1.30 Product Pair Table A6.1. Crackers: National Brand Markup NB Markup Based on WP NB Markup Based on RP NAB PREMIUM SALTINES 4.12 3.02 SALERNO SALTINES 2.93 2.33 NAB PREMIUM SALTINES 2.71 2.33 SALERNO SALTINES 2.45 2.09 NAB PREMIUM SALTINES 2.13 1.48 HONEY MAID GRAHAMS-L 1.91 1.52 KEEBLER GRAHAM CRACK 1.73 1.41 NAB GRAHAM CRACKERS 1.65 1.34 SALERNO SALTINES 1.55 1.16 SALERNO GRAHAM CRACK 1.45 1.22 DELUXE GRAHAM BONUS 1.31 1.03 Weighted Average 2.53 1.98 Product Pair Table A6.2. Crackers: Retailer’s Markup Retailer’s Markup on NB Retailer’s Markup on PL SALERNO SALTINES 1.24 1.66 NAB PREMIUM SALTINES 1.15 1.66 NAB PREMIUM SALTINES 1.16 1.58 SALERNO SALTINES 1.26 1.58 HONEY MAID GRAHAMS-L 1.11 1.39 KEEBLER GRAHAM CRACK 1.12 1.37 NAB GRAHAM CRACKERS 1.11 1.37 SALERNO GRAHAM CRACK 1.15 1.37 NAB PREMIUM SALTINES 1.13 1.32 SALERNO SALTINES 1.13 1.32 DELUXE GRAHAM BONUS 1.04 1.32 Weighted Average 1.14 1.47 Product Pair Table A7.1. Canned Soup: National Brand Markup NB Markup Based on WP NB Markup Based on RP C&B CREAM OF MUSHROO 2.57 2.52 PROG CHICKEN RICE W/ 1.30 1.24 PROG MINESTRONE SOUP 1.29 1.29 PROG CHICKEN NOODLE 1.31 1.26 PROG VEGETABLE SOUP 1.35 1.29 PROG ZESTY MINESTRON 2.06 1.86 CAMP TOMATO SOUP 1.57 1.10 CHUNKY MINESTRONE SO 1.32 1.26 CHUNKY VEGETABLE 1.35 1.25 CHUNKY CHICKEN NOODL 1.29 1.23 CHUNKY CHICKEN RICE 1.27 1.22 CHUNKY VEGETABLE SOU 1.44 1.32 CHUNKY CHICKEN NOODL 1.83 1.75 HOME COOKIN' TOMATO 1.49 1.42 CAMP CHICKEN WITH RI 1.37 1.19 CAMP CREAM OF CELERY 1.43 1.16 CAMP VEGETABLE BEEF 1.72 1.54 CAMP BEAN W/BACON SO 1.29 1.01 CAMP BROCC CHEESE SO 1.54 1.41 CAMPBELL CHICKEN & S 1.34 1.22 HOME COOKIN MINESTRO 1.27 1.22 SWAN CHIX BROTH 1.45 1.13 HEALTHY REQ. VEGETAB 1.74 1.55 ROKEACH VEGETABLE SO 2.03 1.73 Weighted Average 1.53 1.38 Product Pair Table A7.2. Canned Soup: Retailer’s Markup Retailer’s Markup on NB Retailer’s Markup on PL C&B CREAM OF MUSHROO 1.23 1.25 PROG CHICKEN RICE W/ 1.17 1.22 PROG MINESTRONE SOUP 1.30 1.30 PROG CHICKEN NOODLE 1.17 1.22 PROG VEGETABLE SOUP 1.31 1.37 PROG ZESTY MINESTRON 1.19 1.32 CAMP TOMATO SOUP 1.06 1.51 CHUNKY MINESTRONE SO 1.24 1.30 CHUNKY VEGETABLE 1.23 1.33 CHUNKY CHICKEN NOODL 1.17 1.22 CHUNKY CHICKEN RICE 1.17 1.22 CHUNKY VEGETABLE SOU 1.46 1.60 CHUNKY CHICKEN NOODL 1.28 1.34 HOME COOKIN' TOMATO 1.43 1.50 CAMP CHICKEN WITH RI 1.33 1.53 CAMP CREAM OF CELERY 1.29 1.58 CAMP VEGETABLE BEEF 1.30 1.46 CAMP BEAN W/BACON SO 1.43 1.82 CAMP BROCC CHEESE SO 1.28 1.40 CAMPBELL CHICKEN & S 1.30 1.42 HOME COOKIN MINESTRO 