DO INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT AGREEMENTS PROTECT INVESTMENT? Petroleum Evidence Srividya Jandhyala* srividya@gwu.edu Robert Weiner* rweiner@gwu.edu International Business Department George Washington University 2201 G Street NW, Funger Hall 401 Washington, DC 20052 26 August 2012 Abstract: Do international institutions – institutions that transcend country borders– reduce MNEs’ political risk? We examine whether the presence of International Investment Agreements (IIAs), negotiated among countries for increased foreign investor protection, lowers political risk for MNEs. We argue that IIAs limit the ability of host governments to make discriminatory policy changes that adversely affect the value of firms’ investments. However, the need for IIA protection, and the ability to benefit from it, vary with firm characteristics, specifically financial resources and ownership. Using detailed transaction-level data for sale of petroleum reserves in 45 countries, we find that MNEs pay significantly higher amounts for assets protected by IIAs than similar unprotected assets, an effect moderated by the firm’s financial resources and state ownership. *We are grateful to JS Herold for data access, and the George Washington University CIBER for research support. We would also like to thank Heather Berry, Witold Henisz, Steve Kobrin, Noel Maurer, Jordan Siegel, Jennifer Spencer, and the seminar/conference participants at the Indian School of Business, The Fletcher School, Atlanta Competitive Advantage Conference, Academy of International Business, Academy of Management and the International Political Economy Society Annual Conferences for comments on earlier drafts of this paper. Paper contents are our sole responsibility. Introduction In April 2012 Argentina nationalized YPF, the local subsidiary of Spanish oil company Repsol, despite the fact that Spain and Argentina have an International Investment Agreement (IIA), designed to protect each country’s investment in the other. This paper examines IIAs empirically, asking whether MNEs act as if they protect foreign investment. Such agreements are potentially especially important in natural resources, because many resource-rich countries domestic institutions do not protect property rights. Petroleum is of particular interest, as one of the largest industries for international trade and investment (Weiner, 2005). Historically, MNEs have accounted for the vast majority of investment in exploration, refining, and distribution. The industry is also especially vulnerable to property rights violations. Foreign firms make large, upfront investments for licenses, resources, and transportation and refining infrastructure. The upfront investments make them particularly vulnerable to the classical “obsolescing bargaining” problem (Vernon, 1980). Once an investment is sunk, bargaining power shifts from the foreign investor to the host country and the interests of the two parties diverge. When the initial advantages of the MNEs erode, host country governments seek to renegotiate their initial concession agreement to appropriate greater returns from the bargain (Vernon, 1971). Natural resources are also particularly vulnerable as many countries viewed foreign control as compromising their sovereignty (UNCTAD, 2004). The peak period of nationalization was the 1970s: there was growing dissatisfaction with oil concessions signed prior to World War II, viewed as heavily favoring the investors (Stevens, 2008). As in other industries, the outright nationalization of petroleum FDI of the 1970s (Kobrin, 1987; Minor, 1994; Dunning, 1998) has largely been replaced by redistributive policies, wherein countries have unilaterally shifted taxation and contract terms in their favor (Wint, 2005; Henisz & Zelner, 2010). Redistributive policies are often perceived as ‘creeping expropriation’ by 1 foreign investors, whereas host-country governments and their constituents perceive them to be legitimate public policy choices by a sovereign actor. The oil-price boom of the last decade has seen increased concern over both outright and creeping expropriation, o which the 2012 YPF nationalization is but one example. For example, in the year 2000, ground was broken for the Chad-Cameroon oil pipeline – a collaborative endeavor involving three multinational oil corporations (Exxon/Mobil, Petronas Malaysia, and Chevron), the governments of the two countries as well as the World Bank. Once oil began to flow through the pipeline, the Chad government unilaterally declared its intention to renegotiate the agreement by creating a national oil company and expelling Chevron & Petronas (Gould & Winters, 2007; Click & Weiner, 2010). In a similar vein, in 2006, Bolivia nationalized its oil and gas industry, while Ecuador used its troops to take over Occidental Petroleum’s holdings and turn them over to state-owned Petroecuador (Click & Weiner, 2010). Using forced contract renegotiations, Russia turned over BP and Shell’s petroleum operations to local state owned companies (Economist, 2007). Venezuela mandated the sale of foreignowned assets, eventually leading Exxon and ConocoPhillips to exit the country. Thus, property-rights protection is a central issue in the petroleum industry. Facing expropriation or renegotiation, foreign investors could attempt to use the host country institutional system to protect their assets. However, domestic institutions may be biased against foreign investors, or be viewed as corrupt and inefficient. IIAs, however, may provide alternate mechanisms by which investors can protect their assets or seek appropriate compensation in the event of adverse state action. Host- and home-country institutions have long been shown to influence the strategic behavior of multinational enterprises (MNEs) (Hoskisson et al, 2000; Garcia-Canal & Guillen, 2008; Meyer et al, 2009; Holburn & Zelner, 2010). Of particular importance are institutions that shape property rights, 2 because they influence political risk and resource allocation in foreign investment (Kobrin, 1976; Murtha & Lenway, 1994; North, 1990; Henisz & Delios, 2001; Loree & Guisinger, 1995). By focusing on domestic institutions of home and host countries, the literature has largely ignored the proliferation of international institutions – institutions that themselves transcend national borders – governing foreign direct investment (FDI). International institutions are part of a broader, evolving global environment; an additional level of analysis beyond the individual-country level. This environment presents new challenges for global strategy (Ricart et al, 2004; Westney, 2011). In this paper, we examine the effects of international institutions on foreign investment, focusing on International Investment Agreements (IIAs). Since the mid-twentieth century, governments have signed nearly 3000 IIAs, either bilaterally or multilaterally (UNCTAD, 2010). IIAs are aimed at altering the rules governing FDI by providing extensive rights and protection for MNEs, while restricting host governments’ actions (Neumayer & Spess, 2005; Buthe & Milner, 2009), and providing alternatives to domestic courts to settle disputes (UNCTAD, 2004). However, some authors are skeptical of the enhanced property-rights protection claimed for IIAs, arguing that they may be redundant (Yackee, 2009) or ineffective, because of the difficulty in enforcing claims against sovereign states (RoseAckerman, 2009). Our understanding of IIAs’ influence on investment, primarily drawn from literature in political science, economics, and law, is limited. Empirical work is limited to aggregate country-level data. Recent studies examining changes in FDI flows in response to IIAs cannot capture influence of IIAs on firm-level decisions (Salacuse & Sullivan, 2005; Kerner, 2009; Hallward-Driemeyer, 2003, 2009; Tobin & RoseAckerman, 2003). Moreover, these studies yield mixed empirical results, which could be due to countrylevel aggregation, or because the benefits of IIAs apply only under specific circumstances. The 3 effectiveness of IIAs as an institutional solution to political hazards faced by MNEs thus remains an open question. In contrast to the aggregate approach followed in the literature, we examine transaction-level investment data in a single salient industry – petroleum. This is not only the single largest industry for international trade and FDI (Weiner, 2005), but also one with large upfront capital costs and high political salience making it especially prone to political risk (Kobrin, 1987). Drawing on the recent strategy literature on firms’ varying abilities to operate under a given institutional environment (see, for example, Capron & Guillen, 2009; Macher et al, 2011), we develop theory that suggests that the need for IIA protection, as well as MNEs’ ability to benefit from such protection, should vary systematically with firm characteristics. We explore two dimensions that theory suggests may be important, and for which we have firm-level evidence –financial resources and ownership. Our study makes three contributions to the strategy literature. First, we introduce and highlight the role of international institutions in multinational investment, in contrast to the prior focus on domestic institutions of home and host countries. Work on international institutions has focused narrowly on corruption regulations (Cuervo-Cazurra, 2008; Jeong & Weiner, 2012) or coercive pressure of multilateral agencies (Henisz, Zelner & Guillen, 2005). We broaden the discussion by examining property rights, responding to Westney’s (2011: 379) call to examine “the global environment beyond the focus on industry competition and other MNCs that has long dominated strategy models.” Second, we provide direct tests of the effectiveness of international institutions in ameliorating political risk using an asset valuation model. Although political risk arising from weak institutions’ inability to limit the policy discretion of the host government has long been argued to be an important factor limiting firms’ international expansion (Vernon, 1971; Kobrin, 1976; Boddewyn, 1988; Tallman, 1988; Ring, Lenway & Govekar, 1990; Henisz, 2000a), its influence has largely been inferred from indirect 4 outcomes such as capital flow, location choice, and entry mode. We examine transaction values – the amount paid by firms buying petroleum reserves that are routinely traded on world markets. Transaction value should be a cleaner and more accurate reflection of political risk than ex post accounting measures, such as income or return on assets.1 By examining prices paid by firms in reserve acquisitions, we are able to provide a direct estimate of estimate the value, if any, of political risk protection offered by IIAs. Finally, our analysis also contributes to the growing literature on organizational capabilities for assessing and managing non-market risks (see, for example, Henisz, 2000b; Capron & Guillen, 2009; Holburn & Zelner, 2010; Garcia-Canal & Guillen, 2008). While prior studies have shown that firms differ in their ability to operate effectively under a given domestic institutional arrangement, our work examines how firm characteristics allow for differential benefits from international institutions. Political risk and foreign investment International expansion strategy is influenced not just by market conditions but also by political factors (Kobrin et al, 1980). Firms typically undertake large upfront investments in licenses, resources, and infrastructure, making them vulnerable to the classical “obsolescing bargaining” problem. Once an investment is sunk, bargaining power shifts from the foreign investor to the host country and the interests of the two parties diverge. When the initial advantages of the MNEs erode, host-country governments seek to renegotiate initial agreements to appropriate greater returns from the bargain (Vernon, 1971). Governments can alter the profitability of foreign investment through outright expropriation, or by altering contracts, regulations, taxes, tariffs, entry and exit rules, pricing, etc (Henisz, 2000a; Garcia-Canal & Guillen, 2008; Holburn & Zelner, 2010). 