Fisher College of Business Working Paper Series Charles A. Dice Center for Research in Financial Economics Financial Policies, Investment, and the Financial Crisis: Impaired Credit Channel or Diminished Demand for Capital? Kathleen M. Kahle, Eller College of Management, University of Arizona René M. Stulz, Department of Finance, The Ohio State University, NBER, and ECGI Dice Center WP 2011-3 Fisher College of Business WP 2011-03-003 This paper can be downloaded without charge from: http://www.ssrn.com/abstract=1754660 An index to the working paper in the Fisher College of Business Working Paper Series is located at: http://www.ssrn.com/link/Fisher-College-of-Business.html February 2011 fisher.osu.edu Financial policies, investment, and the financial crisis: Impaired credit channel or diminished demand for capital? Kathleen M. Kahle and René M. Stulz* February 2011 * Respectively, associate professor, Eller College of Management, University of Arizona, and Everett D. Reese Chair of Banking and Monetary Economics, Fisher College of Business, Ohio State University, NBER, and ECGI. We thank Christian Leuz, Cathy Schrand, Berk Sensoy, and Mike Weisbach for useful discussions; Viral Acharya, Rudi Fahlenbrach, Jarrad Harford, Jean Helwege, Vince Intintoli, Francisco Perez-Gonzalez, Robert Prilmeier, David Scharfstein, Andrei Shleifer, and participants at the Fall 2010 Corporate Finance meeting of the NBER, the AFE meetings in Denver, and at seminars at Harvard University, Ohio State, the University of Amsterdam, and the University of Tilburg for useful comments; and Matt Wynter and Jia Chen for excellent research assistance. We are especially indebted to Harry DeAngelo for discussions and detailed comments. Financial policies, investment, and the financial crisis: Impaired credit channel or diminished demand for capital? Abstract Though much of the narrative of the financial crisis has focused on the impact of a bank credit supply shock, we show that such a shock cannot explain important features of the financial and investment policies of industrial firms. These features are consistent with a dominant role for the increase in risk and the reduction in demand for goods that occurred during the crisis. The net equity issuance of small firms and unrated firms is abnormally low throughout the crisis, whereas an impaired credit supply by itself would have encouraged these firms to increase their net equity issuance. After September 2008, firms increase their cash holdings rather than use them to mitigate the impact of the credit supply shock. Firms that are more bank-dependent before the crisis do not reduce their capital expenditures more than other firms during the crisis. Finally, the evidence is strongly supportive of theories that emphasize the importance of collateral and corporate net worth in financing and investment policies, as firms with stronger balance sheets reduce capital expenditures less after September 2008. The conventional view of the financial crisis is that bank losses from toxic assets led to fire sales by banks and a bank credit contraction (see Brunnermeier (2009) and Shleifer and Vishny (2010)). These toxic assets were mostly securities backed by subprime and related mortgages, so their loss in value had little to do with the performance of industrial firms, making the credit contraction an exogenous event for these firms. Research in finance, including research on the recent financial crisis, shows that exogenous credit contractions have real effects on firms by forcing them to reduce investment.1 However, an exogenous contraction in the supply of credit was not the only adverse development in the recent crisis. Credit contracted endogenously as well because of a demand shock that led to lower cash flows, loss of investment opportunities, and weaker balance sheets. Further, risk increased sharply in the fall of 2008, making firms less credit worthy and leading to a flight to quality that increased risk premia. In this paper, we assess the relative economic importance of the direct impact of the exogenous bank credit contraction, the decrease in demand and thus expected cash flows, and the increase in risk in explaining the financial and investment policies of firms during the financial crisis. Most of the evidence is inconsistent with the view that the direct impact of the bank credit supply shock on firms was the dominant factor. Contrary to the predictions of the exogenous credit supply shock hypothesis, net debt issuance does not fall during the first year of the crisis and firms most likely to be bank dependent decrease their net equity issuance rather than increase it. After September 2008, net debt issuance drops sharply, but firms hoard cash, and firms more likely to be bank dependent do not decrease capital expenditures more than other firms. Overall, our evidence shows that the demand shock, the resulting endogenous credit contraction, and the reaction of firms to the increase in risk play a dominant role in explaining firms’ financial and investment policies. There is much evidence that financial policies depend on both financial market conditions and macroeconomic conditions (see references in Baker (2009), Erel, Julio, Kim, and Weisbach (2010), and Korajczyk and Levi (2003)). Based on this evidence, we would expect firms to exploit advantageous 1 References to this large literature include work focused on the impact of monetary policy (e.g., Gertler and Gilchrist (1994)), Kashyap, Stein, and Wilcox (1993), and Kashyap, Lamont, and Stein (1994)) as well as more recent work focused on specific events associated with changes in the supply of credit (Leary (2009) and Lemmon and Roberts (2010)). Papers on the financial crisis are discussed later in this introduction. 1 conditions in credit markets and to increase their leverage when such conditions obtain. If the availability of credit becomes temporarily restricted, firms should borrow less. Further, with suddenly less welcoming credit markets, firms would use their cash holdings to finance investment since precautionary holdings of cash exist precisely to mitigate the impact of adverse shocks (see, for instance, Opler, Pinkowitz, Stulz, and Williamson (1999)). Finally, to the extent that a credit contraction is of an unprecedented magnitude, we would expect an unprecedented decrease in net debt issuance. As credit becomes harder to obtain, firms should reduce their dividend payouts, repurchase less stock, and issue more equity (see Leary (2009) for evidence of the latter). In summary, we expect a credit supply shock to be accompanied by a drop in net debt issuance, by an increase in net equity issuance, by a drop in dividends and share repurchases, and by a decrease in cash holdings. Further, the credit supply shock should lead to a greater decrease in investment for the firms that are most affected by the shock. We call this set of predictions the credit supply shock hypothesis. The demand for goods produced by industrial firms fell and growth opportunities for these firms disappeared during the crisis for several reasons. Retail sales peaked in November 2007.2 The saliency of the crisis in financial markets makes it easy to forget that housing has always played a critical role in economic activity and that the housing sector was in recession before the financial crisis.3 Further, it is well-known that oil price increases are a drag on economic activity, and the price of oil peaked in 2008.4 Campbell, Giglio, and Polk (2010) document that one feature of the financial crisis is a sharp decrease in corporate expected cash flows that takes place before September 2008. Finally, consumption fell sharply during the last quarter of 2008, partly because of the increase in risk and partly because of disruptions and decreases in consumer credit. Over the period for which the monthly data is available from the U.S. Census Bureau (1992), retail sales had their worst percentage drop in October 2008, their second worst drop in December 2008, and their third worst drop in November 2008. The next worst change was after 2 See U.S. Census Bureau, monthly retail sales adjusted. Leamer (2007) concludes that “Of the components of GDP, residential investment offers by far the best early warning sign of a recession. Housing starts fell roughly by half from the end of 2005 to the end of 2007.” 4 Hamilton (2009) concludes that the U.S. would not have been in a recession during the period from the fourth quarter of 2007 to the third quarter of 2008 in the absence of the runup in oil prices. 3 2 September 11. Using data from the National Income and Product Account (NIPA) tables from the Bureau of Economic Activity, seasonally-adjusted personal consumption peaked in the second quarter of 2008. The drops in personal consumption in the third and fourth quarters of 2008 were the seventh and sixth worst, respectively, since 1959. The drop in consumption was extremely abrupt immediately after the events of September 2008. For instance, sales of the retailer Neiman Marcus were 25% in October 2008 lower than in October 2007. In contrast, sales in September 2008 were only 11% lower than the previous year. This shock to demand decreased both revenues and cash flows. These dramatic changes in consumption spending around the events of the fall of 2008 may have multiple causes, but assuredly part of these changes reflect consumer fear caused by the financial chaos. As a result of a decrease in demand, the value of firms’ tangible assets decreases: excess supply of goods at current prices leads to a decrease in net worth and collateral, so firms cannot borrow as much as they could previously (Kiyotaki and Moore (1997)). Firms become more highly levered, which worsens agency problems between creditors and shareholders (Jensen and Meckling (1976); Bernanke and Gertler (1989)). For firms whose debt is already risky, the increase in leverage leads to a debt overhang, which makes equity issuance unattractive for shareholders (Myers (1977)). At least since Miller (1963), we know that equity issues are particularly sensitive to the business cycle. In particular, firms tend to issue equity when equity prices are increasing, not when they are falling. Thus the fall in the demand for goods and growth opportunities leads to a decrease in net debt issuance and a decrease in net equity issuance. With the demand shock, cash increases only to the extent that the cash savings from lower investment exceed the cash losses from lower cash flows. We refer to this scenario as the demand shock hypothesis. A striking feature of the recent crisis is the extent to which risk measures increased to unprecedented levels. For instance, the VIX reached levels never before seen. An increase in risk increases risk premia, which decreases firm values and increases the cost of external finance. Uncertainty about the environment also increased, as aspects of the financial system that were believed to be robust (such as the commercial paper market and the repo market) seemed to be failing. Caballero and Krishnamurthy (2008) emphasize the impact of an increase in uncertainty about the environment in creating a flight to safety and cite 3 Greenspan, stating that “When confronted with uncertainty, especially Knightian uncertainty, human beings invariably attempt to disengage from medium to long-term commitments in favor of safety and liquidity…” The increase in risk and uncertainty led to a drop in the supply of capital across debt and equity markets, and valuations fell as risk premia increased. As in our discussion of the demand shock, the decrease in firm values worsens information asymmetries and agency problems, making external financing relatively more expensive for firms in which information asymmetries and agency problems are more prevalent. The risk increase also increases default probabilities for levered firms, raising their cost of debt financing. Further, it provides incentives for firms to postpone investment and strengthen their balance sheet by hoarding cash (see, for instance, Bernanke (1983)). After the collapses of Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, Lehman Brothers, AIG, and Washington Mutual in September of 2008, corporate executives and investors had genuine concerns about whether the financial system would still be functioning when they awoke the next day. There was also considerable uncertainty about government policy, given that Bear Stearns had been rescued but Lehman was allowed to fail. Pastor and Veronesi (2010) show that policy changes are accompanied by falling stock prices, increased volatility, and increased risk premia. When the chairman of the Federal Reserve System and the Secretary of the Treasury testified before Congress that the financial system was close to a collapse, corporate executives would have been foolish to ignore that information. Economists describe the events that happened in the fall of 2008 as a panic (Gorton (2010)). Whether or not the fear was rational, it would not make sense to assume that business executives were unaffected and that this fear did not worsen the impact of the increase in risk. We would expect an increase in risk to raise a firm’s cost of capital, making financing more costly. This increase would be even worse from the perspective of executives if they felt that the market was overreacting. It would further decrease the liquidity of markets, which increases the cost of raising funds. Firms would seek stronger balance sheets, with more liquid assets. We would therefore expect an increase in risk to lead to a drop in net debt and net equity issuance, a drop in payouts, and an increase in cash holdings. We call this the risk hypothesis. 