The Rise and Fall of Securitization ∗ Sergey Chernenko sergey.chernenko@fisher.osu.edu The Ohio State University Sam Hanson shanson@hbs.edu Harvard University Adi Sunderam asunderam@hbs.edu Harvard University May 2014 Abstract The rise and fall of nontraditional securitizations—collateralized debt obligations and mortgagebacked securities backed by nonprime loans—played a central role in the financial crisis. Little is known, however, about the factors that drove the pre-crisis surge in investor demand for these products. Examining insurance companies’ and mutual funds’ holdings of fixed income securities, we find evidence suggesting that both agency problems and neglected risks played an important role in driving investor demand for nontraditional securitizations prior to crisis. We also use our holdings data to shed light on the factors that drove the dramatic collapse of securitization markets beginning in mid-2007. Contrary to conventional crisis narratives, we find little evidence of widespread fire sales. Instead, our evidence is more consistent with the idea that a self-amplifying buyers’ strike drove the dramatic collapse of securitization markets. ∗ We are grateful to Josh Coval, Mihir Desai, Robin Greenwood, David Scharfstein, Erik Stafford, and seminar participants at the 2014 Fixed Income Conference, Harvard, Michigan Ross, Penn State, and the SEC/Maryland Conference on the Regulation of Financial Markets for helpful comments. Hanson and Sunderam gratefully acknowledge funding from the Division of Research at the Harvard Business School. The rise and fall of nontraditional securitizations—collateralized debt obligations and mortgage-backed securities backed by nonprime loans—was at the heart of the recent financial crisis. Although traditional securitizations of prime mortgages, commercial mortgages, and consumer debt had existed for decades, nontraditional securitizations grew exponentially from 2003 to mid-2007. The primary market for nontraditional securitizations then collapsed in dramatic fashion in mid-2007, and secondary market prices for these products fell precipitously throughout 2007 and 2008. These price declines generated enormous losses for large financial intermediaries, ultimately imperiling their soundness and helping to trigger a full-blown systemic crisis in 2008. Despite general agreement on this broad narrative, surprisingly little is known about the underlying factors that drove the pre-crisis surge in investor demand for these nontraditional securitizations and the subsequent collapse of demand. While competing theoretical explanations abound, there has been little detailed empirical work assessing these narratives. In this paper, we use new micro-data on mutual funds’ and insurance companies’ holdings of fixed income securities to shed light on the factors that drove the rise and fall of securitization. Explanations of the rapid rise of nontraditional securitizations from 2003 to mid-2007 point to specific investor types that drove growing demand for these products due to either “beliefs” or “incentives.” Explanations that emphasize “beliefs” argue that some agents misunderstood the risks of investing in securitizations. 1 For instance, demand may have been driven by rating-sensitive investors who were misled by the AAA ratings granted to many securitizations. Alternatively, demand may have been driven by investors who neglected the risk of a large nationwide downturn in house prices, and thus believed that a diversified exposure to subprime mortgages was virtually riskless. By contrast, “incentives” explanations for the securitization boom emphasize the role of principal-agent problems between professional investors and their principals. 2 According to these narratives, investors took on tail risk by buying securitizations. Because these investors received equity-like compensation, buying securitizations rationally maximized investors’ own gains while ultimately destroying value for their principals. Agency explanations for the boom come in many flavors, which differ primarily in where they locate the critical agency conflict within the financial 1 2 See, for instance, Coval, Jurek, and Stafford (2009), Gennaioli, Shleifer, and Vishny (2011). See, for instance, Rajan (2005). 1 system. Some explanations emphasize agency problems between external capital providers and managers at financial institutions. Other explanations emphasize agency conflicts between firm management and individual firm employees (e.g., traders) who wanted to take excessive risks. By studying both mutual funds and insurance companies, we are able to shed light on the role of both types of incentive problems. A key question in assessing these competing narratives is: which investors drove the boom and bust in securitizations? For instance, in the case of “beliefs” explanations, it is natural to ask which types of investors were most prone to these mistaken beliefs. Similarly, in the case of “incentives” explanations of the boom, we want to know which types of investors were most prone to these incentive problems and what factors exacerbated the incentive conflicts. Investor heterogeneity also plays a key role in explanations of the collapse of the market for securitizations from mid-2007 to 2009. A broad theoretical consensus points to fire sales—the forced sale of securities by investors with high valuations to others with low valuations—as the key amplification mechanism at work during the bust. 3 In these explanations, binding leverage constraints forced financial intermediaries, who were natural holders of complex securitizations, to sell to other investors with lower valuations. The resulting decline in prices further tightened intermediary leverage constraints, leading to further forced sales. A central, yet largely untested, prediction of these theories is that the decline in prices was associated with increased trade between levered intermediaries and other investors. In other words, prices declined because large amounts of forced trading significantly changed the identity of the marginal holder. An alternative to the conventional fire-sales view is that investors staged a “buyers’ strike,” refusing to trade due to adverse selection or some other friction. 4 In this paper, we examine data on investors’ holdings of securitizations to shed light on the types of investors who drove the boom and bust. Specifically, we study quarterly fixed income holdings of mutual funds and insurance companies from 2003 to 2010. These “real money” 3 See, for instance, Shleifer and Vishny (1992, 2011), Kiyotaki and Moore (1997), Lorenzoni (2008), Brunnermeier and Pedersen (2009), Geanakopolos (2010), Stein (2012), Brunnermeier and Sanikov (2012), and Dávila (2011) for theoretical treatments of the fire-sale amplification mechanism. 4 See, for instance, Dang, Gorton, and Holmstrom (2010), Hanson and Sunderam (2013), Milbrandt (2013), and Morris and Shin (2012). 2 investors—intermediaries with access to stable capital from household savers—are two of the largest investors in credit assets, owning close to 30% of all corporate bonds and private securitizations. 5 Throughout the analysis we distinguish between traditional securitizations—which were backed by prime residential mortgages, commercial mortgages, and consumer debt—and nontraditional securitizations that consisted of securitizations backed by nonprime home mortgages and collateralized debt obligations. While traditional securitizations had existed for decades, nontraditional securitizations were a far more recent innovation. And the rapid growth in securitization markets during the 2003-2007 boom was concentrated in nontraditional products. 6 We begin by presenting two key aggregate stylized facts about the boom in nontraditional securitizations from 2003 to 2007. First, there was significant variation in credit spreads at issuance on highly-rated securitizations backed by different types of collateral. Spreads on AAA-rated traditional securitizations were negligible. By contrast, spreads on AAA-rated nontraditional securitizations were much wider, in line with spreads on BBB-rated corporate bonds. This suggests a more nuanced view of the boom than simple tellings of either beliefs or incentives theories, which tend to lump all AAA-rated securitizations together. Regardless of whether demand from some investors was elevated due to incentives or beliefs, it appears that there were other investors who clearly differentiated between traditional AAA-rated securitizations and the nontraditional AAArated structure products that were at the heart of the financial crisis. Our second aggregate fact is that mutual funds and insurers as a whole were “below market weight” in securitizations, particularly in nontraditional securitizations. This suggests that the proximate surge in demand for structured finance products did not stem primarily from real-money investors. Nonetheless, to the extent that real-money investors are affected by the same incentive problems and expectational errors as other investors, cross-sectional patterns in their holdings can help shed light on the drivers of the boom in securitization. Given that nontraditional securitizations grew most explosively during the boom, we focus our analysis on these securitizations. A simple 5 According to the Flow of Funds, as of 2007Q2, total outstanding corporate and foreign bonds, which include privatelyissued securitizations, were $10.88 trillion. Of this, mutual funds (excluding money market mutual funds) owned $0.84 trillion (7%), and insurers (both life and property and casualty) owned $2.13 trillion (20%). 6 It should be noted that both traditional and nontraditional securitization markets collapsed in the bust, with traditional securitization recovering more quickly and strongly. 3 variance decomposition underscores the role of investor heterogeneity: variation across investors, as opposed to common variation over time, is crucial for understanding our panel of holdings data. To flesh out the drivers of this investor-level variation, we study the relationship between a host of investor characteristics suggested by theory and holdings of nontraditional securitizations during the boom. For mutual funds, we focus on a key prediction of the incentives narrative: managers facing stronger performance-flow relationship should take more risk. We find little evidence of this. However, we find that inexperienced mutual fund managers invest significantly more in these products than more experienced managers—despite the fact that inexperienced and experienced managers faced similar performance-flow incentives. This is consistent with the idea that inexperienced managers are more prone to beliefs. Moreover, we find a discrete shift away from nontraditional securitizations for managers who were active during the market dislocations of fall 1998, consistent with theories of reinforcement learning. Finally, we find that team-managed mutual funds invest far more in these products than individual-managed funds. This is consistent with the social psychology literature on group polarization in risk-taking, which argues that social dynamics can lead groups to take on beliefs that are more extreme than the beliefs of any single group member. 7 Overall, the results are consistent with the idea that beliefs played an important role in driving mutual fund demand for nontraditional securitizations. Turning to insurance companies, we find that holdings of nontraditional securitizations are concentrated among insurers that are poorly capitalized and have low financial strength ratings. In addition, insurance companies that manage their portfolios internally hold more nontraditional securitizations than those whose portfolios are managed externally, and insurance companies organized as mutuals tend to hold fewer nontraditional securitizations than those organized as stock companies. These findings are consistent with the idea that incentive conflicts play an important in role in explaining insurer demand for nontraditional securitizations. In summary, our evidence suggests that both beliefs and incentives are likely part of the explanation for the pre-crisis surge in investor demand for these products. Finally, we turn to investor behavior during the bust. We find little evidence of increased transaction volume as prices of securitizations declined throughout late 2007 and 2008. Instead, 7 See, for example, Myers and Lamm (1976) and Isenberg (1986) in the social psychology literature and Bliss, Potter, and Schwarz (2008) and Bär , Ciccotello , and Ruenzi (2010) in the mutual funds literature. 4 trading in nontraditional securitizations declined through the boom from 2003 to 2007 and was extremely low during the 2007 to 2009 bust. In contrast, trading in corporate bonds remained relatively constant from 2003 to 2010. This suggests that the collapse of the secondary market for these products may be better described as a buyers’ strike or market freeze than a fire sale. A brief note on our approach is in order. First, the aim of this paper is not to advance one specific narrative of the crisis. Indeed, it is unlikely that one theory alone can completely explain a complex phenomenon like the rise and fall of nontraditional securitization. Second, our analysis is largely descriptive. Lacking clean natural experiments, we are not able to definitively identify causal effects. Instead, we pursue a series of descriptive tests that can help us begin to discriminate between alternative explanations. We carefully consider factors that may confound our interpretations of these tests, but ultimately our tests remain descriptive. Nonetheless, we believe they are a useful first step. In summary, our goal in this paper is to document a series of robust stylized facts that can inform future theoretical and empirical work on the crisis. In this way, our approach is similar to that of Griffin, Harris, Shu, and Topalugua (2011), who study investor behavior in the dot-com boom and bust. The plan for the paper is as follows. Section I provides some background on traditional and nontraditional securitizations. Section II outlines different theoretical narratives of the crisis and develops a number of testable hypotheses. Section III explains the numerous data sources we use in the paper. Section IV analyzes our holdings data to explore drivers of the boom, while Section V uses our data to shed light on the mechanics of the bust. Section VI offers some concluding observations. I. Background on Securitization This section provides a brief background on securitization. Securitizations are created through the process of “pooling”—assembling a pool of cash-flow-generating financial assets such as loans or debt securities—and “tranching”—issuing claims of various priorities backed by that pool. In the United States, the securitization of home mortgages dates back to the late 1960s and early 1970s when various Government Sponsored Enterprises (GSEs), corporations that were implicitly or explicitly backed by the US government, began issuing securities backed by residential 5 mortgage pools. 8 Only “conforming” mortgages—loans to borrowers with high credit (FICO) scores, with low loan-to-value ratios, below a Congressionally-approved loan size limit (non-“Jumbo” loans), and with sufficient documentation—are eligible to be securitized in GSE mortgage-backed securities (GSE MBS). The market for GSE MBS grew exponentially during the 1980s, and by the early 2000s it had overtaken the market for US Treasuries to become the single largest debt market in the US (Fabozzi 2005). The late 1980s saw the advent of several types of private securitizations that were not implicitly backed by the government. We broadly refer to these securitizations as “traditional securitizations”. 9 They include: • Commercial Backed Mortgage Securities (CMBS): The securitization of commercial mortgages into CMBS was pioneered by investment banks in the early 1980s. However, this market only grew to prominence in the early 1990s when the US Government’s Resolution Trust Corporation began relying heavily on CMBS securitizations to sell off the commercial real estate loan portfolios of failed depository institutions. The CMBS market grew rapidly throughout the 1990s and 2000s. • Consumer Asset-Backed Securities (ABS): The securitization of credit card debt, auto loans, and student loans began in the late 1980s. These markets developed rapidly throughout the 1990s, and by 2000 over 30% of all non-mortgage consumer debt had been securitized. However, the market for consumer ABS grew more slowly during the 20032007 boom, and the fraction of consumer debt that had been securitized actually fell to 25% by 2007Q2. • Prime non-GSE MBS: Beginning in 1977, investment banks began securitizing prime “jumbo” home mortgages that conformed to all GSE MBS criteria other than size (Fabozzi 2005; Gorton 2008). 8 Ginnie Mae issued its first MBS in 1968, and Freddie Mac followed in 1971. Fannie Mae did not begin issued MBS until 1981. Ginnie Mae is a government owned corporation and is explicitly guaranteed by the US government. Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac receive a variety of unique government benefits and have historically been perceived as being implicitly backed by the government. 9 The exact definitions of these different types of securitizations are not universally agreed upon. We typically hew closely to conventional investor categorizations. However, we sometimes make simplifications for the sake of clarity. 