Managed Competition in Health Insurance Liran Einav and Jonathan Levin (Stanford and NBER) The Seventh Health Policy Workshop June 5, 2015 1 Rising healthcare cost everywhere, but especially in the US … Health Spending (% of GDP) Per Capita (PPP Adj.) Hope? Reasonably broad consensus, and scattered evidence, that healthcare operates inside the efficiency frontier, so in principle we may be able to cut costs and improve quality at the same time 5-7K per std. enrollee 9-16K per std. enrollee 3 Hope? Reasonably broad consensus, and scattered evidence, that healthcare operates inside the efficiency frontier, so in principle we may be able to cut costs and improve quality at the same time But how? Many economists and policymakers advocate for various forms of managed competition Examples exist in US private sector and in other countries (e.g., Netherlands …), but not a high degree of consensus on how to design the market or on how well it has worked or can work 4 Outline for the rest of the talk Describe in detail one particular environment of managed competition – “Medicare Advantage” – and its key ingredients: competitive pricing and risk adjustments Short digression about risk adjustments Summarize some results from our study of Medicare Advantage (based on recent work with Vilsa Curto, Jon Levin, and Jay Bhattacharya) End up with some open-ended thoughts about healthcare competition 5 Outline for the rest of the talk Describe in detail one particular environment of managed competition – “Medicare Advantage” – and its key ingredients: competitive pricing and risk adjustment Short digression about risk adjustments Summarize some results from our study of Medicare Advantage (based on recent work with Vilsa Curto, Jon Levin, and Jay Bhattacharya) End up with some open-ended thoughts about healthcare competition 6 “Medicare 101” Provides health insurance coverage to essentially all Americans once they turn 65 “Part A” Inpatient spending; Free; (almost) Full coverage Hospitals get reimbursed a fixed amount for each admission, based on DRG “Part B” Outpatient spending; $105/month (in 2014); Residual financial risk exposure: 20% coinsurance rate (plus $150 annual deductible) Fee for service (FFS)! Patient can see anyone, and providers bill Medicare “Part D” (recent, 2006 addition) Prescription drugs via private providers, who compete for Medicare beneficiaries Premiums heavily subsidized and plans receive capitated, risk adjusted rates Medicare is big!!! (and growing …) In 2014: 54M beneficiaries, $580B in spending, ~20% of US healthcare cost 7 Medicare Advantage (MA) Allows Medicare beneficiaries to opt out of traditional, fee-for-service (FFS) Medicare, and enroll in private insurance plans Plans must provide at least the insurance benefits of standard Medicare (parts A and B), and typically provide more generous financial coverage, and additional benefits Medicare pays plans a fixed, risk adjusted amount to cover each enrollee 8 Medicare Advantage (MA) Insurers differentiate themselves mostly through provider networks Once contracts/networks are approved; plans offered on top of it Many participants build off provider networks they offer in other markets Compared to FFS Medicare, MA could be cheaper or more expensive … Presumably lower Q due to more coordinated care Presumably higher P, especially when providers have market power Note: Benefits of managed competition could take a very different form when compared to other (non-FFS) benchmarks 9 MA background Program started in the 1980s, but was relatively small and had “issues”: Low take-up, significant risk selection, no cost savings Major reforms in the last decade, in the direction of what most economists would be routing for: – Annual (instead of monthly) plan choices – Much improved risk adjustment – Bidding system to set plan payments (instead of administratively-set rates) Nowadays the program is big and expanding, covering ~30% of Medicare beneficiaries 10 Expansion of Medicare Advantage 30% 800 Administered Capitation Rates Managed Competition 25% 700 600 20% 500 Number of Contracts Enrollment 15% 400 300 10% Data for talk 2006-2011 5% 0% 200 100 0 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 Our work on Medicare Advantage Great opportunity to assess how well managed competition can work ‒ Large program, many local markets, multiple years, extremely rich and granular data ‒ Universe of beneficiaries (>150M beneficiary years, >12K plan years), including location, demographics, risk scores, and choice sets ‒ Every health claim