4 These three hypotheses are not mutually exclusive and all three play a role during the crisis. Our focus is on whether the financial and investment policies of industrial firms help us understand the relative importance of the three hypotheses. However, the importance of these hypotheses may differ across firm types. For instance, a temporary restriction to credit would have little effect on firms with no debt, and firms whose investment opportunities are already poor could not suffer much from a loss of growth opportunities. There is also no reason for the relative importance of these hypotheses to be constant throughout the crisis. It could be that one dominates at one stage and another at another stage. Finally, a caveat is necessary at this point. Though drawing sharp differences between our three hypotheses helps with the presentation, there are some relations among these hypotheses that blur their boundaries. For example, a restriction in the supply of capital that is expected to be long lasting could lead firms to invest in cash. Similarly, firms that expect the credit markets to be closed must still raise funds to pay off loans or maturing debt issues. They would want to increase cash holdings for that purpose. We investigate firm financial policies using quarterly data, which is the highest frequency corporate data available, from the start of the crisis to its peak. We use the second quarter of 2007 as both the end and the peak of the credit boom since credit spreads for high yield bonds reached their lowest value in that quarter. The third quarter of 2007 is generally considered to be the first quarter of the crisis and the first quarter of 2009 is the peak of the crisis as it corresponds to the lowest value of the S&P 500 index. We begin by examining asset-weighted averages. Equally-weighted averages for U.S. firms are dominated by small firms and, consequently, are not a good proxy for the behavior of the economy as a whole. Using asset-weighted data, there is no evidence of a crisis in the year after the peak of the credit boom. Net debt issuance increases. Net equity issuance does not fall. The ratio of cash to assets does not fall. The ratio of capital expenditures to assets does not fall. Slightly more than one year after the beginning of the crisis, markets were further disrupted by the events of September 2008. In the following, when we discuss financial policies after these events, we consider financial policies for the last quarter of 5 2008 and the first quarter of 2009.5 After the September events, net debt issuance falls, but not to levels that are extreme outliers in the sample and the drop in net debt issuance is more than offset by a reduction in equity repurchases. There is no evidence of changes in dividend payouts. However, cash as a percent of assets (the cash ratio) increases by 1.30 percentage points in the two quarters following September 2008, a two-quarter increase unmatched since the start of our sample. The asset-weighted evidence is not consistent with a dominant role for the credit supply shock hypothesis. It is supportive of the demand hypothesis and the risk hypothesis. After considering the aggregate evidence, we examine various subsets of firms whose financial and investment policies are expected to differ according to the three hypotheses. To isolate the impact of the financial crisis, we use models for debt issuance, equity issuance, cash holdings, and investment developed in the literature before the financial crisis. We estimate these models quarterly and use firm fixed effects to account for unobserved firm characteristics. We then estimate coefficients for a crisis indicator variable and an indicator variable for the last two quarters of the crisis. Using a difference-indifferences approach, these indicator variables are interacted with firm characteristics related to the predictions of the three hypotheses. We start with an analysis of net debt issuance. For the whole sample, net debt issuance as a percentage of assets is significantly higher during the crisis by 11 basis points per quarter. Net debt issuance is similar for small firms or unrated firms. Compared to other firms, it is significantly lower for firms that are in the top quintile of cash holdings in June 2006 and for firms that are highly financially constrained as of June 2006; we define firms as highly constrained if they were net borrowers in the previous year, did not make payouts, had a Tobin’s q above one, and did not have access to public markets. Except for the highly constrained firms, none of the evidence is supportive of the credit supply shock hypothesis. After September 2008, net debt issuance collapses for the whole sample, falling by 96 basis points after accounting for firm characteristics used in the literature to predict net debt issuance. Net 5 One could argue, however, that the financial data for the end of the third quarter of 2008 already partly reflects the impact of the events of September 2008. By considering only the two quarters we do, our analysis is conservative and may ignore some of the impact of these events. 6 debt issuance falls less for large and investment-rated firms, but more for highly levered firms. Small firms, unrated firms, and highly financially constrained firms do not appear to experience a collapse after September 2008 that is worse than for the sample as a whole. Though a drop in net debt issuance is consistent with all three hypotheses, the credit supply shock hypothesis predicts a worse drop for more bank-dependent firms, which is not the case. For the whole sample, net equity issuance is lower by 26 basis points per quarter during the crisis. Except for the highly financially constrained firms, we find no evidence supporting the prediction of the credit supply shock hypothesis that firms substitute equity for debt. Small firms and unrated firms decrease net equity issuance more rather than less. However, highly financially constrained firms decrease their net equity issuance abnormally after September 2008, but not before. In contrast to the credit supply shock hypothesis, the demand shock and the risk hypotheses are consistent with a reduction in net equity issuance. The credit supply shock hypothesis predicts that firms use cash to offset the lack of availability of bank financing. For the whole sample, cash holdings decrease during the crisis, but they increase following September 2008. For large and investment-grade firms, however, cash holdings are not lower during the crisis, and in fact increase during the crisis because of the post-September 2008 increase. Strikingly, the highly constrained firms also increase cash holdings abnormally during the crisis. The explanation for this is that these firms have surprisingly high operating cash flows during the first year of the crisis. Firms with high cash holdings decrease cash holdings throughout the crisis. If firms increase their cash holdings after September 2008 because they expect credit to be restricted, we would expect such an increase to be higher for firms that are bank dependent. This is not the case. Unrated firms, small firms, and highly financially constrained firms do not increase their cash ratio differently from other firms after September 2008. Finally, we examine firms’ investment policies. Small firms, unrated firms, highly constrained firms, and firms with large amounts of short-term debt do not decrease capital expenditures more than other firms during the crisis. Such a finding is not consistent with the credit supply shock hypothesis. However, 7 firms with stronger balance sheets (more cash, less leverage, higher debt rating) reduce capital expenditures less after September 2008. In fact, firms in the highest quintile of cash holdings experience no reduction in capital expenditures, while firms in the highest quintile of leverage experience a reduction in capital expenditures that is twice the size of the rest of the sample. This evidence is strongly supportive of the credit transmission mechanism highlighted by Bernanke and Gertler (1989) and Kiyotaki and Moore (1997). With a shock to future cash flows, firms find it more expensive to borrow, which leads to a drop in capital expenditures. We also examine the evolution of R&D expenditures. All firm types considered spend more on R&D in the fourth quarter of 2008 than the last quarter of the credit boom, but these expenditures drop in the first quarter of 2009. Our evidence complements the literature on the implications of the financial crisis for industrial firms. Most of this literature has focused on identifying the effects of the credit supply shock, while we focus instead on assessing the economic importance for industrial firms of the credit supply shock, the demand shock, and the risk shock. In particular, using survey data, Campello, Graham, and Harvey (2010) provide evidence that firms that were credit constrained in 2008 reduce their spending plans, bypass attractive investment opportunities, and burn more cash. Almeida, Campello, Laranjeira, and Weisbenner (2009) demonstrate that firms which had a substantial proportion of their long-term debt maturing immediately after the third quarter of 2007 reduce investment substantially in comparison to other firms. Campello, Giambona, Graham, and Harvey (2009) show that credit-constrained firms draw down credit lines during the crisis, but also face difficulties in renewing credit lines. The importance of credit lines is also emphasized by Ivashina and Scharfstein (2010a, 2010b), who provide evidence that firms draw down their credit lines after the September 2008 and hoard the funds drawn in cash. Ivashina and Scharfstein (2010b) conclude that “the primary motivation behind the draw-downs was panic from the financial market uncertainty.” Gao and Yun (2009) show that riskier firms experienced a sharp drop in commercial paper issuance. Duchin, Ozbas, and Sensoy (2010) find that firms with greater cash holdings one year before the start of the crisis reduce investment less early in the crisis but not later. They interpret their evidence as consistent with the existence of a supply shock to external finance that is less costly for 8 firms with greater cash holdings. Iyer, Lopes, Peydró, and Schoar (2010) find no credit supply reduction for large firms in Portugal, but find that younger firms with weak bank relationships are affected. Finally, Kuppuswamy and Villalonga (2010) show that the financial crisis had less of an impact on diversified firms. The paper proceeds as follows. In Section 1, we introduce the dataset we use. In Section 2, we show how debt and equity issuance, cash holdings, and capital expenditures evolve during the credit boom and the financial crisis for the asset-weighted and the equally-weighted sample averages. In Sections 3 through 6, we investigate the predictions of the three hypotheses using regression models of debt and equity issuance, cash holdings, and capital expenditures, respectively. We discuss the interpretation of our results and conclude in Section 7. Section 1. The sample Most empirical work in corporate finance uses annual data. For our purpose, such data is unsuitable since it would force us to ignore how corporate financial policies evolve during the crisis and would make it impossible to examine the financial crisis from the top of the credit boom to the peak of the crisis which, as already discussed, we define as the first quarter of 2009. We therefore use quarterly data collected from the CRSP/Compustat Merged (CCM) Fundamentals Quarterly database for 1983-2009. There are distinct problems with the use of quarterly data. First, many of the Compustat data items are only provided annually, so less detailed data is available on a quarterly basis than on a yearly basis. Second, many industries have seasonal factors. There is little we can do to deal with the lack of data availability, but we can address the seasonality issue. The first approach we use to address the seasonality issue is that we compare quarters to identical quarters in other years. The second approach is that we estimate models that specifically allow for seasonality. In our investigation, we use issuance data from the cash flow statement following Fama and French (2008). The capital structure literature often uses other measures, such as changes in debt or equity above a threshold (see, for instance, Leary and Roberts (2005)) or only public issues (e.g., DeAngelo, 9 DeAngelo, and Stulz (2010); Erel, Julio, Kim, and Weisbach (2010)). In this paper, we focus on the funding obtained by corporations from all sources, not just banks or public markets, since substitution across funding sources could help firms offset the impact of a bank credit contraction (see, e.g., Iyer, Lopes, Peydró and Schoar (2010) for evidence of such substitution). We also want to understand the magnitude of financing flows in comparison to more normal times, so that net issuance close to zero is of interest to us. The quarterly issuance data we need in our investigation is only available beginning in the third quarter of 1983. Consequently, our sample effectively starts from that quarter and ends with the first quarter of 2009. We delete observations with negative total assets (atq), negative sales (saleq), negative cash and marketable securities (cheq), cash and marketable securities greater than total assets, and firms not incorporated in the U.S. If a firm changes its fiscal-year end, and thus a given data quarter is reported twice in Compustat (for both the old fiscal quarter and the new fiscal quarter) we retain the observation for the new fiscal quarter only. Finally, we eliminate all financial firms, which we define as firms with SIC codes between 6000 and 6999; we also eliminate utilities, which we define as firms with SIC codes between 4900 and 4949. Section 2. The aggregate evidence At the start of the crisis, our sample includes 3,198 firms. When we divide firms listed on the NYSE into quintiles based on total assets and assign non-NYSE firms to these quintiles, we find that 2,021 of the 3,198 firms are smaller than the largest firm in the bottom quintile of NYSE firms. Consequently, at the beginning of the crisis, two-thirds of our firms are small firms with assets less than $715.7 million. The average and median assets for these firms are $196.6 million and $127.6 million, respectively. In contrast, the mean and median of assets are $31.9 billion and $16.1 billion, respectively, for the firms in the top quintile. Equally-weighted averages reflect small public firms and are not indicative of the behavior of the economy as a whole. Asset-weighted averages better reflect the economy as a whole. Though none of our data includes private firms, asset-weighted capital expenditures increase in the first year of the crisis as 10 they did for the U.S. economy as a whole.6 In this section, we first investigate the implications of assetweighted results for debt and equity issuance, cash holdings, capital expenditures, and operating cash flow for our three hypotheses. We then turn briefly to equally-weighted results. At the end of the section, we examine the role of credit lines for a random sample. Section 2.1. Asset-weighted results Panel A of Table 1 shows the asset-weighted results from the first quarter of 2005 to the first quarter of 2009. The first two columns examine net debt issuance. We use two measures to examine net debt issuance. The first measure is obtained from the statement of cash flows and is calculated as long-term debt issuance (dltisy) minus long-term debt retirement (dltry) divided by lagged assets.7 This measure is higher in the first year of the crisis than in the last year of the boom, but not significantly so.8 Its value at the peak of the crisis is not different from its value at the peak of the boom. Strikingly, this ratio has a negative value 13 times in our dataset, so none of the values during the crisis are extreme values for this variable. An obvious concern is that a relatively stable net debt issuance could mask large changes in long-term debt issuance. This is not the case. We also use a broader measure of debt issuance that includes short-term debt. We refer to this measure as net total debt issuance. It is calculated from balance sheet data and includes changes in both long-term debt (dlttq) and debt in current liabilities (dlcq) during the quarter. Net total debt issuance is 6 Using the September 30, 2010 version of the NIPA data, aggregate gross investment by domestic businesses is $6,346 billion in the year before the crisis and is $6,577 in the first year of the crisis. Aggregate gross investment falls sharply in the fourth quarter of 2008 and again in the first quarter of 2009. It reaches its lowest value in the second quarter of 2009, but the drop from the first quarter to the second quarter is small. The same conclusions hold for aggregate net investment by domestic businesses. 7 Many of the quarterly Compustat variables, including dltis and dltry, are reported on a year-to-date basis. For these variables, in the second, third, and fourth quarter of each fiscal year, the quarterly value is calculated by subtracting the lagged value from the current value. 8 We assess the significance of these changes using two different approaches. The first approach (seasonalityadjusted p-values) is extremely conservative in that we compare the change of interest to changes over identical quarterly calendar periods to account for seasonality. For example, to investigate the statistical significance of a change after September 2008, we use the distribution of two-quarter turn-of-the-year changes in our sample. This approach has low power since it uses only 26 two-quarter changes, but it fully adjusts for seasonality. The second approach (Newey-West p-values) uses all two-quarter changes but relies on Newey-West t-statistics to account for overlap. 