1.25 1.30 SWAN CHIX BROTH 1.52 1.96 HEALTHY REQ. VEGETAB 1.34 1.51 ROKEACH VEGETABLE SO 1.42 1.67 Weighted Average 1.29 1.43 Product Pair Table A8.1. Dish Detergent: National Brand Markup NB Markup Based on WP NB Markup Based on RP DAWN LEMON 1.93 1.81 SUNLIGHT AUTO DISH 1.70 1.61 PALMOLIVE AUTO DISH 1.60 1.50 JOY LEMON 1.54 1.43 SUNLIGHT AUTO DISH 1.36 1.30 SUNLIGHT AUTO DISH 1.36 1.30 LEMON DAWN 1.34 1.22 DIAL AUTO DISH DETER 1.32 1.16 SUNLIGHT AUTO GEL 1.23 1.15 PALMOLIVE AUTO GEL 1.15 1.08 SUNLIGHT LEMON AUTO 1.09 1.00 Weighted Average 1.41 1.32 Product Pair Table A8.2. Dish Detergent: Retailer’s Markup Retailer’s Markup on NB Retailer’s Markup on PL DIAL AUTO DISH DETER 1.05 1.20 PALMOLIVE AUTO GEL 1.11 1.18 SUNLIGHT LEMON AUTO 1.08 1.18 JOY LEMON 1.09 1.17 LEMON DAWN 1.05 1.15 DAWN LEMON 1.08 1.15 SUNLIGHT AUTO DISH 1.09 1.13 SUNLIGHT AUTO DISH 1.09 1.13 SUNLIGHT AUTO GEL 1.06 1.13 PALMOLIVE AUTO DISH 1.05 1.12 SUNLIGHT AUTO DISH 1.06 1.12 Weighted Average 1.07 1.14 Product Pair Table A9.1. Frozen Entrees: National Brand Markup NB Markup Based on WP NB Markup Based on RP CELENTANO CHEESE RAV 2.53 2.72 L.C. BAKED CHEESE RA 1.59 1.71 MRS BELGO'S MEAT RAV 1.52 1.77 MRS BELGO'S CHEESE R 1.50 1.70 TOASTED CHEESE RAVIO 1.45 1.42 HLTHY CHOICE MACARON 1.41 1.43 STFR LXP CHEESE RAVI 1.36 1.53 ITALIA MEAT TORTELLI 1.21 1.50 ORE-IDA CHEESE TORTE 1.19 1.31 STFRS MAC & CHEESE 1.17 1.13 ITALIA CHEESE RAVIOL 1.12 1.28 ITALIA MEAT RAVIOLI 1.12 1.29 LC SWEDISH MEATBALLS 1.09 1.06 LC CAFE CLSC GLAZED 1.06 1.05 FLORESTA MEAT TORTEL 0.85 0.93 Weighted Average 1.22 1.26 Product Pair Table A9.2. Frozen Entrees: Retailer’s Markup Retailer’s Markup on NB Retailer’s Markup on PL LC SWEDISH MEATBALLS 1.21 1.25 STFRS MAC & CHEESE 1.21 1.25 HLTHY CHOICE MACARON 1.27 1.25 LC CAFE CLSC GLAZED 1.15 1.16 TOASTED CHEESE RAVIO 1.14 1.16 STFR LXP CHEESE RAVI 1.19 1.05 L.C. BAKED CHEESE RA 1.13 1.05 ITALIA CHEESE RAVIOL 1.19 1.04 ORE-IDA CHEESE TORTE 1.15 1.04 ITALIA MEAT RAVIOLI 1.19 1.03 MRS BELGO'S CHEESE R 1.17 1.03 ITALIA MEAT TORTELLI 1.27 1.02 CELENTANO CHEESE RAV 1.09 1.02 MRS BELGO'S MEAT RAV 1.17 1.00 FLORESTA MEAT TORTEL 1.07 0.98 Weighted Average 1.18 1.15 Product Pair Table A10.1. Frozen Juice: National Brand Markup NB Markup Based on WP NB Markup Based on RP MM PINK LEMONADE 3.51 1.88 WELCH'S 100% WHITE G 2.23 1.61 MM FRUIT PUNCH 2.18 1.59 MM FRUIT PUNCH 1.96 1.39 SUNKIST PINK LEMONAD 1.91 3.72 HAWAIIAN PUNCH FRT J 1.87 1.41 MM LEMONADE 1.80 1.26 MM PINK LEMONADE 1.79 1.26 ~SENECA APPLE JUICE 1.57 1.64 ~MM ORANGE JUICE 1.52 2.02 ~SENECA APPLE JUICE 1.49 1.09 MINUTE MAID GRAPEFRU 1.48 1.28 DOLE PINEAPPLE ORANG 1.46 1.32 MM ORANGE JUICE 1.43 1.32 WELCH'S CRAN/RASP JC 1.42 1.35 MM ORANGE JUICE W/CA 1.33 1.36 MM ORANGE JUICE 1.32 1.24 TREE TOP APPLE JUICE 1.31 1.28 TREE TOP APPLE JUICE 1.30 1.25 WELCH 100% GRAPE JCE 1.27 1.21 TROP ORANGE JUICE 1.27 1.20 WELCH'S WHITE GRAPE 1.26 1.09 CITRUS HILL ORANGE J 1.25 1.18 TROP SB ORANGE JUICE 1.25 1.17 CITRUS HILL ORANGE J 1.21 1.15 WELCH'S GRAPE JUICE 1.18 1.04 HAWAIIAN PUNCH FRT J 1.11 2.20 MM PINK GRAPEFRUIT J 1.11 1.19 SUNKIST ORANGE JUICE 0.98 0.88 ~TROP TWISTER CRAN/R 0.78 0.89 WELCH ADE ORANGE 0.75 0.93 ~MINUTE MAID CRANBER 0.72 0.81 SUNKIST PINK LEMONAD 0.48 1.28 Weighted Average 1.41 1.28 Product Pair Table A10.2. Frozen Juice: Retailer’s Markup Retailer’s Markup on NB Retailer’s Markup on PL SUNKIST PINK LEMONAD 1.76 2.62 MM PINK LEMONADE 1.33 2.48 MM FRUIT PUNCH 1.54 2.11 MM FRUIT PUNCH 1.44 2.04 MM PINK LEMONADE 1.43 2.03 MM LEMONADE 1.41 2.02 ~SENECA APPLE JUICE 1.40 2.02 HAWAIIAN PUNCH FRT J 1.45 1.92 TREE TOP APPLE JUICE 1.81 1.85 WELCH'S WHITE GRAPE 1.53 1.76 WELCH'S 100% WHITE G 1.27 1.76 WELCH'S GRAPE JUICE 1.50 1.70 TREE TOP APPLE JUICE 1.40 1.47 DOLE PINEAPPLE ORANG 1.29 1.44 MINUTE MAID GRAPEFRU 1.24 1.42 MM PINK GRAPEFRUIT J 1.51 1.41 SUNKIST ORANGE JUICE 1.23 1.36 WELCH 100% GRAPE JCE 1.28 1.34 WELCH ADE ORANGE 1.62 1.31 ~MINUTE MAID CRANBER 1.45 1.29 MM ORANGE JUICE 1.21 1.28 TROP SB ORANGE JUICE 1.20 1.28 ~TROP TWISTER CRAN/R 1.47 1.28 WELCH'S CRAN/RASP JC 1.21 1.28 CITRUS HILL ORANGE J 1.17 1.27 MM ORANGE JUICE W/CA 1.30 1.27 MM ORANGE JUICE 1.17 1.26 TROP ORANGE JUICE 1.20 1.26 CITRUS HILL ORANGE J 1.20 1.23 ~SENECA APPLE JUICE 1.32 1.20 ~MM ORANGE JUICE 1.50 1.12 HAWAIIAN PUNCH FRT J 1.42 0.71 SUNKIST PINK LEMONAD 1.94 0.25 Weighted Average 1.31 1.46 Product Pair Table A11.1. Fabric Softener: National Brand Markup NB Markup Based on WP NB Markup Based on RP ~BOUNCE SINGLE 2.40 1.54 BOUNCE SINGLE SCENTE 2.01 1.89 ~DOWNY REG REFILL 1.92 1.61 ~DOWNY REG REFILL 1.90 1.59 ~DOWNY SUNRISE REFIL 1.90 1.60 ~DOWNY SUNRISE REFIL 1.88 1.58 DOWNY ULTRA REFILL 1.68 1.49 ~DOWNY ULTRA REFILL 1.68 1.49 BOUNCE 1.63 1.47 DOWNY ULTRA REFILL S 1.60 1.48 DOWNY ULTRA REFILL B 1.60 1.48 DOWNY ULTRA REFILL B 1.53 1.47 DOWNY ULTRA REFILL S 1.53 1.47 Weighted Average 1.77 1.56 Product Pair Table A11.2. Fabric Softener: Retailer’s Markup Retailer’s Markup on NB Retailer’s Markup on PL ~BOUNCE SINGLE 1.13 1.76 ~DOWNY SUNRISE REFIL 1.08 1.28 ~DOWNY REG REFILL 1.07 1.28 ~DOWNY SUNRISE REFIL 1.08 1.28 ~DOWNY REG REFILL 1.07 1.28 DOWNY ULTRA REFILL 1.09 1.23 ~DOWNY ULTRA REFILL 1.09 1.23 BOUNCE 1.04 1.16 DOWNY ULTRA REFILL S 1.05 1.14 DOWNY ULTRA REFILL B 1.05 1.14 BOUNCE SINGLE SCENTE 1.03 1.09 DOWNY ULTRA REFILL S 1.05 1.09 DOWNY ULTRA REFILL B 1.05 1.09 Weighted Average 1.06 1.21 Product Pair Table A12.1. Grooming Products: National Brand Markup NB Markup Based on WP NB Markup Based on RP ~SLIM TWIN+ CART 3.58 3.01 SLIM TWIN DISP PPD $ 2.86 1.79 TRAC II PLUS CART 10 2.44 2.06 ~SLIM TWIN CARTRIDGE 2.05 1.71 GOOD NEWS PIVOT PLS 1.62 1.42 GOOD NEWS PIVOT PLUS 1.49 1.31 TC DISP RAZOR SINGLE 1.41 1.19 TOP CARE DOUBLE EDGE 1.33 1.02 TC DISP RAZOR TWIN P 1.21 1.12 TOP CARE DOUBLE EDGE 0.75 1.66 Weighted Average 1.92 1.57 Product Pair Table A12.2. Grooming Products: Retailer’s Markup Retailer’s Markup on NB Retailer’s Markup on PL TC DISP RAZOR SINGLE 1.82 2.16 SLIM TWIN DISP PPD $ 1.17 1.87 TC DISP RAZOR TWIN P 1.37 1.47 TOP CARE DOUBLE EDGE 1.10 1.42 TOP CARE DOUBLE EDGE 1.13 1.28 ~SLIM TWIN+ CART 1.06 1.26 GOOD NEWS PIVOT PLS 1.09 1.25 ~SLIM TWIN CARTRIDGE 1.04 1.24 GOOD NEWS PIVOT PLUS 1.09 1.24 TRAC II PLUS CART 10 1.04 1.24 Weighted Average 1.12 1.37 Product Pair Table A13.1. Laundry Detergents: National Brand Markup NB Markup Based on WP NB Markup Based on RP ULTRA IVORY-SNOW 1.84 1.64 ERA H D LIQ DETERG 1.72 1.61 WOOLITE LIQUID 1.63 1.40 WOOLITE LIQUID 1.52 1.36 ~ULTRA TDE W/BLCH 1.49 1.36 SOLO HD LIQ DETG 1.48 1.41 NON PHOS CONC ALL DE 1.42 1.38 TIDE W/BLEACH ULTRA 1.31 1.26 ~ULTRA TIDE W/BLEACH 1.27 1.22 NP WISK HD LIQ DET 1.17 1.14 FAB ULTRA LIQUID 1.16 1.17 ~ULTRA SURF LIQ 1.15 1.15 SOLO HD LIQUID DETG. 1.07 1.05 ERA H D LIQ DETERG 1.06 1.04 ULTRA BOLD 1.05 1.03 ULTRA WISK W/BLEACH 1.05 1.00 Weighted Average 1.26 1.20 Product Pair Table A13.2. Laundry Detergents: Retailer’s Markup Retailer’s Markup on NB Retailer’s Markup on PL WOOLITE LIQUID 1.11 1.29 WOOLITE LIQUID 1.06 1.19 ULTRA IVORY-SNOW 1.03 1.15 ~ULTRA TDE W/BLCH 1.04 1.14 SOLO HD LIQ DETG 1.05 1.10 ERA H D LIQ DETERG 1.03 1.10 TIDE W/BLEACH ULTRA 1.02 1.07 ULTRA WISK W/BLEACH 1.02 1.07 FAB ULTRA LIQUID 1.06 1.06 NON PHOS CONC ALL DE 1.03 1.06 ~ULTRA TIDE W/BLEACH 1.01 1.05 ULTRA BOLD 1.02 1.05 ERA H D LIQ DETERG 1.03 1.04 SOLO HD LIQUID DETG. 1.03 1.04 NP WISK HD LIQ DET 1.01 1.04 ~ULTRA SURF LIQ 1.04 1.03 Weighted Average 1.03 1.07 Product Pair Table A14.1. Oatmeal: National