made by FFS Medicare beneficiaries ‒ Choices (but not utilization) of MA enrollees ‒ Has the key ingredients of managed competition ‒ Runs in parallel to traditional Medicare, allows for appropriate benchmark that often doesn’t exist in other settings 12 Our work on Medicare Advantage Great opportunity to assess how well managed competition can work ‒ Large program, many local markets, multiple years, extremely rich and granular data ‒ Has the key ingredients of managed competition ‒ Runs in parallel to traditional Medicare, allows for appropriate benchmark that often doesn’t exist in other settings Specifically focused on where the action is in the US context ‒ Private (vs. Public) share of healthcare spending much greater in the US 100% 80% 60% Private 40% Public 20% Czech Slovak Estonia Poland Denmark Finland Hungary Portugal Austria Belgium Netherlands Korea Germany Switzerland Canada Slovenia France US 0% Out-of-Pocket 13 How does MA bidding work? Medicare sets benchmark rate B for each county Plans submit bids to provide “standard” insurance for a “standard” individual Each individual chooses (once a year) a plan in her county, or standard Medicare Benchmark b Number of Year-Plan Pairs 140 120 100 b B Enrollee pays 0 Medicare pays plan93% rb Plan Bid b ($) 7% And Medicare pays a “rebate” of 80 ¾*(B-b) that is passed to consumers 60 as additional benefits Enrollee pays plan b-B Plan receives rb Medicare pays plan rb-(b-B) Risk adj. 40 Extra consumer premium or benefits depend on b-B Plan receives rb for enrolling individual with risk r: 20 0 ‒ One r=3 enrollee generates same revenue (and cost) as three r=1 beneficiaries b - B ($US) ‒ Easier to think about demand and market shares in terms of risk units 14 Outline for the rest of the talk Describe in detail one particular environment of managed competition – “Medicare Advantage” – and its key ingredients: competitive pricing and risk adjustment Short digression about risk adjustments Summarize some results from our study of Medicare Advantage (based on recent work with Vilsa Curto, Jon Levin, and Jay Bhattacharya) End up with some open-ended thoughts about healthcare competition 15 Risk selection The potential for risk selection might be the main concern in insurance markets: Adverse selection and associated inefficiencies Potential for “bad” competitive practices (“cherry picking” and “lemon dropping”) MA is not different: 0.25 MA Share 0.2 0.15 0.1 0.05 0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 Risk Score 7 8 9 10 16 Risk adjustments Typical way to combat adverse selection is to price risk, and charge high-risk people higher premiums Not a great solution in the context of health insurance: ‒ Regressive … We’d generally want to tilt pricing the other way ‒ May price out of the market exactly those we would like to cover the most ‒ May introduce large “reclassification risk” But managed competition is a “sponsored market,” making it possible to address selection concerns in a better way, using risk adjustments This is a way to implement uniform (or constrained) premiums and still compensate insurers for covering a (predictably) riskier consumer pool Progressive … A form of cross subsidy from healthy to sick When the sponsor subsidizes the entire market (as is often the case), take up is less of an issue even for the healthy Reclassification risk not an issue anymore 17 Risk adjustment in MA In MA, risk score r is constructed using predictive models of annual spending using data on health claims from previous year – Basic idea is to map claims to health conditions, and distinguish persistent conditions (e.g. diabetes) from transitory ones (e.g. broken arm) Current model uses gender, age, and 55 health conditions: use claims to “turn on” relevant dummies, and add up corresponding “scores” – Demographics alone explain a tiny fraction (1-2%), current model about 11% 18 Risk adjustment in MA Annual Medicare Spending ($000) 200 180 99th pctile 160 140 95th pctile 120 90th pctile 100 80 75th pctile 60 Mean 40 Median 20 0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 Risk Score 7 8 9 19 Risk adjustment in MA In MA, risk score r is constructed using predictive models of annual spending using data on health claims from previous year – Basic idea is to map claims to health conditions, and distinguish persistent conditions (e.g. diabetes) from transitory ones (e.g. broken arm) Current model uses gender, age, and 55 health conditions: use claims to “turn on” relevant dummies, and add up corresponding “scores” – Demographics alone