11 also not lower during the first year of the crisis than during the last year of the boom. This evidence is consistent with the findings of Chari, Christiano, and Kehoe (2010) who, using macroeconomic data, find no decrease in bank lending to firms.9 However, our measure is broader than theirs since it includes other sources of borrowing besides banks, including public markets.10 Net debt issuance turns negative in the first quarter of 2009. However, there are six quarters since 1983 in which this ratio has a lower value than in the first quarter of 2009. Consequently, the asset-weighted data does not support the notion that the crisis resulted in exceptionally low aggregate net debt issuance; not only are the values that obtain during the crisis not the lowest in our sample period, they are not even in the bottom 5% of the distribution. Importantly, however, these numbers reflect net debt issuance given the policy interventions that took place and they say nothing about what the net debt issuance would have been in the absence of these interventions. It is interesting to compare the net total debt issuance in the first quarter of 2009 to the net total debt issuance in the last quarters of the 1990/1991 and of the 2001 recessions (results not tabulated). For both of these recessions, net debt issuance in the last quarter of the recession is closer to net debt issuance at the peak of the boom in 2007 than it is to net debt issuance at the peak of the financial crisis. In the fourth quarter of 2001, aggregate net debt issuance is 0.97% while in the first quarter of 1991 it is 0.65%. The negative value for aggregate net debt issuance in the first quarter of 2009 is therefore quite different from the experience of the previous two recessions. We turn next to the aggregate ratio of net equity issuance to lagged assets, where net equity issuance is defined as aggregate equity issuance (sstky) minus aggregate equity repurchase (prstkcy). For the assetweighted data, net equity issuance is negative because firms in the aggregate repurchase stock rather than 9 It is also consistent with evidence in Boyson, Helwege, and Jindra (2010) that bank balance sheets did not shrink during the crisis. 10 With the NIPA data cited earlier, businesses are net borrowers until the end of the third quarter of 2008, but their net borrowing is lower in the first year of the crisis than in the last year of the boom, a finding which is inconsistent with our finding here. Since the NIPA data covers private firms, a possible explanation for the inconsistency is that private firms face greater difficulties in borrowing than public firms. Using the flow-of-funds data, corporate credit grows more in 2008 than in eight years since 1977. It also grows in each quarter of 2008 as well as in the first quarter of 2009. 12 issue it. The net equity issuance in the first year of the crisis is similar to the net equity issuance in the last year of the boom. However, after the first year of the crisis, net equity issuance increases because repurchases (not tabulated) decrease sharply. Strikingly, therefore, firms repurchase the least when stock prices are the lowest and the most at the top of boom when they are highest. Though we do not show dividends in the table, dividends to assets do not decrease significantly during the crisis. In comparison to the other recessionary periods, net equity issuance is positive in the first quarter of 1991 and hardly changes during the recession of 2001. Data on the asset-weighted ratio of cash to assets is reported in the next column, where cash is cash and marketable securities (cheq). The cash ratio shows a u-shape during this period. It starts in 2005 with a value of 10.42%, falls to 9.49% at the top of the credit boom, and ends the period at 10.18%. Thus, at the peak of the financial crisis, firms hold more of their assets in the form of cash than at the start of the crisis. After the top of the credit boom, the ratio keeps falling and reaches its lowest point (8.89%) at the end of the third quarter of 2008. In the last two quarters alone, the cash ratio increases significantly by 1.30 percentage points, representing an increase in cash holdings of 14.5%. There is no other two-quarter period in our sample where the cash ratio increases by more than in the two quarters after September 2008.11 In the recession of 1990-1991, which was also associated with a credit crunch, there are only trivial changes in the asset-weighted cash ratio. More specifically, the assetweighted cash ratio falls by 0.06 percentage points from the third quarter of 1990 to the first quarter of 1991. Nothing like the post-September 2008 increase in cash holdings takes place in that recession. Such an increase does occur in the 2001 recession, which was not associated with a credit crunch. In that recession, the aggregate cash ratio increases by 0.62 percentage points. However, just about all of the increase in the cash ratio takes place after September 11. The aggregate cash ratio falls initially in the crisis of 1998. This crisis started in August and the LTCM collapse was in September. The cash ratio falls 11 The next highest increase is 1.22 percentage points from the third quarter of 1999 to the first quarter of 2000. There was much concern about potential software problems at the turn of the century and this concern most likely explains this hoarding. Because cash holdings were lower at that time, the percentage change in cash is higher at the turn of the century (18.8%) than from the third quarter of 2008 to the first quarter of 2009 (14.5%). 13 from 6.52% at the end of June to 6.28% at the end of September. It then increases to 6.63%. The total increase around the LTCM collapse is therefore a trivial 0.11%. There is little evidence that the crisis impacted capital expenditures in 2008. Asset-weighted capital expenditures do not fall in the first year of the crisis. In addition, capital expenditures in each quarter of 2008 are roughly the same as in the corresponding quarter in 2007. Further, asset-weighted capital expenditures do not fall in the last quarter of 2008. Though capital expenditures fall in the first quarter of 2009, so do operating cash flows. Our measure of operating cash flow represents the cash flow available for discretionary investment and is calculated following the approach of Minton and Schrand (1999) (see Appendix for details). Though we do not show the results in the table, we also investigate the evolution of R&D expenses. There is no difference in R&D expenses to assets from the last twelve months of the boom and the first twelve months of the crisis. However, R&D falls in the first quarter of 2009. One concern is that our results could be influenced by the changing composition of the sample as firms cease to exist. Consequently, in untabulated results, we construct a sample of firms that exist continuously from the end of the first quarter of 2007 to the end of the first quarter of 2009. There are 2,547 firms that satisfy this requirement. The change in the aggregate cash ratio after September 2008 for these firms is 1.47 percentage points, as compared to 1.30 percentage points for the whole sample of firms. All the other patterns we discuss continue to exist for this sample. We also verify that the dollar amount of cash holdings increases as well and find that, over the crisis, the aggregate dollar amount of cash held by firms that are continuously in existence increases by roughly $100 billion from the top of the boom to the peak of the crisis. For the whole sample, cash holdings increase by $89 billion in the two quarters after September 2008. Section 2.2. Equally-weighted results We now turn to the equally-weighted results provided in Panel B of Table 1. While we require that firms have data for all variables when examining the asset-weighted results, so that the denominator of the ratios is the same, for the equally-weighted results we construct averages for each variable separately 14 and only require data for that variable. The number of observations reported is the number of firms for which we have cash and assets data. We winsorize the equally-weighted results at the 1% and 99% levels to mitigate the influence of outliers. The story of net debt issuance differs substantially after September 2008 when we examine equallyweighted averages instead of asset-weighted averages. During the first twelve months of the crisis, net debt issuance is the same as during the last twelve months of the credit boom, irrespective of the measure of net debt issuance used. However, net debt issuance collapses after September 2008 when examining the equally-weighted results. For both measures of net debt issuance, we find that net debt issuance is negative in the two quarters after September 2008, i.e. firms are repaying debt on net rather than borrowing. Further, the net total debt issuance measure (that includes short-term debt) reaches its lowest value during our sample period in the first quarter of 2009, and the net long-term debt issuance measure reaches its second lowest value in that quarter. In the two previous recessions, equally-weighted net debt issuance falls, but much less; it stays positive in the recession of 1990-1991 and becomes trivially negative in the recession of 2001. In contrast to net debt issuance, net equity issuance falls sharply in the first year of the crisis. In the last twelve months of the boom, net equity issuance is roughly 1% per quarter; it drops to 0.5% in the first twelve months of the crisis. Strikingly, it turns negative in the last quarter of 2008, albeit by a small amount – this is the only quarter in our sample where equally-weighted net equity issuance is negative. The evidence is inconsistent with the view that the dominant effect was a curtailment of credit. Firms did not substitute equity issuance for debt issuance. Instead, equity issuance drops substantially before debt issuance drops. The net equity issuance drop is large compared to the two previous recessions. In the recession of 2001, equally-weighted net equity issuance actually increases. The cumulative shortfall in financing cash flow from the decrease in net equity issuance for the equally-weighted results is on average more than double the cumulative shortfall from the reduction in net debt issuance. To see this, suppose that from the start of the crisis to its peak, firms continued issuing equity at the same rate as in the last quarter of the credit boom. Over these seven quarters, firms would 15 have issued equity corresponding to approximately 9.94% of assets.12 Instead, they issue equity corresponding to 2.50% of assets, for a shortfall of 7.44% of assets. In contrast, had firms kept issuing debt at the same rate as they did in the last quarter of the credit boom, they would have issued debt equal to approximately 7.35% of assets. Instead, they issue debt equal to 3.79% of assets, for a shortfall of 3.56% of asset. Firms decrease their cash to assets ratio by 1.1 percentage points from the first quarter of 2005 to the top of the boom. The magnitude is similar to the 1.3 percentage point drop for the asset-weighted results. However, instead of a u-shape pattern of cash holdings, the cash ratio falls from the top of the boom to the peak of the crisis by 1.78 percentage points. The cash ratio increases by 0.58 percentage points after September 2008. We also investigate the medians for the sample used for the equally-weighted average. We find an increase in the median cash ratio after September 2008 of 0.91 percentage points. In evaluating significance, we report p-values for paired t-tests using the firms that exist in the third quarter of 2008 and the first quarter of 2009. For these firms, the cash ratio increases by 0.70 percentage points, which is statistically significant at the 1% level. The evidence is consistent with the view that small firms use their precautionary cash holdings to cope with adverse shocks. This behavior does not show up in the asset-weighted results because, while there are many small firms, their weight in the asset-weighted average is small. In the 1990-1991 recession, the equally-weighted cash ratio falls by 0.42% when we average across the same firms. In contrast, in the 2001 recession, the average ratio increases by 1.28%. However, in the 2001 recession, the cash increase is a post-September 11 phenomenon. Finally, we consider capital expenditures. Again, equally-weighted capital expenditures are essentially unchanged from the last year of the boom to the first year of the crisis. However, they fall sharply in the first quarter of 2009. This one-quarter fall in 2009 is greater than the fall in either of the previous recessions from the peak to the last quarter of the recession. As for the asset-weighted results, 12 Note that, for simplicity, we use actual assets in these computations rather than what the assets would have been had equity issuance or debt issuance been different. 16 the drop in capital expenditures is accompanied by a very large drop in operating cash flows. In fact, capital expenditures decrease proportionately less than cash flows. Section 2.3. Lines of Credit As discussed in our review of the literature, much attention has been paid to the role of credit lines and credit line draw-downs during the financial crisis. Using the approach of Sufi (2009), we construct a random sample of 300 firms as of the second quarter of 2007 to examine the economic importance of credit line draw-downs for firms meeting our sampling criteria. We then obtain data on lines of credit available and draw-downs from 10-Qs and 10-Ks. Table 2 shows data for the asset-weighted sample and the equally-weighted sample. Not surprisingly, given the existing literature, many firms have access to credit lines. Out of our 300 firms, 243 or 81% have credit lines in the second quarter of 2007. Columns 4-6 of Table 2 examine only those firms in each quarter that have existing lines of credit. Column 4 shows that the percentage of firms with credit lines having new draw-downs peaks in the fourth quarter of 2007 at 37.28%. The next column shows the percentage of new draw-downs in each quarter as a percentage of the total line of credit. This amount also peaks in the fourth quarter of 2007. Column 6 shows the ratio of total draw-downs outstanding as a fraction of the total line of credit. This fraction increases the most in the last quarter of 2007; the increase in the last quarter of 2008 is only 1 percent. Our results for the average total drawdown outstanding to total line of credit are higher throughout the crisis compared to the estimates in Ivashina and Scharfstein (2010b). In their sample, the percentage drawn increases by 3.81% (from 20.04% to 23.85%) in the third quarter of 2008 but falls in the fourth quarter to 23.30%. We do not observe such an increase in the third quarter of 2008. However, our sample selection procedure is different. Their sample includes only manufacturing firms that have revolving lines before the crisis and still outstanding in the fourth quarter of 2008. Our sample makes no such requirements: It only requires firms to be in existence before the crisis and is chosen randomly from more than 3,000 firms in Compustat. These sample differences could well explain the differences in results. 