1 Accounting measures are not consistently reported (or not reported at all) at a country level (Tallman 1991; Healy et al 2011), and may also reflect realizations (or the absence thereof) of political hazards. 5 Since the 1970s, creeping expropriations –unilateral changes in taxation or other contract terms in favor of the host government – have largely replaced outright expropriations (Wint, 2005; Henisz & Zelner, 2010). Regulated industries such as petroleum, telecommunications, electricity, water, and banking, however, continue to be especially sensitive to such risks (Garcia-Canal & Guillen, 2008). For example, the Chad government nationalized the Chad-Cameroon pipeline once oil began to flow through it and expelled the multinational companies responsible for commissioning it (Gould & Winters, 2007; Click & Weiner, 2010). Similarly, Russia turned over BP and Shell’s petroleum operations to local state owned companies using forced contract negotiations (Economist, 2007). In addressing the question of how firms can protect themselves against post-investment policy changes, the strategic management literature has identified the importance of political constraints on the policymaking process (Henisz & Delios, 2001). Prior work has emphasized the role of strong domestic institutions, such as constraints on the executive branch by other branches of government, and independence of the courts and judiciary (Henisz, 2000b; Knack & Keefer, 1995). However, domestic institutions may be biased against foreign investors. IIAs provide an alternative, international mechanism by which host governments are constrained, and firms can protect their assets against adverse policy changes. International Investment Agreements: Theory We refer to international institutions as those rules or principles that are negotiated between the home and host countries either bilaterally or multilaterally (Ramamurti, 2001). Such principles establish institutions that define the “rules of the game” (North, 1990:3), but are not confined to the boundaries of any one country. Rather, their implementation either requires coordination among the members or the establishment of a multilateral body, while resting on the foundations of national laws and regulations. Examples include inter-governmental organizations (IGOs), international standard setting 6 organizations, and cross-border associations of various types. Some observers have argued that these have transformed the international business environment such that firms and nations are no longer the only relevant levels of analysis, and that research should consider a model of global environment populated by international institutions (Ricart et al, 2004; Westney, 2011). We focus on IIAs – international agreements that establish rules governing property rights protection for FDI. Typical agreements have clauses on ‘fair and equitable’ treatment, including ‘national treatment’ and ‘most favored nation’ treatment of foreign investment in the host country. These clauses entitle foreign firms to be treated in a fair manner and on par with domestic firms, as well as firms from other similarly protected countries. IIAs may protect contractual rights, guarantee the right to transfer profits in hard currency to the home country, and prohibit or restrict the use of performance requirements (Elkins, Guzman & Simmons, 2006). They also impose restrictions on discriminatory expropriation, and policy changes that are not for a public purpose. In all cases, the foreign investor is guaranteed prompt, adequate, and just compensation in accordance with the due process of law (Hallward-Driemeier, 2003). Finally, and perhaps most importantly, IIAs provide the MNEs the right to take the host government to international arbitration (UNCTAD, 2004) as alternative to local courts. International arbitration typically occurs through the International Center for Settlement of Investment Disputes (ICSID) or the UN Commission on International Trade Law (UNCITRAL). In this way, IIAs are sometimes seen as a commitment mechanism by which host country governments signal their attitude towards protecting foreign firms’ property rights. Appendix A provides a brief historical account of IIA evolution. The most prominent of the IIAs are Bilateral Investment Treaties (BITs), signed between pairs of countries (henceforth, dyads), establishing reciprocal terms and conditions for FDI. Since the first BIT signed between Pakistan and Germany in 1959, over 2700 additional treaties have been signed involving 7 almost every country in the world (Figure 1).2 BITs are also the most common instruments used by foreign firms to file claims against host countries, with about 80 percent of known treaty-based investorstate dispute-settlement cases initiated using a BIT (UNCTAD, 2009).3 In contrast to most FDI, the petroleum sector also has a multilateral treaty – Energy Charter Treaty (ECT) – governing foreign investments. The ECT aims to create a level playing field for energy sector investments, create a stable interface between the foreign investor and the host government, and reduce the non-commercial risks of such investments to a minimum. Although it was initiated as an effort to help secure Eastern European energy supplies for Western Europe (Konoplyanik & Walde, 2006), its membership in 2010 had grown to fifty-one states including non-European countries such as Japan, Australia, and Mongolia. ECT FDI-protection provisions are similar to modern BITs including clauses for investor-state dispute settlement through international arbitration (Konoplyanik & Walde, 2006). Unlike BITs (where at least one party in each dyad is almost always a developing country), the ECT also protects investments from one industrialized country into another. This is potentially important, as firms have experienced adverse changes in regulation even in countries where domestic policy constraints are relatively high. Examples include the UK and Israeli governments changing tax rates on oil production (Manzano & Monaldi, 2008, Levinson & Chazan, 2010), or oil-exporting provinces of Canada and the US raising royalties after investment has been sunk. Hypotheses We hypothesize that IIAs, where present, allow MNEs to better manage political risk through three types of assurances, thereby influencing the firm’s assessment of asset value. 2 3 As of 2008 about 13% of all home-host dyads had a BIT protecting foreign investment (UNCTAD, 2009) Some cases are private; neither their filing nor resolution is public information. 8 First, IIAs take effort to negotiate; successfully agreeing and signing an IIA can help build trust between nations, reducing the likelihood of actions by host governments against MNEs based in signatory countries (Rangan and Sengul, 2009), even when actions may lie outside the formal scope of the IIA. Second, IIAs specifically outline the restrictions on host government’s actions towards property-rights protection. Clearly specifying these rules may itself provide foreign investors with greater bargaining leverage in negotiations with host country governments. For example, in mid-2010, UK-based Cairn Energy agreed to sell its majority stake in an oilfield in Rajasthan, India, to Vedanta Resources, an Indian company. The sale was stalled due to a dispute over oil royalties which were being paid in full by Cairn’s equity partner – state-owned ONGC (Oil and Natural Gas Corporation) (Financial Times, 2011). Although ONGC wanted the tax liability to be changed as a condition for state approval of the sale, Cairn disputed the imposition of the extra financial burden. The presence of a UK-India BIT provided Cairn with an additional negotiating tool. The Indian Ministry of External Affairs recognized that attempts to impose a settlement in the dispute between Cairn and state-run ONGC would be considered as a denial of “fair and equitable treatment” under the treaty, exposing the country to potential arbitration claims (Economic Times, 2011). Finally, IIAs allow foreign firms to seek international arbitration. If the MNE believes that a host government has unfairly expropriated its assets, the firm can initiate international arbitration proceedings at a neutral body such as ICSID without approval or support of home governments. Host countries cannot prevent such proceedings from going forward; this is also an expansion of investor rights. Unlike domestic courts, host governments have little control over the process or final decision of the international arbitration tribunal (Elkins, Guzman & Simmons, 2006). Decisions have limited avenues for appeal and cannot be amended by the domestic court system or legislation. 