6 The boom in securitization from 2003 to 2007 prominently featured new types of securitizations that developed after these traditional securitizations. We label the second set of securitizations “nontraditional”. They include • Nonprime RMBS: The securitization of subprime and Alt-A home mortgages began in the mid 1990s (Lehman Brothers 2004). Alt-A mortgages are non-conforming due to high loan-to-value ratios or a lack of sufficient documentation. Subprime mortgages are nonconforming because the borrower has a low FICO score. The origination and securitization of nonprime mortgages exploded during the boom from 2003-2007. 10 • Collateralized Debt Obligations (CDOs): CDOs are securitizations backed by a portfolio of fixed income assets. Depending on the underlying assets, CDOs are classified as collateralized bond obligations (CBOs), collateralized loan obligations (CLOs), or ABS CDOs. CBOs are collateralized largely by corporate bonds and were the most common type of CDO in the late 1990s and early 2000s. However, this market grew slowly after the prominent downgrades of several CBOs backed by high yield bonds in 2002. CLOs primarily use unsecured loans to highly leveraged corporations (“levered loans”) as collateral. CLO issuance boomed from 2003 to 2007. ABS CDOs use bonds from other securitizations as the underlying collateral. ABS CDOs, particularly those using nonprime RMBS as collateral, grew explosively over the course of the boom. Many of the most dramatic losses by large financial intermediaries announced during 2007 and 2008 were linked to ABS CDOs. 11 Although our classification of securitizations into traditional and nontraditional is not universally used in the academic literature, the classification is meaningful and also serves as a useful short-hand. Furthermore, it is motivated by the historical evolution of these markets described above, classifications widely employed by practitioners, as well as by the differences in new-issue pricing that we discuss below. 10 See Fabozzi (2005), Gorton (2008), and Ashcraft and Schuermann (2008) for further background on nonprime MBS. Oddly, market participants sometimes refer to subprime mortgages as home equity loans (HEL). This is because the first subprime MBS securitizations in the mid-1990s actually contained second lien mortgages or home equity loans (Lehman Brothers 2004). Over time, these were replaced by first lien mortgages, but the name stuck. 11 See Shivdasani and Wang (2013) for further background on CLOs. See A. K. Barnett-Hart (2009) and Cordell, Huang, and Williams (2012) for more detail on ABS CDOs. 7 II. Narratives of the Rise and Fall In this section, we discuss competing narratives of the boom and bust in nontraditional securitization with an eye towards motivating our empirical tests. Our description of these narratives and their predictions is deliberately stark. Our goal in this paper is not to provide definitive tests of the different narratives. Instead, our goal is to document a series of robust stylized facts that can inform future research about the mechanisms that drove the rise and fall of securitization. 12 In pursuing this goal, our approach is to document correlations, even if they reflect endogenous relationships between investor characteristics and holdings of structured products. A. Narratives of the Rise Explanations of the boom in securitization can broadly be grouped into two categories: beliefs and incentives. 13 We describe each of these narratives in turn, outlining their empirical predictions for prices and patterns in investor holdings. A.1 Beliefs In the context of the 2003-2007 securitization boom, beliefs explanations argue that investors misunderstood the risks of investing in nontraditional securitizations. Essentially, investors treated all AAA-rated securitizations as though they were virtually risk-free. For instance, Gerardi, Lehnert, Sherlund, and Willen (2008) and Gennaioli, Shleifer, and Vishny (2012) argue that investors neglected the risk of a substantial nationwide downturn in house prices and therefore believed that diversified exposure to residential mortgages was almost riskless. Coval, Jurek, and Stafford (2010) argue that investors focused on credit ratings which reflected expected losses, but neglected the systematic risk embedded in securitizations. Ashcraft, Goldsmith-Pinkham, and Vickery (2010) and Rajan, Seru, and Vig (2012) argue that investors and rating agencies failed to update their models of 12 Erel, Nadauld, and Stulz (2013) carry out a similar exercise for bank holding companies. However, they are not able to examine variation across the type of collateral backing the securitization. 13 We do not explicitly focus on explanations of the boom that emphasize the demand for safe, “money-like” assets (e.g., Caballero, 2009; Caballero and Farhi, 2013; Gorton and Metrick 2009, 2010). While these explanations are surely important, they can fall into either the beliefs or incentives categories depending on the reasons that investors perceived nontraditional securitizations to be money-like. Similarly, we largely bypass explanations focusing on the role of international demand for safe assets (e.g., Bernanke 2005, Bernanke, et. al. 2011, Caballero, 2009; Shin, 2012). Since our data only included US-based mutual funds and insurers, it is not particularly useful for addressing these questions. 8 loan default in the face of deteriorating loan underwriting standards, thus neglecting the risks associated with lending to riskier households. We begin with predictions about prices. Simple versions of the beliefs narrative for the boom have strong predictions for security prices. Specifically, if the demand from investors who neglected these risks was large enough, then the yield of all AAA-rated securitizations should have been similar and close to those on default-free government bonds. Beliefs 1: Prices of AAA-rated nontraditional securitizations should have been highly homogeneous and close to risk-free rates. We next turn to predictions about holdings. In beliefs narratives, a key question is which types of investors were the optimists who bought large quantities of nontraditional securitizations during the boom. In the simplest version of the beliefs narrative, all investors incorrectly assessed the risks of securitizations. This suggests that most of the variation in our holdings data should be driven by common variation over time. Beliefs 2: Under a simple version of the narrative, most variation in holdings of nontraditional securitizations should be common variation over time. In more nuanced versions of this narrative, particular subsets of investors may have been more susceptible to beliefs. For instance, Gennaioli, Shleifer, and Vishny (2012) argue that unsophisticated investors were shocked by the swift decline of nationwide home price. Consistent with this, anecdotal accounts suggest that demand from smaller, less sophisticated investors like small insurance companies and pension funds played an important role in fueling the boom. 14 Coval, Jurek, and Stafford (2010) argue that rating-sensitive investors, and the rating agencies themselves, were crucial because ratings measure expected loss rather than systematic risk. From a security design perspective, the AAA-rated tranches of securitization are “economic catastrophe bonds” that load heavily on tail risk and therefore maximize yield for a given expected loss. In the context of mutual funds, the literature has argued that inexperienced managers may be more prone to beliefs (e.g., Greenwood and Nagel, 2009; Malmandier and Nagel, 2011; Campbell, Ramadorai, and Ranish, 2013). Similarly, the literature on group polarization in social psychology 14 For instance, the town of Narvik, Norway suffered significant losses on CDO investments and appeared in the infamous stick figure “Subprime Primer” (http://www.nytimes.com/2007/12/02/world/europe/02norway.html). Springfield, MA also suffered similar losses (http://dealbook.nytimes.com/2008/01/28/in-this-city-cdo-spells-trouble/). 9 argues that groups tend to make decisions that are more extreme than the initial inclinations of its members. This suggests that team-managed mutual funds may take more extreme positions in securitizations than individually-managed funds. Finally, the level of expertise of a mutual fund family in evaluating fixed income securities may proxy for the accuracy of its beliefs. Specifically, under the beliefs view, it seems natural to think that unsophisticated mutual funds seeking “safe” assets would be large holders of securitizations, while more sophisticated funds would correctly avoid these products. Beliefs 3: Mutual funds managed by less experienced managers and mutual funds managed by teams should have purchased more nontraditional securitizations. A.2 Incentives In contrast to beliefs narratives, incentives narratives of the boom emphasize agency problems within the financial sector. 15 In these explanations of the boom, sophisticated actors within financial institutions correctly understood the risks of securitizations all along. However, due to incentive frictions between these agents and their ultimate principals, these agents purchased more securitizations than their ultimate principals would have if acting on their own behalf. For prices, the incentives narrative has similar implications to the beliefs narratives. In very simple versions of the narrative, given enough demand from financial institutions fraught with agency problems, the prices of AAA-rated securitizations should have been highly homogenous. Essentially, if principals treated all AAA-rated securities as though they were risk free, agents would demand as much of these securities as possible, regardless of their true riskiness. Incentives 1: Under the incentives narrative, prices of AAA-rated nontraditional securitizations should have been highly homogeneous and close to risk-free rates. Different versions of the incentives narrative locate the critical agency friction at different points within the financial system. Some emphasize agency problems between external capital providers and managers at financial institutions. For instance, the mutual fund literature typically argues that agency problems between fund managers and investors stem from the relationship between fund performance and future flows (Chevalier and Ellison, 1997, 1998). Since expected fund inflows are a convex function of past fund outperformance, managers face incentives to take on 15 There is a large literature studying the incentives faced by loan officers in the origination process (e.g., Keys, Mukherjee, Seru, and Vig 2009). We focus on incentive problems with investors who ultimately purchased those loans. 10 significant risk to thus maximize their expected future compensation even if this does not maximize expected fund returns. Thus, according to the incentives view, the stronger the performance-flow relationship facing a fund manager, the larger her holdings of securitizations should be. Incentives 2: Mutual funds’ holdings of nontraditional securitizations should be correlated with the strength of the performance-flow relationship faced by funds. Because insurance companies sometimes outsource the management of their portfolios to external asset managers, they also offer a venue for studying this type of incentive problem. In this kind of delegated asset management, the central conflict is between traders, who are compensated based on risk-adjusted performance, and external capital providers. If capital providers cannot perfectly observe risk-taking and therefore perfectly risk-adjust performance, traders may have incentives to take excessive risks. This benchmarking problem may be particularly acute for highlyrated securitizations since, almost by construction, they perform well outside of adverse, lowprobability economic states (e.g., Acharya, Pagano, and Volpin, 2013; Adrian and Shin, 2013). 16 Incentives 3: Under the incentives narrative, insurers that have externally managed portfolios should buy more nontraditional securitizations. Agency problems between external capital providers and managers at financial institutions can also take the form of risk-shifting in the tradition of Jensen and Meckling (1976). In these narratives (e.g., Landier, Sraer, and Thesmar, 2011), managers acting on behalf of existing shareholders bought securitizations to take on tail risk, increasing the expected payoff to equity, while reducing total firm value at creditors’ expense. 17,18 For instance, the capitalization levels and ratings of insurance companies may reflect the strength of the agency conflict between their equity holders and their creditors, implicit (i.e., the government) and explicit (i.e., policyholders).19 Specifically, less well-capitalized insurers may have stronger risk-shifting incentives, and may therefore be more likely to hold nontraditional securitizations. Finally, insurance companies are 16 Ellul and Yerramilli (2012) provide evidence that banks with stronger risk management took less tail risk in the boom. Beltratti and Stulz (2011), Fahlenbrach and Stulz (2011), and Erel, Nadauld, and Stulz (2013) argue that incentive conflicts between shareholders and managers have little power to explain the performance of banks during the crisis. 18 The “too big to fail” version of this story focuses on the government’s role as an implicit creditor of large financial institutions. Under this explanation, these institutions bought securitizations to rationally maximize the value of their implicit government guarantees. See e.g., Acharya, Cooley, Richardson, and Walter, 2009; Acharya and Richardson, 2009; Acharya, Schanbl, and Suarez, 2011; and Iannotta and Pennacchi, 2012. 19 The literature on risk-taking incentives in insurance companies is less well-developed than the comparable literature on mutual funds. Important exceptions include Becker and Ivashina (2013), who show that within rating insurers tend to hold riskier corporate bonds, and Koijen and Yogo (2013), who study regulatory capital arbitrage by insurers. 17 11 typically organized either as public companies with external shareholders or as mutuals, which are owned by policyholders. These differences in organizational form also create differences in the strength of the agency conflict between equity holders and creditors. In the case of mutual companies, policy holders are effectively providing both equity and debt to mutual insurance companies, potentially reducing the scope for risk-shifting. Incentives 4: Insurers with less capital and low ratings should buy more nontraditional securitizations. In addition, insurers organized as mutuals should buy less. Note that both the beliefs and incentives narratives provide reasons why some investors may have had elevated demand for nontraditional securitizations. The large literature on limits to arbitrage initiated by DeLong et al (1990a) and Shleifer and Vishny (1997) suggests that other investors may have been reluctant to aggressively lean against these demand shocks. This combination of demand shocks and limited arbitrageur risk-bearing capacity would then explain why these demand shocks raised equilibrium prices and led to a surge in issuance. Going further, rational investors may even have had incentives to “ride” a bubble rather than leaning against it as in DeLong et al. (1990b) and Abreu and Brunnermeier (2002). B. Narratives of the Bust In contrast to the strong disagreement about the drivers of the boom in securitizations, there is wider consensus about the ensuing market collapse from mid-2007 to 2009. The frictionless null hypothesis is that the decline in the prices of securitizations during the financial crisis was driven by bad news about their fundamental values (i.e., news about discounted expected cash flows). If all investors simultaneously revised their assessment of fundamental value, we would not expect the collapse in prices to be associated with a surge in trading volume. By contrast, narratives of the bust have typically emphasized amplification mechanisms that led prices to over-react to this bad news. B.1 Fire sales The most common narrative of the bust suggests that fire sales significantly amplified the impact of this initial bad news on prices. In these explanations, binding leverage constraints forced financial intermediaries—who were the natural holders of securitizations—to sell to other investors with lower valuations. The resulting decline in prices further tightened leverage constraints, leading to further forced sales. In other words, fire-sales theories articulate a natural amplification mechanism 12 whereby some initial moderately bad news could have ultimately had a severe impact on prices. 20 A critical feature of these explanations is that the decline in the prices of securitizations was associated with increased trade between levered intermediaries and other investors. Put differently, these explanations for the bust emphasize fire sales not fire holds. Prices declined because the identity of the marginal investor changed as natural holders were forced to sell their holding to others. 