Brand Markup NB Markup Based on WP NB Markup Based on RP QUICK QUAKER OATS 1.77 1.31 QUICK QUAKER OATS 1.51 1.20 QUAKER INST OATML RS 1.48 1.27 QUAKER INSTANT OATME 1.47 1.26 QUAKER INST OATML MP 1.40 1.18 Weighted Average 1.55 1.24 Product Pair Table A14.2. Oatmeal: Retailer’s Markup Retailer’s Markup on NB Retailer’s Markup on PL QUICK QUAKER OATS 1.11 1.63 QUAKER INST OATML MP 1.09 1.29 QUAKER INSTANT OATME 1.09 1.27 QUAKER INST OATML RS 1.08 1.27 QUICK QUAKER OATS 1.08 1.24 Weighted Average 1.09 1.38 Product Pair Table A15.1. Snack Cracker: National Brand Markup NB Markup Based on WP NB Markup Based on RP SUNSHINE CHEEZ IT 1.61 1.30 KEEBLER CLUB CRACKE 1.43 1.21 TOWN HOUSE CHEDDAR J 1.52 1.23 NABISCO RITZ CRACKER 1.65 1.36 NABISCO RITZ CRACKER 1.90 1.49 ~NABISCO RITZ BITS 1.65 1.32 NABISCO CHEESE NIPS 1.67 1.32 WORTZ SALTINES 0.48 0.66 Weighted Average 1.49 1.24 Product Pair Table A15.2. Snack Cracker: Retailer’s Markup Retailer’s Markup on NB Retailer’s Markup on PL SUNSHINE CHEEZ IT 1.15 1.43 KEEBLER CLUB CRACKE 1.12 1.32 TOWN HOUSE CHEDDAR J 1.16 1.43 NABISCO RITZ CRACKER 1.09 1.32 NABISCO RITZ CRACKER 1.13 1.43 ~NABISCO RITZ BITS 1.13 1.40 NABISCO CHEESE NIPS 1.16 1.48 WORTZ SALTINES 1.92 1.38 Weighted Average 1.23 1.40 Product Pair Table A16.1. Tooth Brushes: National Brand Markup NB Markup Based on WP NB Markup Based on RP PEPSODENT T/B SOFT P 2.47 1.19 PEPSODENT T/B MEDIUM 2.58 1.19 CREST T.B. #6 SOFT S 12.31 3.26 CREST T.B. #2 MED ST 12.87 3.28 CREST T.B. #5 SOFT S 13.98 3.31 CREST T.B. #1 MED ST 13.74 3.31 REACH BETWEEN SOFT 12.25 2.91 REACH BETWEEN MEDIUM 10.92 2.91 J&J FLOSS WAX REG 2.03 1.52 J&J FLOSS UNW REG 2.04 1.52 J&J FLOSS WAX MINT 2.04 1.53 Weighted Average 7.93 2.36 Product Pair Table A16.2. Tooth Brushes: Retailer’s Markup Retailer’s Markup on NB Retailer’s Markup on PL PEPSODENT T/B SOFT P 2.00 4.15 PEPSODENT T/B MEDIUM 1.96 4.26 CREST T.B. #6 SOFT S 1.15 4.33 CREST T.B. #2 MED ST 1.14 4.49 CREST T.B. #5 SOFT S 1.15 4.85 CREST T.B. #1 MED ST 1.14 4.75 REACH BETWEEN SOFT 1.21 5.08 REACH BETWEEN MEDIUM 1.21 4.53 J&J FLOSS WAX REG 1.42 1.90 J&J FLOSS UNW REG 1.42 1.91 J&J FLOSS WAX MINT 1.42 1.89 Weighted Average 1.38 3.83 Product Pair Table A17.1. Canned Tuna: National Brand Markup NB Markup Based on WP NB Markup Based on RP C O S LITE TUNA - WA 1.89 1.60 C O S LITE TUNA - WA 1.89 1.59 C O S LITE TUNA - WA 1.88 1.51 C O S SOLID WHITE - 1.23 1.17 C O S CHUNK LIGHT WA 1.12 1.10 C O S SOLID WHITE - 1.09 1.09 C O S CHUNK LIGHT WA 1.08 1.05 