9 By raising the host governments’ costs of expropriation or other policy changes that redistribute returns from foreign investment, IIAs may act as an institutional mechanism by which firms can protect foreign assets. These guarantees may provide a more favorable institutional context for foreign investment – it provides greater certainty about the future treatment of assets by the state (Henisz, 2000a), reduces transaction, search, and production costs (Akerlof, 1970; Khanna & Rivkin, 2001), and allows firms to better specify property rights, monitor and enforce contracts, and appropriate higher returns from their foreign assets (Levy & Spiller, 1994; Oxley, 1999). Since assets protected by an IIA face reduced risks and a potentially higher rate of return, investors should value those assets higher than similar but unprotected ones. Thus, Hypothesis 1: Transaction value of foreign assets will be higher in the presence of an International Investment Agreement. Firm-level factors Firms differ in their ability to operate effectively under a given institutional arrangement. Scholars have described how a firm’s experience with a particular activity (see, for example, Capron & Guillen, 2009; Xia, Baol & Delios, 2009; Henisz & Delios, 2001) or ownership structure (Garcia-Canal & Guillen, 2008) moderates the influence of national level institutions. We extend this analysis to examine whether firm characteristics also moderate the effect of international institutions. Financial Resources: Strategy scholars have long debated the strategic advantages and disadvantages of large firm size (see, for example, Gale 1972; Woo & Cooper, 1981; Chen & Hambrick, 1995). A central tenant in this stream of work is that firm size is a proxy for resources available (Schuler & Rehbein, 1996) 10 which in turn influence its capabilities, economic power, and strategic choices (Dean, Brown & Bamford, 1998). In the upstream petroleum industry, reserves – underground discovered and commercially recoverable quantities of oil and gas – are a key measure of financial resources. Reserves are a firm’s inventory of future production, and hence closely related to firm valuation (Arnott, 2004; Osmunden, 2010). Bank loans are also collateralized against reserves (Muñoz, 2009). Academic studies have established significant relationships between petroleum firms’ borrowing capacity and their reserves (Chung, Ghicas & Pastena, 1993), and between reserves and firm value (Misund et al, 2005). Thus, we propose that firms with large petroleum reserves – which we categorize as firms with greater financial resources – behave differently than those with fewer resources in examining the effectiveness of IIAs. In particular, limited resources provide substantial disadvantages in effectively utilizing IIAs. An IIA is effective only when an MNE’s ability and willingness to impose reputational and financial costs on the host government in case of unfair treatment remains credible. A financially resource-constrained firm may be less willing or able to undertake the costs involved in utilizing IIAs, for two reasons. First, international arbitration is an expensive process and requires specialized intermediaries. UNCTAD, (2009) estimated claimants’ arbitration costs and legal fees at $5-12 million (equal to 5-10% of our median sample investment of $114 million); in comparison, the median equity-market value of publiclytraded firms on the Toronto Stock Exchange (the exchange with the largest number of petroleum listings) is about $19 million (as of 2nd quarter, 2012). Further, the burden of selection of arbitrators itself falls on the parties to the arbitration, and in some cases, so does the choice of arbitration rules and venue for arbitration. We argue that firms with larger reserves should be better able to absorb financial costs associated with the use of IIAs and also have better access to specialized intermediaries, and thus should be able to take better advantage of IIAs. 11 Second, enforcement of arbitral awards by winning firms may also depend on their resources. In the absence of supranational law enforcement, the jurisprudence and enforceability of awards is questionable (Yackee, 2008). In the event that a host government does not pay, firms must rely on their home governments for assistance, which can include diplomatic, political, or economic pressure, or other forms of peaceful dispute settlement. Empirical studies have shown that ability to influence the home government varies with firm size and financial resources (Macher et al, 2011; Chong & Gradstein, 2010). Greater resources allow the firm to become politically engaged (Schuler & Rehbein, 1997). Thus if IIAs are effective, the positive effect on valuation of foreign assets will be higher for firms with greater financial resources. Hypothesis 2: Firm financial resources moderate the relationship between International Investment Agreements and the transaction value of foreign assets, such that the relationship is stronger for firms with greater resources. Ownership: When a government owns a stake in a firm, the firm is less likely to need IIAs in protecting its resources abroad. Rather, state ownership gives the firm a more tolerant risk attitude (Garcia-Canal & Guillen, 2008; Megginson & Netter, 2001) and greater access to diplomatic mechanisms of dispute resolution. Further, the home government may also put additional pressure on the host to resolve the dispute by linking various issues in the state’s foreign policy to the dispute on hand. While it does not preclude the use of international arbitration, this option gives state-owned firms a potentially less expensive and more effective mechanism of dispute resolution. Non-state owned firms are less likely to utilize this alternative mechanism and will thus value the protection offered by IIAs to a greater extent. Thus, we propose that 12 Hypothesis 3: State ownership moderates the relationship between International Investment Agreements and the transaction value of foreign assets, such that the relationship is stronger for nonstate owned firms. Empirical analysis We test our hypotheses using worldwide transactions for petroleum reserves. As noted above, reserves are simply inventory to be produced in the future; they are thus more homogenous and hence comparable across firms than assets such as banks or organizational divisions. In addition, commonly used metrics account for cost variations that affect reserve value, and widely quoted petroleum prices serve to establish discounted-cash flows, allowing ready valuation of each asset. Finally, unlike most other assets, petroleum reserves are actively traded in a global market, allowing us to exploit a database of reserve-transaction announcements that include reported prices and reserve size. Because reserves are central to firm valuation and borrowing capacity (Arnott, 2004; Muñoz, 2009), considerable care is taken in the industry to determine reserve size. Specialist firms with expertise in engineering and geology are used to audit reserves. Reserves are reported accordance with accounting standards set out by inter alia, the US Securities and Exchange Commission, Canadian Securities Administrators, State Commission for Reserves of the Russian Federation, Norwegian Petroleum Directorate, and Society of Petroleum Engineers. The exact size of each reserve, however, is unobservable; instead the industry employs probabilistic definitions. Reserves are typically characterized as ‘proved’ (1P) or ‘proved + probable’ (2P). Proved reserves refer to the quantity of oil and gas in the ground that is economically extractable at current prices and costs with 90 percent probability. Probable reserves are similarly defined, but with 50 percent 13 probability. All else equal, 1P transactions are more valuable; and we control for which figure is reported in each transaction. We use publicly-announced-transaction data collected and maintained by the US firm John S. Herold Incorporated (JSH) for the period 2000-2007.4 During this time period, there were 2176 reserve deals of at least $10 million, our threshold for analysis. We consider only transactions in which all reserves were located in a single host-country, and the buyer (or buyer consortium) came from a single home-country – resulting in 1954 transactions. After dropping deals with missing values, we retain 1592 observations. Approximately three-fourths of these transaction are of assets located in the US or Canada. This distribution is in part due to national regulations (some of the largest oil-producing countries like Saudi Arabia, Kuwait, Iraq, Iran, and Mexico are not represented in the data because reserve ownership is a state monopoly), and in part due to geology. Outside the US and Canada, much of the worldwide oil reserves are offshore, where substantial scale economies result in large transaction sizes and fewer transactions. With the exception of parts of the Gulf of Mexico, Alaska, California, and Newfoundland, offshore drilling is prohibited in North America; and most transactions are for onshore reserves, which can be economic on a smaller scale.5 In order to avoid our results being dominated by North American transactions, we exclude them from our statistical analysis. Our final sample consists of 409 observations. Table 1 shows the distribution of transactions by host country (country wherein reserves are located) in the sample. We follow the asset pricing model developed by Click & Weiner (2010), and model the value of a petroleum reserve as (1) 4 5 We are grateful to JSH (now a part of IHS Inc.) for permission to use the data. Median deal size in North America is roughly $77 million, vs. $114 million outside North America. 14 Where refers to the reserve value, R is the size of the reserve, and and are respectively expected petroleum prices and costs over the life of the reserve. Costs are often estimated as proportional to prices, both because the main component of cost is output taxes and royalties, and because production costs tend to rise with prices.6 Thus, our specification for conventional reserves transforms to (2) Rewriting in logarithmic form, and introducing international agreements, political risk, and other control variables, we arrive at the equation that we estimate: (3) Dependent variable: Our dependent variable is the value of petroleum reserves in the ground on a per barrel basis for each transaction. Following industry practice, we aggregate reserves of crude oil and natural gas based on thermal energy equivalence – the energy in 1 barrel of oil is on average equal to the energy in 6000 cubic feet of gas (Berry, Hasan & O’Bryan, 1998). Thus our dependent variable is measured in equivalent barrels of oil. Using the value per barrel of oil at the transaction level, rather than aggregate FDI flows as the dependent variable allows us to mitigate potential endogeneity issues in estimation. Some authors have argued that increased FDI flows in a host country may cause an IIA to be signed with the home country as investors seek additional protection for their investment (Swenson, 2009; Aisbett, 2009; Kerner, 6 Petroleum production is heavily taxed worldwide, through a variety of fiscal structures. While complex and nonlinear in output, they are effectively linear in prices (Van Benthem and Stroebel 2010), motivating (2). 