17 In columns 7-10 of Table 3, we examine the importance of credit lines and credit line draw-downs using asset-weighted averages and equally-weighted averages. Looking first at the asset-weighted sample, we find that the ratio of total lines of credit to total assets is 9.5% at the start of the crisis. The aggregate amount of new draw-downs per quarter divided by total assets is less than 1% of assets in all quarters except one, the fourth quarter of 2007, when it is 1.28%. Yet, during that quarter, in untabulated results, the ratio of cash holdings to total assets for our random sample falls. New draw-downs in the last two quarters are much lower than in the fourth quarter of 2007. We turn next to the equally-weighted results. In our equally-weighted sample, credit lines represent 15.0% of assets in the sample formation quarter, which is not very different from the 16.5% in the Sufi (2009) sample or from the data collected by Gao and Yun (2009) for manufacturing firms in 2008. The equally-weighted average of the new draw-downs in the fourth quarter of 2007 is 1.72%. It is much lower in the fourth quarter of 2008, when it is 1.03%. This percentage drawdown is similar to the percentage drawdown in the first quarter of 2008. It is also similar to the new drawdowns to assets in the third quarter of 2006 (not tabulated) for the same firms, which was 0.96%. This evidence on draw-downs seems consistent with both the credit channel hypothesis and the risk hypothesis. Section 3. Did credit contract more for firms more likely to be bank dependent? Section 2 shows that equally-weighted net total debt issuance does not fall in the first year of the crisis. It falls sharply after September 2008, however. We next explore whether net total debt issuance is lower for firms that are more likely to be bank dependent, as is predicted by the credit supply shock hypothesis. First, we consider raw data. Second, we use abnormal net total debt issuance from a regression model. In Panel A of Table 3, we assign firms to subgroups as of the end of the previous quarter. The first column of Panel A of Table 3 shows the data for net total debt issuance for firms with investment-grade debt. Strikingly, investment-rated firms borrow substantially more during the first year of the crisis than during the last year of the boom. The increase is statistically significant. After September 2008, the net 18 debt issuance of investment-rated firms falls to 0.01% in the first quarter of 2009. This contrasts with the lowest net total debt issuance for investment-rated firms in the sample, which is -0.23%. Surprisingly, however, the net long-term debt issuance of investment-rated firms is not different in the first quarter of 2009 from the last quarter of the boom (not reported in the table). Turning to unrated firms, which are more bank dependent as they do not have access to public debt, we find that their net total debt issuance is not significantly different in the first year of the crisis from the last year of the credit boom. However, the net debt issuance of unrated firms in the first quarter of 2009 is lower than in any other sample quarter. Next, we divide firms into five quintiles of asset sizes using NYSE cut-offs. We expect the smallest firms to be more bank dependent and reproduce results for only these firms. Small firms are typically considered to be financially constrained (e.g., Almeida, Campello, and Weisbach (2004)) and their main source of debt finance is loans from banks. We find that net total debt issuance of the smallest firms does not fall in the first year of the crisis, but it reaches an extremely low value in the first quarter of 2009. Not surprisingly, the net total debt issuance of the largest firms also does not fall during the first year of the crisis (not reported in the table), but it is -0.01% in the first quarter of 2009. Over our entire sample period, the four smallest size quintiles never experience a net total debt issuance rate lower than the one they experience in the first quarter of 2009. However, the situation of the largest firms is different; they experience lower net total debt issuance in 18 other quarters during the sample period. Since small firms rely much more on bank loans than large firms, our evidence is consistent with the evidence in Becker and Ivashina (2010) of a serious supply shock to bank debt in 2009. We also construct a sample of firms that are financially constrained before the crisis using a definition that is similar to the definition of Korajczyk and Levi (2003). We define a firm to be KL financially constrained in quarter t if it (1) does not pay dividends, (2) does not have net equity repurchases, (3) does not have a credit rating, and (4) has a Tobin’s q greater than one (defined as the market value of the assets divided by the book value, where market value of assets is book value of assets minus book equity plus market value of equity) in quarter t-1. With this definition of financially constrained firms, we isolate firms that have investment opportunities that outpace their internally generated cash flow and that do not 19 have access to public debt markets. The net debt issuance of these firms is not different in the first year of the crisis from the last year of the credit boom. Strikingly, these firms have higher net debt issuance in the third quarter of 2008 than at the top of the credit boom. However, their net debt issuance falls sharply after the third quarter of 2008. There is no quarter before the crisis when these firms have negative net debt issuance, but in the first quarter of 2009 their net debt issuance is -0.10%. The next column considers firms that have no debt at the end of the previous quarter. Presumably, such firms should have unused debt capacity. These firms are able to borrow at the peak of the crisis. They have the highest net debt issuance of any subgroup in the first quarter of 2009, at 0.36%. We then investigate firms whose cash to assets ratio is in the top quintile of cash to assets ratios. These firms do not have to borrow – they have extremely large amounts of cash by any standard. At the start of the crisis, these firms have an average cash to assets ratio of 61%; their median cash ratio is the same. Their net debt issuance is significantly lower during the crisis than in the last year of the boom. Further, their net debt issuance is the second lowest of any subgroup in the first quarter of 2009. The last column examines firms whose leverage ratio is in the top quintile of debt to asset ratios. These firms are highly levered, so that a drop in firm value would increase the risk of their debt sharply. Their net debt issuance is insignificantly different in the first year of the crisis, but it plummets afterwards. This is the group of firms with the most negative net debt issuance of any group. While net debt issuance attains extreme values in the first quarter of 2009 for firms that are more likely to be bank dependent, so does operating cash flow (not reported). For almost all subgroups, operating cash flow in the first quarter of 2009 is roughly 200 basis points less than in the third quarter of 2008. For many types of firms, the operating cash flow of the first quarter of 2009 is the lowest in the sample. For instance, for unrated firms, operating cash flow in the first quarter of 2009 is 0.88%. The lowest operating cash flow between 1983 and 2004 is 1.20% and the average is 2.49%. Such low cash flows would make it harder for firms to raise funds even in the absence of a credit supply shock. It is noteworthy that the mean KMV EDF, a widely used estimate of the probability of default, for the North 20 American CDX index (125 investment grade names) increased from 0.69% on September 15, 2008 (the day of the Lehman bankruptcy) to 2.99% at the end of March 2009. The raw data on net debt issuance does not allow us to understand whether the changes in net debt issuance are unusual during the crisis (after controlling for the determinants of debt issuance) and whether they are more so for firms that are more likely to be bank dependent. To estimate abnormal debt issuance, we follow Fama and French (2008). We estimate their models from 1995 to 2009. However, they estimate their models using annual data, and some of the variables they use are not reported quarterly. Consequently, we modify some variable definitions to account for the limitations of quarterly data. We regress net debt issuance of period t on the following variables computed for period t-1: the percentage change in assets from the previous quarter (negative coefficient), operating cash flow to assets (positive coefficient), dividends to assets (positive coefficient), a dummy variable equal to one if the firms pays dividends (negative coefficient), lagged leverage (negative coefficient), an indicator variable equal to one if book equity is negative (positive coefficient), the lagged log market capitalization (negative coefficient), the market-to-book ratio (positive coefficient), lagged cash over assets (negative coefficient), lagged debt in current liabilities over assets (negative coefficient), R&D over assets (positive coefficient), capital expenditures over assets (positive coefficient), and the change in the stock price (negative coefficient). To save space, we do not reproduce the regression coefficients on these regressors. All coefficients are significant in all the regressions we estimate and these coefficients are similar in all the regressions as well. We take into account seasonal effects through indicator variables. Only the fourth quarter indicator variable is significant and its coefficient is always negative. We also use firm fixedeffects to capture unmodeled firm characteristics. To capture changes during the financial crisis, we use a financial crisis indicator variable and a crisis peak indicator variable. The financial crisis indicator variable equals one for each crisis quarter. The crisis peak indicator variable equals one for each quarter after September 2008. To test the hypothesis that firms of a given subgroup have a different change in net total debt issuance from the other firms, we create an indicator variable for that subgroup and interact that indicator variable with the crisis indicator variables. 21 The interactions capture how the subgroup reacts differently to the crisis from the remainder of the sample. For the regressions we report in Panel B of Table 3, we form the subgroups at the end of the second quarter of 2006 as in Duchin, Ozbas, and Sensoy (2010), so there is no reason to believe that the crisis itself affects a firm’s assignment into a subgroup. We also estimate regressions with quarterly assignments to groups, however, and discuss the cases where the results differ meaningfully. The first regression is for the whole sample. We see that net total debt issuance is higher by 0.11% during the crisis, but the value of the crisis peak indicator variable is -0.96%, so that for the last two quarters of the sample, net total debt issuance is abnormally low by -0.85%. We next investigate whether abnormal net total debt issuance is significantly different for the unrated firms and the smallest firms. Both interactions are positive for unrated firms, indicating that their net debt issuance drops by less than for the other firms both during the crisis and during the last two quarters of our sample. The interactions are insignificant for the smallest firms. The crisis interaction is not significant for the KL financially constrained firms, but the crisis peak indicator variable is positive and significant (not reported). We create a subgroup of KL financially constrained firms that have positive net debt issuance in the year ending in June 2006. As discussed earlier, we call these highly constrained firms. These firms borrow less during the crisis as the crisis indicator variable interaction has a value of -0.59%. However, the peak crisis interaction is not significant for these firms and the coefficient is positive, so their net debt issuance does not change more than for other firms after September 2008. It is striking, though, that these firms’ average operating cash flow normalized by assets in the first year of the crisis is 66.20% higher than their average operating cash flow normalized by assets in the last year of the credit boom. Firms with no debt at the end of the second quarter of 2006 have a positive and significant crisis interaction as well as a positive and significant peak crisis interaction, indicating that they have abnormal net debt issuance relative to other firms. In the next regression, we show that firms with high holdings of cash borrow less during the crisis than other firms, but they have positive abnormal net debt issuance after September 2008, so their net debt issuance falls significantly less than for other firms. 22 In the last column, we turn to firms that are in the top quintile of leverage at the end of the second quarter of 2006. These firms have abnormal net borrowing of -1% per quarter during the crisis and their abnormal borrowing falls by an additional 1.28% per quarter after September 2008. In results not reported in the table, we also consider firms that at the end of the second quarter of 2006 are in the top quintile of the ratio of short-term debt to assets. These firms face the greatest rollover risk. They have abnormally low net total debt issuance during the crisis and the crisis peak interaction is negative as well. However, both the crisis interaction and the crisis peak interaction have absolute values that are lower than for the firms in the top quintile of leverage. A concern with our approach is that more bank-dependent firms could be subjected to different shocks during the crisis that have nothing to do with these firms being bank dependent. As a result, the patterns we uncover could be caused by these unmodeled shocks. One way to investigate this possibility is to check whether our results still hold when we estimate our regressions within industries since shocks would be more similar within industries. Consequently, we estimate all the models for firms producing or selling durable consumer goods.13 Obviously, this approach restricts the sample as the firms producing or selling durable consumer goods represent slightly more than 10% of the total number of firms in the sample. Nevertheless, the patterns documented for the whole sample hold when we restrict firms to this industry. The regression evidence overall shows the net debt issuance of firms that would generally be considered to be financially constrained in the literature (namely the smallest firms, unrated firms, and firms satisfying the Korajczyk and Levi (2006) definition of financially constrained firms) does not fall abnormally compared to the net debt issuance of other firms during the crisis. However, highly financially constrained firms experience a significant reduction in their net debt issuance during the crisis relative to other firms, though this finding does not hold at the peak of the crisis. The highly financially constrained firms reduce their net debt issuance before September 2008 in a way that is consistent with the hypothesis 13 We define the durable consumer goods industry based on the Fama-French 49 industry classification and include Consumer Goods, Apparel, and Retail. 