Weighted Average 1.23 1.16 Product Pair Table A17.2. Canned Tuna: Retailer’s Markup Retailer’s Markup on NB Retailer’s Markup on PL C O S LITE TUNA - WA 1.32 1.64 C O S LITE TUNA - WA 1.26 1.50 C O S LITE TUNA - WA 1.24 1.45 C O S SOLID WHITE - 1.16 1.21 C O S SOLID WHITE - 1.20 1.19 C O S CHUNK LIGHT WA 1.12 1.14 C O S CHUNK LIGHT WA 1.08 1.10 Weighted Average 1.14 1.20 Product Pair Table A18.1. Tooth Paste: National Brand Markup NB Markup Based on WP NB Markup Based on RP ARM & HAMMER DENTAL 1.57 1.32 PEPSODENT TP W/BAKIN 0.50 0.52 AIM TARTER GEL # 0.69 0.74 PEPSODENT W/FLORIDE 1.53 1.49 CLOSE UP BAKING SODA 1.09 0.95 CLOSE-UP TARTAR CONT 1.22 1.15 ARM & HAMMER DENTAL 1.70 1.45 ~COLGATE TARTER GEL 1.70 1.56 *COLGATE TARTAR REG 1.39 1.22 *COLGATE TARTAR GEL 1.42 1.25 ~COLGATE TARTER GEL 1.38 1.24 *CREST TRT GEL 1.41 1.25 *CREST REG 2.22 1.60 *CREST TRT REG 1.38 1.23 *AQUA FRESH TOOTHPAS 2.16 1.65 AQUAFRESH TOOTHPASTE 2.05 1.49 Weighted Average 1.46 1.26 Product Pair Table A18.2. Tooth Paste: Retailer’s Markup Retailer’s Markup on NB Retailer’s Markup on PL ARM & HAMMER DENTAL 1.09 1.29 PEPSODENT TP W/BAKIN 1.33 1.29 AIM TARTER GEL # 1.28 1.20 PEPSODENT W/FLORIDE 1.39 1.43 CLOSE UP BAKING SODA 1.12 1.29 CLOSE-UP TARTAR CONT 1.11 1.19 ARM & HAMMER DENTAL 1.10 1.29 ~COLGATE TARTER GEL 1.08 1.18 *COLGATE TARTAR REG 1.06 1.20 *COLGATE TARTAR GEL 1.06 1.20 ~COLGATE TARTER GEL 1.08 1.21 *CREST TRT GEL 1.06 1.20 *CREST REG 1.03 1.42 *CREST TRT REG 1.06 1.20 *AQUA FRESH TOOTHPAS 1.08 1.42 AQUAFRESH TOOTHPASTE 1.03 1.41 Weighted Average 1.12 1.28 Product Pair Table A19.1. Soft Drinks: National Brand Markup NB Markup Based on WP NB Markup Based on RP PEPSI COLA N/R 1.81 1.57 PEPSI DIET N/R 1.91 1.61 PEPSI COLA 2.10 1.57 SCHWEPPS TONIC N/R 1.82 1.29 SCHWEPPS GINGER ALE 1.56 1.24 SCHWEPPES DIET TONIC 1.79 1.28 SCHWEPPES LIME SELTZ 1.95 1.25 SCHWEPPES GINGER ALE 1.83 1.41 CANADA DRY GINGER AL 1.90 1.43 CANADA DRY TONIC WAT 1.98 1.43 R.C. COLA 1.59 1.32 ROYAL CROWN COLA 1.70 1.35 HIRES ROOT BEER N/R 1.98 1.90 SUNKIST ORANGE 2.23 1.59 COCA-COLA CLASSIC 1.83 1.57 DIET COKE 1.91 1.62 MIN MAID FRUIT PUNCH 2.19 1.80 BARQ'S ROOT BEER 2.79 1.87 BARQ'S DIET RT BEER 2.12 1.65 NEW YORK SELTZER COL 1.80 1.50 A W RT BEER REG 1.55 1.31 A W ROOT BEER SF 1.51 1.30 SEAGRAMS GINGERALE 1 2.42 1.38 SEAGRAMS TONIC 1 LIT 2.48 1.46 SEAGRAMS GINGR ALE$ 1.94 1.68 SEAGRAM'S LEMON LIME 1.75 1.51 CANFIELDS LEMON SELT 1.98 1.30 CANFIELD GINGER ALE 2.37 1.79 CANFIELD TONIC 2.62 1.93 CANFIELD COLA NR 