21 In this way, different explanations for the bust have very different implications for aggregate trading patterns. The fundamentals-driven narrative suggests no reason for trading behavior to change with the onset of the financial crisis, while the fire sales narrative suggests increased trade at the beginning of the crisis. Fire Sales 1: Under the fire sales narrative, transaction volume in nontraditional securitizations should have risen during the crisis. In addition, we can examine the cross-section of our transactions data to further distinguish between different narratives of the bust. For instance, fire sales narratives predict that mutual funds suffering large outflows are forced to liquidate their structured product holdings. A related prediction, from the large literature on limited arbitrage, suggests that externally managed funds may have been forced to sell more of their risky holdings than internally managed funds due to frictions between fund managers and external capital providers. Fire Sales 2: Under the fire sales narrative, mutual funds facing outflows and insurance companies with externally managed portfolios should sell more nontraditional securitizations. B.2 Buyers’ strikes A second explanation that has received less attention is that investors’ uncertainty about the valuations of securitizations changed dramatically. In these narratives, investors staged a “buyers’ strike”, and prices entered a downward spiral characterized by a near absence of trade. Precipitous price declines and a collapse of trading volume may be explained by a variety of frictional amplification mechanisms. In Diamond and Rajan (2012), for instance, institutions that would 20 See Kiyotaki and Moore, 1997; Shleifer and Vishny, 1992, 2011; Geanakoplos, 2009; Brunnermeier and Pedersen, 2009; Stein, 2012 for fire-sale explanations. 21 Merrill, Nadauld, Stulz, and Sherland (2012) provide evidence that some insurers sold some nonprime residential mortgage backed securities at fire sale discounts. However, the aggregate volume of transactions they study is quite small. Ellul, Jotikasthira, Lundblad, and Wang (2012) exploit a difference in regulation between property and casualty insurers and life insurers to argue that mark-to-market accounting can exacerbate fire sales. Ellul, Jotikasthira, and Lundblad (2011) argue that regulation forced insurers into fire sales of corporate bonds before the crisis. Coval and Stafford (2007) study fire sales by mutual funds in equity markets. 13 otherwise sell assets at fire-sale prices instead refuse to do so due to a risk-shifting problem. By contrast, Dang, Gorton, and Holmstrom (2010) and Hanson and Sunderam (2013) rely on adverse selection mechanisms. In these models, bad news lowers prices and raises uncertainty about asset valuations; as a result, the scope for adverse selection between informed and uninformed investors becomes too large and trade collapses. Milbrandt (2012) presents a model where trade freezes because financial intermediaries wish to avoid recognizing losses that tighten their capital constraints. In the model, prices fall until the potential profits from transacting exceed the shadow cost of the tightening capital constraints. Buyers’ Strikes 1: Under the buyers’ strikes narrative, transaction volume in nontraditional securitizations should have collapsed during the crisis. III. Data The data we use in our analysis comes from a number of different sources which are described below. A. Mutual Fund and Insurance Holdings Our primary data set is the Thomson Reuters eMAXX database of quarterly security-level holdings of asset-backed securities by US-domiciled mutual funds and insurance companies. Thomson Reuters obtains par value holdings data from regulatory filings—Schedule D for insurance companies and Forms N-CSR(S) and N-Q for mutual funds—as well as directly from these firms. Our sample period runs from 2003Q1 to 2010Q4, which is long enough to allow us to study changes in the demand for securitizations during the boom as well as trading during the crisis. The sample of firm-quarter observations conditions on having at least one asset- or mortgage-backed security in the investment portfolio, including GSE MBS securities. Our cross-sectional results are therefore conditional on having some exposure to securitizations. The firms that are missing from the data are largely those that by regulation or choice never invest in securitizations. 22 22 There are two exceptions to this general statement. The first is that some money market mutual funds (MMMFs) are included in the eMAXX data during the early part of our sample period, but disappear over time. Because of these coverage issues and because risk taking by MMMFs has been studied before (Kacperczyk and Schnabl, 2013; Chernenko and Sunderam, 2013), we exclude MMMFs from our analysis. The second exception is that separate accounts of insurance companies are included in the eMAXX data during 2003-2004 and 2009Q4-2010Q4, but not during 2005Q12009Q3. We therefore exclude separate accounts from the analysis. 14 B. Securities We supplement our holdings data by collecting detailed security-level data from a number of sources. To obtain comprehensive data on the collateral backing each security, we collect security data from the three major credit rating agencies—Fitch, Moody’s, and S&P—and from Bloomberg. 23 Some examples of collateral descriptions in these data are “MBS - Prime Jumbo”, “CDO - Cash ABS - Mezzanine”, “ABS - Floorplans - Auto Dealer”, or “Subprime/Home Equity RMBS”. These descriptions allow us to differentiate between traditional and nontraditional securitizations. To simplify the analysis, we classify securitizations into six broad collateral types: (1) GSE MBS, (2) CMBS, (3) consumer ABS, (4) prime private-label RMBS, (5) nonprime private-label RMBS, and (6) CDOs. Our focus is on explaining the demand for the nontraditional securitizations that were at the heart of the credit boom and crisis. We therefore calculate the share of nonprime RMBS and CDOs in a given investor’s overall bond portfolio and label it nontraditional share. In addition to information on collateral, we collect data on the coupon or spread at issuance from Moody’s and Bloomberg, the initial credit rating from Fitch, Moody’s and S&P, and the time series of outstanding amounts from Bloomberg. C. Mutual Funds We also collect data on the characteristics of the investors in our eMAXX data. We obtain mutual fund characteristics from the CRSP Mutual Fund Database. We construct a fund-level link between eMAXX and CRSP. We first match funds based on the spelling distance between their names and then manually check both matched and unmatched observations. We are able to link 84% (2,355 out of 2,813) mutual funds in eMAXX to CRSP. Our cross-sectional analysis excludes index funds since they follow a passive investment strategy. We also exclude funds that invest solely in government securities since the mandates of these funds routinely restrict them from investing in private securitizations. Finally, we exclude the handful of equity and municipal bond funds that show up in our data because they account for a very 23 eMAXX provides some information on the collateral backing each security, but the information is not granular enough for our purposes. The most common value of the collateral variable, accounting for 68.5% of all security-level observations, is Single Family Mortgage Loans. This is a very broad category that mixes agency securities together with private-label subprime RMBS. 15 small fraction of aggregate securitization holdings and invest a very small share of their portfolio in securitizations. From Morningstar we obtain data on the portfolio managers of all US mutual funds, including their age, educational background, and their start and end dates managing different funds. We use birth year when available and educational background information to infer each manager’s age. We measure manager’s experience using the first time we observe them managing a mutual fund. D. Insurance Companies We obtain insurance company data from AM Best. The AM Best data includes information on insurers’ assets, capitalization, income, realized and unrealized capital gains, insurance premia, and AM Best’s financial strength rating for individual insurers. We are able to match 84% (3,630 out of 4,302) of insurance companies in eMAXX to AM Best. Overall, our data on insurance companies is similar to our data on mutual funds, except that we do not have biographic data on insurer portfolio managers. IV. The Rise A. Aggregate Facts In this section, we use our data to shed light on the drivers of the boom in securitization between 2003 and 2007. As discussed in Section III, the two main explanations we explore are those based on incentives and those based on beliefs. We start by examining aggregate time-series facts about the boom, before turning to more detailed cross-sectional analyses. A.1 Aggregate issuance during the boom We begin by providing some background statistics on the explosive growth of the market for securitizations between 2003 and 2007. Figure 1 shows the dramatic rise and fall of issuance of securitizations. Issuance of nontraditional securitizations almost quadrupled from $98 billion in 2002Q4 to $420 billion at the peak in 2006Q4. By comparison, issuance of traditional securitizations roughly doubled from $103 billion in 2002Q4 to $200 billion at its peak in 2007Q2. Panel B shows that out of traditional securitizations, consumer ABS was roughly stable, and most of the growth took place in CMBS. Panel C shows that the growth of nontraditional securitizations was dominated by nonprime RMBS, while CDO issuance was concentrated in 2005-2006. 16 A.2 Primary market pricing during the boom As this rapid growth in issuance and outstanding amounts was taking place, there was surprisingly little adjustment in the prices of securitizations. In Panel A of Figure 2, we plot the quarterly time series of average credit spreads for AAA-rated securitizations backed by different types of collateral from 2003Q1 to 2007Q4. We compute value-weighted averages of new-issue spreads, restricting attention to the spreads on floating rate notes indexed to 1-, 3-, and 6-month LIBOR to avoid benchmarking issues. Panel A shows that during the boom, credit spreads on AAA-rated nontraditional securitizations were significantly wider than those on other comparably-rated credit assets, including AAA-rated traditional securitizations and corporate bonds. The data reject the conventional view that investors were willing to buy any AAA-rated asset at nearly risk-free rates. The difference in spreads between nontraditional AAA-rated products and traditional AAA-rated bonds, while modest in absolute terms, is economically meaningful relative to typical spreads on AAA-rated assets. Indeed, spreads on AAA-rated nonprime RMBS, CMBS, and CDOs were closer to those on BBB-rated corporate bonds than to those on AAA-rated corporate bonds. During the height of the boom from 2004Q1 to 2007Q2, AAA-rated consumer ABS spreads averaged 9 bps, AAA-rated nonprime RMBS spreads averaged 22 bps, and AAA-rated CDOs spreads averaged 34 bps. This can be compared with corporate bond spreads that averaged 4 bps (over LIBOR) for AAA-rated bonds and 37 bps for BBBrated bonds. Panel B of Figure 2 shows similar variation in the prices of BBB-rated securitizations. BBBrated tranches of traditional consumer ABS securitizations largely traded in line with BBB-rated corporate bonds. By contrast, BBB-rated nonprime RMBS, CMBS, and CDO tranches traded in line with BB-rated and B-rated corporate junk bonds. Specifically, from 2004Q1 to 2007Q2, spreads on BBB-rated consumer ABS averaged 81 bps, spreads on BBB-rated RMBS averaged 179 bps, and those on BBB-rated CDOs averaged 231 bps. This compares with corporate bond spreads that averaged 37 bps (over LIBOR) for BBB-rated bonds, 131 bps for BB-rated bonds, and 231 for Brated bonds. At the same time, we find little difference in the cross-sectional dispersion of spreads within a given rating and collateral class. For instance, from 2004Q1 to 2007Q2 the cross-sectional standard deviation of spreads among AAA-rated consumer ABS averaged 10 bps, whereas the cross-sectional 17 dispersion for AAA-rated CDOs averaged 12 bps. Thus, the bulk of variation in credit spreads within a given rating was across collateral classes as opposed to within collateral class. 24 The very wide spreads on nontraditional securitizations are an underappreciated fact about the boom, and one that creates problems for simple versions of both beliefs and incentives explanations. As discussed above, if beliefs or incentives affect the demand for all securitizations similarly, then we would expect the prices of securitizations to be quite homogenous. For instance, taken literally, in Gennaioli, Shleifer, and Vishny’s (2012) neglected risks model of the boom, all investors should have treated all securitizations as a perfect substitute for riskless Treasuries. Instead, the price variation we observe suggests that the marginal buyer of nontraditional securitizations believed these assets were significantly more risky than traditional securitizations. 25 Moreover, the observed variation in spreads lines up with ex post loss rates, at least directionally. Figure 3 plots average spreads on different asset classes during the boom, against their cumulative loss rates in the bust as reported by Moody’s (2012). The figure shows a positive correlation, indicating that the securities investors regarded as more risky during the boom did in fact suffer more losses during the bust. This does not mean that investors got prices “right” during the boom. Given the ex post losses, investors should have been charging spreads an order of magnitude larger. However, it does show that investors correctly understood the ordering of risk across products. Of course, this does not rule out beliefs or incentives as key drivers of the boom. It merely suggests a more complex story in which agents disagreed about the risks of nontraditional ABS, but investors with more conservative valuations had limited risk-bearing capacity. A.3 Who bought securitizations during the boom? The variation in prices documented above suggests that data on investor holdings are critical for understanding drivers of the boom. They suggest important heterogeneity in investor attitudes towards different types of securitizations, making it important to know which intermediaries were driving demand. Relatively little is known about which intermediaries bought subprime RMBS and 24 Thus, our results do not contradict those in Adelino (2010), who finds that, in the cross-section of AAA-rated subprime RMBS, new issue credit spreads have very little predictive power for future downgrades or default. His findings within an asset class and rating are consistent with our between asset class findings. 25 It seems plausible that the pricing differences between traditional and nontraditional securitizations were, to a significant degree, about expected losses as opposed to differences in risk premia. Since all highly-rated securitization tranches are like “economic catastrophe bonds” which only incur losses in systematically bad times, it is difficult to appeal solely to risk premia to explain the differences between traditional and nontraditional ABS pricing. 18 CDOs during the boom. To some extent, this gap in our knowledge reflects shortcomings in reporting: prior to the crisis, regulatory filings for banks and insurers did not readily distinguish between securitizations and traditional corporate bonds. Fortunately, we can use our eMAXX data to begin to fill in these holes in our understanding. 26 Tables 1 and 2 report estimates of the outstanding quantity of various private credit securities and the estimated holdings of insurers and mutual funds from 2003 to 2010. In Table 1, we report holdings of all private credit securities, which include corporate bonds, foreign bonds, and privately issued ABS. In 2003Q2, insurers owned 26% of private credit securities which trended down to 20% by 2010Q4. Mutual funds owned 7% of private credit securities in 2003Q2 which trended up to 11% by 2010Q4. Thus, our data capture two of the largest investors in credit assets. We use these numbers as a benchmark for assessing the overall weight of insurers and mutual funds within private credit securities markets. We next report holdings of traditional consumer ABS and CMBS. Both insurers and mutual funds were underweight traditional consumer ABS. However, insurers were consistently overweight CMBS, holding approximately one-third of outstanding CMBS from 2003 to 2010. This is consistent with insurers’ long-standing expertise in commercial real estate. According to the Flow of Funds, insurers’ market share of all commercial mortgages, not including CMBS holdings, averaged 28% from 1952 to 2000. 27 Table 2 shows the evolution of outstanding amounts and holdings for nontraditional securitizations—private RMBS and CDOs/CLOs. As shown in Table 2, outstanding RMBS and CDOs/CLOs surged during the boom. However, both insurers and mutual funds were lightening up on subprime RMBS, alt-A RMBS, and CDOs/CLOs exposure from 2003 to 2007. Specifically, comparing insurers’ market shares in Panel B with their share of all private credit securities in Panel 26 Previous estimates, put together in the midst of the crisis, include Lehman Brothers (2007, 2008). According to the National Association of Insurance Commissioners (2012), insurers invest in commercial real estate “for three primary reasons: (1) to increase the level of asset type diversification in their investment portfolio; (2) to match long-term assets with long-term liabilities, because commercial mortgage loans are generally long-term with fixed interest rates and almost always include prepayment (call) protections; and (3) to minimize credit losses, because, based on historical experience, commercial mortgage loans have had modest realized credit losses.” See http://www.naic.org/capital_markets_archive/121026.htm for further background. 27 19 A, we see that insurers became more underweight RMBS and CDOs as issuance boomed from 2003 to 2007Q2. 