15 2009). The possibility that IIAs are an effect, rather than a cause of FDI decisions, is unlikely to arise here, as it would require that country level decisions regarding IIA partners are driven by transaction values. The two-stage Heckman procedure described in the robustness tests supports this view. Independent variables: Our independent variable of primary interest is the presence of an International Investment Agreement (IIA). For every transaction, we create a dummy, IIA, coded 1 if the transaction is protected by an international investment agreement, and 0 otherwise. Roughly 31 percent of our sample transactions are covered by IIAs. We code the variable IIA to be 1 if the home and host countries of a transaction either have a BIT (87%) or are signatories to the ECT (13%). Our second variable of interest is a firm’s financial resources. As discussed above, we proxy for financial resources using the size of a firm’s worldwide petroleum reserves. We use JSH’s classification of a firm’s reserves as large, medium, or small, and create a dummy variable, Financial Resources, that is equal to 1 for firms with large reserves and zero otherwise. The third variable in our analysis captures whether a firm undertaking FDI is state-owned. The dummy variable Foreign State Ownership is coded 1 for foreign government ownership. Control variables: We also include a number of control variables, broadly classified under three categories – host country, transaction, and reserve. Host country controls: We first control for the host country’s political risk. Political risk has been shown to impact asset values (Click & Weiner, 2010); the greater the political risk in the host country, the lower is the reserve value. Thus, we control for the extent of host country political risk using the political 16 constraints (Polcon) measure (Henisz, 2000b).7 We also include a set of host country dummies to capture other factors that vary by country and may impact the asset value (e.g: royalty and tax rates, other cost factors, geographic distance, infrastructure quality). Transaction level controls: We introduce a set of four controls at the transaction level. We differentiate between asset purchases by domestic and foreign investors. Domestic investors may have access to superior local information or different risk perceptions when compared to their foreign rivals which may influence their assessment of asset value. To control for this, we include an indicator variable, coded 1 for all transactions in which the home country of the buyer is different from the host country where the reserves are located, and 0 otherwise. We control for whether the transaction involved a Merger or Acquisition (M&A), or a pure asset sale. M&A entails purchase of an entire firm with all its assets and liabilities, or a fraction of the target firm’s equity. Asset sales refer to specific reserve assets, and entail no claim on the seller’s equity8. Asset sales are typically smaller in size and value than mergers and acquisitions; the sign of their effect on value per barrel of oil is unclear. Since the value of the petroleum in the ground should depend on its expected market price once extracted, we follow Click & Weiner (2010) and include the expected future price of petroleum, measured by futures strip prices (the average of futures prices of the nearest 36 months ahead) for crude oil and natural gas on the New York Mercantile Exchange (NYMEX). We consider the source of the transaction announcement (buyer or seller). Although reserves are typically assessed by outside consultants, buyers may be systematically more optimistic in interpreting reserve data and advice than sellers, and thus report larger reserves (Click & Weiner 2010). Thus, we 7 8 Our results are robust to using the alternate International Country Risk Guide (ICRG) measure of risk Asset sales account for approximately 69% of all reserve transactions in our data 17 include a dummy variable that takes the value 1 for those transactions in which data are reported by the buyer; we expect the coefficient to be negative. Oil and reserve level controls: We include a series of controls for the quality of oil and the type of reserve. These variables are expected to capture the physical characteristics of the reserve. Since some transactions report proved (1P), while others report proved + probable (2P) reserve volumes, we include an indicator for reserve-reporting type (Proved + Probable dummy). Reserves estimated with lower probability are less valuable; and we expect this dummy variable to have a negative coefficient. Next, we include two variables to control for the quality of oil. First, we include a dummy variable for heavy crude (Heavy Oil) because it fetches less in world markets than other types of oil; thus we expect the coefficient of this dummy to be negative. Second, we construct a variable that represents the percentage of natural gas in each reserve9. If oil and gas are identically priced based on their energy equivalence, we would expect the coefficient of this term to be equal to 0. Finally, we control for differences in extraction costs and technology employed to recover and process the petroleum using a series of dummy variables. Excluding the onshore conventional process, we include dummy variables for each of the following categories: coalbed methane, liquefied natural gas (LNG), offshore shallow water, offshore deep water, frontier, and enhanced recovery production, and diversified. Except for the last category, each of the other categories is costlier than conventional extraction. Diversified refers to reserves with diverse characteristics; its effect on reserve value is unclear. 9 Although our dependent variable is measured in equivalent barrels of oil, some authors have argued that the ratio of the market values of oil and gas need not be equal to their energy ratios (Adelman & Watkins, 1995). 18 In addition to all the above controls, we finally include year dummies to account for any time specific effects beyond oil price changes, as discussed above. Results We present the summary statistics for our sample and the correlations among the main variables in Table 2. The mean value of petroleum in the ground (i.e., asset value) is exp(1.49) = $4.47/barrel of oil equivalent and the mean market value is exp(3.77) = $43.69/barrel of oil equivalent. Our main results using OLS models with robust standard errors are presented in Table 3. Model 1 of Table3 includes all the control variables discussed above. Model 2 introduces the main IIA variable while Models 3-5 show the interaction effects of IIA with Firm Resources and Foreign State Ownership. Across the models, we observe that the host country political risk variables are not significant. We do not interpret this as the lack of an effect of political risk; rather we contend that the effect of political risk may be absorbed in the host country and year dummies. Turning to the transaction level controls, we find that cross-border transactions are not valued higher than domestic ones while M&A transactions are typically associated with higher value compared to pure asset sales. We also observe that as the futures strip price of petroleum increases, the value of the petroleum reserve increases. Consistent with our expectation, we find that the coefficient of the Proved + Probable dummy is negative and significant. This suggests that investors value reserves estimated with a lower probability to have a lower value. In addition, we find that the coefficient on the dummy for information being provided by the buyer to be negative and significant, suggesting a discounting of such information. We next examine the control variables capturing the physical properties of the asset. Looking at the variables capturing the quality of petroleum reserves – Heavy Oil and % gas of proved reserves – we find 19 that the coefficient of the first term is not significant, while that of the second is negative and significant. In an all-gas transaction, value per barrel of oil equivalent is 0.6% lower than an otherwise similar all-oil transaction. Finally, we examine the variation in extraction costs as compared to conventional reserves, and find that although some of the dummies are not significant, those that are have the expected sign. In Model 2, we introduce our main independent variable of interest – the IIA dummy. We find the coefficient of this dummy to be positive and significant. We interpret this coefficient to suggest that the presence of an IIA increases investors’ valuation of a foreign petroleum asset by approximately 27%. Thus, we find support for first hypothesis. The next two models (Models 3-4) include the two interaction terms of IIA with Financial Resources and Foreign State Ownership respectively. In interpreting these interaction effects, we follow Brambor, Clark & Golder (2006) who argue that we cannot infer whether a variable has a meaningful conditional effect on the dependent variable simply by looking at the magnitude and significance of the coefficient on the interaction term alone. In order to examine conditional hypotheses (such as the interaction effects presented here), we need to perform conditional tests that take into account the coefficients of the main and interaction terms together, and calculate the relevant standard errors (in addition to the ones reported in the traditional regression table). In other words, the effect of IIA on the dependent variable depends on the value of the conditioning variables (firm characteristics). In order to assess the interaction terms in our models, we calculate the marginal effects of IIA under (1) large and small conditions of the firm’s financial resources, and (2) state-owned and non-state owned conditions of the firm’s ownership. These effects are presented, along with their corresponding standard errors, in Table 4. We find that firms with large and small financial resources differ significantly – for firms with large financial resources, the presence of an IIA increases their willingness to pay for 20 foreign petroleum assets by 43%. For firms with small financial resources however, there is a small but insignificant negative effect. In Figure 2a, we plot this interaction effect. We interpret this finding to suggest that financial resources interact with international institutions, and thus provide support for hypothesis 2. Similarly, we find that firms with and without state ownership differ significantly. For firms without state ownership, the presence of an IIA significantly increases mean value of foreign petroleum assets by 30%. For firms with foreign state ownership, this effect is insignificant. In Figure 2b, we plot this interaction effect. We interpret