explain a tiny fraction (1-2%), current model about 11% Fully predictive model could explain ~25%, but constraints exist: ‒ “Gaming” and “Upcoding” ‒ Political/procedural constraints, requiring risk score coefficients to “make sense” Makes one wonder about the trade-off between transparency and efficiency 20 Risk selection in MA Some risk selection remains (although may be competed away): 0.4 0.35 Mortality Rate 0.3 0.25 FFS Medicare 0.2 0.15 0.1 MA 0.05 0 0 1 2 3 4 >5 Risk Score We’ll adjust for it later, but to a first order risk selection is not a huge deal anymore – (although in theory, better-yet-imperfect scoring may make things worse) 21 Risk score as an economic object Risk adjustment models are becoming common and important E.g., in the new “ObamaCare” Health Insurance Exchanges in the US and in many employer-provided US settings This trend will continue with the advent of “big data” So far risk adjustment models are treated as “purely” predictive, essentially trying to maximize R2, with only little input from economics and economists This should probably change … 22 Example: Risk scores in Medicare Part D (based on work with Amy Finkelstein, Ray Kluender, and Paul Schrimpf) Convex kink in Medicare Part D contracts should lead to “bunching” due to “moral hazard” (as in Saez’s and Chetty’s work on labor supply) Out-ofpocket spending Catastrophic covg. “Bunching” at the kink Deductible “Donut hole” Coins. arm Total spending 23 Example: Clear bunching at the convex kink 2.4% 2.0% 1.6% 1.2% 0.8% 0.4% 0.0% -$2,000 -$1,500 -$1,000 -$500 $0 $500 $1,000 $1,500 Total Annual Drug Expenditure (relative to Kink) $2,000 Example: Who is bunching and how they get scored? But those who bunch are younger healthier males, who would likely spend significantly more under alternative coverages (e.g., in the absence of the kink) 78.5 0.68 78.0 0.67 Average Age 77.5 Fraction Died Fraction Female 7.5% 6.5% 0.66 77.0 5.5% 0.65 76.5 4.5% 0.64 76.0 3.5% 0.63 75.5 75.0 -$2,000 -$1,500 -$1,000 -$500 $0 $500 $1,000 $1,500 0.62 -$2,000 -$1,500 -$1,000 $2,000 -$500 $0 $500 $1,000 $1,500 2.5% -$2,000 -$1,500 -$1,000 $2,000 Total Annual Drug Expenditure (relative to Kink) Total Annual Drug Expenditure (relative to Kink) While risk scores, by design, capture none of this: Average Risk Score 1.15 1.10 1.05 1.00 0.95 0.90 0.85 0.80 0.75 -$2,000 -$1,500 -$1,000 -$500 $0 $500 $1,000 -$500 $0 $500 $1,000 $1,500 Total Annual Drug Expenditure (relative to Kink) $1,500 Total Annual Drug Expenditure (relative to Kink) $2,000 $2,000 10,000 10,000 9,000 9,000 Annual Spending under No-Deductible Contract Annual Spending under Filled-Gap Contract Perfect scoring in sample Imperfect out of sample 8,000 7,000 6,000 5,000 4,000 3,000 Correlation = 0.964 2,000 1,000 8,000 Correlation = 0.992 7,000 6,000 5,000 4,000 3,000 2,000 1,000 0 0 0 1,000 2,000 3,000 4,000 5,000 Annual Spending under The Standard Contract 6,000 7,000 0 1,000 2,000 3,000 4,000 5,000 Annual Spending under The Standard Contract 6,000 7,000 Risk score as an economic object 1. Risk score in one plan may not be great for another, as incentives change – – Why? We predict spending, which is a combination of (at least) two components: health and a behavioral response to it (“moral hazard”) For most contexts we would have probably wanted to predict only the health component (if we only knew how) 2. Many good health spending predictors are endogenous to past behavior – – – • Do we want to reward smoking behavior by scoring it high? Or perhaps use the scoring model to penalize smokers and encourage them to quit? To engage in this, an equilibrium model is needed, a clear objective function of the policy, and within this context one can decide about the best scoring model; it is unlikely to be the one that maximizes R2 Note: In very different contexts (Google AdWords, eBay), scoring algorithms are being used, quite effectively, to tilt market operation toward the objective of the market maker. No reason that healthcare markets won’t take advantage of this as well! 27 Outline for the rest of the talk Describe in detail one particular environment of managed competition – “Medicare Advantage” – and its key ingredients: competitive pricing and risk adjustment Short digression about risk adjustments Summarize some results from our study of Medicare Advantage (based on recent work with Vilsa Curto, Jon Levin, and Jay Bhattacharya) End up with some open-ended thoughts about healthcare competition 28 Our work on Medicare Advantage Great opportunity to assess how well managed competition