28 We see similar patterns for mutual funds. 29 This suggests that demand for these assets was not primarily coming from the regulated, unlevered sector. If regulatory arbitrage was driving the surge in investor demand, it was not the desire of insurance companies to arbitrage their capital regulations in order to hold high-yielding securities. Indeed, looking across collateral types, the share of real money investors appears to be negatively correlated with the new issue credit spreads shown in Figure 2. Moreover, the distribution of ratings for insurance company and mutual fund holdings, shown in Figures 4 and 5, shows that they were not tilting their portfolios towards tranches with a particular rating. Approximately 80% of their holdings are rated AAA, which is roughly the share of issuance volume that was AAA-rated. The one exception is holdings of CDOs, where only 40% of holdings are AAA-rated. This suggests that regulatory arbitrage was not creating demand for AAA-rated CDOs among insurers and mutual funds. Though the evidence suggests that mutual funds and insurers did not drive the growth of securitizations, they were still important holders of these products, with about $90 billion in total holdings as of 2007. In the next sections, we turn to more detailed cross-sectional determinants of insurance company and mutual fund holdings. To the extent that these investors were affected by the same incentives and biased beliefs as other investors, cross-sectional patterns in their holdings should shed light on drivers of the boom in securitization more generally. B. Mutual Funds In this section we examine portfolio weights of nontraditional securitizations in the investment portfolios of mutual funds, before turning to insurance companies in the next section. B.1 Variance Decomposition We start by reporting the results of a simple variance decomposition of the share of nontraditional securitizations in a fund’s bond portfolio. The results in Table 3 suggest that variation 28 The National Association of Insurance Commissioners also finds that insurer holdings of CDOs are quite low. See http://www.naic.org/capital_markets_archive/110218.htm. 29 The finding that mutual funds and insurers held very few CDOs is consistent with data on publically announced structured finance write-downs as of January 2009. In short, with the exception of AIG, US-based life and P&C insurers announced few CDO write-downs. Furthermore, few stand-alone commercial banks had large CDO write-downs: almost all bank CDO write-downs were in banks with a broker-dealer. See http://www.docstoc.com/docs/45701126/Creditfluxwritedowns-Microsoft-Excel-Spreadsheet_-78-kb-xls. 20 across funds, as opposed to common variation over time, is crucial for understanding mutual fund holdings of securitizations. Specifically, common variation over time can explain less than 2% of total variation in the portfolio share of nontraditional securitizations. Fund fixed effects, on the other hand, explain more than 60% of total variation. We might expect funds within the same fund family to face similar incentives and to have access to similar information. As a result, fund investment decisions are likely to be correlated within a family. Columns 5-7 confirm this intuition. Fund family fixed effects can explain about 30% of total variation in nontraditional share. Nevertheless, in large families, those with at least 10 funds, there is significant variation across different funds that belong to the same family, suggesting that heterogeneity across individual portfolio mandates and managers plays an important role. The R2 of family fixed effects for these funds is only 11%. Overall, the results of this variance decomposition underscore the role of investor heterogeneity. To assess the beliefs and incentives narratives of the boom, we therefore examine the cross-sectional patterns in mutual fund holdings of nontraditional securitizations. B.2 Mutual Funds versus Variable Annuities To begin our analysis, we focus on a key prediction of the incentives narrative: managers facing strong performance-flow relationships should take more risk. Our ideal experiment would hold fixed fund managers’ information and vary their incentives. This suggests comparing the investment decisions one manager makes for two different funds with different performance-flow sensitivities. Of course, different funds managed by the same manager are likely to have different investment objectives and restrictions, which would confound the comparison. We would like to isolate cases where the same manager is in charge of multiple funds with the same investment objective and benchmark but different performance-flow sensitivities. Variable annuities provide an excellent laboratory to approximate this ideal experiment. Variable annuities are a type of insurance contract whose value depends on the performance of the investment options selected by the purchaser of the insurance policy. The underlying investment options are typically mutual funds. These variable annuity funds are regulated and structured just like regular mutual funds under the Investment Company Act of 1940. The only difference is that variable annuity funds are available only to purchasers of variable annuities. Because they are not widely available and sold as part of an insurance product, variable annuity funds are likely to face different 21 performance-flow relationships, and therefore risk-taking incentives, than regular mutual funds. Table 4 shows that variable annuity funds face lower performance-flow sensitivities than regular mutual funds. CRSP’s coverage of variable annuities does not start until 2008Q3. 30 As a result, we can only look at the performance-flow relationship after the crisis. Specifically, we use monthly data for the January 20009 to June 2013 period. We include all bond and hybrid funds and do not limit the sample to funds in our eMAXX data. Comparing the coefficients on past returns interacted with regular and variable annuity fund dummies, performance-flow relationship is 2-3 times stronger in regular mutual funds than in variable annuity funds. Given such large difference in the performance-flow relationship, the incentives story would predict that regular funds would engage in more risk taking than comparable variable annuity funds. We therefore study a sample of fund pairs where one fund is a variable annuity fund, and its paired fund is a regular mutual fund managed by the same portfolio manager. To construct this paired sample, we start with a sample of 328 variable annuity funds in our eMAXX data as of 2003Q4. We then manually search for a regular mutual fund that is offered by the same fund adviser. For example, Hartford High Yield HLS Fund is a variable annuity fund in our data. It is offered by Hartford Life Insurance Company and its affiliates and is managed by Hartford Investment Management Company (HIMCO). We search the list of regular mutual funds managed by HIMCO for a regular fund with the same investment objective and find one—the Hartford High Yield Fund. According to their prospectuses, the two funds have the same investment goal—high current income with growth of capital a secondary objective—and investment strategy. The text describing the investment goals and investment strategies of the two funds are virtually identical. The two funds are also managed by the same team of three portfolio managers. The only difference between the two funds is that Hartford High Yield HLS Fund serves as an “underlying investment option[s] for certain variable annuity and variable life insurance separate accounts of Hartford Life Insurance Company and its affiliates.” We are able to find matching funds for 158 variable annuities (about one half of the original sample). A handful of regular funds serve as matches for multiple variable annuities. Figure 6 shows the time series of nontraditional share for matched pairs. The number of fund pairs peaks in 2003Q4, 30 CRSP does have some variable annuities before 2008Q3. But their number jumps by about an order of magnitude in 2008Q3. Furthermore, before 2008Q3, just four insurance companies account for 90% of all variable annuities. 22 the point in time as of which we actually form matched pairs, and declines over time. Nontraditional shares track each other quite closely. Figure 6 does not control for differences in size which could in principle affect nontraditional share. However, controlling for size does not affect our results. Despite significant differences in the performance-flow relationship, Figure 6 shows that managers make similar investment decisions in their regular and variable annuity funds. The fact that we see such similar behavior despite meaningful differences in incentives points to the importance of information and beliefs. One caveat is that in addition to facing weaker performance-flow relationship, variable annuity funds also experience somewhat less volatile fund flows. 31 Having more stable funding could have made variable annuity funds more willing to invest in securitizations, offsetting the effects of facing weaker incentives. The difference in the volatility of fund flows is smaller, however, than the difference in the performance-flow relationship. Controlling for objective and size, the volatility of fund flows into variable annuities is lower by around 7%. This is about 13% of the average annualized volatility of 51%. B.3 Manager Experience Manager experience is another characteristic that may affect the strength of the performanceflow relationship facing a mutual fund. Career concern stories emphasize the importance of strong performance for young inexperienced managers. For instance, Chevalier and Ellison (1999) also find that the relationship between fund flows and past performance is stronger in younger funds, and that the termination of younger managers is more sensitive to performance than the termination of older managers. If younger fund managers face stronger performance-flow incentives we might expect them to tilt their portfolios towards higher-yielding, riskier securitizations. In this section, we examine this prediction in more detail. In our analysis, we use two alternative proxies for manager experience, both from Morningstar. Our first proxy is age. Morningstar provides birth year information for about 20% of managers in our data. Otherwise, we impute the age of managers based on their graduation information (Chevalier and Ellison, 1999). Specifically, we have information on the year fund managers received their undergraduate, masters, MBA, and PhD degrees. We assume that managers receive these degrees when they are 22, 27, 27, and 29 years of age. These numbers correspond to the 31 Based on data for the January 2009 – June 2013 period. 23 median age of mutual fund managers receiving these degrees in our data. Our imputed age measure is available for about 60% of fund-quarter observations in our sample. Our second proxy for experience is the number of years each manager has been managing mutual funds. Using the start and end dates for fund-manager pairs in our Morningstar data, we calculate the first time each manager appears in our data. We then compute the manager’s experience as the difference between December 31, 2004 and this date. Of course, the experience of the fund manager is potentially endogenous to the fund’s investment strategy. For example, a fund that intends to invest more heavily in complex securitizations might want to hire younger portfolio managers, or more managers, to analyze these securities. Such endogeneity concerns are one reason we measure manager experience and the number of portfolio managers as of a single point in time. 32 To the extent that the boom in securitization was largely unanticipated in 2004, then if we measure experience as of 2004 it is less likely that funds chose the experience of their managers in response to the boom. Table 5 reports summary statistics for mutual fund managers in our data. The average manager is 45 years old and has 8.5 years of experience managing mutual funds. In addition to experience, we also contrast the behavior of individually-managed and team-managed funds. About 64% of funds in our data are team-managed. The median fund has 2 managers. In Figure 7 we plot the average nontraditional share of funds managed by experienced versus inexperienced managers. The plot on the left splits managers based on their experience managing mutual funds. Both experienced and inexperienced funds start with about a 3% portfolio weight in nontraditional securitizations. Starting in 2004, all managers increase their nontraditional share, but inexperienced managers increase their nontraditional share by significantly more than experienced managers. The nontraditional share of inexperienced managers peaks at around 8% while that of experienced managers peaks at around 5%. The plot on the right splits managers based on their age instead of experience. Here the picture is less clear. Although younger managers tend to have higher nontraditional shares, especially around the peak of the credit boom, the difference is smaller at around 1%. Overall, the difference in results highlights the importance of experience managing mutual funds as opposed to age per se. 32 Greenwood and Nagel (2009) use the same approach. 24 We examine the association between experience and nontraditional share more rigorously in Table 6. Except for 2009, where it is close to zero, the coefficient on experience is negative and statistically significant. Consistent with Figure 7, the coefficient is largest in magnitude during 2007. At that point, the nontraditional share of experienced managers was 3.4% less than the nontraditional share of inexperienced managers. This effect is economically large compared to the average nontraditional share of 6.1%. These splits are consistent with the idea that incentives motivated young managers to take on more risks. However, the incentives narrative rests on the premise that young managers face stronger performance-flow relationships. The existing literature shows that this is the case for equity mutual funds. However, Table 7 shows it is not the case for the bond mutual funds in our data. Consistent with prior literature, we find that fund flows respond strongly to past performance. However, when we interact past performance with experience, we do not find any differences in the performanceflow relationship for young and inexperienced managers on one hand and old and experienced managers on the other hand. If not differences in incentives, what explains the tendency of young managers to invest in nontraditional securitizations? It could be that experience directly affects manager’s beliefs. This idea is explored by Greenwood and Nagel (2009), Malmandier and Nagel (2011a, 2011b), and Campbell, Ramodarai, and Ranish (2013). For example, Greenwood and Nagel (2009) find that young managers were more heavily invested in technology stocks at the peak of the technology bubble, and that they were more likely to exhibit return-chasing behavior. In the context of bond markets, managers who have not managed through a credit cycle, experienced sharp movements in interest rates, or sudden unwinding of carry trades, might be less likely to fully appreciate the risks involved in investing in securitizations. We find evidence consistent with this in Table 8. The effect of experience seems to be highly nonlinear—in our data it appears to matter most when a manager has at least 7-8 years of experience. These are the managers who were active during the market dislocations of fall 1998—which saw turbulent fluctuations in credit spreads following Russian default in August which endangered a highly leveraged hedge fund called LTCM—and perhaps learned about risk in that episode. 33 One of 33 At the same time, it is possible that the crisis was a period during which investors learned a lot about the ability of fund 25 the key results of career concerns models is that learning about skill takes place early on. Here we find the opposite result—little learning appears to take place for the first seven years. Overall, the nonlinearity in the effect of experience on nontraditional share is more consistent with managers learning about risk than with investors learning about manager ability. B.4 Team-managed Funds The size of the management team is another dimension along which funds may differ in their propensity to act on biased beliefs. The social psychology literature on group polarization suggests that social dynamics can lead groups to take on beliefs that are more extreme than the beliefs of any single group member. For example, if the initial tendency of individual group members is to take on a risky gamble or to engage in an altruistic act, then following group discussion, members will take on even more extreme beliefs and attitudes. The social psychology literature has explored two main explanations for the group polarization phenomenon. The informational influence or persuasive argument theory suggests that a kind of non-Bayesian updating tends to occur in groups. Essentially, group discussion tends to elicit arguments in favor of the initially preferred alternative, and group members do not adjust for the fact that they are exposed to a subset of information and possible arguments. 