this finding to provide support for hypothesis 3. This pattern of results is also observed in the full model where we include both interaction terms simultaneously. Robustness checks We undertake a series of robustness checks to assess both competing explanations for our results, and the validity of our empirical approach. We address theoretical issues first; statistical considerations, including potential endogeneity and selection bias, follow. Theoretical issues: Strategy researchers have argued that the extent of vertical integration could have an important effect on a firm’s performance (see, for example, Rothaermel, Hitt & Jobe, 2006), and hence its financial resources. In the petroleum industry firms with the largest resources tend to be vertically integrated. Thus, our results on firms’ financial resources may instead be due to vertical integration .We consider this possibility by examining the effect of vertical integration both theoretically and empirically. Although correlated with financial resources, the theoretical relationship between vertical integration and political risk (and hence the value of IIA protection) depends on the role played by integration in a firm’s strategy. Transaction-cost economics (which views integration as moving the supply chain inside 21 the firm to substitute for poorly functioning intermediate markets) predicts that political risk will impact horizontal FDI and vertical FDI differently. Aizenman and Marion (2004) show that when FDI is vertical, host countries have more bargaining power in renegotiating post-entry terms with MNEs, because of potential costly disruption to the supply chain. Under horizontal FDI (where the MNE undertakes similar activities across countries), in contrast, MNEs have more leverage from their ability to shift production to other countries. Thus, vertical FDI is more vulnerable to political hazards than horizontal FDI, and should value IIAs more. Hence, the transaction-cost view predicts that vertical integration moderates the relationship between IIAs and asset value, such that the relationship is stronger for vertical FDI. An alternative view is that integration can add value by leveraging firms’ intangible assets across vertical stages, rather than internalizing the supply chain. Ramondo et al’s (2012) finding that vertical integration in US MNEs is not associated with higher intra-firm flow of goods is consistent with this view. Moreover, active trading by intermediaries is prevalent in crude oil markets (but not in natural gas), on which integrated firms often rely (Smith 2009; Weiner 2006). In this view, the relationship between IIAs and asset value would not differ between horizontal and vertical FDI. In Table 5, we report the regression results that include the dummy variable Integrated (=1 for vertically integrated firms, 0 otherwise). Model 1 weakly supports the view that the effect of vertical integration is similar to that of financial resources – i.e. vertically integrated firms value IIAs but their non-integrated counterparts do not. However, adding the vertical integration terms to our baseline model does not alter the effects of financial resources reported earlier, while the effect of vertical integration is no longer significant (Model 2). Empirical issues: 22 Our empirical specifications above assume take IIAs as exogenous. Yet a literature in political economy explains likelihood of signing an IIA by characteristics of the countries involved (Elkins, Guzman & Simmons, 2006; Jandhyala, Henisz & Mansfield, 2011). IIAs as a policy response to underlying conditions raise the possibility of endogeneity bias, e.g., if these conditions include lobbying by firms engaging in FDI that wish to raise the value of their investments. Indeed, endogeneity has been shown to bias estimate results of relationships between FDI flows and BITs, and may explain some of the mixed results in the literature (Aisbett, 2009; Kerner, 2009). We address endogeneity through a Heckman (1979) two-stage procedure. The first stage is a probit model to estimate the likelihood of two countries’ signing an IIA. Table 6 reports results from our firststage-model, based on Jandhyala, Henisz & Mansfield (2011). The model’s explanatory variables are proxies for vertical FDI potential (dyad per capita income difference), horizontal FDI potential (size of dyad economies), diffusion of IIAs (total number of BITs and ECT members), geographic distance between dyad countries, and dyad political risk (average dyad POLCON score)10. Table 7 reports the second stage regression of transaction value on the variables in Table 3, augmented by the Inverse Mills Ratio (IMR) as an indicator of endogeneity bias. The IMR coefficient is insignificant, however, indicating the absence of such bias. Further, the coefficients of the IIA variable and its interaction with firm size and foreign state ownership remain similar to those reported in the main results. A second concern is that non-IIA transactions are under-sampled. If IIAs add value by protecting FDI, then selection bias may occur if observations not protected by IIAs (“non-IIA transactions”) fall just below our threshold for sample inclusion. We address this potential selection bias by lowering the threshold for non-IIA transactions. To be conservative (and hence err in the opposite direction of 10 The results reported in this table use all potential home-host dyads worldwide. We also estimated this model on the countries in our sample, with similar results. 23 oversampling non-IIA transactions), we chose $8 million as the threshold value for non-IIA transactions (compared to $10 million for IIA-transactions)11. Lowering the threshold adds 7 non-IIA transactions to the sample; but does not affect our empirical results above (Model 1, Table 8). Next, we explore the different effects of IIAs for firms with greater and lesser financial resources by undertaking a sub-sample analysis. Models 2 and 3 in Table 8 include only firms with large and small financial resources respectively. In Model 2 (large financial resources sub-sample), we observe that the coefficient of IIA is positive and significant. However, in Model 3 (small financial resources sub-sample), the coefficient of IIA is not significant. We explore a similar sub-sample analysis with foreign state ownership in Models 4-5 in Table 8. In Model 4 (firms with foreign state ownership), the coefficient of IIA is not significant, while it is positive and significant in Model 5 (firms without foreign state ownership). A fourth concern may be that our results are confounded by including both BITs and ECT in the coding of IIAs. While a BIT and the ECT provide similar protection for foreign investors, they also differ in some ways. As the name suggests, BITs are bilateral in nature, signed between one home and host country. They are also specifically designed to protect foreign investment. However, the ECT is a multilateral agreement with a much broader scope, governing both trade and investment in the energy sector. In our sample, the vast majority of transactions are protected by a BIT (87%). Thus, we restrict the next model to only protection from BITs and include its interaction with Financial Resources and Foreign State Ownership. In Model 6, we observe a pattern of results similar to that reported using the IIA dummy although the results are significant only at the 10% level. Another concern might be that our results are reflecting some differences between domestic and crossborder transactions as we compare IIA protected cross-border transactions against both non-IIA 11 This effectively allows for IIAs to enhance asset value by up to 25 percent ($10 million/$8 million = 1.25) 24 protected cross-border as well as domestic transactions in our primary specifications. Since IIAs may provide little or no protection for domestic transactions,12 we may be confounding the comparison set. Thus, we restrict our sample to only cross-border transactions (those in which the buyer’s home country is different from the country in which reserves are located). We find that the results are substantively similar to those reported above, although the Foreign State Ownership interaction is no longer significant. Finally, we consider that some of the countries in our sample have very few transactions. With one or two transactions per country, our results may be driven by cross-national differences rather than the difference in IIA protection. Thus, in Model 5, we restrict our sample to those countries in which five or more transactions are reported. This reduces the number of host countries in our sample from 45 to 18. However, the results are consistent with those reported for the full sample. The presence of an IIA increases willingness to pay for foreign assets by 45% for firms with large financial resources while this effect is not significant for those with small resources. Similarly, IIAs increase the willingness to pay by non-foreign sate owned firms by 33% while the effect is not significant for foreign state owned firms. Taken together, our results support the argument that IIAs provide investor protection, but this effect is moderated by a firm’s financial resources and foreign state ownership; IIA protection enhances value only for firms with large financial resources, and those not owned by a foreign state. Discussion Political-risk considerations in foreign investment decisions have prompted many strategy scholars to examine host-government policies and domestic institutional arrangements that may reduce the risks 12 BITs provide no protection for domestic investment. The ECT is less clear; e.g., foreign shareholders brought a claim under ECT against the Russian government after it expropriated domestic company Yukos. 