23 that more bank-dependent firms were more affected. We will see, however, that the story of these firms is more subtle. In any case, it is worth noting that the assets of the highly financially constrained firms represent less 1% of the total assets of the firms in the sample at the end of June 2006. Finally, highly levered firms and firms with a high short-term debt ratio borrow less during the crisis and even less at the peak of the crisis. Section 4. Is there a substitution effect towards equity? In this section, we investigate net equity issuance. In the first column of Panel A of Table 4, we show the evolution of net equity issuance for investment grade firms. These firms repurchase more than they issue. The level of net equity issuance of these firms is not significantly different in the first year of the crisis from the last year of the boom. However, net equity issuance increases dramatically after September 2008 for these firms as they decrease repurchases, reaching -0.14% in the first quarter of 2009. We already saw that for the equally-weighted average, net equity issuance falls sharply during the crisis. When we consider subgroups of firms that are more likely to be bank-dependent, the result is even stronger, as seen in Panel A of Table 4. In particular, for the smallest firms, net equity issuance is 1.90% per quarter in the last year of the boom, but 1.12% per quarter in the first year of the crisis. Net equity issuance drops to 0.52% in the first quarter of 2009 for these firms, a net equity issuance rate which is the lowest since the start of our sample period in 1983. A similar result holds for unrated firms. Net equity issuance of KL constrained firms falls in the first year of the crisis by almost 80 basis points. Further, their net equity issuance in the last quarter of 2008 is slightly more than one sixth of their net equity issuance at the top of the credit boom. For firms with no debt, net equity issuance is 2.05% during the last quarter of the credit boom. It is negative each quarter of 2008. Prior to 2008, net equity issuance of nodebt firms was negative in only one quarter, the third quarter of 2002. The high cash firms are heavy net equity issuers in the year after selection as their net equity issuance averages 3.13% of assets per quarter, but it drops to 1.59% of net assets in the first year of the crisis and falls to 0.19% in the fourth quarter of 24 2008 before increasing to 1.20% in the first quarter of 2009. Finally, the high leverage firms significantly decrease their net equity issuance in the first year of the crisis. It could be that fundamentals led to an even sharper decrease in net equity issuance than the one we observe, i.e. there could have been substitution towards equity by firms that are more bank-dependent in the sense that they would have abnormally high net equity issuance given the evolution of fundamentals. To examine this possibility, we estimate regression models of net equity issuance. These models again follow Fama and French (2008) and are the same as the ones used for net debt issuance. Our control variables (and the sign of their coefficients from the regressions) are the values of the following variables computed at the end of the previous quarter: the percentage change in assets from the previous quarter (negative coefficient), operating cash flow to assets (negative coefficient), dividends to assets (not significant), a dummy variable equal to one if the firms pays dividends (not significant), lagged leverage (positive coefficient), an indicator variable equal to one if book equity is negative (not significant), the lagged log market capitalization (negative coefficient), the market-to-book ratio (positive coefficient), lagged cash over assets (negative coefficient), lagged debt in current liabilities over assets (positive coefficient), R&D over assets (positive coefficient), capital expenditures over assets (positive coefficient), and the change in the stock price (positive coefficient). We also include indicator variables for quarters to capture seasonality. The indicator variable for the third quarter is significantly negative and the seasonal variable for the fourth quarter is significantly positive. To save space, we do not reproduce the coefficients on these variables in the table. All regression coefficients are similar in sign and magnitude in each regression. Table 4 reproduces estimates for the crisis indicator variables and interactions. We see from the first regression that net equity issuance is abnormally low during the crisis, but that compared to the other quarters of the crisis, it is higher after September 2008. This abnormally higher net equity issuance after September 2008 could be evidence of substitution towards equity because of an impaired credit channel. However, for that to be the case, we would want abnormally high net equity issuance for firms that experience a greater abnormal decrease in net debt issuance. 25 As in the analysis of net debt issuance, we create subgroups based on the status of firms at the end of the second quarter of 2006 to make sure that our classification is not affected by the crisis. The next two regressions immediately put to rest the possibility that firms with greater abnormal decrease in net debt issuance issue more equity. The unrated firms have even lower net equity issuance during the crisis and post-September 2008 than the other firms in the sample. The same is true for the smallest firms. In results not reproduced in the table, we investigate large firms and investment grade firms using the same regression framework. We find that the abnormal net equity issuance increase is concentrated among these firms and is explained by a sharp drop in equity repurchases after September 2008. When we turn to the KL financially constrained firms (estimates not reproduced), their net equity issuance falls more during the crisis and falls further after September 2008. Turning to the subset of highly financially constrained firms, we find that these firms do not have a significant crisis interaction, but their net equity issuance drops more after September 2008 than for other firms. This pattern is the opposite from the one we would expect with a bank credit supply shock. Firms with no debt have a negative crisis interaction, but do not have a negative peak crisis interaction. The net equity issuance of firms with high cash is abnormally low throughout the crisis and further decreases abnormally after September 2008. Finally, the crisis interaction is positive for the highly levered firms, but they abnormally reduce net equity issuance after September 2008. Firms with high short-term debt (regression estimates not reproduced) do not have net equity issuance that differs from the remainder of the sample. When we estimate our regressions for durables only, we find that equity issuance falls during the crisis, but is higher after September 2008. As for the whole sample, however, bank-dependent firms do not experience this increase in equity issuance because it is driven by firms that decrease repurchases. It follows from the results in Panel B of Table 4 that for the subgroups which are more likely to be bank dependent, net equity issuance falls before September 2008 even when net debt issuance does not. Further, there is no evidence of a substitution effect towards equity from the firms that had the greatest credit contraction. 26 Section 5. Did cash holdings fall? In the presence of an unexpected credit supply contraction, we would expect firms to use their cash balances to mitigate the adverse impact of the credit contraction. Paradoxically, for most types of firms, cash ratios fall in the first year of the crisis when net debt issuance does not fall, but cash ratios increase after September 2008 when net debt issuance falls sharply. In the first column of Panel A of Table 5, we show the cash ratio for investment grade firms. The average ratio of cash to assets for these firms is not significantly different in the last year of the boom from the first year of the crisis. However, the ratio increases dramatically from 8.28% at the end of September 2008 to 9.47% at the end of March 2009. Turning next to the smallest firms, we find in Panel A of Table 5 that their average ratio of cash to assets falls from 27.85% to 26.97% from the last year of the credit boom to the first year of the credit crisis. The drop is statistically significant. However, the cash ratio is 25.14% at the end of September 2008 and increases to 25.72% at the end of the first quarter of 2009, a statistically significant increase. For large firms (not reported), the drop in the first year of the crisis is insignificant, but the increase in the cash ratio after September 2008 is significant and much larger, as the average cash ratio increases from 8.56% at the end of the September to 9.80% at the end of March 2009. Unrated firms behave like the smallest firms, while investment-grade firms behave like the largest firms. We also find a similar pattern for KL financially constrained firms. For these firms, cash holdings average 34.95% in the last year of the boom, 34.10% in the first year of the crisis, and fall to 30.65% by the end of September 2008. However, they increase to 34.17% by the end of January 2009. It should be noted, however, that for all other subgroups discussed so far, there is no material difference in the change in the average cash ratio after September 2008 if we compare firms that belong to the same subgroup at the end of September 2008 and at the end of March 2009 or follow the firms that belong to the subgroup in the third quarter of 2008 even if they do not belong to that subgroup at the end of March 2009. This is not the case for the KL constrained firms in Panel A. The change in the cash ratio of the KL constrained firms at the end of September 2008 is essentially zero from then to the end of March 2008 while the average cash holdings of KL constrained firms selected quarterly increase sharply. However, in neither case does the ratio of cash to assets fall. 27 An interesting group of firms is the group with no debt. We would expect the changes in credit markets to have less impact on firms with no debt than on more typical firms. These firms have an extremely high cash ratio of 42.07% at the end of the credit boom. The cash ratio of these firms falls to 38.32% at the end of the third quarter of 2008. However, these firms hoard cash after September 2008, as their cash ratio increases to 40.27% by the end of our sample. We also want to examine a subset of firms that did not draw down credit lines. For this purpose, we investigate firms that have no debt at the end of the quarter (results not tabulated). Because these firms have no debt at the end of the quarter, they typically have negative net debt issuance during the quarter. These firms experience a 1.19 percentage point increase in the cash ratio after the events of September 2008. This increase is statistically significant as well and represents a 15.38% increase in cash holdings. It follows that the increase in cash holdings is not tied to credit line draw-downs. Though we reproduce the cash ratio of firms with a cash ratio in the top quintile of cash ratios, changes in the cash ratio for firms belonging to that quintile are not informative since firms are selected based on their cash ratio. It is instructive to note, however, that the cash ratio of firms in the top quintile of cash ratios is extremely high. In particular, firms in the top quintile of cash ratios have an average cash ratio of 61.10% at the end of the credit boom. The firms that have a high cash ratio at the end of September 2008 decrease it by 1.32% over the next two quarters. High leverage firms have a much lower cash ratio. Their cash ratio stays remarkably stable throughout the crisis. To understand better where the cash comes from for the firms that increase their cash holdings sharply, we divide the sample into quintiles based on the change in cash in the last two quarters of the sample period normalized by assets at the end of September 2008. We then compare the firms in the top quintile of cash increases to the firms in the bottom quintile of cash increases. The results are striking. The average operating cash flow to assets of the firms in the top quintile for the last two quarters is 5.46%; in contrast, it is -2.28% for the firms in the bottom quintile. The firms in the bottom quintile have negative net debt issuance of -0.32% on average for these two quarters, while the firms in the top quintile have positive net debt issuance of 0.47%. The firms in the top and bottom quintiles have similar capital 28 expenditures to assets, but the firms in the bottom quintile spend 3.14% of assets on R&D on average across the two quarters, while the firms in the top quintile spend only 1.62%. We also compare the firm characteristics for the fourth quarter of 2008 and the first quarter of 2009 to the last two identical quarters of the boom, namely the fourth quarter of 2006 and the first quarter of 2007. Strikingly, capital expenditures fall for firms in the bottom and top quintile, but they fall only by 0.24% for firms in the bottom quintile and by 0.45% for firms in the top quintile – in other words, firms that hoard cash more actually decrease capital expenditures more. Both types of firms have higher R&D expenditures to assets in the last two quarters of the sample than in the fourth quarter of 2006 and the first quarter of 2007. Net equity issuance falls sharply for firms in the bottom quintile, but is largely unchanged for firms in the top quintile. The bottom line of this comparison is that firms that accumulate the most cash are firms that have high operating cash flow, are still borrowing, and do not suffer a large drop in equity issuance. We now turn to the estimation of a cash holdings model. Our model for the expected cash ratio is the model used in Bates, Kahle, and Stulz (2009), but we estimate this model using quarterly data. This model allows for a transaction demand for cash as well as a precautionary demand for cash. The dependent variable is the cash ratio, and the following explanatory variables are used: the standard deviation of cash flows at the industry level using two-digit SIC codes (positive coefficient), the marketto-book ratio (positive coefficient), the log of firm size (insignificant coefficient), the ratio of cash flow to assets (positive coefficient), the ratio of net working capital to assets (negative coefficient), capital expenditures to assets (negative coefficient), leverage (negative coefficient), R&D to assets (negative coefficient), a dummy variable for missing data on R&D (insignificant), dividends to assets (positive coefficient), acquisitions to assets (negative coefficient), net equity issuance to assets (positive coefficient), and net debt issuance to assets (positive coefficient).14 The coefficient estimates are consistent with the coefficient estimates in Bates, Kahle, and Stulz (2009). Because we use quarterly data, we add to the model indicator variables for the second, third, and fourth quarters to accommodate 14 Not all firms report R&D on a quarterly basis. When a firm does not report R&D quarterly, we use the annual R&D, divided by four, as an estimate of R&D in each quarter of that year. Results are similar if we set R&D as missing for these firms. 