can work ‒ Large program, many local markets, multiple years, extremely rich and granular data ‒ Has the key ingredients of managed competition ‒ Runs in parallel to traditional Medicare, allows for appropriate benchmark that often doesn’t exist in other settings Specifically focused on where the action is in the US context ‒ Private (vs. Public) share of healthcare spending much greater in the US ‒ Much of the US spending differential concentrated at the elderly population Basic goal: ‒ Are there “gains from trade” in allowing seniors to enroll in private plans? ‒ Who captures the gain? Beneficiaries, insurers, and/or tax payers? ‒ Potential effects of changes in market design 29 Gov’t Spends Extra on Private Plans Avg. across MA enrollees MA Plan Payment $670 Rebate Payments $76 Tot. Gov’t Payment As fraction of predicted FFS $746 Amounts are per enrollee month So from now on, multiply each number by ~15M*12 = 180M / year Gov’t Spends Extra on Private Plans Avg. across MA enrollees As fraction of predicted FFS MA Plan Payment $670 99% Rebate Payments $76 12% Tot. Gov’t Payment $746 111% Predicted FFS Cost $675 100% Amounts are per enrollee month We use a pure predictive model to account non-parametrically for heterogeneity across county-year pairs Would not have been possible without having FFS Medicare running in parallel We adjust for risk selection using the differential mortality between MA and FFS enrollees Gov’t Spends Extra on Private Plans Avg. across MA enrollees As fraction of predicted FFS MA Plan Payment $670 99% Rebate Payments $76 12% Tot. Gov’t Payment $746 111% Predicted FFS Cost $675 100% Amounts are per enrollee month Plans bid at the level of FFS cost => so cost likely lower? Government payments are well above matched FFS costs due to the rebates, which presumably attract enrollees Enrollees get extra benefits but may not like restrictions => CS? Market power Risk selection is at least partially “solved” by risk adjustment, but a much more “traditional” concern remains Many MA plans available in each market, but markets highly concentrated: – In 66% of the markets, C2 > 75% – In 94% of the markets, C3 > 75% – In 60% of the market, C3 > 90% And “traditional” concerns call for “traditional” analyses … Benchmarks and Bidding Incentives Plan demand depends on 𝑝𝑗 = 𝑏𝑗 − 𝐵 𝜋𝑗 = 𝑝𝑗 + 𝐵 − 𝑐𝑗 𝑄𝑗 𝑝1 , … , 𝑝𝑁 i.e. 𝜋𝑗 = 𝑏𝑗 − 𝑐𝑗 𝑄𝑗 , where 𝑄𝑗 is “risk-weighted” demand Benchmark plays the role of a subsidy 𝑑𝑝𝑗 𝑑𝑝𝑗 = 𝑑𝐵 𝑑 −𝑐 ⇒ 𝑑𝑏𝑗 𝑑𝑏𝑗 =1− 𝑑𝐵 𝑑𝑐 Under “perfect” competition 𝑏𝑗 = 𝑐 ⇒ 𝑑𝑏𝑗 𝑑𝐵 =0 34 Determinants of Plan Bids Estimate sensitivity of plan bids to benchmarks and FFS costs Incomplete (~40%) pass-through of benchmark changes market power is important Bids only weakly correlated with FFS costs in same locations: Related finding in the context of FFS vs Employer-Provided insurance Confirming the potential benefits of managed competition Suggest looking for alternative ways to estimate plan costs … We will thus follow the IO literature and use first order conditions for optimal bidding to back out cost Implied Plan Markups and Costs Estimate plan choice model to identify consumer price sensitivity, and extent to which consumers benefit from MA plans Identify demand off changes in plan bids over time, and variation in plan bids within the same contract Recall 𝑝𝑗 = 𝑏𝑗 − 𝐵 and 𝜋𝑗 = 𝑝𝑗 + 𝐵 − 𝑐𝑗 𝑄𝑗 𝑝1 , … , 𝑝𝑁 First order condition: 𝑑 ln 𝑄𝑗 𝑏𝑗 = 𝑐𝑗 + 𝑑𝑏𝑗 −1 36 Sources of Competition Estimated mark-ups are $55-140 for “standard” enrollee Competition comes both from FFS Medicare and other MA plans If plan j increases its bid by $20 ‒ It loses about 20% of its enrollees ‒ About 1/2 of these go to other MA plans ‒ About 1/2 of these switch to FFS Medicare By the same logic, a decrease in the benchmark has the same effect as an identical decrease in the bids of all rival plans 37 Putting the Pieces Together Avg. across MA enrollees 2006-10 Imputed FFS Cost $675 Estimated MA Cost $586 Plan Payment $681 Tot. Gov’t Payment $756 Program “surplus” and incidence Cost savings from MA $89 (“Disutility” from MA) - $26 Gov’t Net Surplus - $81 Plan Surplus $95 Consumer Surplus $49 38 Potential for market design Actual (2006-10) Pred. FFS Cost Est. MA Cost Plan Payment Tot. Gov’t Payment $675 $586 $681 $756 MA share 18.2% Benchmarks 100% FFS $50 Lower Rebates At 50% At 100% Program “surplus” and incidence Gov’t Net Surplus Plan Surplus Consumer Surplus -$81 $95 $49 39 Potential for market design Actual (2006-10) Benchmarks 100% FFS $50 Lower Pred. FFS Cost Est. MA Cost Plan Payment Tot. Gov’t Payment $675 $586 $681 $756 $691 $598 $674 $731 $676 $587 $660 $716 MA share 18.2% 13.7% 15.4% -$40 $76 $40 -$40 $73 $38 Rebates At 50% At 100% Program “surplus” and incidence Gov’t Net Surplus Plan Surplus Consumer Surplus -$81 $95 $49 40 Potential for market design Actual (2006-10) Benchmarks 100% FFS $50 Lower Rebates At 50% At 100% Pred. FFS Cost Est. MA Cost Plan Payment Tot. Gov’t Payment $675 $586 $681 $756 $691 $598 $674 $731 $676 $587 $660 $716 $672 $590 $722 $744 $676 $581 $654 $789 MA share 18.2% 13.7% 15.4% 12.2% 26.4% -$40 $76 $40 -$40 $73 $38 -$72 $132 $17 -$113 $73 $77 Program “surplus” and incidence Gov’t Net Surplus Plan Surplus Consumer Surplus -$81 $95 $49 41 Market Design Summary 42 Room for more customization? Implied MA Costs ($US) 1,400 1,200 1,000 800 600 400 Rural Urban 200 0 0 200 400 600 800 1,000 1,200 1,400 Predicted FFS Costs for MA Enrollees ($US) 43 Outline for the rest of the talk Describe in detail one particular environment of managed competition – “Medicare Advantage” – and its key ingredients: competitive pricing and risk adjustment Short digression about risk adjustments Summarize some results from our study of Medicare Advantage (based on recent work with Vilsa Curto, Jon Levin, and Jay Bhattacharya) End up with some open-ended thoughts about healthcare competition 44 Can we rely on consumers? Our work on MA suggests that not-very-price-sensitive consumers give rise to market power, and other recent work suggests other “behavioral” concerns that may be consistent with it (inertia, inattention, “mistakes”) Informed consumer choices have (at least) two important roles: Drive competition to the right margin: downward pressure on prices, and upward pressure on “value” per dollar Sort consumers to better and more efficient plans Creative market design (defaults, benchmarking, etc.) could help on the former, but the latter would remain a concern One difficulty is that key choice made when consumers aren’t well informed, but when stuff happens and they become informed, key choice cannot be changed perhaps there is room for some form of “secondary markets” or joint optimization, with a split of the potential gain from trade? 45 The transactable unit? Typical unit is a person-year Too narrow? Leads to too much weight on short-run rather than long-run costs and benefits Some longer-run incentives are already built in, but not fully priced Too broad? May not take advantage of economies of scale, learning, and specialization Many forms of healthcare (but not all) are tradable goods and can be performed (cheaper and/or better) elsewhere For some “separable” components of health (e.g., hip replacements?), could design competition at the component level 46 The role of competition? Ideal goal: healthcare that is cheaper and better at the same time In the absence of the ideal, some possible answers: 1. Cheaper delivery of the “same” care 2. Better care at similar or not too expensive prices 3. Sorting people to “worse” but presumably cheaper care, which is still “good enough” Much focus on the first two Even in context where it makes less sense (e.g., Medicare part D) May want to encourage market designs that focus on the latter Could imagine private market having comparative advantage in facilitating money for health/comfort transactions 47 Health vs. Healthcare Not the same thing … But very much bundled: in coverage, in measurement, and in incentives Better and more objective measures of health would allow us to contract on outputs rather than inputs, and to separate amenities (Waiting time for the doctor, Driving time to surgical or radiation facility, Quality of post-labor recovery room) from “pure” health Reasonable argument to make that the government should do the best to provide good health, but not so clear that it should mandate, subsidize, or guarantee better-than-respectable amenities One concern is that at least in the US amenities are heavily subsidized, little incentives for insurers to offer “economy service,” and all Americans are “flying business” … 48 Final slide Healthcare costs keep going up, and cannot do this forever, so something will need to happen Many are optimistic that Information Technology and various forms of “big data” have the potential to completely transform production of healthcare, in a way that would make it affordable and accessible to many But once the healthcare version of Ford’s Model T shows up, are markets designed to help it grow and get adopted? Perhaps, but very slowly ... Healthcare markets should make this a primary goal 49