1.66 1.66 CANFIELD DIET COLA N 2.09 1.64 CANFIELD SWISS CREME 1.75 1.52 CANFIELD COLA 3LITER 2.02 1.30 Weighted Average 1.68 1.45 Product Pair Table A19.2. Soft Drinks: Retailer’s Markup Retailer’s Markup on NB Retailer’s Markup on PL PEPSI COLA N/R 1.12 1.29 PEPSI DIET N/R 1.10 1.31 PEPSI COLA 1.05 1.40 SCHWEPPS TONIC N/R 1.24 1.74 SCHWEPPS GINGER ALE 1.33 1.67 SCHWEPPES DIET TONIC 1.24 1.74 SCHWEPPES LIME SELTZ 1.12 1.75 SCHWEPPES GINGER ALE 1.05 1.36 CANADA DRY GINGER AL 1.28 1.70 CANADA DRY TONIC WAT 1.28 1.77 R.C. COLA 1.08 1.30 ROYAL CROWN COLA 1.12 1.40 HIRES ROOT BEER N/R 1.24 1.29 SUNKIST ORANGE 0.96 1.34 COCA-COLA CLASSIC 1.11 1.29 DIET COKE 1.11 1.31 MIN MAID FRUIT PUNCH 1.17 1.42 BARQ'S ROOT BEER 0.96 1.43 BARQ'S DIET RT BEER 1.05 1.35 NEW YORK SELTZER COL 1.35 1.63 A W RT BEER REG 1.09 1.30 A W ROOT BEER SF 1.14 1.32 SEAGRAMS GINGERALE 1 1.18 2.07 SEAGRAMS TONIC 1 LIT 1.25 2.12 SEAGRAMS GINGR ALE$ 1.23 1.42 SEAGRAM'S LEMON LIME 1.27 1.47 CANFIELDS LEMON SELT 1.16 1.76 CANFIELD GINGER ALE 1.17 1.55 CANFIELD TONIC 1.17 1.59 CANFIELD COLA NR 1.25 1.25 CANFIELD DIET COLA N 0.97 1.23 CANFIELD SWISS CREME 1.21 1.40 CANFIELD COLA 3LITER 0.98 1.52 Weighted Average 1.29 1.48 Product Pair Chart 1. Average National Brand Markups Based on the Wholesale and Retail Prices Forzen Entrees Canned Tuna Laundry Detergents Cheeses Bottled Juices Frozen Juices Dish Detergents Toothpastes Snack Crackers Cereals Canned Soups Oatmeals Cookies Soft Drinks Fabric Softeners Grooming Products Analgesics Crackers Tooth Brushes 0.00 1.00 2.00 3.00 4.00 5.00 6.00 7.00 8.00 Wholesale Prices Retail Prices Chart 2. National Brand Markup Based on Wholesale Prices and the Retailer Markups Forzen Entrees Canned Tuna Laundry Detergents Cheeses Bottled Juices Frozen Juices Dish Detergents Toothpastes Snack Crackers Cereals Canned Soups Oatmeals Cookies Soft Drinks Fabric Softeners Grooming Products Analgesics Crackers Tooth Brushes 0.00 1.00 2.00 3.00 4.00 5.00 6.00 7.00 8.00 Retailer Markup on National Brand Retailer Markup on Private Label National Brand Markup Chart 3. Retailer's Markup on National Brand and Private Label Products Forzen Entrees Canned Tuna Laundry Detergents Cheeses Bottled Juices Frozen Juices Dish Detergents Toothpastes Snack Crackers Cereals Canned Soups Oatmeals Cookies Soft Drinks Fabric Softeners Grooming Products Analgesics Crackers Tooth Brushes 0.00 0.50 1.00 1.50 2.00 2.50 3.00 3.50 Retailer Markup on National Brand Retailer Markup on Private Label 4.00