29 seasonal effects. The indicator variables for the third and fourth quarters have negative significant coefficients. As with the debt and equity issuance models, we allow for firm fixed effects and estimate the model over the period 1995 to the end of the sample. We do not report the coefficients to save space. We first estimate a regression for the whole sample. The cash ratio is significantly lower during the crisis by 0.94%. However, the cash ratio increases abnormally after September 2008 by 0.59%. The regression shows that abnormal cash holdings follow a u-shape pattern as they fall during the crisis but increase after the events of September 2008. The next two regressions show that unrated and small firms decrease their cash ratio more during the crisis than other firms. However, after September 2008, there is no difference for the smallest or the unrated firms. Turning to KL financially constrained firms (not tabulated), we find that the cash ratio of these firms does not evolve differently from the sample as a whole. The subset of highly constrained firms actually has an abnormal increase in the cash ratio during the crisis, but the abnormal increase after September 2008 in excess of the sample as a whole is not statistically significant even though economically large. Firms with no debt experience an abnormal decrease in cash during the crisis and a further abnormal decrease in cash after September 2008. Firms with high cash holdings experience abnormal decreases in cash holdings in excess of the sample as well and these decreases are economically large. Finally, firms with high leverage do not behave differently from the other firms. For robustness, we examine several other regressions. The firms with high short-term debt hold a positive abnormal amount of cash during the crisis, but they do not increase cash holdings after September 2008 abnormally. Though we do not reproduce the results, we also estimate the regressions classifying firms each quarter. When we do so, the increase in cash holdings of firms with no debt and firms with high leverage after September 2008 is not significantly different from the increase of the whole sample. We also estimate the model for firms that have no debt at the end of a quarter, which are firms for which credit line draw-downs are irrelevant. We find that these firms do not behave differently from the firms that have no debt at the beginning of a quarter. Finally, firms in the durables industry exhibit the 30 same patterns as those documented for the sample as a whole. For these firms, cash falls during the crisis, but increases after September 2008. It follows from this discussion that firms reduce cash holdings abnormally before September 2008, but after September 2008, most subgroups of firms either increase cash holdings abnormally or stop consuming cash. The exceptions are firms with high cash holdings or no debt at the end of the second quarter of 2006. However, the average cash ratio of firms that are most likely to be bank dependent does not increase differently from the cash ratio of other firms after September 2008. Section 6. Capital expenditures and the financial crisis As shown in Panel A of Table 6, capital expenditures do not differ on average in the first year of the crisis and the last year of the boom for any type of firm. Though we do not show the results in the table, this is the case even for firms with high short-term debt holdings. However, after September 2008, capital expenditures fall for all types of firms. The fall from September 2008 to the end of the sample period is smallest for high cash firms in percent or percentage points, but it is important to note that these firms are the firms that invest the least in the last year of the boom among the various subgroups we consider. The fall is the largest for the KL financially constrained firms, but it is interesting to note that the ratio of capital expenditures to assets of these firms has a higher value in the fourth quarter of 2008 than the average quarterly value during the last year of the credit boom, so that all the decrease takes place in the first quarter of 2009. The capital expenditure ratio of these firms in the third quarter of 2008 is actually the highest since 2000, and their capital expenditure ratio in the second quarter of 2008 is the second highest since 2000. Though we do not tabulate the results, we also investigate the ratio of R&D expenditures to assets. There is no difference between R&D in the last year of the boom and the first year of the crisis for any type of firms. Not surprisingly, the firms with high cash holdings have extremely high R&D expenditures as their quarterly average in the first year of the crisis is 4.57%. For all types of firms, R&D in the fourth quarter of 2008 is higher than R&D in the last quarter of the boom. However, R&D does fall in the first 31 quarter of 2009. The drop in R&D is smaller in magnitude to the drop in capital expenditures, except for the high cash firms. For the high cash firms, capital expenditures drop by 0.17% while R&D expenditures drop by 0.43%. It is noteworthy that in the year before the crisis, the high cash firms had quarterly capital expenditures of only 0.87%. In contrast, their quarterly R&D expenditures were 4.31%. In other words, capital expenditures are low for high cash firms compared to R&D expenditures. The credit supply shock hypothesis predicts that capital expenditures should fall the most for the most bank-dependent firms. To examine this hypothesis, we estimate regressions for capital expenditures in Panel B of Table 6. We regress capital expenditures to assets in period t on four lags of market-to-book and four lags of operating cash flow. The regression model is the same as the one in Duchin et al. (2010), except that we use several lags because we use quarterly data, as within-quarter adjustments seem implausible. The lagged variables have significantly positive coefficients. We also use indicator variables for the last three quarters of the year. All these indicator variables have positive and significant coefficients. For brevity, we do not reproduce the coefficient estimates. For the sample as a whole, capital expenditures are abnormally low during the crisis by 0.11% per quarter. This finding is surprising since capital expenditures are roughly the same for the sample in the last year of the boom and the first year of the crisis. However, because the stock market does not fall early in the crisis, the model would predict higher capital expenditures. Capital expenditures become significantly lower by 0.20% after September 2008. Turning to the smallest firms and the unrated firms, they invest more during the crisis and their investment does not evolve differently from other firms after September 2008. Further, capital expenditures for KL financially constrained firms (not tabulated) and for highly financially constrained firms in June 2006 do not evolve differently from the sample as a whole. The post-September 2008 shock is not different for firms that have no debt, even though these firms invest more during the crisis. However, firms with a high cash ratio have abnormally higher investment throughout the crisis compared to other firms, so that they do not experience a decrease in investment after September 2008. This latter finding is different from Duchin et al. (2010) who find that firms with more cash invest more only in the first year of the crisis, but a possible explanation is that they did not 32 have access to complete data for the first quarter of 2009. Finally, firms with high leverage invest more during the crisis, but they experience a decrease in investment after September 2008 that is twice the size of the decrease of other firms in the sample. Firms with high short-term debt do not experience abnormal decreases in investment either for the crisis as a whole or after September 2008. As we did in the earlier sections, we also estimate our regressions for firms in the durables goods industry only. The patterns uncovered in this section hold for those firms as well. Bank-dependent firms do not decrease capital expenditures more after September 2008 and firms with high cash holdings do not decrease capital expenditures abnormally throughout the crisis. The only result that differs is that, while firms with no debt where the attribution is made quarterly do not decrease capital expenditures more than other firms after September 2008, firms that have no debt in June 2006 do so. In summary, capital expenditures are abnormally low during the crisis and drop sharply after September 2008. However, firms that are financially constrained before the crisis do not reduce capital expenditures more. In fact, financially constrained firms have abnormally higher capital expenditures during the crisis than other firms, but the abnormal decrease in their capital expenditures after September 2008 is insignificantly different from the sample as a whole. In contrast, firms that have stronger balance sheets before the crisis or before September 2008 experience a lower reduction in capital expenditures. In particular, firms that have high cash holdings or not debt in June 2006 do not reduce capital expenditures abnormally after September 2008, firms that have no debt or an investment rating decrease capital expenditures less, but firms with high debt decrease capital expenditures drastically. Section 7. Conclusion We examine financial and investment policies of firms in the last year of the credit boom and from the start of the 2007 financial crisis to its peak to understand what these policies tell us about the financial crisis. The conventional view of the crisis focuses on the impact on industrial firms of a bank credit supply shock resulting from bank losses in so-called toxic assets. However, the crisis also reduced 33 demand for goods and increased risk. We explore the impact on financial and investment policies of these three shocks. If the bank credit supply shock is the dominant shock, we expect more bank-dependent firms to have lower net debt issuance, a greater decrease in cash holdings, an increase in net equity issuance, and a greater drop in capital expenditures than less bank-dependent firms. Net debt issuance increases before September 2008 for most subsamples in our study, including for firms that are expected to depend on banks for their borrowing. Net debt issuance falls sharply after September 2008, but not more for the bank-dependent subsamples of firms. We find that net equity issuance decreases during the crisis and that this decrease occurs before the decrease in net debt issuance. There is no evidence that net equity issuance decreases less for more bank-dependent firms. Further, while the ratio of cash to assets decreases for bank-dependent firms before September 2008, it either increases or stays constant in all other subsamples, except for the subsample of firms in the top quintile of cash ratios. These firms have an average cash to assets ratio at the peak of the credit boom of 61%, which would allow them to pay for their average capital expenditures and R&D expenditures in the last year of the boom for several years if their operating cash flow were zero and they could not raise any money. There is no evidence that more bank-dependent firms reduce capital expenditures more during the crisis. None of these findings is consistent with a dominant role in financing and investment policies of an exogenous bank credit contraction. In this paper, we focus on the economic importance of a bank credit contraction for non-financial public firms. Therefore, we have nothing to say about the impact of reduced credit availability for consumers. Such reduced credit availability would affect firms through the demand shock in our analysis. We find asset-weighted as well as equally-weighted net debt issuance to be positive in every quarter in 2008; the flow-of-funds data has business credit growing in every quarter of 2008 as well. However, in the flow-of-funds data, household debt falls in 2008 for the first time since 1977, the first year the data is available. Further, we do not have data for private firms. This lack of data on private firms may explain why new loans fall in 2008 compared to 2007 according to the flow-of-funds data, but they do not in our data. According to Dealogic, there were leveraged buyouts totaling $375.1 billion in 2007, but in 2008 34 leveraged buyouts were only for $61.1 billion.15 The dramatic drop in leveraged buyouts represents a sharp decrease in borrowing that undoubtedly explains part of the drop in the amount of new loans in 2008 but does not show up in our data as we focus on public companies. In contrast to the prevalent narrative of the crisis which focuses on the dominant role of the bank credit supply shock, we show that net equity issuance decreases materially early in the crisis, before net debt issuance falls, and is unusually low throughout the crisis. The cumulative decline in financing cash flows during the crisis from reduced net equity issuance exceeds the cumulative loss from decreased net debt issuance for small and unrated firms, which are firms that we would expect to rely on banks for their borrowing. The decrease in net equity issuance is consistent with a decrease in expected cash flows and a loss of investment opportunities, and with an increase in the cost of equity as investors become more risk averse. The cash hoarding we document after September 2008 for most types of firms (except those with the highest ratio of cash to assets) is consistent with a greater demand for precautionary cash holdings resulting from an increase in risk, including an increase in risks associated with the provision of capital to firms. As firms face a loss in future expected cash flows, so that their net worth falls and their prospects dim, we would expect them to find it more expensive and difficult to borrow, as emphasized by theories of endogenous contraction of credit. In support of the latter theories, we find that capital expenditures decrease less for firms that are financially stronger before the crisis and more for firms that are highly levered before the crisis. Our findings strongly suggest a first-order impact on corporations of the decrease in demand and the increase in risk that took place during the crisis. 15 See “Final 2008 data confirm: ‘Little but tumbleweeds’ in LBO arena,” Deal Journal, January 7, 2009, The Wall Street Journal. 35 References Almeida, Heitor, Murillo Campello, and Michael S. Weisbach, 2004, The cash flow sensitivity of cash, Journal of Finance 59, 1777-1804. Almeida, Heitor, Murillo Campello, Bruno Laranjeira and Scott Weisbenner, 2009, Corporate debt maturity and the real effects of the 2007 financial crisis, working paper, University of Illinois, Ill. Baker, Malcolm, 2009, Capital market-driven corporate finance, Annual Review of Financial Economics 1, 181-205. Bates, Thomas, Kathleen Kahle, and René Stulz, 2009, Why do U.S. firms hold so much more cash than they used to? Journal of Finance 64, 1985-2022. Becker, Bo, and Victoria Ivashina, 2010, Cyclicality of credit supply: Firm level evidence, unpublished paper, Harvard Business School, MA. Bernanke, Ben S., 1983, Nonmonetary effects of the financial crisis in the propagation of the Great Depression, The American Economic Review 73, 257-276. Bernanke, Ben S., 2007, The financial accelerator and the credit channel, Federal Reserve Board, Washington, D.C. Bernanke, Ben, and Mark Gertler, 1989, Agency costs, net worth, and business fluctuations, American Economic Review 79, 14-31. Boyson, Nicole, Jean Helwege, and Jan Jindra, 2010, Crises, liquidity shocks, and fire sales at financial institutions, working paper, University of South Carolina. Brunnermeier, Markus K., 2009, Deciphering the liquidity and credit crunch 2007-2008, Journal of Economic Perspectives 23, 77-100. Caballero, Ricardo J., and Arvind Krishnamurthy, 2008, Collective risk management in a flight to quality episode, Journal of Finance 63, 2195-2230. Campbell, John Y., Stefano Giglio, and Christopher Polk, 2010, Hard times, working paper, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA. Campello, Murillo, Erasmo Giambona, John R. Graham, and Campbell R. Harvey, 2009, Liquidity management and corporate investment during a financial crisis, working paper, University of Illinois, Ill. Campello, Murillo, John R. Graham, and Campbell R. Harvey, 2010, The real effects of financial constraints: Evidence from a financial crisis, Journal of Financial Economics, forthcoming. Chari, V.V., Lawrence J. Christiano, and Patrick J. Kehoe, 2008, Facts and Myths about the Financial Crisis of 2008, working paper, Federal Reserve Bank of Minnesota. DeAngelo, Harry, Linda DeAngelo, and René M. Stulz, 2010, Seasoned equity offerings, market timing, and the corporate lifecycle, Journal of Financial Economics 95, 275-295. 