34 According to the interpersonal comparison explanation, group members perceive the group ideal to be more extreme than their individual positions. In an attempt to gain acceptance and to be perceived more favorably by the group, members end up exaggerating their personal preferences. Figure 8 shows that team-managed funds tend to have higher nontraditional share than individually managed funds. Nontraditional share of experienced individuals is virtually flat throughout our sample period. Inexperienced individuals appear to increase their nontraditional share somewhat early on in 2003 and 2004, but otherwise their holdings of securitizations are mostly flat throughout the boom. Inexperienced individuals do appear to dramatically reduce their holdings in early 2009. In contrast, team-managed funds and, in particular, inexperienced team-managed funds stand out. These funds more than double the share of their portfolios allocated to nontraditional managers active at the time. According to career-concerns stories, prior learning about manager ability would result in weaker performance-flow relationship and weaker incentives for experienced managers to invest in securitizations. Although career concerns and learning about manager ability could potentially explain the importance of being active during 1998, they are inconsistent with experience not mattering for managers with less than 7 years of experience. 34 This is related to the idea of “persuasion bias” explored in DeMarzo, Zwiebel, and Vayanos (2003). 26 securitizations. Once the crisis starts, their holdings fall rapidly back to the 2003-2004 levels. Table 9 formalizes these results in a regression setting. Team-managed mutual funds have 2.7% higher nontraditional share in 2007 than individually managed funds. These results are consistent with the idea that team-managed funds take on exposure to nontraditional securitizations due to beliefs. Moreover, the results in Table 7 show that teammanaged funds do not face stronger performance-flow relationships. Thus, differences in incentives are unlikely to explain our results. Overall, our analysis of the cross section of mutual fund holdings of securitizations is more consistent with beliefs narratives of the boom than incentives narratives. The securitizations holdings of mutual funds do not appear to vary with the strength of the performance-flow relationships they face. However, funds managed by teams and young individuals take more risk, consistent with beliefs narratives. Of course, this evidence is simply suggestive, not definitive. Moreover, mutual funds may not face the type of incentive problems relevant for incentives narratives of the boom. Therefore, we next turn to our data on insurance company holdings. C. Insurance Companies Insurance companies are the single largest institutional holder of credit securities. Moreover, they are large regulated financial intermediaries, so their holdings may give us insight into the behavior of other such intermediaries including banks and broker dealers. C.1 Variance Decomposition We again start by a simple variance decomposition of the share of nontraditional securitizations in an insurers’ portfolio. As with mutual funds above, the results in Table 10 suggest that variation across insurers, as opposed to common variation over time, is crucial for understanding insurer holdings of securitizations. Specifically, common variation over time can explain less than 1% of total variation in the portfolio share of nontraditional securitizations. Insurer fixed effects, on the other hand, explain more than 58% of total variation. Among insurers, life insurers account for roughly 18% of corporate bond holdings, while property and casualty (P&C) insurers account for 3%. Figure 9a shows that P&C insurers tend to invest less in nontraditional securitizations than life insurers, though the time-series patterns are similar for both types. Holdings fall in 2003, rise from 2004-2008, and then fall afterwards. The difference in levels between P&C and life insurance holdings of nontraditional securitizations is in 27 line with the general tendency of P&C insurers to have safer portfolios. For instance, according to the 2007Q2 Flow of Funds, Treasuries and Agencies made up 17% of the total assets of P&C insurers. In contrast, Treasuries and Agencies made up 10% of total life insurance assets. These differences can be explained by differences in regulations and the demand for liquidity of P&C and life insurers. Specifically, P&C insurers have a stronger precautionary demand for liquidity because the payouts on their policies tend to be lumpier and harder to predict than the payouts on life policies. Indeed, as we will see in Section V.B, P&C insurers tend to transact more than life insurers, particularly in their holdings of GSE MBS. C.2 Financial Strength We now turn to more detailed analysis of cross-sectional determinants of insurance company holdings. Insurance companies offer an interesting laboratory for testing different versions of the incentives view. There are a number of frictions that could generate agency problems within insurance companies. For instance, equity holders are residual claimants on the values of insurers’ asset portfolios net of policyholder claims. Thus, insurers’ capitalization levels and financial strength ratings may reflect the strength of the agency conflict between their equity holders and their creditors. To combat this problem, regulation requires insurance companies to maintain minimum levels of capital on a risk-adjusted basis. That is, like banks, insurers with riskier portfolios are subject to higher capital requirements. However, to the extent that these regulations are imperfect, less wellcapitalized insurers may have stronger risk-shifting incentives, and therefore be more likely to hold nontraditional securitizations. To test this hypothesis, in Figure 9c we split insurers by their capital-assets ratios as of 2003. Since capital-assets ratios are correlated with size, we define high-capital insurers to be those with above median capital-assets ratios within a given size decile (based on total assets). We hold the classification constant over time to ensure that the results are not driven by a compositional shift in the set of insurers that have low versus high capital ratios. Figure 9c shows insurers with low and high capital ratios initially have similar holdings of nontraditional securitizations in 2003. Over the course of the boom, both types of insurers increase their portfolio allocations to securitizations. However, insurers with low capital ratios increase their portfolio weights far more than insurers with high capital ratios. This is consistent with the notion that these poorly capitalized insurers engaged in risk-shifting. Tables 11 and 12 formalize this 28 evidence in regressions. Table 11 shows that the level of nontraditional share is negatively correlated with insurer capital ratios, with the magnitude of the effects growing over time. The effect is economically significant. The standard deviation of the capital-assets ratio is around 20%, so that a one standard deviation increase in capitalization is associated with a 2.4% (percentage points) lower nontraditional share in 2007, relative to a mean nontraditional share of 2.2%. Panel B of Table 11 shows that the results also hold in differences. Between 2003 and 2007, insurers with low capital ratios increase their nontraditional share more than insurers with high capital ratios. Of course, the capital-assets ratio is a crude proxy for insolvency risk, which is the ultimate driver of risk-shifting behavior. For instance, insurers may have a similar risk of insolvency, but optimally have different capital because their policy liabilities have different risks. To address this concern, we obtain data from A.M. Best on the financial strength of insurers. A.M. Best is a credit rating agency dedicated to the insurance industry. Its credit ratings are based on a quantitative and qualitative evaluation of an insurer’s ability to meet its ongoing policy and contract obligations. In Figure 9b, we split insurers into those with high and low financial strength ratings as of 2003. To ensure that the results are not driven by size, we again define highly-rated insurers to be those with above median ratings within a given size decile. The figure shows a pattern similar to our splits based on capital ratios. Low-rated insurers have initial portfolio allocations to nontraditional securitizations similar to those of high-rated insurers. However, over the course of the boom, lowrated insurers increase their nontraditional shares more than high-rated insurers. Table 12 formalizes this evidence in a regression setting. Again, the magnitudes are economically and statistically significant. In 2007, highly-rated insurers have nontraditional shares 2.3 percentage points lower than low-rated insurers, relative to a mean nontraditional share of 2.4%. Overall, although not conclusive, the evidence is consistent with the notion that financially weaker insurance companies engaged in risk-shifting by purchasing nontraditional securitizations. C.3 Organizational Form Insurers are organized as either stock companies with external shareholders or mutuals which are owned by policyholders. These differences in organizational form may create differences in the strength of the agency conflict between equity holders and other claimants. Specifically, in the case of mutual companies, policy holders effectively provide both equity and debt, which may reduce the scope for risk-shifting. 29 To examine this difference, Figure 9d compares the nontraditional shares of mutual insurance companies versus non-mutuals. Note that here we cannot adjust for size in the way we did when examining insurer capitalization, since insurers are either mutuals or not. Nevertheless, Figure 9d shows that mutual insurance companies tend to have lower nontraditional shares than non-mutuals and this difference increases over the 2003-2007 boom in securitization. Table 13 shows that this difference is not statistically significant. However, the magnitudes are still economically meaningful. Mutuals have about a nontraditional share about 1% lower than non-mutuals of the same size, consistent with the notion that agency conflicts between external shareholders and insurance company policyholders could affect holdings of nontraditional securitizations. In addition to variation in their organizational form, insurers also vary in the way they manage their investment portfolios. Specifically, insurance companies sometimes outsource the management of their portfolios to external managers. The difference between internally managed portfolios and externally managed portfolios may shed light on the impact of agency frictions on portfolio allocations to nontraditional securitizations. On one hand, external managers may have incentives to take excessive risk due to performance-based compensation. On the other hand, internal risk management may bring its own set of agency problems. To examine this difference, Figure 9f compares the nontraditional shares of internally managed versus externally managed insurance portfolios. Again, we cannot adjust for size here since portfolios are either internally managed or not. Nevertheless, Figure 9f shows that internally managed portfolios tend to have higher nontraditional shares than externally managed portfolios during the 2003-2007 boom in securitizations. This is consistent with the idea that externally managed portfolios are more subject to stricter limits on portfolio allocations, possibly due to agency conflicts. Table 14 shows that the difference in levels is not statistically significant. However, the magnitudes of the point estimates are still economically meaningful. Externally managed portfolios have about a nontraditional share about 1% lower than internally managed portfolios for insurers of the same size. In summary, our analysis of insurance companies suggests that incentive problems may have played an important role in driving their demand for nontraditional securitizations. V. The Fall Overall, our evidence suggests that both beliefs and incentives played important roles in 30 driving the boom in securitization. We now turn to the collapse of the market for securitizations from 2007 to 2009. A. Aggregate Evidence As discussed in the hypothesis development section, the conventional macro-finance view of the collapse is that there were significant fire sales of securitizations by leveraged intermediaries during this period. This view suggests that we should observe high transaction volume during the crisis, as the leveraged sector sells securitizations to the unlevered investors in our data. In contrast, narratives of a “buyers’ strike” or market freeze suggest there should be little transaction volume during the crisis. Figure 10 shows the time series of insurer transactions by collateral type. We plot turnover, the absolute value of transactions (i.e. buys + sells) normalized by total holdings. Thus, if an insurer sells its entire existing portfolio and buys a portfolio of new securities, turnover will be 200%. We take a four-quarter moving average to smooth the data series. As reference points, we also plot turnover for GSE MBS, which are in our eMAXX data, and corporate bonds. 35 The figure shows that, during the boom, securitizations generally traded less than GSE MBS and more than corporate bonds. Turnover in nonprime RMBS and traditional consumer ABS is close to turnover in GSE MBS pre-crisis, while CMBS and CDOs trade substantially less. As the crisis sets in, trade in all types of structured falls substantially. In contrast, turnover of GSE MBS and corporate bonds remains relatively constant throughout the crisis. Overall, there is little evidence that real money investors bought large amounts of securitizations in the crisis. There was little trade, and overall par dollars of these products held by mutual fund and insurers fall during the crisis. 36 Figure 11 shows similar patterns for mutual funds. For mutual funds, we do not directly observe transactions; we only observe changes in holdings from one quarter to the next. We therefore impute transactions by adjusting the change in the holdings of each security for the change in the security’s overall outstanding amount due to defaults and prepayments. We scale sales and purchases 35 We obtain data on insurance company corporate bond transactions from Mergent FISD. The underlying source of the data is the same set of regulatory filings that eMAXX collects our securitizations transaction data from. 36 The fall in par dollars held does not reflect trade. It instead reflects prepayments and defaults. When the collateral in a securitization prepays or defaults, the (par) dollar holdings of an investor in the securitization naturally fall. The crisis was associated with both defaults and mortgage prepayments. We use data from Bloomberg on total CUSIP-level amounts outstanding to verify that the decline in holdings is driven by prepayments rather than trade. Insurers and mutual funds hold a constant fraction of the amount outstanding, but the total outstanding declines due to defaults and prepayments. 31 by average holdings during the previous and current quarters, and then take a four-quarter moving average to smooth the data series. The figure shows that the turnover of GSE MBS is about twice as high as the turnover of non-agency asset-backed securities. The turnover of nonprime RMBS trends down over time from around 35% in late 2004 to around 10% by the end of the sample period. The decline in nonprime RMBS turnover is especially pronounced during the crisis: it falls from 27% in 2007Q2 to 14% in 2008Q4. The turnover of CMBS and CDOs is relatively stable before the start of the crisis in the second half of 2007 and experiences similarly large declines during the crisis. Finally, the turnover of GSE MBS and traditional consumer ABS picks up during the crisis, potentially consistent with funds choosing to transact in these more liquid securities. These aggregate facts are inconsistent with simple fire sales stories like Kyotaki and Moore (1997), Geanakoplos (2009), Brunnermeier and Pedersen (2009), Shleifer and Vishny (1992), and Stein (2012). In most fire-sales narratives, outsized declines in prices are mediated by high trade volume. Unless the demand curve for securitizations was very inelastic, the tiny volume of secondary trade we observe seems insufficient to significantly depress equilibrium prices. 37 Overall, given that both prices and trading volume drop substantially, the buyers’ strike narrative seems to be more consistent with the data. One issue that arises with our analysis is that we do not observe the full universe of holders or transactions. Thus, we can only make direct statements about transactions where at least one party is either an insurance company or mutual fund. However, as discussed above, our data covers an economically significant portion of the universe of securitizations, and insurers and mutual funds make up a large fraction of total credit investor assets. One possibility is there were wide-spread firesales that led to a reallocation of securitizations within the class of levered intermediaries, but not between leveraged and unlevered intermediaries. However, to the extent that fire sales generally result in the transfer of security holdings from one broad class of financial intermediary (levered investors) to another (unlevered investors), it is natural to think that our data should capture at least one side of the transaction. 