25 for foreign investors. For example, prior literature has examined the strategic actions of developing countries (Murtha & Lenway, 1994), legal policies (La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, Shleifer & Vishny, 1998), political institutional arrangements (Henisz, 2000a), and electoral cycles (Vaaler, 2008) on the likelihood of increased foreign investment. However, there has been a scarcity of work examining the role of international institutional arrangements as safeguards for investors. Yet international institutions for trade and investment are rapidly proliferating; the World Trade Organization, Regional Trade Agreements, and Bilateral Investment Treaties are all examples of international institutions that have significantly altered the rules of international commercial transactions. As noted by Westney (2011: 380), we are witnessing “a profound transformation of regulatory patterns, involving the decline of the state-centered regulation that MNCs have become so adept at managing, in favor of an array of new regulatory modes” shaped by states, international organizations, and civil society. Thus, in studying MNE strategy, we need to extend our analysis beyond country-specific institutions (Ramamurti, 2001; Chan, Isobe & Makino, 2008). Our analysis takes a step down this path. This study offers an empirical test of the effectiveness of IIAs in protecting international investment. We demonstrate that MNEs value assets protected by IIAs higher than similar unprotected assets; an effect that is moderated by a firm’s financial resources and ownership. As discussed above, IIAs alter risk perception by providing extensive rights and protection for MNEs, while restricting host governments’ discriminatory policy changes that expropriate the firm’s assets. Thus, they provide an alternate, international mechanism by which host country political risk may be lowered. Our results also have implications for MNE managers evaluating their institutional environments. Managers evaluating risk considerations in a potential host country need to take into account their firm’s own characteristics in evaluating the benefits, if any, of institutional arrangements. Our empirical 26 analysis focuses on the petroleum sector. While studies of a single sector offer researchers a powerful arena for testing propositions, they also raise the issue of generalizability of findings. Investments in natural resources or regulated industries with large, upfront capital costs and high political salience are especially prone to political risks. Thus, managers in these industries may be particularly sensitive to national and international institutional arrangements. Exploring the role of IIAs across multiple industries remains open for future research. In addition, we need to explore how alternate mechanisms of property rights protection interact with international institutional arrangements. International arbitration is an expensive process, and usually a last resort for MNEs, as it severely restricts their ability to continue operating in the host country. Since exploration and production of natural resources is a long term commitment, MNEs, especially small firms, may seek alternate strategic mechanisms such as equity participation by the host government or the involvement of other stakeholders for managing these risks (Maniruzzaman, 2009-10). For example, a joint venture by a foreign investing firm has been shown to be a strategic tool in countries where public expropriation hazards are high (Delios & Henisz, 2000). These mechanisms may substitute for IIAs. Data limitations prevent us from exploring this, however, and it remains an open question. While our analysis highlights the mechanisms by which IIAs can support foreign investors’ property rights, some concerns have also been raised about the effectiveness of the protective dispute resolution system. Although the number of investment-treaty disputes have risen in the last decade to over 300 (UNCTAD, 2009), the jurisprudence and enforceability of resulting awards is still in its infancy (Yackee, 2008). Managers may be particularly concerned that host governments may be unwilling or unable to honor the arbitral decisions that go against them (Rose-Ackerman, 2009). Thus, uncertainty with regards to implementation of IIAs and post-award behavior may reduce their value to investors. In future work, 27 we would like to explore how a country’s history and reputation in international arbitration influences investors’ expectations of property rights protection. Finally, we acknowledge that our explanations rely, in part, on inference. We attribute the positive and significant effects of IIAs we find in the econometric analysis to increased property rights protection for foreign investors without directly observing property rights mechanisms. Thus, a more granular approach – examining specific motivations of asset valuation coupled with qualitative analysis – would greatly enhance our understanding of the micro-processes and mechanisms that influence the strategic choices of foreign investors. 28 Appendix A – Historical context of International Investment Agreements Prior to World War II, investors’ recourse to nationalization of assets abroad was restricted to vague customary international law and extra-legal enforcement mechanisms, including military force and diplomacy. Following the war, many newly independent countries and the socialist-bloc countries chose to close their economies to foreign investment and began to expropriate existing investment (Vandevelde, 2009). Developing countries worked within the United Nations (UN) General Assembly to pass the 1962 resolution declaring the right of nations to permanent sovereignty over their natural wealth, which would be exercised for the well-being of the people of the state concerned, and the right to expropriate foreign investment with limited or inadequate compensation (Newcombe & Paradell, 2009). In response to the threat of uncompensated expropriation, developed countries began to establish IIAs that guaranteed the rights of investors. The US, for example, built investment protection clauses into its traditional Friendship, Commerce and Navigation treaties (Newcombe & Paradell, 2009). Led by the Germans, the European countries began to sign BITs from the 1960s to promote and protect foreign direct investment (Vandevelde, 2009). These treaties combined similar (and sometimes identical standards) on the admission and establishment conditions for investment, and the protection of foreign investment (Newcombe & Paradell, 2009). In addition, investors are given assurances regarding their property rights through clauses that provide the right to take the host government to international arbitration if its actions are deemed to substantially expropriate the business of the firm (UNCTAD, 2004) without the requirement to use that country’s domestic courts. The rise of economic liberalism and the Washington Consensus (Williamson, 1990) coupled with scarce private capital due to the debt crisis of the 1980s catalyzed a dramatic shift in the attitude of developing countries towards foreign investors. Many countries began to actively seek foreign investment for economic development and stabilization (Kobrin, 2005). In doing so, IIAs provided a commitment mechanism by which developing country governments could signal their changing attitudes towards property rights of foreign investors. As a result, the number of IIAs exploded in the 1990s (Jandhyala, Henisz & Mansfield, 2011). By the end of 2009, there were over 3000 agreements governing international investment negotiated either bilaterally or multilaterally (UNCTAD, 2010). 29 References Adelman MA, Watkins GC. 1995. Reserve asset values and the Hotelling Valuation Principle: Further Evidence. Southern Economic Journal 61(3): 664-673 Aizenman J, Marion N. 2004. The merits of horizontal versus vertical FDI in the presence of uncertainty. Journal of International Economics 62(1): 125-148 Aisbett E. 2009. Bilateral Investment Treaties and Foreign Direct Investment: Correlation versus Causation. In KP Sauvant, LE Sachs (Eds.), The Effects of Treaties on Foreign Direct Investment. Bilateral Investment Treaties, Double Taxation Treaties, and Investment Flows. Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK Akerlof GA. 1970. The Market for "Lemons": Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 84(3): 488-500 Arnott, R. 2004. Oil and Gas Reserves: Communication with the Financial Sector. Chatham House Briefing Paper SDP BP 04/02, October. www.chathamhouse.org/sites/default/files/public/General/arnott_sdp_bp_0402.pdf Berry KT, Hasan T, O'Bryan D. 1998. Relative information content of proven reserves: The BOEs-revenue versus BOEs-energy. Journal of Energy Finance & Development 3(1): 1-11 Boddewyn JJ. 1988. Political Aspects of MNE Theory. Journal of International Business Studies 19(3): 341363 Brambor T, Clark WR, Golder M. 2006. Understanding interaction models: Improving empirical analyses. Political Analysis 14(1): 63-82 Buthe T, Milner H. 2009. Bilateral Investment Treaties and Foreign Direct Investment: A Political Analysis. In KP Sauvant, LE Sachs (Eds.), The Effects of Treaties on Foreign Direct Investment. Bilateral Investment Treaties, Double Taxation Treaties, and Investment Flows. Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK Capron L, Guillén M. 2009. National corporate governance institutions and post-acquisition target reorganization. Strategic Management Journal 30(8): 803-833 Chan CM, Isobe T, Makino S. 2008. Which country matters? Institutional development and foreign affiliate performance. Strategic Management Journal 29(11): 1179-1205 Chen M-J, Hambrick DC. 1995. Speed, Stealth, and Selective Attack: How Small Firms Differ from Large Firms in Competitive Behavior. The Academy of Management Journal 38(2): 453-482 Chong A, Gradstein M. 2010. Firm-Level Determinants of Political Influence. Economics & Politics 22(3): 233-256 Chung K-H, Ghicas D, Pastena V. 1993. Lenders' Use of Accounting Information in the Oil and Gas Industry. The Accounting Review 68(4): 885-895 Click RW, Weiner RJ. 2010. Resource Nationalism Meets the Market: Political Risk and the Value of Petroleum Assets. Journal of International Business Studies 41: 783-803 Cuervo-Cazurra A. 2008. The Effectiveness of Laws against Bribery Abroad. Journal of International Business Studies 39(4): 634-651 Dean TJ, Brown RL, Bamford CE. 1998. Differences in Large and Small Firm Responses to Environmental Context: Strategic Implications from a Comparative Analysis of Business Formations. Strategic Management Journal 19(8): 709-728 Delios A, Henisz WJ. 2000. Japanese Firms' Investment Strategies in Emerging Economies. The Academy of Management Journal 43(3): 305-323 Economic Times. 26 April 2011. Forcing Royalty on Cairn May Hit UK Ties Economist. 2007. Gazprom strikes again?, 24 May 2007: Elkins Z, Guzman AT, Simmons BA. 2006. Competing for Capital: The Diffusion of Bilateral Investment Treaties, 1960-2000. International Organization 60(4): 811-846 FinancialTimes. 3 May 2011. Cairn India: Vedanta Should Take the Hint. Financial Times 30 Gale BT. 1972. Market Share and Rate of Return. The Review of Economics and Statistics 54(4): 412-423 García-Canal E, Guillén MF. 2008. Risk and the strategy of foreign location choice in regulated industries. Strategic Management Journal 29(10): 1097-1115 Gould JA, Winters MS. 2007. An Obsolescing Bargain in Chad: Shifts in Leverage between the Government and the World Bank. Business and Politics 9(2): 1-34 Hallward-Driemeier M. 2003. Do bilateral investment treaties attract foreign direct investment? Only a bit… and they could bite. World Bank: Washington, DC Hallward-Driemeier M. 2009. Do Bilateral Investment Treaties Attract FDI? Only a Bit... and they could bite. In KP Sauvant, LE Sachs (Eds.), The Effects of Treaties on Foreign Direct Investment. Bilateral Investment Treaties, Double Taxation Treaties, and Investment Flows. Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK Healy PM, Kuppuswamy V, Serafeim G. 2011. What Impedes Oil and Gas Companies Transparency? SSRN eLibrary Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1961404 Heckman JJ. 1979. Sample Selection Bias as a Specification Error. Econometrica 47: 153-161 Henisz WJ. 2000a. The Institutional Environment for Multinational Investment. Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization 16(2): 334-364 Henisz WJ. 2000b. The institutional environment for economic growth. Economics and Politics 12(1): 131 Henisz WJ, Delios A. 2001. Uncertainty, Imitation, and Plant Location: Japanese Multinational Corporations, 1990-1996. Administrative Science Quarterly 46(3): 443-475 Henisz WJ, Zelner BA. 2010. The Hidden Risks in Emerging Markets. Harvard Business Review 88(4): 8895 Henisz WJ, Zelner BA, Guillen MF. 2005. The Worldwide Diffusion of Market-Oriented Infrastructure Reform, 1977-1999. American Sociological Review 70(6): 871-897 Holburn GLF, Zelner BA. 2010. Political capabilities, policy risk, and international investment strategy: evidence from the global electric power generation industry. Strategic Management Journal 31(12) Hoskisson RE, Eden L, Lau CM, Wright M. 2000. Strategy in Emerging Economies. The Academy of Management Journal 43(3): 249-267 Jandhyala S, Henisz WJ, Mansfield ED. 2011. Three Waves of BITs: The Global Diffusion of Foreign Investment Policy. Journal of Conflict Resolution 55(6): 1047-1073 Jeong Y, Weiner RJ. 2012. Who Bribes? Evidence from the United Nations Oil-for-Food Program. Strategic Management Journal Forthcoming Kerner A. 2009. Why Should I Believe You? The Costs and Consequences of Bilateral Investment Treaties. International Studies Quarterly 53(1): 73-102 Khanna T, Rivkin JW. 2001. Estimating the Performance Effects of Business Groups in Emerging Markets. Strategic Management Journal 22(1): 45-74 Knack S, Keefer P. 1995. Institutions and Economic Performance: Cross-Country Tests Using Alternative Institutional Measures. Economics and Politics 7(3): 207-227 Kobrin SJ. 1976. The Environmental Determinants of Foreign Direct Manufacturing Investment: An Ex Post Empirical Analysis. Journal of International Business Studies 7(2): 29-42 Kobrin SJ. 1980. Foreign enterprise and forced divestment in LDCs. International Organization 34(1): 6588 Kobrin SJ. 1987. Testing the Bargaining Hypothesis in the Manufacturing Sector in Developing Countries. International Organization 41(4): 609-638 Kobrin SJ. 2005. The determinants of liberalization of FDI policy in developing countries: A crosssectional analysis, 1992–2001. Transnational Corporations 14(1): 67-104 Konoplyanik A, Walde T. 2006. Energy Charter Treaty and its role in international energy. Journal of Energy and Natural Resources Law 24(4): 523-558 31 La Porta R, Lopez-de-Silanes F, Shleifer A, Vishny RW. 1998. Law and Finance. The Journal of Political Economy 106(6): 1113-1155 Levinson C, Chazan G. 2010. Big gas find sparks a frenzy in Israel. Wall Street Journal, Dec. 30. Levy B, Spiller PT. 1994. The Institutional Foundations of Regulatory Commitment: A Comparative Analysis of Telecommunications Regulation. Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization 10(2): 201-246 Loree DW, Guisinger SE. 1995. Policy and Non-Policy Determinants of U.S. Equity Foreign Direct Investment. Journal of International Business Studies 26(2): 281-299 Macher JT, Mayo JW, Schiffer M. 2011. The Influence of Firms on Government. The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy 11(1): 1935-1682 Maniruzzaman AFM. 2009-10. The Issue of Resource Nationalism: Risk Engineering and Dispute Management in the Oil and Gas Industry. Texas Journal of Oil, Gas, and Energy Law 79: 79-108 Manzano O, Monaldi F. 2008. The Political Economy of Oil Production in Latin America. Economia 9(1): 59-103 Megginson WL, Netter JM. 2001. From state to market: A survey of empirical studies on privatization. Journal of Economic Literature 39(2): 321-389 Meyer KE, Estrin S, Bhaumik SK, Peng MW. 2009. Institutions, resources, and entry strategies in emerging economies. Strategic Management Journal 30(1): 61-80 Muñoz JS. 2009. Financing of Oil and Gas Transactions. Texas Journal of Oil, Gas, and Energy Law 4(2): 225-267 Murtha TP, Lenway SA. 1994. Country Capabilities and the Strategic State: How National Political Institutions Affect Multinational Corporations' Strategies. Strategic Management Journal 15: 113-129 Neumayer E, Spess L. 2005. Do bilateral investment treaties increase foreign direct investment to developing countries? World development 33(10): 1567-1585 Newcombe AP, Paradell L. 2009. Law and Practice of Investment Treaties: Standards of Treatment. Kluwer Law International: The Netherlands North DC. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance. Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK Osmundsen, P. 2010. Chasing Reserves: Incentives and Ownership. In Bjørndal et al, ed., Energy, Natural Resources and Environmental Economics (Energy Systems). Berlin: Springer-Verlag. Oxley JE. 1999. Institutional Environment and the Mechanisms of Governance: The Impact of Intellectual Property Protection on the Structure of Inter-Firm Alliances. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 38(3): 283-309 Ramamurti R. 2001. The Obsolescing 'Bargaining Model'? MNC-Host Developing Country Relations Revisited. Journal of International Business Studies 32(1): 23-39 Ramondo N, Rappoport V,Kim Ruhl K. 2012. Horizontal vs. Vertical FDI: Revisiting Evidence from U.S. Multinationals. Working paper, March. Rangan S, Sengul M. 2009. The Influence of Macro Structure on the Foreign Market Performance of Transnational Firms: The Value of IGO Connections, Export Dependence, and Immigration Links. Administrative Science Quarterly 54(2): 229-267 Ricart JE, Enright MJ, Ghemawat P, Hart SL, Khanna T. 2004. New Frontiers in International Strategy. Journal of International Business Studies 35(3): 175-200 Ring PS, Lenway SA, Govekar M. 1990. Management of the Political Imperative in International Business. Strategic Management Journal 11(2): 141-151 Rose-Ackerman S. 2009. The Global BITs Regime and the Domestic Environment for Investment. In KP Sauvant, LE Sachs (Eds.), The Effects of Treaties on Foreign Direct Investment. Bilateral Investment Treaties, Double Taxation Treaties, and Investment Flows. Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK 32 Rothaermel FT, Hitt MA, Jobe LA. 2006. Balancing vertical integration and strategic outsourcing: effects on product portfolio, product success, and firm performance. Strategic Management Journal 27(11): 1033-1056 Salacuse JW, Sullivan NP. 2005. Do BITs Really Work?: An Evaluation of Bilateral Investment Treaties and Their Grand Bargain. Harvard International Law Journal 46(1): 67-130 Schuler DA, Rehbein K. 1997. The filtering role of the firm in corporate political involvement. Business and Society 36(2): 116-139 Smith, JL. 2009. World Oil: Market or Mayhem? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 23(3): 145–64. Swenson D. 2009. Why do Developing Countries sign BITs? In KP Sauvant, LE Sachs (Eds.), The Effects of Treaties on Foreign Direct Investment. Bilateral Investment Treaties, Double Taxation Treaties, and Investment Flows. Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK Tallman SB. 1988. Home Country Political Risk and Foreign Direct Investment in the United States. Journal of International Business Studies 19(2): 219-234 Tallman SB. 1991. Strategic management models and resource-based strategies among mnes in a host market. Strategic Management Journal 12(S1): 69-82 UNCTAD. 2004. International Investment Agreements: Key Issues. United Nations: New York and Geneva UNCTAD. 2009. Latest Developments in Investor-State Dispute Settlement, International Investment Agreements Monitor, Vol. 1. United Nations: New York and Geneva UNCTAD. 2010. Investing in a Low-Carbon Economy. United Nations: New York and Geneva Vaaler PM. 2008. How do MNCs vote in developing country elections? The Academy of Management Journal 51(1): 21-43 Van Benthem A, Stroebel J. 2010. Resource Extraction Contracts Under Threat of Expropriation: Theory and Evidence. USAEE Working Paper No. 10-042 Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1554102 Vandevelde K. 2009. A Brief History of International Investment Agreements. In KP Sauvant, LE Sachs (Eds.), The Effect of Treaties on Foreign Direct Investment: Bilateral Investment Treaties, Double Taxation Treaties, and Investment Flows. Oxford University Press Vernon R. 1971. Sovereignty at Bay. Basic Books: New York Weiner RJ. 2005. Speculation in International Crises: Report from the Gulf. Journal of International Business Studies 36(5): 576-587 Weiner RJ. 2006. "Do Crises Tear the Fabric of Oil Trade?" Resources for the Future Disc. Paper 06-16. Westney DE. 2011. Global strategy and global business environment: changing models of the global business environment. Global Strategy Journal 1(3-4): 377-381 Williamson J. 1990. What Washington Means by Policy Reform. In J Williamson (Ed.), Latin America Adjustment: How Much Has Happened? Institute for International Economics: Washington, DC Wint AG. 2005. Has the Obsolescing Bargain Obsolesced? Negotiating with Foreign Investors. In R Grosse (Ed.), International Business and Government Relations in the 21st Century: 315-338. Cambridge University Press: Cambridge Woo CY, Cooper AC. 1982. The surprising case for low market share. Harvard Business Review 60(6): 106 Xia J, Boal K, Delios A. 2009. When experience meets national institutional environmental change: foreign entry attempts of U.S. firms in the Central and Eastern European region. Strategic Management Journal 30(12): 1286-1309 Yackee J. 2009. Do BITs Really Work? Revisiting the Empirical Link between Investment Treaties and Foreign Direct Investment. In KP Sauvant, LE Sachs (Eds.), The Effects of Treaties on Foreign Direct Investment. Bilateral Investment Treaties, Double Taxation Treaties, and Investment Flows. Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK Yackee JW. 2008. Do We Really Need BITs - Toward a Return to Contract in International Investment Law. Asian Journal of WTO and International Health Law and Policy 3(12): 121-146 33 0 1000 2000 3000 Figure 1: Worldwide cumulative number of BITs signed, 1959-2008 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 year Source: UNCTAD 34 Table 1: Countries of petroleum reserves transactions in the sample Total number of transactions = 409 Asset Location Algeria Angola Argentina Australia Azerbaijan Bangladesh Brazil Cameroon China Colombia Congo Croatia Denmark Ecuador Egypt France Gabon Germany Guatemala India Indonesia Ireland Japan Total Transactions 6 3 19 33 5 3 3 2 11 10 9 1 5 6 11 3 4 1 1 3 34 1 1 Asset Location Kazakhstan Libya Mongolia Netherlands, The New Zealand Nigeria Norway Oman Pakistan Papua New Guinea Peru Philippines Romania Russia Sudan Thailand Trinidad and Tobago Tunisia Turkey Ukraine United Kingdom Venezuela Total Transactions 24 3 1 5 6 1 25 3 3 3 1 3 1 77 4 4 4 5 1 2 54 4 35 Table 2: Summary Statistics and correlation table for the main variables -1- -2- -3- -4- -5- -6- -7- -8- -9- -10- -11- -12- -13- -14- -15- -16- -17- -18- Mean 1.50 0.31 0.68 0.12 0.43 0.64 3.78 0.30 0.36 0.04 19.55 0.35 0.02 0.03 0.14 0.03 0.03 0.01 SD 1.16 0.46 0.47 0.33 0.32 0.48 0.48 0.46 0.48 0.19 34.78 0.48 0.15 0.17 0.35 0.18 0.18 0.10 Min -2.92 0 0 0 0 0 2.99 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Max 4.15 1 1 1 0.87 1 4.50 1 1 1 100 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 ln(V/R) 1.00 2 IIA 0.04 1.00 3 Resources Foreign State Ownership Host Polcon -0.20 0.04 1.00 0.02 0.26 0.20 1.00 0.25 -0.05 0.09 -0.07 1.00 0.17 0.50 -0.02 0.28 0.03 1.00 0.35 -0.04 -0.33 -0.10 -0.14 -0.02 1.00 0.06 0.02 -0.11 -0.12 -0.10 -0.04 0.15 1.00 -0.22 -0.01 -0.02 -0.05 0.03 -0.04 0.22 -0.13 1.00 0.05 0.11 -0.02 0.11 -0.03 0.05 0.01 -0.05 -0.12 1.00 0.04 0.02 0.03 0.05 0.26 0.02 -0.13 0.08 -0.42 -0.11 1.00 12 Crossborder ln(Oil Strip Price) M&A Proved + Probable Heavy Oil % Gas of proved reserve Buyer report 0.03 -0.06 -0.17 -0.11 0.04 -0.01 0.23 -0.08 0.09 -0.02 -0.12 1.00 13 Coal Bed 0.05 -0.10 -0.04 -0.06 0.20 -0.17 0.14 0.08 -0.04 -0.03 0.25 0.03 1.00 14 -0.16 0.04 0.12 0.07 0.02 0.07 -0.13 -0.11 -0.04 -0.04 0.25 -0.10 -0.03 1.00 0.24 -0.07 -0.09 -0.07 0.21 0.06 0.29 -0.14 0.21 -0.08 -0.03 0.10 -0.06 -0.07 1.00 16 LNG Shallow Water Deep Water 0.00 -0.07 0.10 0.13 0.13 0.08 0.10 -0.12 0.20 -0.04 -0.04 0.09 -0.03 -0.03 -0.08 1.00 17 Frontier -0.17 0.09 0.03 -0.03 -0.16 -0.04 0.01 0.06 0.04 -0.04 -0.10 -0.05 -0.03 -0.03 -0.07 -0.03 1.00 18 Diversified 0.07 -0.01 0.02 -0.04 -0.04 -0.03 0.07 0.10 -0.02 -0.02 0.03 -0.07 -0.01 -0.02 -0.04 -0.02 -0.02 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 15 1.00 36 Table 3: OLS models with robust standard errors Dependent variable = ln(Transaction value of petroleum reserves, per barrel) -1- -0.1014 (0.103) -20.2716* (0.133) -0.0948 (0.102) 0.2163 (0.160) 0.1467 (0.170) -3-0.0649 (0.214) -0.2396+ (0.126) 0.5044* (0.238) 0.0902 (0.168) 0.1023 (0.506) Crossborder 0.1159 (0.100) ln(Oil Strip Price) 1.0050* (0.432) M&A transaction 0.1783+ (0.100) Proved + Probable Dummy -1.0233*** (0.117) Heavy Oil -0.198 (0.218) % Gas of Proved Reserve -0.0060*** (0.002) Buyer Report -0.2067* (0.092) Coal Bed -0.5369+ (0.279) Liquefied Natural Gas (LNG) -0.5929+ (0.354) Shallow Water -0.0243 (0.152) Deep Water 0.0678 (0.307) Frontier -0.0968 (0.301) Diversified 0.6189+ (0.318) Host Country Dummies Yes Year Dummies Yes Constant -1.9917 (1.406) Number of Transactions 409 R-sq 0.6 Note: Robust standard errors in parantheses + p<0.1, * p<0.05, ** p<0.01, *** p<0.001 -0.0798 (0.519) -0.0217 (0.114) 1.0250* (0.432) 0.1675+ (0.101) -1.0521*** (0.121) -0.1953 (0.212) -0.0061*** (0.002) -0.2060* (0.092) -0.5681* (0.271) -0.5955+ (0.353) -0.0002 (0.148) 0.1233 (0.311) -0.1417 (0.299) 0.6355* (0.285) Yes Yes -1.9361 (1.411) 409 0.61 -0.1574 (0.505) -0.0026 (0.116) 0.9402* (0.429) 0.1495 (0.098) -1.0667*** (0.119) -0.2219 (0.219) -0.0061*** (0.002) -0.2001* (0.092) -0.6020* (0.263) -0.6276+ (0.358) -0.0312 (0.148) 0.0906 (0.326) -0.1612 (0.297) 0.6648* (0.290) Yes Yes -1.5483 (1.410) 409 0.61 IIA (H1) Financial Resources IIA * Financial Resources (H2) Foreign State Ownership IIA * Foreign State Ownership (H3) Host Polcon -40.3007* (0.139) -0.0915 (0.103) 0.241 (0.316) -0.154 (0.352) -0.0661 (0.521) -0.036 (0.112) 1.0213* (0.431) 0.1688+ (0.101) -1.0537*** (0.121) -0.1888 (0.212) -0.0063*** (0.002) -0.2057* (0.092) -0.5630* (0.270) -0.5771 (0.354) -0.003 (0.148) 0.1235 (0.312) -0.1439 (0.300) 0.6396* (0.284) Yes Yes -1.9267 (1.405) 409 0.61 -5-0.0328 (0.216) -0.2432+ (0.125) 0.5389* (0.238) 0.265 (0.308) -0.2919 (0.347) -0.1368 (0.506) -0.0282 (0.114) 0.9274* (0.425) 0.1508 (0.099) -1.0707*** (0.119) -0.2113 (0.220) -0.0064*** (0.002) -0.1992* (0.092) -0.5946* (0.264) -0.5950+ (0.359) -0.0386 (0.147) 0.0888 (0.329) -0.1665 (0.299) 0.6745* (0.287) Yes Yes -1.5041 (1.395) 409 0.62 37 Figure 2a: Interaction Effect of IIA and Firm Resources (Based on Model 3 in Table 3) 1.3 1.4 1.5 1.6 1.7 1.8 Graph of IIA * Resources interaction 0 1 International Investment Agreement Resources = Low Resources = High Figure 2b: Interaction Effect of IIA and Foreign State Ownership (Based on Model 4 in Table 3) 1.4 1.5 1.6 1.7 1.8 Graph of IIA * Foreign State Ownership interaction 0 1 International Investment Agreement Foreign State Ownership = 0 Foreign State Ownership = 1 38 Table 4: Effect of Change IIA = 0 to IIA = 1 (Based on Models 3-5 of Table 3) Financial Resources = Low Financial Resources = High Model 3 -0.06 (0.21) 0.43** (0.14) Foreign State Ownership = 0 Foreign State Ownership = 1 Model 4 0.3* (0.13) 0.14 (0.33) Model 5 -0.06 (0.21) 0.46*** (0.14) 0.33* (0.13) 0.04 (0.32) Note: Standard Errors in Parantheses + p<0.1, * p<0.05, ** p<0.01, *** p<0.001 39 Table 5: Robustness tests, OLS models with robust standard errors & Vertical Integration controls Dependent variable = ln(Transaction value of petroleum reserves, per barrel) -1IIA -20.023 (0.167) -0.1727 (0.127) 0.3526+ (0.204) -0.2296 (0.245) -0.2649+ (0.153) 0.5991+ (0.315) 0.3123 (0.320) -0.3063 (0.374) -0.0602 (0.143) 0.0787 (0.240) 0.3679 (0.538) 0.3424 (0.532) -0.0142 (0.126) 1.2743** (0.465) 0.1942+ (0.108) -0.2305* (0.102) Yes Yes Yes -2.9187+ (1.496) 367 0.59 -0.0442 (0.125) 1.0940* (0.463) 0.1774+ (0.107) -0.2173* (0.101) Yes Yes Yes -2.1802 (1.523) 367 0.6 Financial Resources IIA * Financial Resources Foreign State Ownership IIA * Foreign State Ownership Integrated IIA * Integrated Host country level controls: Host Country Polcon Transaction level controls: Crossborder transaction ln(Oil Strip price) M&A transaction Buyer report Reserve level controls Country dummies Year dummies Constant Number of observations R-Squared Note: Robust standard errors in parantheses + p<0.1, * p<0.05, ** p<0.01, *** p<0.001 40 Table 6: Probit for Heckman Two-Stage Model Dependent variable = Presence of an IIA (0/1) Average of dyad POLCON scores Vertical FDI - ln(abs diff of GDP/C of dyad) Horizontal FDI - ln(sum GDP of dyad) Horizontal FDI - ln((dyad GDP difference)^2) Total worldwide BITs Total worldwide ECT members ln(distance between dyad countries) Constant Number of observations Pseudo R-square Log likelihood Chi-square Note: Standard errors in parantheses + p<0.1, * p<0.05, ** p<0.01, *** p<0.001 All countries 1.0436*** (0.028) 0.0227*** (0.004) 0.4537*** (0.009) -0.0691*** (0.003) 0.0003*** (0.000) 0.0079 (0.005) -0.7414*** (0.008) -4.7422*** (0.218) 95,888 0.29 -33790.64 18,059.39 41 Table 7: Robustness Tests – Second stage OLS model with robust standard errors Dependent variable = ln(Transaction value of petroleum reserves, per barrel) Inverse Mills Ratio (from first stage) IIA Financial Resources -1-0.0138 (0.181) 0.2704* (0.131) -0.0953 (0.102) -3-0.0119 (0.181) 0.2996* (0.137) -0.0919 (0.102) 0.1493 (0.171) -2-0.001 (0.178) -0.065 (0.213) -0.2396+ (0.126) 0.5043* (0.238) 0.0904 (0.168) 0.243 (0.316) -0.1536 (0.353) -40.0035 (0.178) -0.0325 (0.215) -0.2431+ (0.125) 0.5390* (0.238) 0.2644 (0.308) -0.2921 (0.348) -0.0825 (0.517) -0.1576 (0.503) -0.0685 (0.520) -0.1361 (0.505) -0.1501 (1.689) 1.0229* (0.435) 0.1676+ (0.101) -0.2063* (0.092) Yes Yes Yes -1.7885 (2.392) 409 0.61 -0.0118 (1.665) 0.9401* (0.431) 0.1496 (0.099) -0.2001* (0.092) Yes Yes Yes -1.5377 (2.357) 409 0.61 -0.1467 (1.688) 1.0195* (0.433) 0.1689+ (0.101) -0.2060* (0.093) Yes Yes Yes -1.7995 (2.398) 409 0.61 0.0042 (1.661) 0.9279* (0.427) 0.1508 (0.099) -0.1991* (0.092) Yes Yes Yes -1.5413 (2.363) 409 0.62 IIA * Financial Resources Foreign State Ownership IIA * Foreign State Ownership Host country level controls: Host Polcon Transaction level controls: Crossborder ln(Oil Strip Price) M&A transaction Buyer Report Reserve level control Host Country Dummies Year Dummies Constant Number of Transactions R-sq Note: Robust standard errors in parantheses + p<0.1, * p<0.05, ** p<0.01, *** p<0.001 42 Table 8: Robustness tests, OLS models with robust standard errors Dependent variable = ln(Transaction value of petroleum reserves, per barrel) IIA -1- -2- Lower non-IIA threshold -0.031 (0.214) Large Reserves 0.5146** (0.176) -3Small/ Medium Reserves -0.2162 (0.331) -4Foreign State Owned 0.7423 (1.030) -5Non Foreign State Owned 0.3104* (0.145) BIT Financial Resources IIA * Financial Resources -0.2176+ (0.129) 0.5120* (0.239) -0.9268 (1.122) -0.0606 (0.107) BIT * Resources Foreign State Ownership IIA * Foreign State Ownership 0.2572 (0.295) -0.2826 (0.335) -0.0825 (0.193) Transaction level controls: Crossborder ln(Oil Strip Price) M&A transaction Buyer Report Reserve level controls: Host Country Dummies Year Dummies BIT -0.0831 (0.229) -0.2155+ (0.122) 0.5036+ (0.259) 0.3632 (0.303) 1.8943** (0.559) BIT * Foreign State Ownership Host country level controls: Host Polcon -6- -7- -8- Crossborder -0.1818 (0.241) >=5 Transactions 0.0244 (0.240) -0.271 (0.182) 0.5566* (0.274) -0.2064 (0.136) 0.4488+ (0.258) 0.2275 (0.309) -0.1498 (0.356) 0.2122 (0.391) -0.1939 (0.425) -0.4405 (0.619) 0.0957 (0.542) 0.9073 (0.555) 0.3250* (0.130) -0.2674* (0.115) Yes Yes Yes -0.0374 (0.118) 0.8258+ (0.443) 0.1638 (0.106) -0.2451* (0.099) Yes Yes Yes -0.4468 (0.363) -0.125 (0.506) -0.1331 (0.607) 0.1713 (1.255) 0.0032 (0.119) 0.7587 (0.462) 0.1618 (0.098) -0.2204* (0.093) Yes Yes Yes -0.0662 (0.156) 1.0942* (0.512) 0.1746 (0.141) -0.1954 (0.129) Yes Yes Yes 0.147 (0.254) 0.7782 (0.747) 0.1694 (0.223) -0.2765 (0.193) Yes Yes Yes -2.0876 (2.147) 0.2516 (0.635) -0.0627 (0.504) 2.1058 (2.545) 1.1078 (1.529) -0.7828 (0.702) Yes Yes Yes -0.0318 (0.115) 0.9574* (0.449) 0.136 (0.103) -0.2295* (0.097) Yes Yes Yes 0.0427 (0.110) 0.9099* (0.431) 0.1547 (0.099) -0.2118* (0.092) Yes Yes Yes 43 Constant Number of Transactions R-sq Note: Robust standard errors in parantheses + p<0.1, * p<0.05, ** p<0.01, *** p<0.001 -1.0002 (1.484) 416 0.61 -2.2202 (1.682) 278 0.63 -1.5842 (2.432) 131 0.68 -4.9642 (9.383) 51 0.92 -1.8989 (1.444) 358 0.62 -1.549 (1.410) 409 0.61 -1.2896 (1.795) 263 0.63 -1.3283 (1.464) 345 0.6 44