36 Duchin, Ran, Oguzhan Ozbas, and Berk A. Sensoy, 2010, Costly external finance, corporate investment, and the subprime mortgage financial crisis, Journal of Financial Economics, forthcoming. Durand, Robert B., Dominic Lim, and J. Kenton Zumwalt, 2007, Fear and the Fama-French factors, working paper, Colorado State University. Erel, Isil, Brandon Julio, Woojin Kim, and Michael S. Weisbach, 2010, Macroeconomic conditions and the structure of securities, working paper, The Ohio State University, OH. Fama, Eugene F. and Kenneth R. French, 2005, Financing decisions: Who issues stock?, Journal of Financial Economics 76, 549-582. Fama, Eugene F. and Kenneth R. French, 2008, Opportunistic financing, working paper, University of Chicago. Faulkender, Michael and Mitchell A. Petersen, 2006, Does the source of capital affect capital structure?, Review of Financial Studies 19, 45-79. Gao, Pengjie, and Hayong Yun, 2009, Commercial paper, lines of credit, and the real effects of the financial crisis of 2008: Firm-level evidence from the manufacturing industry, working paper, University of Notre Dame, Notre Dame, IN. Gertler, Mark and Simon Gilchrist, 1994, Monetary policy, business cycles, and the behavior of small manufacturing firms, The Quarterly Journal of Economics 109(2), 309-40. Gorton, Gary, 2010, Slapped by the invisible hand: The panic of 2007, Oxford University Press, Oxford. Hamilton, James D., 2009, Causes and consequences of the oil shock of 2007-08, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 215-259. Ivashina, Victoria, and David Scharfstein, 2010a, Bank lending during the financial crisis of 2008, Journal of Financial Economics 97, 319-338. Ivashina, Victoria, and David Scharfstein, 2010b, Liquidity management in the financial crisis, working paper, Harvard Business School. Iyer, Rajkamal, Samuel Lopes, José-Luis Peydró, and Antoinette Schoar, 2010, Interbank liquidity crunch and the firm credit crunch: Evidence from the 2007-2009 crisis, unpublished, MIT, Cambridge, MA. Kashyap, Anil K., Owen A. Lamont and Jeremy C. Stein, 1994, Credit conditions and the cyclical behavior of inventories, The Quarterly Journal of Economics 109(3), 565-92. Kashyap, Anil K., Jeremy C. Stein and David W. Wilcox, 1993, Monetary policy and credit conditions: Evidence from the composition of external finance, American Economic Review 83, 78-98. Kiyotaki, Nobuhiro and John Moore, 1997, Credit cycles, Journal of Political Economy 105, 211-248. Korajczyk, Robert A. and A. Levi, 2003, Capital structure choice: macroeconomic conditions and financial constraints, Journal of Financial Economics 68, 75-109. 37 Kuppuswamy, Venkat, and Belen Villalonga, 2010, Does diversification create value in the presence of external financial constraints? Evidence from the 2008-2009 financial crisis, Harvard Business School working paper, Boston, MA. Leamer, Edward E., 2007, Housing is the business cycle, NBER working paper, NBER, Cambridge, MA. Leary, Mark T., 2009, Bank loan supply, lender choice, and corporate capital structure, Journal of Finance 64(3), 1143-1185. Leary, Mark T., and Michael R. Roberts, 2005, Do firms rebalance their capital structure?, Journal of Finance 60, 2575-2619. Lemmon, Michael and Michael R. Roberts, 2010, The response of corporate financing and investment to changes in the supply of credit, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 43, 555-587. Miller, Merton H., 1963, The corporate income tax and corporate financial policies, Cowles Foundation Paper 210b. Minton, Bernadette A., and Catherine Schrand, 1999, The impact of cash flow volatility on discretionary investment and the costs of debt and equity financing, Journal of Financial Economics 54, 423-460. Myers, Stewart, 1977, Determinants of corporate borrowing, Journal of Financial Economics 5, 147-175. Opler, Tim, Lee Pinkowitz, René M. Stulz, and Rohan Williamson, 1999, The determinants and implications of corporate cash holdings, Journal of Financial Economics 52, 3-46. Pastor, Lubos, and Pietro Veronesi, 2010, Uncertainty about government policy and stock prices, working paper, University of Chicago. Shleifer, Andrei, and Robert Vishny, 2010, Unstable banking, Journal of Financial Economics 97, 306318. Sufi, Amir, 2009, Bank lines of credit in corporate finance: An empirical analysis, Review of Financial Studies 22, 1057-1088. 38 Table 1: Financial Policies Statistics During the Credit Boom and the Financial Crisis Panel A: Financial Policies Using Asset-weighted Averages This table examines the time series of firm financial policy variables, on an asset-weighted basis, from the first quarter of 2005 to the first quarter of 2009. We begin with quarterly data collected from the CRSP/Compustat Merged (CCM) Fundamentals Quarterly database for 1980-2009. We delete observations with negative total assets (ATQ), negative sales (SALEQ), negative cash and marketable securities (CHQ), cash and marketable securities greater than total assets, and firms not incorporated in the U.S. We also eliminate all financial firms, which we define as firms with SIC codes between 6000 and 6999, and utilities, which we define as firms with SIC codes between 4900 and 4949. Other variable definitions are provided in the Appendix. To examine the significance of the time series changes we use two approaches. In the seasonality-adjusted p-values, we compare the change of interest to changes over identical quarterly calendar periods to account for seasonality. For the Newey-West pvalues, we use all two-quarter changes but rely on Newey-West t-statistics to account for overlap. Quarter Cash to assets Net longterm debt issuance Net total debt issuance Net equity issuance Capex Operating cash flow Avg 1983-2004 0.0675 0.0036 0.0065 -0.0009 0.0183 0.0451 Avg 1990-2004 0.0666 0.0036 0.0056 -0.0008 0.0171 0.0454 Min 0.0486 -0.0057 -0.0164 -0.0076 0.0097 0.0204 Max 0.1077 0.0144 0.0460 0.0061 0.0295 0.0608 Std. Dev. 0.0149 0.0034 0.0077 0.0021 0.0040 0.0076 0.0924 0.0069 0.0090 -0.0089 0.0146 0.0430 Crisis vs pre crisis Avg (2007Q3-2008Q2) Avg (2006Q3-2007Q2) 0.0956 0.0055 0.0073 -0.0084 0.0144 0.0454 -0.0032 0.0014 0.0017 -0.0005 0.0002 -0.0024 seasonality adjusted p-values 0.6484 0.5044 0.7192 0.8116 0.9365 0.6943 2009Q1 0.1018 0.0077 -0.0019 -0.0019 0.0111 0.0236 2008Q4 0.0981 0.0035 0.0009 -0.0028 0.0156 0.0484 2008Q3 0.0889 0.0061 0.0043 -0.0065 0.0155 0.0442 2007Q2 0.0949 0.0077 0.0087 -0.0110 0.0143 0.0458 Difference (2009Q1 - 2008Q3) 0.0130 0.0016 -0.0062 0.0046 -0.0044 -0.0206 Newey West test p-values 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 Seasonality adjusted p-values 0.0433 0.7082 0.2423 0.0758 0.0842 0.0274 Difference (2009Q1 - 2007Q2) 0.0070 0.0000 -0.0106 0.0091 -0.0032 -0.0222 Newey West test p-values 0.0000 0.6400 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 Seasonality adjusted p-values 0.4982 0.9995 0.1844 0.0009 0.3788 0.0234 Difference 39 Table 1, Panel B: Financial Policies Using Equally-Weighted Averages This table examines the means of the time series of firm financial policy variables, on an equal-weighted basis, from the first quarter of 2005 to the first quarter of 2009. We begin with quarterly data collected from the CRSP/Compustat Merged (CCM) Fundamentals Quarterly database for 1980-2009. We delete observations with negative total assets (ATQ), negative sales (SALEQ), negative cash and marketable securities (CHQ), cash and marketable securities greater than total assets, and firms not incorporated in the U.S. We also eliminate all financial firms, which we define as firms with SIC codes between 6000 and 6999, and utilities, which we define as firms with SIC codes between 4900 and 4949. Other variable definitions are provided in the Appendix. We report p-values for paired t-tests using the firms that exist in both quarters when examining the significance of the difference between the quarters of interest. Quarter Cash to assets Net longterm debt issuance Net total debt issuance Net equity issuance Capex Operating cash flow Avg 1983-2004 0.1605 0.0049 0.0086 0.0125 0.0184 0.0272 Avg 1990-2004 0.1721 0.0044 0.0074 0.0138 0.0172 0.0288 Min 0.1215 -0.0020 -0.0013 0.0027 0.0105 0.0120 Max 0.2316 0.0144 0.0197 0.0354 0.0275 0.0426 Std. Dev. 0.0319 0.0034 0.0050 0.0055 0.0035 0.0070 Avg (2007Q3-2008Q2) 0.2105 0.0066 0.0086 0.0050 0.0148 0.0318 Avg (2006Q3-2007Q2) 0.2198 0.0065 0.0082 0.0105 0.0147 0.0317 -0.0092 0.0001 0.0004 -0.0055 0.0001 0.0001 Ttest pre vs post crisis 0.0034 0.8549 0.6294 0.0001 0.7855 0.9726 2009Q1 0.2015 -0.0015 -0.0045 0.0030 0.0097 0.0131 2008Q4 0.2008 -0.0002 -0.0004 -0.0000 0.0131 0.0305 2008Q3 0.1957 0.0045 0.0081 0.0021 0.0144 0.0320 2007Q2 0.2193 0.0079 0.0105 0.0142 0.0150 0.0301 Diff. (2009Q1 - 2008Q3) 0.0058 -0.0060 -0.0126 0.0010 -0.0046 -0.0189 Paired Diff. 0.0070 -0.0057 -0.0124 0.0013 -0.0049 -0.0203 Ttest 2008Q3=2009Q1 0.0001 0.0001 0.0001 0.1426 0.0001 0.0001 Diff. (2009Q1 - 2007Q2) -0.0178 -0.0094 -0.0150 -0.0112 -0.0053 -0.0171 Paired Diff. -0.0196 -0.0096 -0.0163 -0.0109 -0.0061 -0.0202 0.0001 0.0001 0.0001 0.0001 0.0001 0.0001 Crisis vs pre crisis Difference Ttest 2007Q2=2009Q1 40 Table 2: Summary Statistics on Lines of Credit This table examines data on lines of credit for a random sample of 300 firms chosen as of the second quarter of 2007. We follow the approach in Sufi (2009) in sampling the firms. % new drawdown is the percentage of firms in that quarter that draw down a line of credit. Drawdown to loc is the ratio of the amount drawn down to the firm’s total line of credit. Loc/assets is the ratio of lines of credit to total assets. Drawdown/assets is the ratio of new draw-downs in that quarter to total assets. Quarter 2007Q1 2007Q2 2007Q3 2007Q4 2008Q1 2008Q2 2008Q3 2008Q4 2009Q1 Nobs. 283 300 293 279 277 265 262 252 246 % Nobs with loc 0.806 0.810 0.823 0.817 0.830 0.834 0.828 0.833 0.829 For obs. with loc > 0: new % new drawdown drawdown to loc 0.2719 0.0387 0.3210 0.0428 0.2780 0.0409 0.3728 0.0784 0.3478 0.0660 0.2760 0.0311 0.3134 0.0491 0.3238 0.0527 0.2892 0.0285 Aggregate sample new loc/ drawdown/ assets assets 0.0916 0.0037 0.0953 0.0031 0.0945 0.0032 0.0973 0.0128 0.0951 0.0050 0.0883 0.0019 0.0913 0.0057 0.0997 0.0048 0.1003 0.0016 total drawdown to loc 0.2533 0.2537 0.2533 0.2842 0.3078 0.2943 0.3015 0.3117 0.3273 41 Equal-weighted sample new loc/ drawdown/ assets assets 0.1456 0.0066 0.1502 0.0093 0.1463 0.0079 0.1583 0.0172 0.1556 0.0109 0.1573 0.0056 0.1601 0.0086 0.1754 0.0103 0.1651 0.0066 Table 3: Net total debt issuance Panel A examines time series data for subgroups determined at the end of each previous quarter. We divide firms quarterly into firms with an investment grade rating, a speculative rating, and no rating using the S&P long-term rating (splticrm) available on Compustat. Size quintiles are formed quarterly by dividing all NYSE firms into five quintiles based on assets; we then assign the non-NYSE firms to these quintiles. We define a firm to be KL financially constrained if it (1) does not pay dividends, (2) does not have net equity repurchases, (3) does not have a credit rating, and (4) has a Tobin’s q greater than one (defined as the market value of the assets divided by the book value, where market value of assets is book value minus book equity plus market value of equity). No-debt firms are firms whose leverage ratio is zero at the end of the previous quarter. Hicash (hilev) firms are firms that are in the top quintile of cash to assets (leverage) at the end of the previous quarter. Panel B shows regression estimates. The crisis indicator variable takes value 1 in each quarter after Q2 of 2007. The crisis peak indicator variable takes value 1 for the last two quarters of the sample. Except in the first regression, we interact the crisis indicator variable and the crisis peak indicator variable with a subgroup indicator variable and include the subgroup indicator variable in the regression as well. The subgroups are formed at the end of June 2006 and are (1) investment-rated firms, (2) unrated firms, (3) small firms, namely firms whose asset size is below the top of the bottom quintile of NYSE firms, (4) highly constrained firms, which are KL constrained firms in June 2006 that had positive net issuance in the four quarters ending in June 2006, (5) no debt firms, (6) high cash firms, and (7) high leverage firms. The regressions use control variables that are not reported. These variables are listed in the text and their definition is provided in the Appendix. 42 Panel A: Net Total Debt Issuance Investment Grade Unrated Smallest KL Constrained No Debt High Cash High Lev 0.0074 -0.0023 0.0204 0.0055 0.0082 -0.0015 0.0171 0.0049 0.0092 -0.0011 0.0194 0.0052 0.0134 0.0019 0.0279 0.0061 0.0102 0.0039 0.0175 0.0033 0.0063 -0.0003 0.0196 0.0039 0.0012 -0.0175 0.0203 0.0080 Crisis vs pre crisis Avg (2007Q3-2008Q2) Avg (2006Q3-2007Q2) Difference Ttest 0.0109 0.0060 0.0049 0.0180 0.0083 0.0069 0.0014 0.1540 0.0083 0.0083 0.0000 0.9997 0.0097 0.0075 0.0023 0.2804 0.0073 0.0080 -0.0008 0.5592 0.0020 0.0058 -0.0038 0.0182 0.0069 0.0088 -0.0019 0.4442 2009Q1 2008Q4 2008Q3 2007Q2 0.0001 0.0029 0.0065 0.0069 -0.0035 -0.0005 0.0087 0.0089 -0.0025 -0.0007 0.0086 0.0104 -0.0010 0.0026 0.0109 0.0082 0.0036 0.0071 0.0065 0.0082 -0.0058 -0.0009 0.0000 0.0076 -0.0175 -0.0153 0.0001 0.0168 Diff. (2009Q1 - 2008Q3) Paired Diff. (2009Q1 - 2008Q3) Ttest 2008Q3=2009Q1* -0.0064 -0.0067 0.0545 -0.0122 -0.0117 0.0001 -0.0111 -0.0108 0.0001 -0.0120 -0.0150 0.0001 -0.0029 -0.0050 0.0086 -0.0059 -0.0030 0.2645 -0.0176 -0.0169 0.0001 Diff. (2009Q1 - 2007Q2) Paired Diff. (2009Q1 - 2007Q2) Ttest 2007Q2=2009Q1 -0.0068 -0.0068 0.0079 -0.0124 -0.0134 0.0001 -0.0129 -0.0143 0.0001 -0.0093 -0.0100 0.0019 -0.0046 -0.0073 0.0060 -0.0135 -0.0107 0.0028 -0.0343 -0.0327 0.0001 Avg 1983-2004 Min Max Std. Dev. 43 Panel B: Net Total Debt Issuance Regressions (splits as of 2006Q2) Whole sample crisis Unrated Smallest Highly Constrained No Debt Hicash Hilev 0.0274*** (0.000) Yes -0.0018* (0.081) 0.0005 (0.458) 0.0039*** (0.002) -0.0126*** (0.000) 0.0043** (0.015) 0.0273*** (0.000) Yes 0.0003 (0.733) 0.0010 (0.194) 0.0008 (0.497) -0.0110*** (0.000) 0.0025 (0.139) 0.0274*** (0.000) Yes 0.0012** (0.040) 0.0066*** (0.005) -0.0059** (0.026) -0.0098*** (0.000) 0.0031 (0.387) 0.0277*** (0.000) Yes 0.0006 (0.351) 0.0007 (0.440) 0.0025* (0.058) -0.0115*** (0.000) 0.0097*** (0.000) 0.0272*** (0.000) Yes 0.0012* (0.069) 0.0045*** (0.001) -0.0027* (0.084) -0.0112*** (0.000) 0.0100*** (0.000) 0.0275*** (0.000) Yes 0.0027*** (0.000) 0.0030* (0.087) -0.0101*** (0.000) -0.0072*** (0.000) -0.0128*** (0.000) 0.0276*** (0.000) Yes 182,604 7,984 0.044 180,756 7,633 0.044 180,756 7,633 0.043 182,604 7,984 0.044 180,756 7,633 0.044 180,756 7,633 0.044 180,756 7,633 0.044 0.0011* (0.051) split dummy crisis X split dummy post-Sept 2008 -0.0096*** (0.000) post-Sept X split dummy Constant Fixed Effects Observations Number of gvkey Adjusted R-squared Robust pvalues in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 44 Table 4: Net equity issuance Panel A examines time series data for subgroups determined at the end of each previous quarter. We divide firms quarterly into firms with an investment grade rating, a speculative rating, and no rating using the S&P long-term rating (splticrm) available on Compustat. Size quintiles are formed quarterly by dividing all NYSE firms into five quintiles based on assets; we then assign the non-NYSE firms to these quintiles. We define a firm to be KL financially constrained if it (1) does not pay dividends, (2) does not have net equity repurchases, (3) does not have a credit rating, and (4) has a Tobin’s q greater than one (defined as the market value of the assets divided by the book value, where market value of assets is book value minus book equity plus market value of equity). No-debt firms are firms whose leverage ratio is zero at the end of the previous quarter. Hicash (hilev) firms are firms that are in the top quintile of cash to assets (leverage) at the end of the previous quarter. Panel B shows regression estimates. The crisis indicator variable takes value 1 in each quarter after Q2 of 2007. The crisis peak indicator variable takes value 1 for the last two quarters of the sample. Except in the first regression, we interact the crisis indicator variable and the crisis peak indicator variable with a subgroup indicator variable and include the subgroup indicator variable in the regression as well. The subgroups are formed at the end of June 2006 and are (1) investment-rated firms, (2) unrated firms, (3) small firms, namely firms whose asset size is below the top of the bottom quintile of NYSE firms, (4) highly constrained firms, which are KL constrained firms in June 2006 that had positive net issuance in the four quarters ending in June 2006, (5) no debt firms, (6) high cash firms, and (7) high leverage firms. The regressions use control variables that are not reported. These variables are listed in the text and their definition is provided in the Appendix. 