37 For instance, one way to generate an extremely inelastic demand curve in a fire-sale setting would be to posit two types of investors: natural buyers with high valuations and unnatural buyers with very low valuations. Suppose the supply of the risky asset is 100 units, all initially held by natural buyers with high valuations. Now, if some shock forces natural buyers to sell even 1 unit of their holdings, unnatural buyers with low valuations will become the marginal holders and price will plummet precipitously. Of course, this is a knife-edge result. It relies on the risk-bearing capacity of natural buyers being just enough to hold the entire asset supply before the shock. 32 Overall, the evidence appears most consistent with the notion that the collapse of the secondary market for securitizations was driven by a buyer’s strike rather than a fire sale. In models of buyers’ strikes, price declines spiral without any trade. While collapse happens instantly in the models discussed in Section II, one can imagine the mechanisms spiraling more slowly over the course of the crisis in practice. For instance, in adverse selection driven models, increases in the uncertainty of uninformed investors might dampen trading, in turn causing uncertainty to rise further. B. Cross-sectional Evidence We next turn to cross-sectional analyses of our transactions data. While the aggregate data show that the total volume of transactions was small during the bust, there may still be cross-sectional evidence that certain insurers or mutual funds were forced to sell during bust. 38 We begin by analyzing insurance company transactions in Table 15. The table shows that larger insurers tended to buy more nontraditional securitizations during the boom, consistent with their higher holdings of those products. There is some evidence that larger insurers also tended to increase their purchases in the crisis, but the magnitude of the effect is quite small. Otherwise, there is little evidence that insurers were forced to sell nontraditional securitizations during the bust. If anything, there is evidence that stronger insurers with higher financial strength ratings sold more. These are unlikely to be forced sales. Insurers appear to be much more active in transacting in the GSE MBS market. Large insurers are net sellers of GSE MBS in the boom and become increasing net sellers during the crisis. We next turn to mutual fund transactions in Table 16. The table shows that mutual funds experiencing inflows tend to make net purchases of nontraditional securitizations during the boom, a trend that does not change in the crisis. However, mutual funds experiencing outflows during the boom do not tend to sell their nontraditional securitizations. This trend continues in the crisis—there is no evidence that mutual funds suffering outflows are forced to sell their nontraditional securitizations. Mutual funds with high nontraditional share of course purchased more nontraditional securitizations during the boom. These funds ceased their purchases in the bust, but there is no evidence that they actively sold off their holdings during the crisis. Like insurers, mutual funds appear to be much more active transacting in the GSE MBS 38 Indeed, Merrill, Nadauld, Stulz, and Sherland (2012) provide evidence that P&C insurers sold some nonprime residential mortgage backed securities at fire sale discounts during the crisis. 33 market. The sensitivity of GSE MBS purchases to inflows and outflows is much higher than the sensitivity of nontraditional securitization purchases. When mutual funds have inflows, they tend to increase their GSE MBS purchases. When they suffer outflows, they tend to sell GSE MBS. Moreover, these sensitivities increase in the crisis. Overall, the results are consistent with the Scholes (2000) model of liquidity management. Mutual funds and insurers that faced liquidity needs transacted in the most liquid securitization market, the market for GSE MBS. If there were forced sales in any secondary markets for securitizations, it seems likely that those forced sales would take place in the market for GSE MBS. Indeed, some have argued that the Federal Reserve’s first quantitative easing program was so effective because it provided liquidity in the market for GSE MBS at a time when there was high demand for liquidity in that market. 39 Our results are consistent with this notion. VI. Conclusion Nontraditional securitizations—nonprime RMBS and CDOs—were at the heart of the recent financial crisis. The demand for these securities fed the housing boom during the early and mid2000s, while declines in their prices during 2007-2008 generated large losses for financial intermediaries, ultimately imperiling their soundness and triggering a full-blown crisis. We have many anecdotal narratives and theoretical models of the rise and fall of nontraditional securitizations, but little systematic empirical evidence. Using novel micro-data on insurance companies’ and mutual funds’ holdings of both traditional and nontraditional securitizations, this paper begins to shed light on the factors that drove the rise and fall of securitization. We document a number of robust stylized facts that should inform future theoretical and empirical work on the crisis. First, insurance companies and mutual funds as a whole were below market weight in securitizations, in particular nontraditional securitizations. In 2007Q2, right before the start of the crisis, insurance companies and mutual funds held 27.3% of all private credit securities but only 4.3% of nontraditional securitizations. This suggests that the proximate surge in demand for structured products did not stem from these real-money investors. 39 See Sack (2009), who argues that one reason the Federal Reserve’s first quantitative easing program had a “large impact on MBS rates, is that the market began from a point of substantial spreads—ones that were well above market norms. These wide spreads could have reflected poor liquidity and an elevated liquidity premium on these securities.” Krishnamurthy and Vissing-Jorgensen (2013) make a similar argument about the first round of Fed asset purchases. 34 Second, heterogeneity across security classes and investors is key to understanding the crisis. While spreads on AAA-rated traditional securitizations were negligible, spreads on AAA-rated nontraditional securitizations were much wider, in line with spreads on BBB-rated corporate bonds. This suggests a more nuanced view of the boom than the simple tellings of either beliefs or incentives theories, which tend to lump all AAA-rated securitizations together. There were some investors who understood and differentiated between the AAA tranches of traditional and nontraditional securitizations. Simple variance decomposition underlines the importance of investor heterogeneity: variation across investors as opposed to common variation over time is crucial for understanding our holdings data. The behavior of mutual funds is more consistent with beliefs than with incentives. We find little evidence that funds facing stronger performance-flow relationship took on more risk by investing in nontraditional securitizations. Despite not facing stronger performance-flow relationship, inexperienced mutual fund managers invested significantly more in these products than did more experienced managers. This is consistent with the idea that inexperienced managers are more prone to beliefs. Supporting this idea is a discrete shift away from nontraditional securitizations by managers who were active during the market dislocations of fall 1998. Turning to insurance companies, we find that holdings of nontraditional securitizations are concentrated among insurers that are poorly capitalized and have low financial strength ratings. In addition, insurance companies that manage their portfolios internally hold more nontraditional securitizations than those whose portfolios are managed externally, and insurance companies organized as mutuals tend to hold fewer nontraditional securitizations than those organized as stock companies. These findings are consistent with the idea that incentive conflicts play an important in role in explaining insurer holdings of nontraditional securitizations. In summary, our evidence suggests that both beliefs and incentives are likely part of the explanation for the pre-crisis surge in investor demand for these products. In contrast to multiple narratives of the boom, explanations of the bust center on a single narrative of fire sales—the forced sales of securities by investors with high valuations to investors with low valuations. A central, yet largely untested, prediction of fire sales models is that the decline in prices was associated with increased trade between levered intermediaries and other investors. We find no evidence of increased transaction volume as prices of securitizations declined throughout late 35 2007 and 2008. Instead, turnover of nontraditional securitizations experienced large declines during the crisis. Turnover of GSE MBS, and to a lesser extent of traditional consumer ABS, increased; and to the extent that mutual funds suffered outflows, they met redemptions through sales of GSE MBS. Our results therefore challenge the importance of fire sales during the crisis, or at least the canonical models of fire sales, and suggest that the collapse of the secondary market may be better described as a buyers’ strike. We hope that future research builds on the stylized facts documented in our paper to shed further light on the rise and fall of securitization. 36 References Acharya, Viral V., Thomas Cooley, Matthew Richardson, and Ingo Walter, 2010, Manufacturing Tail Risk: A Perspective on the Financial Crisis of 2007-09, Foundations and Trends in Finance 4, 247325. Acharya, Viral V., Thomas Cooley, Matthew Richardson, and Ingo Walter, 2010, Market Failures and Regulatory Failures: Lessons from Past and Present Crises, Masahiro Kawai and Eswar Prasad, ed.: Financial Sector Regulation and Reforms in Emerging Markets (Brookings Institution Press). Acharya, Viral V., Marco Pagano, and Paolo Volpin, 2013, Seeking Alpha: Excess Risk Taking and Competition for Managerial Talent, NBER Working Paper 18891. Acharya, Viral V, Philipp Schnabl, and Gustavo A Suarez, 2012, Securitization without risk transfer, Journal of Financial Economics 107, 515-536. Adrian, Tobias, and Hyun Song Shin, 2013, Procyclical Leverage and Value at Risk, Review of Financial Studies, forthcoming. Ashcraft, Adam B., and Til Schuermann, 2008, Understanding the Securitization of Subprime Mortgage Credit, Foundations and Trends in Finance 2, 191-309. Ashcraft, Adam B., Paul Goldsmith-Pinkham, and James Vickery, 2010, MBS ratings and the mortgage credit boom, Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Report 449. Bär, Michaela, Conrad S. Ciccotello, and Stefan Ruenzi, 2010, Risk management and team-managed mutual funds, Journal of Risk Management in Financial Institutions 4, 57–73. Barnett-Hart, Anna Katherine, 2009, The Story of the CDO Market Meltdown: An Empirical Analysis, Harvard College Undergraduate Thesis. Becker, Bo, and Victoria Ivashina, 2012, Reaching for Yield in the Bond Market, Working Paper. Beltratti, Andrea, and Rene M. Stulz, 2012, The credit crisis around the globe: Why did some banks perform better? Journal of Financial Economics 105, 1–17. Bernanke, Ben S., 2005, Monetary Policy in a World of Mobile Capital, Cato Journal 25, 1-12. Bernanke, Ben S., Carol Bertaut, Laurie Pounder DeMarco, and Steven Kamin, 2011, International Capital Flows and the Returns to Safe Assets in the United States, 2003-2007, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System International Finance Discussion Paper 1014. Black, Fisher, 1986, Noise, The Journal of Finance 41, 529–543. Bliss, Richard T, Mark E Potter, and Christopher Schwarz, 2008, Performance Characteristics of Individually-Managed versus Team-Managed Mutual Funds, Journal of Portfolio Management 34, 110-119. 37 Brunnermeier, Markus, and Yuliy Sannikov, 2013, A Macroeconomic Model with a Financial Sector, American Economic Review, in press. Brunnermeier, Markus, and Lasse Pedersen, 2009, Market Liquidity and Funding Liquidity, Review of Financial Studies 22, 2201–2238. Caballero, Ricardo, 2010, The “Other” Imbalance and the Financial Crisis, NBER Working Paper 15636. Caballero, Ricardo and Emmanuel Farhi, 2013, A Model of the Safe Asset Mechanism (SAM): Safety Traps and Economic Policy, Working Paper. Chernenko, Sergey, and Aditya Vikram Sunderam, 2013, Frictions in Shadow Banking: Evidence from the Lending Behavior of Money Market Mutual Funds, Working Paper. Chevalier, Judith, and Glenn Ellison, 1997, Risk Taking by Mutual Funds as a Response to Incentives, Journal of Political Economy 105, 1167–1200. Chevalier, Judith, and Glenn Ellison, 1999, Career concerns of mutual fund managers, The Quarterly Journal of Economics 114, 389–432. Cordell, Larry, Yilin Huang, and Meredith Williams, 2012, Collateral damage: Sizing and assessing the subprime CDO crisis, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Working Paper 11-30. Coval, Joshua, Standard & Poor's, 2007, Asset fire sales (and purchases) in equity markets, Journal of Financial Economics 86, 479–512. Coval, Joshua, Jakub Jurek, and Erik Stafford, 2009, The Economics of Structured Finance, Journal of Economic Perspectives 23: 3-25. Dang, Tri Vi, Gary B. Gorton, and Bengt Holmstrom, 2011, Ignorance, Debt and Financial Crises, Working Paper. Dávila, Eduardo, 2011, Dissecting Fire Sales Externalities, Working Paper. De Long, J. Bradford, Andrei Shleifer, Lawrence H. Summers, and Robert J. Waldmann, 1990, Noise Trader Risk in Financial Markets, The Journal of Political Economy 98, 703-738. Ellul, Andrew, and Vijay Yerramilli, 2012, Stronger Risk Controls, Lower Risk: Evidence from U.S. Bank Holding Companies, Journal of Finance, Forthcoming. Erel, Isil, Taylor Nadauld, Rene M. Stulz, 2013, Why Did U.S. Banks Invest in Highly-Rated Securitization Tranches? Working Paper. Fabozzi, Frank J., 2005, The Structured Finance Market: An Investor’s Perspective, Financial Analysts Journal, 27-40. 38 Fahlenbrach, Rüdiger, and René M. Stulz, 2011, Bank CEO Incentives and the Credit Crisis, Journal of Financial Economics 99, 11-26. Geanakopolos, John, 2009, The Leverage Cycle, in D. Acemoglu, K. Rogoff, and M. Woodford, eds.: NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2009, pp. 1-65 (University of Chicago Press). Geanakopolos, John, 2010, Incorporating Financial Features into Macroeconomics: Discussion, in Macroeconomic Challenges: The Decade Ahead. Jackson Hole, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Economic Policy Symposium, 2010. Gennaioli, Nicola, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert Vishny, 2012, Journal of Financial Economics, Journal of Financial Economics 104, 452–468. Gerardi, Kristopher, Andreas Lehnert, Shane M. Sherlund, and Paul Willen, 2008, Making Sense of the Subprime Crisis, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 39(2), 69-159. Gorton, Gary B., 2008, The Panic of 2007, in Maintaining Stability in a Changing Financial System, Proceedings of the 2008 Jackson Hole Conference, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, 2008. Gorton, Gary B., and Andrew Metrick, 2010, Regulating the Shadow Banking System, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2010, 261-312. Gorton, Gary B., and Andrew Metrick, Haircuts, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review 92(6). Greenwood, Robin, and Stefan Nagel, 2009, Inexperienced investors and bubbles, Journal of Financial Economics 93, 239–258. Hanson, Samuel Gregory, and Aditya Vikram Sunderam, 2013, Are There Too Many Safe Securities? Securitization and the Incentives for Information Production, Journal of Financial Economics 108, 565–584. Harrison, J Michael, and David M. Kreps, 1978, Speculative Investor Behavior in a Stock Market with Heterogeneous Expectations, The Quarterly Journal of Economics 92(2), 323-36. Hong, Harrison, and Jeremy C. Stein, 2003, Differences of Opinion, Short-Sales Constraints and Market Crashes, Review of Financial Studies 16, 487-525. Iannotta, Giuliano, and George Pennacchi, 2012, Bank Regulation, Credit Ratings, and Systematic Risk, Working Paper. Isenberg, Daniel J., 1986, Group polarization: A critical review and meta-analysis, Journal of Personal and Social Psychology 50(6), 1141-1151. Jensen, Michael, and William H. Meckling, 1976, Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and Ownership Structure, Journal of Financial Economics 3, 305-360. Kacperczyk, Marcin, and Philipp Schnabl, 2013, How safe are money market funds? Quarterly Journal of Economics 128, 1073–1122. 39 Keys, Benjamin J., Tanmoy K. Mukherjee, Amit Seru, and Vikrant Vig, 2009, Did Securitization Lead to Lax Screening? Evidence from Subprime Loans, Quarterly Journal of Economics 125, 307362. Kiyotaki, Nobuhiro, and John Moore, 1997, Credit Cycles, Journal of Political Economy 105, 211248. Landier, Augustin, David Sraer, and David Thesmar, 2011. The Risk-Shifting Hypothesis, IDEI Working Paper 699. Lorenzoni, G., 2008, Inefficient Credit Booms, Review of Economic Studies 75, 809-833. Merrill, Craig, Taylor Nadauld, Rene M Stulz, and Shane M Sherlund, 2013, Why did financial institutions sell RMBS at fire sale prices during the financial crisis? Charles A. Dice Working Paper 2013-2. Milbradt, Konstantin, 2012, Level 3 Assets: Booking Profits, Concealing Losses, Review of Financial Studies 25, 55-95. Miller, Edward M., 1977, Risk, Uncertainty, and Divergence of Opinion, The Journal of Finance 32, 1151-1168. Myers, David G, and Helmut Lamm, 1976, The Group Polarization Phenomenon, Psychological Bulletin 83, 602–627. Morris, Stephen, and Hyun Song Shin, 2012, Contagious Adverse Selection, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 4, 1-21. Rajan, Uday, Amir Seru, and Vikrant Vig, 2012, The Failure of Models that Predict Failure: Distance, Incentives and Defaults, Journal of Financial Economics, accepted. Scheinkman, Jose, and Wei Xiong, 2003, Overconfidence and speculative bubbles, Journal of Political Economy 111, 1183–1219. Shin, H. “Global Banking Glut and Loan Risk Premium”, Mundell-Fleming Lecture, IMF Economic Review 60 (2), 155-192, 2012 Shleifer, Andrei, and Robert Vishny, 1992, Liquidation Values and Debt Capacity: A Market Equilibrium Approach, Journal of Finance 47, 1343-1366. Shleifer, Andrei and Robert Vishny, 2011, Fire Sales in Finance and Macroeconomics, Journal of Economic Perspectives 25, 29-48. 40 Figure 1 Issuance of Traditional and Nontraditional Securitizations This figure shows quarterly issuance of traditional and nontraditional securitizations in SDC data. Traditional securitizations include CMBS, prime RMBS, consumer ABS, and other ABS. Nontraditional securitizations include nonprime RMBS and CDOs. (a) Traditional vs. Nontraditional (b) Traditional Traditional vs. Non-Traditional Securitization Traditional Securitization 100 Proceeds ($ billion) Proceeds ($ billion) 400 300 200 100 80 60 40 20 2008q4 2007q4 2006q4 2005q4 2004q4 2003q4 CMBS Consumer ABS Non-traditional (c) Nontraditional Prime RMBS Other ABS (d) CDO Collateralized Debt Obligations Nontraditional Securitization 100 Proceeds ($ billion) 300 200 100 80 60 40 20 CBO CDO 42 CLO ABS CDO 2008q4 2007q4 2006q4 2005q4 2004q4 2003q4 2002q4 2001q4 2000q4 1999q4 2008q4 2007q4 2006q4 2005q4 2004q4 2003q4 2001q4 2000q4 1999q4 2002q4 Nonprime RMBS 1998q4 0 0 1998q4 Proceeds ($ billion) 2002q4 2001q4 2000q4 1998q4 2008q4 2006q4 2004q4 2002q4 2000q4 1998q4 1996q4 1994q4 1992q4 1990q4 1988q4 Traditional 1999q4 0 0 Figure 2 Credit Spreads on Securitizations and Corporate Bonds, 2003-2007 This figure plots the credit spreads on newly issued securitizations versus the spreads on corporate bonds. Each quarter we compute the value-weighted average credit spread on securitizations, based on the underlying collateral. We compute this average for traditional consumer asset-backed securities backed by credit card loans, automotive loans, student loans, and other personal loans (“Consumer ABS”); private residential mortgage backed securities (RMBS) backed by subprime and Alt-A mortgages (“Non-Prime RMBS”); commercial mortgage backed securities (CMBS); and collateralized debt obligations (“CDOs”). We compute value-weighted averages of new-issue spreads, restricting attention to the spreads on floating rate notes indexed to 1-, 3-, and 6-month LIBOR to avoid benchmarking issues. In Panel A, we plot the credit spreads on newly issued AAA-rated securitizations. For reference, we plot the average secondary spreads over LIBOR (based on interest rate swaps) on 3-year AAA-rated and BBB-rated corporate bonds from Barclays. In Panel B, we plot the credit spreads on newly issued BBB-rated securitizations alongside the spreads on BBB-rated, BB-rated and B-rated corporate bonds. (a) AAA (b) BBB 500 100 450 400 80 350 bps bps 300 60 250 200 40 150 100 20 50 0 0 2003q2 2003q2 2004q2 2003q4 2005q2 2004q4 AAA Consumer ABS AAA Non-Prime RMBS AAA Corporate 2006q2 2005q4 2004q2 2003q4 2007q2 2006q4 2007q4 AAA CMBS AAA CDOs BBB Corporate 43 2005q2 2004q4 BBB Consumer ABS BBB Non-Prime RMBS BBB Corporate B Corporate 2006q2 2005q4 2007q2 2006q4 BBB CMBS BBB CDOs BB Corporate 2007q4 Figure 3 Ex-Ante Spreads versus Realized Loss Rates This figure shows realized loss rates versus average spreads during the boom, 2003–2007. Realized loss rates are from Moody’s (2012). Corporate spreads are from Bloomberg. For securitizations, we compute value-weighted averages of new-issue spreads for securities in our eMAXX data, restricting attention to the spreads on floating rate notes indexed to 1-, 3-, and 6-month LIBOR to avoid benchmarking issues. (a) (b) 25 AAA Securitization vs. Corporate Spreads 8 M BS R e BB B N on - pr im 70 60 O 50 BB B C D 40 or at e or p B C or B at B e B or p C BB C B BB AA AAA C A Coorp C rp o or o ra po ra te ra te te BB B C or po ra te on su m C er A M BS BS 30 20 10 0 M BS R e pr im 1 1.5 Average Spread in Boom 2 2.5 44 or at e on N A .5 1 Average Spread in Boom BB C or p AA 0 Fitted values BBB Securitization vs. Corporate Spreads Cumulative 5 yr Loss AA A 6 (c) .5 AA AAA C A orp C o on ra t AA sume er A C A M BS BS BB B C or po ra te 5 4 Average Spread in Boom 0 2 Cumulative 5 yr Loss 0 15 20 or p C B or at e 0 10 or at e Cumulative 5 yr Loss 30 20 10 AAA AAA BCBCoCoo Brprporpoo C rarara or tetete po ra te BB C or p 0 Cumulative 5 yr Loss C C C D C O Co r po ra 40 te Corporate Spreads 1.5 Figure 4 Rating Composition of Mutual Fund Portfolios For each mutual fund-quarter observation we calculate the fraction of the portfolio invested in tranches with di↵erent ratings. We then calculate the average across funds. We do this separately for di↵erent types of securitizations: consumer ABS, CDO, CMBS, and nonprime RMBS. We use at-issuance ratings from Moody’s and restrict the sample to deals rated by Moody’s. NR means that the overall securitization deal was rated by Moody’s but the specific tranche was not. (a) Consumer ABS (b) CDO .8 .5 .4 .6 .3 .4 .2 .2 .1 0 0 2003q4 2004q4 2005q4 Aaa Ba 2006q4 2007q4 Aa B 2008q4 A Caa 2009q4 2010q4 2003q4 Baa NR 2004q4 2005q4 Aaa Ba (c) CMBS 2006q4 Aa B 2007q4 2008q4 A Caa 2009q4 2010q4 Baa NR (d) Nonprime RMBS 1 .8 .8 .6 .6 .4 .4 .2 .2 0 0 2003q4 2004q4 Aaa Ba 2005q4 2006q4 Aa B 2007q4 A Caa 2008q4 2009q4 2010q4 Baa NR 2003q4 2004q4 Aaa Ba 45 2005q4 2006q4 Aa B 2007q4 A Caa 2008q4 2009q4 Baa NR 2010q4 Figure 5 Rating Composition of Insurance Company Portfolios For each insurance firm-quarter observation we calculate the fraction of the portfolio invested in tranches with di↵erent ratings. We then calculate the average across insurance firms. We do this separately for di↵erent types of securitizations: consumer ABS, CDO, CMBS, and nonprime RMBS. We use at-issuance ratings from Moody’s and restrict the sample to deals rated by Moody’s. NR means that the overall securitization deal was rated by Moody’s but the specific tranche was not. (a) Consumer ABS (b) CDO 1 .6 .8 .4 .6 .4 .2 .2 0 0 2003q4 2004q4 2005q4 Aaa Ba 2006q4 2007q4 Aa B 2008q4 A Caa 2009q4 2010q4 2003q4 Baa NR 2004q4 2005q4 Aaa Ba (c) CMBS 2006q4 Aa B 2007q4 2008q4 A Caa 2009q4 2010q4 Baa NR (d) Nonprime RMBS 1 1 .8 .8 .6 .6 .4 .4 .2 .2 0 0 2003q4 2004q4 Aaa Ba 2005q4 2006q4 Aa B 2007q4 A Caa 2008q4 2009q4 2010q4 Baa NR 2003q4 2004q4 Aaa Ba 46 2005q4 2006q4 Aa B 2007q4 A Caa 2008q4 2009q4 Baa NR 2010q4 Figure 6 Nontraditional Share of Variable Annuities versus Regular Mutual Funds The sample consists of matched pairs of variable annuities and regular mutual funds that have the same investment objectives and are managed by the same portfolio managers. We form the sample of matched pairs as of 2003Q4. .07 160 140 .05 120 .04 100 .03 .02 80 2003q3 2004q3 2005q3 2006q3 2007q3 2008q3 2009q3 2010q3 Variable Annuity Funds # Fund Pairs 47 Regular Mutual Funds # Fund Pairs Nontraditional share .06 Figure 7 Mutual Fund Manager Experience and Nontraditional Share This figure shows the average nontraditional share of mutual funds managed by experienced versus inexperienced portfolio managers. We split mutual funds into two groups based on the median value of manager experience in Panel A and of manager age in Panel B. Manager characteristics are measured as of 2004Q4. For team-managed funds we take the average of individual managers. (b) Age .08 .08 .07 .07 Nontraditional share Nontraditional share (a) Experience .06 .05 .04 .06 .05 .04 .03 .03 .02 .02 2003q4 2004q4 2005q4 2006q4 2007q4 2008q4 2009q4 2010q4 Inexperienced Experienced 2003q4 2004q4 2005q4 2006q4 2007q4 2008q4 2009q4 2010q4 Young 48 Old Figure 8 Experience and Nontraditional Share in Individually- versus Team-Managed Funds This figure shows the average nontraditional share of mutual funds managed by experienced versus inexperienced individual managers and teams. We separately split individually- and team-managed funds into experienced and inexperienced ones based on their median value of experience. Manager characteristics are measured as of 2004Q4. For team-managed funds we take the average of individual managers. .1 Nontraditional share .08 .06 .04 .02 2003q4 2004q4 2005q4 2006q4 2007q4 2008q4 2009q4 2010q4 Inexperienced individual Inexperienced team 49 Experienced individual Experienced team Figure 9 Insurance Company Characteristics and Nontraditional Share This figure shows the average nontraditional share of insurance companies split based on di↵erent characteristics. Rating is the 2002 financial strength rating from AM Best. (a) Type (b) Rating 0.080 0.080 0.070 0.060 0.060 0.040 0.050 0.020 0.040 0.000 0.030 2003q4 2004q4 2005q4 2006q4 2007q4 2008q4 2009q4 2010q4 Life 2003q4 2004q4 2005q4 2006q4 2007q4 2008q4 2009q4 2010q4 P&C Weak rating (c) Capital Strong rating (d) Mutual 0.070 0.060 0.060 0.050 0.050 0.040 0.040 0.030 0.030 2003q4 2004q4 2005q4 2006q4 2007q4 2008q4 2009q4 2010q4 Weak capital 2003q4 2004q4 2005q4 2006q4 2007q4 2008q4 2009q4 2010q4 Strong capital Non mutual (e) Public Mutual (f ) External 0.060 .06 0.055 .05 0.050 0.045 .04 0.040 .03 0.035 2003q4 2004q4 2005q4 2006q4 2007q4 2008q4 2009q4 2010q4 Private Public 2003q3 2004q3 2005q3 2006q3 Internal 50 2007q3 2008q3 External 2009q3 2010q3 Figure 10 Insurance Company Portfolio Turnover Turnover is the absolute value of transactions, buys and sells, normalized by average holdings during quarters t 1 and t. Transactions in private securitizations and in GSE MBS are from eMAXX. Transactions in corporate bonds are from Mergent FISD. (a) ABS (b) CDO .3 .3 .25 .2 .2 .15 .1 .1 .05 0 2003q4 2004q4 2005q4 Agencies 2006q4 2007q4 2008q4 Corporates 2009q4 2010q4 2003q4 ABS 2004q4 2005q4 Agencies (c) CMBS 2006q4 2007q4 2008q4 Corporates 2009q4 2010q4 ABS (d) Nonprime RMBS .3 .3 .25 .25 .2 .2 .15 .15 .1 .1 .05 .05 2003q4 2004q4 2005q4 Agencies 2006q4 2007q4 Corporates 2008q4 2009q4 2010q4 ABS 2003q4 2004q4 2005q4 Agencies 51 2006q4 2007q4 Corporates 2008q4 2009q4 ABS 2010q4 Figure 11 Mutual Fund Portfolio Turnover Turnover is the absolute value of transactions, buys and sells, normalized by average holdings during quarters t 1 and t. Sales and purchases are calculated as the change in par holdings adjusted for the change in security’s outstanding amount using outstanding factors from Bloomberg. Interestand principal-only tranches are excluded using the following screens: a) zero original balance from any of the three rating agencies; b) tranche name; c) fund’s holdings of a security are greater than 150% of outstanding balance; d) security weight in the fund’s portfolio is greater than 10%; e) outstanding factor is less than 0.01 or greater than 2; f) fund’s holdings of the security are greater than $100 million. The sample of funds consists of bond and hybrid funds matched to CRSP. .8 .6 .4 .2 0 2003q4 2004q4 2005q4 2006q4 GSE MBS CDO Nonprime RMBS 52 2007q4 2008q4 2009q4 Consumer ABS CMBS 2010q4 Table 1 Outstanding asset-backed securities and holdings of insurers and mutual funds by underlying collateral type, 2003-2010 This table reports estimates of the outstanding balance of US asset-backed securities by underlying collateral type. The sources for estimated outstanding are listed in the footnotes. For each collateral type, we compute aggregate par holdings by insurers and mutual funds using our eMaxx holdings data. For the market, % refers to the share of a given collateral type in the aggregate outstanding amount of all private credit securities. For insurance and mutual funds, % refers to the shares of a given collateral type in the aggregate portfolios of insurance firms and mutual funds. All private credit securitiesa 53 2003Q2 2003Q4 2004Q2 2004Q4 2005Q2 2005Q4 2006Q2 2006Q4 2007Q2 2007Q4 2008Q2 2008Q4 2009Q2 2009Q4 2010Q2 2010Q4 Market $ % 6,776 100.0% 7,178 100.0% 7,524 100.0% 8,071 100.0% 8,541 100.0% 8,852 100.0% 9,415 100.0% 10,103 100.0% 10,879 100.0% 11,577 100.0% 11,698 100.0% 11,170 100.0% 11,676 100.0% 11,654 100.0% 11,432 100.0% 11,816 100.0% Insurance $ % 1,755 25.9% 1,829 25.5% 1,927 25.6% 2,002 24.8% 2,060 24.1% 2,088 23.6% 2,127 22.6% 2,097 20.8% 2,132 19.6% 2,145 18.5% 2,143 18.3% 2,085 18.7% 2,146 18.4% 2,226 19.1% 2,288 20.0% 2,353 19.9% Mutual Funds $ % 504 7.4% 531 7.4% 560 7.4% 594 7.4% 631 7.4% 660 7.5% 706 7.5% 764 7.6% 837 7.7% 886 7.7% 958 8.2% 956 8.6% 1,035 8.9% 1,121 9.6% 1,181 10.3% 1,243 10.5% Traditional consumer ABSb Mutual Market Insurance Funds $ % $ % $ % 701 10.3% 93 5.3% 22 4.4% 721 10.0% 100 5.5% 20 3.8% 726 9.7% 101 5.3% 25 4.4% 729 9.0% 98 4.9% 24 4.1% 762 8.9% 90 4.4% 24 3.8% 781 8.8% 89 4.3% 28 4.3% 794 8.4% 84 4.0% 23 3.3% 836 8.3% 76 3.6% 24 3.1% 870 8.0% 64 3.0% 27 3.2% 894 7.7% 68 3.2% 26 2.9% 894 7.6% 85 4.0% 34 3.6% 835 7.5% 75 3.6% 27 2.8% 808 6.9% 68 3.2% 26 2.5% 798 6.8% 70 3.1% 23 2.1% 744 6.5% 75 3.3% 32 2.7% 690 5.8% 68 2.9% 28 2.3% CMBSc Market $ % 313 4.6% 343 4.8% 368 4.9% 394 4.9% 439 5.1% 506 5.7% 553 5.9% 614 6.1% 697 6.4% 758 6.5% 741 6.3% 718 6.4% 703 6.0% 671 5.8% 647 5.7% 617 5.2% Insurance $ % 108 6.1% 119 6.5% 130 6.7% 145 7.2% 153 7.4% 168 8.1% 185 8.7% 189 9.0% 195 9.1% 216 10.1% 222 10.4% 223 10.7% 221 10.3% 227 10.2% 220 9.6% 208 8.8% Mutual Funds $ % 10 2.0% 11 2.0% 11 2.0% 13 2.1% 15 2.3% 21 3.2% 19 2.7% 24 3.2% 38 4.5% 41 4.6% 48 5.0% 50 5.3% 48 4.7% 52 4.6% 58 4.9% 59 4.8% a Data on the outstanding quantity of all private credit securities, which include corporate bonds, foreign bonds, and privately issued ABS is from table L.212 ‘Corporate and Foreign Bonds’ of the Federal Reserve’s Financial Accounts of the United States (i.e. the Z1 release which was formerly known as the Flow of Funds Accounts). Data on the holding of insurers (which includes both P&C and life insurers) and mutual funds (which excludes money market mutual funds) is also from Table L.212. b Data on the outstanding quantity of traditional consumer ABS, which consists of ABS collateralized by credit card debt, automotive loans, student loans, manufactured housing and equipment loans, is from SIFMA at http://www.sifma.org/uploadedFiles/Research/Statistics/StatisticsFiles/SF-US-ABS-SIFMA.xls. c Data on the outstanding quantity of CMBS, which consists of MBS collateralized by commercial mortgages and multifamily residential mortgages, is from tables L.219 ‘Multifamily Residential Mortgages’ and Table L.220 ‘Commercial Mortgages’ of the Federal Reserve’s Financial Accounts of the United States. 54 Insurance $ % 29 1.6% 22 1.2% 29 1.5% 51 2.5% 55 2.7% 62 3.0% 69 3.2% 74 3.5% 73 3.4% 84 3.9% 83 3.9% 82 3.9% 74 3.4% 67 3.0% 62 2.7% 54 2.3% Mutual Funds $ % 6 1.3% 5 0.9% 10 1.7% 10 1.7% 11 1.7% 13 2.0% 12 1.7% 15 1.9% 19 2.2% 25 2.8% 23 2.4% 22 2.3% 18 1.8% 16 1.5% 20 1.7% 22 1.8% Market $ % 563 8.3% 601 8.4% 765 10.2% 929 11.5% 1,139 13.3% 1,349 15.2% 1,579 16.8% 1,808 17.9% 1,852 17.0% 1,895 16.4% 1,729 14.8% 1,563 14.0% 1,437 12.3% 1,311 11.2% 1,221 10.7% 1,131 9.6% Insurance $ % 73 4.2% 56 3.1% 65 3.4% 83 4.2% 96 4.7% 109 5.2% 117 5.5% 122 5.8% 115 5.4% 130 6.1% 138 6.4% 136 6.5% 126 5.9% 125 5.6% 119 5.2% 107 4.6% Subprime RMBSb Mutual Funds $ % 8 1.6% 8 1.5% 10 1.8% 14 2.4% 16 2.5% 18 2.7% 14 2.0% 16 2.1% 19 2.3% 17 1.9% 18 1.9% 16 1.7% 13 1.3% 11 1.0% 13 1.1% 14 1.1% Market $ % 279 4.1% 302 4.2% 347 4.6% 391 4.8% 454 5.3% 517 5.8% 627 6.7% 795 7.9% 961 8.8% 1,005 8.7% 1,004 8.6% 1,018 9.1% 987 8.5% 936 8.0% 872 7.6% 838 7.1% Insurance $ % 21 1.2% 20 1.1% 21 1.1% 23 1.1% 21 1.0% 24 1.2% 24 1.1% 23 1.1% 21 1.0% 21 1.0% 27 1.3% 27 1.3% 26 1.2% 26 1.2% 25 1.1% 24 1.0% CDOsc Mutual Funds $ % 4 0.8% 5 0.9% 6 1.0% 5 0.9% 3 0.5% 2 0.4% 2 0.2% 2 0.2% 2 0.3% 2 0.3% 4 0.4% 2 0.2% 2 0.2% 1 0.1% 2 0.1% 2 0.1% Data on the outstanding quantity of CBOs, CDOs, and CLOs is from SIFMA at http://www.sifma.org/uploadedFiles/Research/Statistics/StatisticsFiles/SF-Global-CDO-SIFMA.xls. SIFMA provides data on global CBOs, CDOs, and CLOs outstandings. Based on SIFMA’s issuance data by currency, we assume that 75% of outstanding CDOs and CLOs are USD-denominated. c Data on the outstanding quantity of subprime RMBS, a subset of all private RMBS, is from SIFMA at http://www.sifma.org/uploadedFiles/Research/Statistics/StatisticsFiles/SF-US-ABS-SIFMA.xls. Specifically, we use the series for ‘home equity ABS’—market-speak for subprime RMBS. b Data on the outstanding quantity of private RMBS, which consists of private MBS collateralized by first lien single-family residential mortgages, is from table L.218 ‘Home Mortgages’ of Federal Reserve’s Financial Accounts of the United States. a 2003Q2 2003Q4 2004Q2 2004Q4 2005Q2 2005Q4 2006Q2 2006Q4 2007Q2 2007Q4 2008Q2 2008Q4 2009Q2 2009Q4 2010Q2 2010Q4 Market $ % 297 4.4% 276 3.8% 314 4.2% 351 4.3% 388 4.5% 425 4.8% 462 4.9% 499 4.9% 525 4.8% 552 4.8% 518 4.4% 484 4.3% 436 3.7% 389 3.3% 350 3.1% 311 2.6% All Private RMBSa This table reports estimates of the outstanding balance of US asset-backed securities by underlying collateral type. The sources for estimated outstanding are listed in the footnotes. For each collateral type, we compute aggregate par holdings by insurers and mutual funds using our eMaxx holdings data. For the market, % refers to the share of a given collateral type in the aggregate outstanding amount of all private credit securities. For insurance and mutual funds, % refers to the shares of a given collateral type in the aggregate portfolios of insurance firms and mutual funds. Table 2 Outstanding asset-backed securities and holdings of insurers and mutual funds by underlying collateral