45 Panel A: Net Equity Issuance (splits calculated quarterly) Investment Grade Unrated Smallest KL Constrained No Debt High Cash High Lev Avg 1983-2004 Min Max Std. Dev. -0.0019 -0.0090 0.0042 0.0024 0.0148 0.0041 0.0429 0.0067 0.0180 0.0055 0.0487 0.0075 0.0254 0.0096 0.0686 0.0097 0.0150 -0.0003 0.0552 0.0088 0.0215 0.0055 0.0908 0.0134 0.0133 0.0040 0.0261 0.0045 Crisis vs pre crisis Avg (2007Q3-2008Q2) Avg (2006Q3-2007Q2) Difference Ttest -0.0106 -0.0097 -0.0009 0.2234 0.0080 0.0152 -0.0071 0.0001 0.0112 0.0190 -0.0079 0.0001 0.0169 0.0247 -0.0078 0.0028 0.0045 0.0143 -0.0098 0.0001 0.0159 0.0313 -0.0154 0.0001 0.0081 0.0116 -0.0035 0.0571 2009Q1 2008Q4 2008Q3 2007Q2 -0.0014 -0.0048 -0.0084 -0.0106 0.0042 0.0005 0.0040 0.0204 0.0052 0.0016 0.0054 0.0254 0.0150 0.0054 0.0105 0.0306 0.0031 -0.0054 -0.0007 0.0205 0.0120 0.0019 0.0091 0.0415 0.0056 0.0061 0.0049 0.0125 Diff. (2009Q1 - 2008Q3) Paired Diff. (2009Q1 - 2008Q3) Ttest 2008Q3=2009Q1* 0.0069 0.0072 0.0001 0.0002 0.0006 0.6170 -0.0002 0.0000 0.9880 0.0045 -0.0029 0.3411 0.0038 0.0037 0.1136 0.0029 0.0058 0.1131 0.0007 0.0005 0.8290 Diff. (2009Q1 - 2007Q2) Paired Diff. (2009Q1 - 2007Q2) Ttest 2007Q2=2009Q1 0.0092 0.0093 0.0001 -0.0162 -0.0162 0.0001 -0.0202 -0.0214 0.0001 -0.0156 -0.0285 0.0001 -0.0174 -0.0177 0.0004 -0.0296 -0.0297 0.0001 -0.0069 -0.0068 0.0641 46 Panel B: Net Equity Issuance Regressions (splits as of 2006Q2) Whole sample crisis -0.0026*** (0.000) split dummy crisis X split dummy post-Sept 2008 0.0013** (0.033) Post-Sept X split dummy Constant Fixed Effects Observations Number of gvkey Adjusted R-squared 0.0126*** (0.000) Yes 184,186 8,077 0.071 Unrated Smallest 0.0004 (0.550) -0.0007 (0.306) -0.0039*** (0.000) 0.0056*** (0.000) -0.0054*** (0.000) 0.0124*** (0.000) Yes -0.0008 (0.148) -0.0005 (0.525) -0.0031*** (0.002) 0.0071*** (0.000) -0.0090*** (0.000) 0.0126*** (0.000) Yes 182,331 7,722 0.072 182,331 7,722 0.072 Highly Constrained -0.0025*** (0.000) -0.0018 (0.363) 0.0009 (0.716) 0.0017*** (0.007) -0.0051** (0.017) 0.0125*** (0.000) Yes 184,186 8,077 0.071 Robust pvalues in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 47 No Debt Hicash Hilev -0.0018*** (0.000) -0.0024* (0.066) -0.0029* (0.063) 0.0021*** (0.001) -0.0013 (0.376) 0.0124*** (0.000) Yes -0.0015*** (0.001) 0.0023 (0.224) -0.0100*** (0.000) 0.0024*** (0.000) -0.0043** (0.042) 0.0127*** (0.000) Yes -0.0030*** (0.000) -0.0015 (0.200) 0.0025* (0.063) 0.0023*** (0.000) -0.0027* (0.061) 0.0123*** (0.000) Yes 182,331 7,722 0.072 182,331 7,722 0.072 182,331 7,722 0.071 Table 5: Cash to Assets Panel A examines time series data for subgroups determined at the end of each previous quarter. We divide firms quarterly into firms with an investment grade rating, a speculative rating, and no rating using the S&P long-term rating (splticrm) available on Compustat. Size quintiles are formed quarterly by dividing all NYSE firms into five quintiles based on assets; we then assign the non-NYSE firms to these quintiles. We define a firm to be KL financially constrained if it (1) does not pay dividends, (2) does not have net equity repurchases, (3) does not have a credit rating, and (4) has a Tobin’s q greater than one (defined as the market value of the assets divided by the book value, where market value of assets is book value minus book equity plus market value of equity). No-debt firms are firms whose leverage ratio is zero at the end of the previous quarter. Hicash (hilev) firms are firms that are in the top quintile of cash to assets (leverage) at the end of the previous quarter. Panel B shows regression estimates. The crisis indicator variable takes value 1 in each quarter after Q2 of 2007. The crisis peak indicator variable takes value 1 for the last two quarters of the sample. Except in the first regression, we interact the crisis indicator variable and the crisis peak indicator variable with a subgroup indicator variable and include the subgroup indicator variable in the regression as well. The subgroups are formed at the end of June 2006 and are (1) investment-rated firms, (2) unrated firms, (3) small firms, namely firms whose asset size is below the top of the bottom quintile of NYSE firms, (4) highly constrained firms, which are KL constrained firms in June 2006 that had positive net issuance in the four quarters ending in June 2006, (5) no debt firms, (6) high cash firms, and (7) high leverage firms. The regressions use control variables that are not reported. These variables are listed in the text and their definition is provided in the Appendix. 48 Panel A: Cash to Assets (splits calculated quarterly) Investment Grade Unrated Smallest KL Constrained No Debt High Cash High Lev 0.0594 0.0450 0.0924 0.0110 0.1801 0.1215 0.2755 0.0441 0.1946 0.1430 0.2857 0.0412 0.2306 0.1599 0.3686 0.0610 0.3734 0.3264 0.4450 0.0337 0.4700 0.3621 0.6160 0.0850 0.0721 0.0499 0.1284 0.0179 0.0810 0.0821 -0.0011 0.7722 0.2562 0.2671 -0.0109 0.0147 0.2697 0.2785 -0.0087 0.0833 0.3410 0.3495 -0.0085 0.4133 0.4020 0.4207 -0.0187 0.1243 0.5904 0.6077 -0.0173 0.2079 0.1161 0.1156 0.0005 0.9224 2009Q1 2008Q4 2008Q3 2007Q2 0.0947 0.0868 0.0828 0.0804 0.2414 0.2417 0.2370 0.2677 0.2572 0.2581 0.2514 0.2785 0.3417 0.3058 0.3065 0.3379 0.4027 0.3936 0.3832 0.4195 0.5586 0.5612 0.5628 0.6110 0.1117 0.1181 0.1151 0.1130 Diff. (2009Q1 - 2008Q3) Paired Diff. (2009Q1 - 2008Q3) Ttest 2008Q3=2009Q1* 0.0119 0.0105 0.0001 0.0044 0.0060 0.0006 0.0058 0.0050 0.0139 0.0352 0.0020 0.6142 0.0195 0.0126 0.0022 -0.0042 -0.0132 0.0050 -0.0034 0.0024 0.3919 Diff. (2009Q1 - 2007Q2) Paired Diff. (2009Q1 - 2007Q2) Ttest 2007Q2=2009Q1 0.0143 0.0128 0.0021 -0.0263 -0.0292 0.0001 -0.0213 -0.0316 0.0001 0.0038 -0.0444 0.0001 -0.0167 -0.0501 0.0001 -0.0524 -0.1104 0.0001 -0.0013 -0.0057 0.2300 Avg 1983-2004 Min Max Std. Dev. Crisis vs pre crisis Avg (2007Q3-2008Q2) Avg (2006Q3-2007Q2) Difference Ttest 49 Panel B: Cash to Assets Regressions (splits as of 2006Q2) Whole sample crisis -0.0094*** (0.000) split dummy crisis X split dummy post-Sept 2008 0.0059*** (0.003) Post-Sept X split dummy Constant Fixed Effects Observations Number of gvkey Adjusted R-squared 0.2558*** (0.000) Yes 182,301 7,907 0.144 Unrated Smallest 0.0035 (0.158) -0.0041 (0.110) -0.0148*** (0.000) 0.0102*** (0.000) -0.0016 (0.651) 0.2543*** (0.000) Yes -0.0026 (0.290) -0.0037 (0.205) -0.0083** (0.015) 0.0119*** (0.000) -0.0047 (0.198) 0.2561*** (0.000) Yes 180,184 7,544 0.144 180,184 7,544 0.144 Highly Constrained -0.0094*** (0.000) -0.0160** (0.029) 0.0117** (0.037) 0.0053** (0.012) 0.0093 (0.141) 0.2536*** (0.000) Yes 182,301 7,907 0.145 Robust pvalues in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 50 No Debt Hicash Hilev -0.0076*** (0.000) 0.0125** (0.031) -0.0172*** (0.001) 0.0112*** (0.000) -0.0110* (0.076) 0.2590*** (0.000) Yes -0.0081*** (0.000) 0.0706*** (0.000) -0.0552*** (0.000) 0.0133*** (0.000) -0.0301*** (0.000) 0.2655*** (0.000) Yes -0.0118*** (0.000) 0.0143*** (0.000) 0.0035 (0.354) 0.0099*** (0.000) -0.0049 (0.236) 0.2602*** (0.000) Yes 180,184 7,544 0.144 180,184 7,544 0.149 180,184 7,544 0.144 Table 6: Capital Expenditures Panel A examines time series data for subgroups determined at the end of each previous quarter. We divide firms quarterly into firms with an investment grade rating, a speculative rating, and no rating using the S&P long-term rating (splticrm) available on Compustat. Size quintiles are formed quarterly by dividing all NYSE firms into five quintiles based on assets; we then assign the non-NYSE firms to these quintiles. We define a firm to be KL financially constrained if it (1) does not pay dividends, (2) does not have net equity repurchases, (3) does not have a credit rating, and (4) has a Tobin’s q greater than one (defined as the market value of the assets divided by the book value, where market value of assets is book value minus book equity plus market value of equity). No-debt firms are firms whose leverage ratio is zero at the end of the previous quarter. Hicash (hilev) firms are firms that are in the top quintile of cash to assets (leverage) at the end of the previous quarter. Panel B shows regression estimates. The crisis indicator variable takes value 1 in each quarter after Q2 of 2007. The crisis peak indicator variable takes value 1 for the last two quarters of the sample. Except in the first regression, we interact the crisis indicator variable and the crisis peak indicator variable with a subgroup indicator variable and include the subgroup indicator variable in the regression as well. The subgroups are formed at the end of June 2006 and are (1) investment-rated firms, (2) unrated firms, (3) small firms, namely firms whose asset size is below the top of the bottom quintile of NYSE firms, (4) highly constrained firms, which are KL constrained firms in June 2006 that had positive net issuance in the four quarters ending in June 2006, (5) no debt firms, (6) high cash firms, and (7) high leverage firms. The regressions use control variables that are not reported. These variables are listed in the text and their definition is provided in the Appendix. 51 Panel A: Capital Expenditures Investment Grade Unrated Smallest KL Constrained No Debt High Cash High Lev 0.0189 0.0107 0.0276 0.0038 0.0180 0.0104 0.0275 0.0035 0.0181 0.0101 0.0281 0.0037 0.0205 0.0107 0.0339 0.0050 0.0163 0.0086 0.0268 0.0038 0.0169 0.0065 0.0281 0.0048 0.0173 0.0107 0.0241 0.0033 0.0138 0.0139 -0.0001 0.8942 0.0141 0.0141 0.0000 0.9289 0.0141 0.0140 0.0002 0.7639 0.0151 0.0144 0.0006 0.4779 0.0114 0.0112 0.0001 0.8522 0.0095 0.0087 0.0008 0.3094 0.0168 0.0165 0.0003 0.6963 0.0100 0.0139 0.0134 0.0137 0.0091 0.0123 0.0136 0.0142 0.0085 0.0117 0.0132 0.0141 0.0097 0.0151 0.0171 0.0152 0.0077 0.0105 0.0118 0.0119 0.0065 0.0074 0.0085 0.0091 0.0103 0.0143 0.0151 0.0176 Diff. (2009Q1 - 2008Q3) Paired Diff. (2009Q1 - 2008Q3) Ttest 2008Q3=2009Q1* -0.0034 -0.0036 0.0001 -0.0045 -0.0048 0.0001 -0.0047 -0.0049 0.0001 -0.0074 -0.0071 0.0001 -0.0041 -0.0039 0.0001 -0.0020 -0.0028 0.0001 -0.0048 -0.0052 0.0001 Diff. (2009Q1 - 2007Q2) Paired Diff. (2009Q1 - 2007Q2) Ttest 2007Q2=2009Q1 -0.0037 -0.0042 0.0001 -0.0051 -0.0059 0.0001 -0.0056 -0.0063 0.0001 -0.0055 -0.0062 0.0001 -0.0042 -0.0049 0.0001 -0.0026 -0.0034 0.0001 -0.0073 -0.0081 0.0001 Avg 1983-2004 Min Max Std. Dev. Crisis vs pre crisis Avg (2007Q3-2008Q2) Avg (2006Q3-2007Q2) Difference Ttest 2009Q1 2008Q4 2008Q3 2007Q2 52 Panel B: Capital Expenditure Regressions Whole sample crisis -0.0011*** (0.000) split dummy crisis X split dummy post-Sept 2008 -0.0020*** (0.000) Post-Sept X split dummy Constant Fixed Effects Observations Number of gvkey Adjusted R-squared 0.0078*** (0.000) Yes 173,594 7,618 0.046 Unrated Smallest -0.0010*** (0.006) -0.0013*** (0.000) 0.0008* (0.069) -0.0024*** (0.000) 0.0006 (0.221) 0.0079*** (0.000) Yes -0.0013*** (0.000) -0.0013*** (0.000) 0.0013*** (0.002) -0.0018*** (0.000) -0.0003 (0.491) 0.0078*** (0.000) Yes 172,445 7,312 0.047 172,445 7,312 0.047 Highly Constrained -0.0011*** (0.000) -0.0007 (0.369) 0.0008 (0.300) -0.0021*** (0.000) 0.0009 (0.332) 0.0078*** (0.000) Yes 173,594 7,618 0.046 Robust pvalues in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 53 No Debt Hicash Hilev -0.0014*** (0.000) -0.0012*** (0.001) 0.0022*** (0.000) -0.0021*** (0.000) 0.0006 (0.371) 0.0078*** (0.000) Yes -0.0014*** (0.000) -0.0013*** (0.003) 0.0026*** (0.000) -0.0024*** (0.000) 0.0024*** (0.000) 0.0078*** (0.000) Yes -0.0012*** (0.000) -0.0018*** (0.001) 0.0018*** (0.004) -0.0017*** (0.000) -0.0016** (0.012) 0.0078*** (0.000) Yes 172,445 7,312 0.047 172,445 7,312 0.047 172,445 7,312 0.047 Appendix All variables are quarterly, unless otherwise noted. For variables reported on a year-to-date basis, the quarterly value is calculated by subtracting the lagged value from the current value; in the first quarter of a fiscal year, the lagged value is set equal to zero. Variables names preceded by “lag” are the value of that variable in the previous quarter; variable names preceded by lag2 are the value of that variable two quarters prior. Variable name Description Acquisitions acquisitions (acqy) divided by assets Avgtint average of monthly intermediate term treasuries during the quarter Capex capital expenditures (capxy) / lagged assets Cash cash and marketable securities (cheq) divided by assets Dividend dummy dummy variable equal to one if firm paid dividends Dividends total cash dividends (dvy) minus preferred dividends (dvpq) paid during the quarter, divided by lagged assets Dqsize assets minus lagged assets, divided by lagged assets HYspread spread of Merrill Lynch US High Yield 100 Index over intermediate term treasuries, averaged over each month of the quarter Leverage long-term debt (dlttq) plus debt in current liabilities (dlcq), divided by assets (atq) logMC log (market value of equity) MB market-to-book calculated as book value of assets (atq) minus book value of common equity (ceqq) plus the market value of common equity (cshoq*prccq) Mkt lev long-term debt (dlttq) plus debt in current liabilities (dlcq), divided by long-term debt (dlttq) plus debt in current liabilities (dlcq) plus the market value of common equity Net equity Issuance equity issuance (sstky) minus aggregate equity repurchase (prstkcy), divided by lagged assets Net LT debt Issuance long-term debt issuance (dltisy) minus long-term debt retirement (dltry) divided by lagged assets Net total debt issuance change in long-term debt (dlttq) and debt in current liabilities (dlcq) during the quarter, divided by lagged assets NgBE dummy variable equal to one if book equity (ceqq) is less than 0 NWC working capital (wcapq) minus cash, divided by assets 54 Variable name Description OCF (operating cash flow) Operating cash flow calculated following Minton and Schrand (1999) as sales (saleq) less cost of goods sold (cogsq) less selling, general and administrative expenses (xsgaq) less the change in working capital for the period, divided by total assets (atq). Working capital is current assets other than cash and short-term investments less current liabilities and is calculated as the sum of the nonmissing amounts for accounts receivable (rectq), inventory (invtq), and other current assets (acoq) less the sum of the non-missing amounts for accounts payable (apq), income taxes payable (txpq), and other current liabilities (lcoq). If all components of working capital are missing in either the current quarter or the previous quarter, working capital and operating cash flow are both set equal to missing. Quarterly selling, general and administrative expenses exclude onequarter of annual research and development costs (xrd) and advertising expenses (xad) when those data items are available. PPE PPE (ppentq) divided by assets R&D R&D (xrdq) / assets. If R&D is only reported annually, then quarterly R&D is set equal to one-fourth of annual R&D. If R&D is missing, it is set equal to 0. Rated dummy variable equal to one if the S&P long-term rating (splticrm) available on Compustat is investment grade or speculative Rdmiss dummy variable equal to one if R&D is missing in Compustat Sigma12 the median of the standard deviations of cash flow/assets over past 12 quarters for firms in the same industry, as defined by two-digit SIC code. Size log (book value of assets in 2009 dollars) STDebt change in debt in current liabilities (dlcq), divided by lagged assets 55