type, 2003-2010 Table 3 Variance Decomposition of Mutual Funds’ Nontraditional Share This table reports the R2 from the regressions of mutual funds’ nontraditional share on various fixed e↵ects. The sample of funds consists of bond and hybrid mutual funds. The sample period is 2003Q1–2010Q4. Adjusted R N 2 Date Objective 0.017 0.145 26550 26550 Objective ⇥ Date 0.175 26550 55 Family Fund All 5 Funds 10 Funds 0.623 0.312 0.231 0.116 26550 24331 18454 11762 Table 4 Performance-Flow Relationship in Variable Annuity versus Regular Mutual Funds This table reports the results of the performance-flow regressions for variable annuity versus regular mutual funds. The sample consists of all bond and hybrid funds in CRSP Mutual Fund Database. The sample period is January 2009–June 2013. Fund flows are winsorized at the 1st and 99th percentiles in columns 1–2 and at the 5th and 95th percentiles in columns 3–4. Objective-month date fixed e↵ects are included in all specifications. Standard errors are adjusted for clustering by fund in columns 2–4. *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at 10%, 5%, and 1%. Variable annuity Rett 1⇥ Regular Rett 1⇥ Variable annuity Log(TNAt Rett 1⇥ (1) 0.003⇤⇤⇤ (0.001) 0.192⇤⇤⇤ (0.025) 0.057⇤ (0.031) (2) 0.003⇤⇤ (0.002) 0.192⇤⇤⇤ (0.034) 0.057 (0.036) (3) 0.001 (0.001) 0.121⇤⇤⇤ (0.016) 0.057⇤⇤⇤ (0.016) 0.018⇤⇤⇤ (0.000) 323208 0.016 0.018⇤⇤⇤ (0.001) 323208 0.016 0.009⇤⇤⇤ (0.000) 323208 0.036 1) Log(TNAt Constant N Adjusted R2 1) 56 (4) 0.000 (0.001) 0.111⇤⇤⇤ (0.018) 0.044⇤⇤ (0.018) 0.001⇤⇤⇤ (0.000) 0.005⇤⇤⇤ (0.002) 0.012⇤⇤⇤ (0.001) 323208 0.038 Table 5 Summary Statistics: Mutual Fund Managers This table reports summary statistics for mutual fund managers in our data. The unit of observation is fund-quarter. The sample of funds consists of bond and hybrid mutual funds. The sample period is 2003Q1–2010Q4. Fund manager characteristics are measured as of December 31, 2004. Team managed Number of fund managers Age Experience N 23377 23377 15379 22832 Mean 0.7 2.7 45.2 8.5 57 Median 1.0 2.0 44.0 7.9 SD 0.5 2.5 7.1 4.5 Min 0.0 0.0 29.0 0.0 Max 1.0 21.0 71.0 29.1 Table 6 Nontraditional Share of Mutual Funds This table reports the results of the regressions of mutual funds’ nontraditional share on fund and portfolio manager characteristics. Experienced is a binary variable equal to 1 for funds above the median of experience. Manager characteristics are measured as of 2004Q4. Retail share is the share of retail share classes in fund assets. Family retail share is the share of retail share classes in fund family assets. Family ETF, equity, and taxable shares are the shares of ETFs, equity funds, and taxable bond funds in fund family assets. The omitted category is municipal funds. Objective fixed e↵ects are included. Standard errors are adjusted for clustering by fund. *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at 10%, 5%, and 1%. Experienced Log(TNA) Log(Family TNA) Log(Fund age) Retail share Family retail share Family ETF share Family equity share Family taxable share Constant N Adjusted R2 2004 0.006⇤ (0.004) 0.002 (0.002) 0.002 (0.001) 0.002 (0.003) 0.007 (0.007) 0.003 (0.008) 0.005 (0.024) 0.003 (0.012) 0.031⇤⇤ (0.014) 0.006 (0.014) 3102 0.287 2005 0.009⇤⇤ (0.004) 0.003 (0.002) 0.001 (0.001) 0.010⇤⇤ (0.004) 0.019⇤⇤ (0.008) 0.019⇤ (0.010) 0.018 (0.034) 0.003 (0.027) 0.026 (0.028) 0.042 (0.032) 2969 0.303 58 2006 0.020⇤⇤⇤ (0.006) 0.005⇤ (0.003) 0.000 (0.002) 0.011⇤ (0.007) 0.020⇤ (0.010) 0.035⇤⇤ (0.014) 0.017 (0.035) 0.001 (0.047) 0.033 (0.048) 0.062 (0.054) 2915 0.272 2007 0.034⇤⇤⇤ (0.007) 0.005⇤ (0.003) 0.002 (0.002) 0.013⇤ (0.008) 0.010 (0.010) 0.006 (0.015) 0.049 (0.045) 0.019 (0.028) 0.087⇤⇤ (0.036) 0.055⇤ (0.031) 2935 0.185 2008 0.023⇤⇤⇤ (0.007) 0.001 (0.003) 0.001 (0.002) 0.003 (0.006) 0.009 (0.010) 0.018 (0.016) 0.068⇤⇤ (0.029) 0.019 (0.036) 0.097⇤⇤ (0.044) 0.024 (0.035) 2888 0.177 2009 0.001 (0.006) 0.003 (0.002) 0.001 (0.002) 0.006 (0.005) 0.009 (0.014) 0.021 (0.022) 0.096⇤⇤ (0.038) 0.026 (0.032) 0.054 (0.034) 0.023 (0.034) 2706 0.118 Table 7 Manager Experience and Performance-Flow Relationship This table reports the results of monthly performance-flow regressions for bond and hybrid mutual funds in our sample. The sample period is 2003–2010. Fund manager characteristics are measured as of December 31, 2004. Fund flows are winsorized at the 1st and 99th percentiles. Objective-date fixed e↵ects are included. Heteroskedasticity robust standard errors are reported. *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at 10%, 5%, and 1%. Returnt 1 Log(TNA)t Returnt 1 1⇥ Log(TNA)t 1⇥ Old 1 (1) 0.368⇤⇤⇤ (0.037) 0.002⇤⇤⇤ (0.000) 0.016⇤⇤⇤ (0.004) Old Returnt (2) 0.379⇤⇤⇤ (0.043) 0.001⇤⇤⇤ (0.000) 0.015⇤⇤⇤ (0.004) 0.001⇤⇤ (0.000) 0.005 (0.017) 1⇥ Experienced Team managed Returnt 1⇥ Constant N Adjusted R2 (4) 0.362⇤⇤⇤ (0.040) 0.002⇤⇤⇤ (0.000) 0.016⇤⇤⇤ (0.005) 0.001⇤ (0.000) 0.010 (0.015) Experienced Returnt (3) 0.367⇤⇤⇤ (0.037) 0.002⇤⇤⇤ (0.000) 0.016⇤⇤⇤ (0.004) Team managed 0.012⇤⇤⇤ (0.001) 131465 0.056 59 0.010⇤⇤⇤ (0.001) 88402 0.052 0.012⇤⇤⇤ (0.001) 131465 0.056 0.001⇤⇤⇤ (0.000) 0.010 (0.015) 0.014⇤⇤⇤ (0.001) 134186 0.054 Table 8 Nonlinearity of Experience This table reports the results of the regressions of mutual funds’ nontraditional share on portfolio manager experience defined using di↵erent cuto↵s. Manager characteristics are measured as of 2004Q4. The sample period is 2007Q1–2007Q4. Same controls as in Table 6 are included but not reported. Objective fixed e↵ects are included. Standard errors are adjusted for clustering by fund. *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at 10%, 5%, and 1%. Experienced N Adjusted R2 2001 0.000 (0.011) 2935 0.164 Started managing mutual funds 2000 1999 1998 0.002 0.005 0.014⇤ (0.009) (0.008) (0.007) 2935 2935 2935 0.164 0.164 0.167 60 before January 1 1997 1996 ⇤⇤⇤ 0.032 0.023⇤⇤⇤ (0.007) (0.007) 2935 2935 0.182 0.173 1995 0.027⇤⇤⇤ (0.006) 2935 0.176 Table 9 Teams, Experience, and Nontraditional Share This table reports the results of the regressions of mutual funds’ nontraditional share on fund and portfolio manager characteristics. The sample period is 2007Q1–2007Q4. Experienced is a binary variable equal to 1 for funds above the median of experience. Manager characteristics are measured as of 2006Q4. Retail share is the share of retail share classes in fund assets. Family retail share is the share of retail share classes in fund family assets. Family ETF, equity, and taxable shares are the shares of ETFs, equity funds, and taxable bond funds in fund family assets. The omitted category is municipal funds. Objective fixed e↵ects are included. Standard errors are adjusted for clustering by fund. *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at 10%, 5%, and 1%. Log(Experience) (1) 0.004 (0.004) Log(Manager age) (2) 0.068 (0.041) (3) 0.009 (0.010) 0.053 (0.050) (4) (5) 0.021⇤⇤⇤ (0.007) Experienced 0.022⇤⇤ (0.011) 0.027⇤⇤⇤ (0.010) Experience percentile Team Experienced ⇥ Team Log(TNA) Log(Family TNA) Log(Fund age) Retail share Family retail share Family ETF share Family equity share Family taxable share Constant N Adjusted R2 (6) 0.006⇤⇤ (0.003) 0.003 (0.003) 0.012⇤ (0.007) 0.005 (0.010) 0.007 (0.015) 0.081⇤ (0.046) 0.022 (0.038) 0.045 (0.039) 0.087⇤ (0.050) 3224 0.163 0.006 (0.004) 0.005 (0.004) 0.017 (0.010) 0.004 (0.013) 0.004 (0.020) 0.944 (0.722) 0.029 (0.054) 0.062 (0.051) 0.365⇤⇤ (0.183) 2187 0.181 61 0.007 (0.004) 0.004 (0.004) 0.016 (0.010) 0.004 (0.013) 0.004 (0.020) 0.836 (0.714) 0.026 (0.054) 0.066 (0.052) 0.322 (0.203) 2187 0.182 0.007⇤⇤ (0.003) 0.003 (0.003) 0.012⇤ (0.007) 0.003 (0.010) 0.005 (0.015) 0.086⇤ (0.047) 0.021 (0.038) 0.047 (0.039) 0.084⇤ (0.049) 3224 0.170 0.007⇤⇤ (0.003) 0.003 (0.003) 0.012⇤ (0.007) 0.004 (0.010) 0.005 (0.015) 0.083⇤ (0.047) 0.020 (0.038) 0.048 (0.038) 0.085⇤ (0.049) 3224 0.166 0.027⇤⇤ (0.013) 0.005 (0.015) 0.007⇤⇤ (0.003) 0.002 (0.003) 0.011 (0.007) 0.004 (0.010) 0.002 (0.015) 0.091⇤ (0.047) 0.014 (0.037) 0.055 (0.038) 0.050 (0.050) 3224 0.182 Table 10 Variance Decomposition of Insurance Companies’ Nontraditional Share This table reports the R2 from the regressions of insurance companies’ nontraditional share on date, firm, and financial group fixed e↵ects. Financial group fixed e↵ect refers to the ultimate parent according to AM Best. Adjusted R N 2 Date 0.002 77272 Firm 0.582 77272 62 Group 0.458 77272 Table 11 Nontraditional Share and Capital Ratio This table reports the results of the regressions of insurance companies’ nontraditional share. The change in nontraditional share is calculated relative to 2004. Size is the log of the par value of the bond portfolio. Standard errors are adjusted for clustering by firm. *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at 10%, 5%, and 1%. 2004 Capital/Assets2003 Size Constant N Adjusted R2 Capital/Assets2003 Size Constant N Adjusted R2 2005 2006 2007 Panel A: Nontraditional Share 0.071⇤⇤⇤ 0.098⇤⇤⇤ 0.119⇤⇤⇤ 0.122⇤⇤⇤ (0.017) (0.019) (0.021) (0.025) 0.002 0.003⇤ 0.003 0.004⇤ (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) 0.024 0.020 0.033 0.027 (0.019) (0.018) (0.020) (0.023) 967 891 834 742 0.144 0.217 0.205 0.210 Panel B: Change in Nontraditional Share 0.025⇤⇤⇤ 0.039⇤⇤⇤ 0.045⇤⇤⇤ (0.009) (0.015) (0.016) 0.003⇤⇤ 0.003 0.004⇤ (0.001) (0.002) (0.002) 0.018 0.009 0.016 (0.013) (0.019) (0.021) 886 824 733 0.130 0.082 0.110 63 2008 2009 0.117⇤⇤⇤ (0.027) 0.005⇤⇤ (0.002) 0.021 (0.023) 732 0.189 0.099⇤⇤⇤ (0.031) 0.003 (0.002) 0.033 (0.025) 732 0.111 0.037⇤ (0.020) 0.005⇤⇤ (0.002) 0.022 (0.021) 721 0.086 0.020 (0.026) 0.003⇤ (0.002) 0.011 (0.021) 712 0.027 Table 12 Nontraditional Share and Financial Strength Rating This table reports the results of the regressions of insurance companies’ nontraditional share. The change in nontraditional share is calculated relative to 2004. Strong rating is a binary variable equal to one for firms whose 2003 AM Best financial strength rating is above the median. Size is the log of the par value of the bond portfolio. Standard errors are adjusted for clustering by firm. *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at 10%, 5%, and 1%. 2004 Strong rating Size Constant N Adjusted R2 Strong rating Size Constant N Adjusted R2 2005 2006 2007 Panel A: Nontraditional Share 0.003 0.012 0.018⇤ 0.023⇤⇤ (0.008) (0.009) (0.010) (0.011) ⇤⇤ ⇤⇤⇤ ⇤⇤⇤ 0.004 0.007 0.008 0.009⇤⇤⇤ (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.003) 0.014 0.032⇤ 0.030 0.038 (0.016) (0.019) (0.021) (0.023) 831 768 726 652 0.064 0.131 0.127 0.160 Panel B: Change in Nontraditional Share 0.013⇤⇤ 0.019⇤⇤ 0.025⇤⇤⇤ (0.006) (0.008) (0.008) ⇤⇤⇤ ⇤⇤ 0.004 0.005 0.006⇤⇤⇤ (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) 0.030⇤⇤ 0.026 0.035⇤ (0.013) (0.017) (0.019) 766 722 650 0.231 0.160 0.237 64 2008 2009 0.027⇤⇤ (0.012) 0.010⇤⇤⇤ (0.003) 0.041⇤ (0.024) 639 0.173 0.021⇤ (0.012) 0.008⇤⇤⇤ (0.003) 0.026 (0.025) 633 0.101 0.029⇤⇤⇤ (0.009) 0.007⇤⇤⇤ (0.002) 0.038⇤⇤ (0.019) 635 0.230 0.023⇤⇤ (0.010) 0.005⇤⇤ (0.002) 0.023 (0.021) 621 0.117 Table 13 Nontraditional Share and Mutual Organization Form This table reports the results of the regressions of insurance companies’ nontraditional share. The change in nontraditional share is calculated relative to 2004. Mutual insurance firms are owned by policyholders. Size is the log of the par value of the bond portfolio. Standard errors are adjusted for clustering by firm. *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at 10%, 5%, and 1%. 2004 Mutual Size Constant N Adjusted R2 Mutual Size Constant N Adjusted R2 2005 2006 2007 Panel A: Nontraditional Share 0.001 0.003 0.004 0.010 (0.011) (0.017) (0.020) (0.019) 0.005⇤⇤⇤ 0.007⇤⇤⇤ 0.007⇤⇤⇤ 0.008⇤⇤⇤ (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) 0.016 0.034⇤ 0.033 0.040⇤ (0.016) (0.018) (0.021) (0.021) 1045 1109 1093 997 0.070 0.106 0.088 0.105 Panel B: Change in Nontraditional Share 0.001 0.000 0.005 (0.009) (0.012) (0.012) 0.004⇤⇤ 0.004⇤⇤ 0.006⇤⇤ (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) 0.031⇤⇤ 0.032 0.042⇤ (0.015) (0.021) (0.022) 954 880 778 0.094 0.055 0.084 65 2008 2009 0.009 (0.021) 0.009⇤⇤⇤ (0.002) 0.042⇤⇤ (0.021) 1117 0.103 0.003 (0.026) 0.007⇤⇤⇤ (0.002) 0.026 (0.023) 1251 0.058 0.005 (0.014) 0.006⇤⇤⇤ (0.002) 0.043⇤⇤ (0.021) 766 0.073 0.000 (0.019) 0.004⇤ (0.002) 0.023 (0.023) 757 0.024 Table 14 Nontraditional Share and External Managers This table reports the results of the regressions of insurance companies’ nontraditional share. The change in nontraditional share is calculated relative to 2004. External manager is a binary variable equal to one for firms whose bond portfolios are managed by unaffiliated external managers. An insurance company and an asset management firm are considered to be unaffiliated if they have di↵erent ultimate parents in Capital IQ. Size is the log of the par value of the bond portfolio. Standard errors are adjusted for clustering by firm. *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at 10%, 5%, and 1%. 2004 External manager Size Constant N Adjusted R2 External manager Size Constant N Adjusted R2 2005 2006 2007 Panel A: Nontraditional Share 0.007 0.005 0.010 0.008 (0.005) (0.007) (0.008) (0.009) 0.002 0.006⇤⇤⇤ 0.007⇤⇤⇤ 0.007⇤⇤⇤ (0.001) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) 0.001 0.060⇤⇤⇤ 0.063⇤⇤ 0.062⇤⇤ (0.021) (0.023) (0.032) (0.027) 2300 2265 2203 2088 0.021 0.094 0.085 0.091 Panel B: Change in Nontraditional Share 0.004 0.007 0.005 (0.005) (0.007) (0.007) 0.003⇤⇤⇤ 0.005⇤⇤ 0.005⇤⇤ (0.001) (0.002) (0.002) 0.044⇤⇤ 0.055⇤ 0.054⇤ (0.020) (0.032) (0.029) 2100 2007 1858 0.086 0.069 0.069 66 2008 2009 0.009 (0.009) 0.008⇤⇤⇤ (0.002) 0.066⇤⇤ (0.028) 2165 0.083 0.004 (0.010) 0.007⇤⇤⇤ (0.002) 0.052⇤ (0.030) 2219 0.043 0.008 (0.008) 0.005⇤⇤ (0.002) 0.054 (0.033) 1855 0.061 0.004 (0.009) 0.004⇤ (0.002) 0.041 (0.034) 1847 0.025 Table 15 Cross-Sectional Determinants of Insurance Company Transactions This table reports the results of the regressions of net purchases of nontraditional securitizations and of GSE MBS on various insurance company characteristics. Net purchases are scaled by the lagged par value of the insurance firm’s fixed income portfolio. Crisis is 2007Q3–2009Q2. External manager is a binary variable equal to one for firms whose bond portfolios are managed by unaffiliated external managers. An insurance company and an asset management firm are considered to be unaffiliated if they have di↵erent ultimate parents in Capital IQ. Strong rating is a binary variable equal to one for firms whose 2003 AM Best financial strength rating is above the median. P&C is a binary variable equal to one for property and casualty insurance. The omitted caterogy is life insurance. Date fixed e↵ects are included. Standard errors are adjusted for clustering by firm. *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at 10%, 5%, and 1%. Size Size ⇥ Crisis External External ⇥ Crisis Strong capital Strong capital ⇥ Crisis Strong rating Strong rating ⇥ Crisis P&C P&C ⇥ Crisis Constant N Adjusted R2 Net purchases of Nontraditional securitizations GSE MBS (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) 0.020⇤⇤ 0.025⇤⇤⇤ 0.025⇤⇤⇤ 0.016⇤ 0.426⇤⇤⇤ 0.398⇤⇤⇤ 0.406⇤⇤⇤ 0.424⇤⇤⇤ (0.008) (0.008) (0.009) (0.009) (0.034) (0.032) (0.035) (0.036) 0.017 0.027⇤⇤ 0.027⇤⇤ 0.020 0.183⇤⇤⇤ 0.123⇤⇤ 0.169⇤⇤⇤ 0.192⇤⇤⇤ (0.014) (0.013) (0.014) (0.016) (0.067) (0.060) (0.062) (0.068) 0.025 0.281⇤ (0.039) (0.158) 0.142 0.236 (0.088) (0.277) 0.055 0.153 (0.036) (0.134) 0.025 0.058 (0.074) (0.222) 0.036 0.178 (0.042) (0.155) 0.127⇤ 0.324 (0.068) (0.269) 0.028 0.624⇤⇤⇤ (0.041) (0.151) 0.010 0.093 (0.084) (0.283) 0.110⇤⇤ 0.013 0.043 0.138⇤⇤ 5.107⇤⇤⇤ 4.778⇤⇤⇤ 5.005⇤⇤⇤ 4.973⇤⇤⇤ (0.052) (0.042) (0.046) (0.061) (0.287) (0.227) (0.237) (0.280) 41956 39467 36063 44514 41956 39467 36063 44514 0.005 0.007 0.006 0.006 0.029 0.029 0.031 0.030 67 Table 16 Cross-Sectional Determinants of Mutual Fund Transactions This table reports the results of the regressions of net purchases of nontraditional securitizations and of GSE MBS on mutual fund flows. Net purchases of nontraditional securitizations are calculated as the change in par holdings adjusted for the change in security’s outstanding amount using outstanding factors from Bloomberg. Net purchases of GSE MBS are calculated similarly except that we use aggregate instead of security-specific prepayment information. Specifically we calculate aggregate prepayment speed as gross issuance of Fannie and Freddie MBS minus the change in outstanding amount. Net purchases are scaled by the lagged par value of the mutual fund’s bond portfolio. Crisis is 2007Q3–2009Q2. Fund flows are scaled by lagged total net assets, and are winsorized at the 1st and 99th percentiles. Inflows are equal to max(0, Fund flows). Outflows are equal to max(0, Fund flows). Size is the log of the par value of the bond portfolio. Objective-date fixed e↵ects are included. Standard errors are adjusted for clustering by fund. *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at 10%, 5%, and 1%. Inflows Inflows ⇥ Crisis Outflows Outflows ⇥ Crisis Size Size ⇥ Crisis Nontraditional share Nontraditional share ⇥ Crisis Constant N Adjusted R2 Net purchases of Nontraditional securitizations GSE MBS (1) (2) (3) (4) 0.216⇤⇤⇤ 0.187⇤⇤⇤ 0.423⇤⇤⇤ 0.390⇤⇤⇤ (0.048) (0.046) (0.054) (0.054) 0.076 0.040 0.235⇤⇤ 0.245⇤⇤⇤ (0.072) (0.071) (0.094) (0.094) ⇤⇤⇤ 0.032 0.105 0.194 0.263⇤⇤⇤ (0.071) (0.069) (0.063) (0.063) ⇤ 0.056 0.040 0.283 0.273⇤ (0.097) (0.096) (0.150) (0.159) 0.005⇤⇤⇤ 0.006⇤⇤⇤ (0.001) (0.001) 0.004⇤⇤⇤ 0.001 (0.001) (0.001) 0.176⇤⇤⇤ 0.024⇤⇤ (0.026) (0.011) ⇤⇤⇤ 0.104 0.005 (0.028) (0.024) 0.014⇤⇤⇤ 0.056⇤⇤⇤ 0.022⇤⇤⇤ 0.088⇤⇤⇤ (0.001) (0.007) (0.001) (0.008) 20076 20076 23537 23537 0.047 0.083 0.072 0.078 68