Targeting Party Policies: Are Certain Governments More Susceptible to Transnational Terrorism Kathleen Deloughery∗ March 15, 2008 Abstract The goal of this paper is to determine if the political orientation of the leadership of a country affects the likelihood of that country being the target of a terrorist attack. Econometric techniques are used to reduce the bias due to potential two-way causation by correcting for the possibility that being the target of terrorist attacks in the past determines which political party is voted into power in the future. I will correct for this by utilizing variables that influence elections as instruments. This paper will build on the existing literature discussing who is most likely to be the target of a terrorist attack. More importantly, this research can provide individuals a way to reduce the likelihood of their country being attacked through the leaders they elect. Additionally, countries will be able to better measure the risk they face. Finally, it might be possible to learn more about the mechanism through which terrorists choose their targets by determining if political orientation affects the probability of becoming a target. Results show that joining political or economic unions with other countries is highly correlated with the number of terrorist attacks a country faces. However, separation of church and state, and government control over production and the economy are issues that appear to predict terror activity under several specifications. Results show that countries with capitalist markets face more terrorist attacks. Additionally, countries that support state involvement in religion also experience more terrorist attacks. A ten percent change in the policy scores of these issues could influence the number of terror attacks in a country by anywhere between 0.3 and 0.76 attacks in a given year1 . ∗ Please email deloughery.1@osu.edu for any questions or comments about this paper. This is a preliminary draft, please do not quote or cite without permission. 1 This research was performed under an appointment to the Department of Homeland Security (DHS) Scholarship and Fellowship Program, administered by the Oak Ridge Institute for Science and Education (ORISE) through an interagency agreement between the U.S. Department of Energy (DOE) and DHS. ORISE is managed by Oak Ridge Associated Universities (ORAU) under DOE contract number DE-AC0506OR23100. All opinions expressed in this paper are the author’s and do not necessarily reflect the policies and views of DHS, DOE, or ORAU/ORISE. 1 1 Introduction While terrorism has been an international security issue for decades, more researchers from economics, political science, international relations, and sociology have examined aspects of terrorism since the attacks of September 11th, 2001. Most of these studies have examined either the optimal response to terrorism or the consequences and causes of terrorism. Despite the growth of the amount of research on terrorism, there have been very few studies examining the choices made by terrorist organizations. Economists are well suited to answer questions about terrorist actions because terrorist organizations are thought to behave rationally by responding to incentives2 . Since terrorist organizations behave rationally, they must have objectives: gaining supporters and coercing target governments. These objectives will be at the forefront in all of their decisions. Like other individuals, terrorists maximize their utility by consuming goods subject to their limited resources. Unlike other individuals, these goods can be produced through terrorist and non-terrorist activities. Examples of goods produced through terrorism are political instability, media attention, and declining resolve of the target government. In order to produce these commodities, terrorist organizations must decide the location, method, timing, and target of each attack. Additionally, few studies have been done in economics on how to reduce terrorism. Most research of this nature has focused on whether countries should follow a strategy of deterrence or preemption in fighting terrorism. However, these decisions are usually made after terrorist attacks occur. Instead, it is important to examine why terrorists choose certain countries to attack and not others. Therefore, a paper analyzing governmental policies and how they affect terrorism in that country is important. The first aspect to undertake when writing this paper is to define terrorism. According to Alex Schmid and Albert Jongman, there are over 100 definitions of terrorism, both scholarly and political. However, these researchers find that there are two main ingredients in any terrorism definition: the presence or threat of violence and a political or social motive. The three secondary aspects included in most of the definitions are the victim, perpetrator, and audience. Additionally there are two important aspects that separate terrorism from crime. First, terrorism has a ideological objective, where premeditated crime usually has a purely economic motive3 . Second, a terrorist act is carried out in the hope of affecting a group larger than the immediate targets. This difference between crime and 2 Sandler and Enders The Political Economy of Terrorism has a section in the first chapter about the rationality of terrorist organizations 3 Krueger and Maleckova make this argument in their 2003 paper 2 terrorism plays into the goal of the terrorist organization to coerce a targeted government to alter its policies. A commonly used definition is: terrorism is the premeditated threat or use of excessive violence to obtain a political, religious, or ideological objective by intimidation or fear. Terrorist attacks appear random to the general population, perpetuating the fear that they bring about. However, researchers have examined terrorist attacks and found patterns. For instance, evidence shows that democratic countries are the most likely targets of suicide attacks. This finding occurs because eliciting fear in society has the most impact in a democratic society. Enacting change is easier in these societies, because individuals have the power to elect their officials. Terrorist organizations hope that the fear and anxiety caused by an attack, and the possibility of future violence, will cause citizens to persuade their government to make concessions. Additionally, terrorism is more likely to succeed when the group operates in an open society because of unrestricted travel and free press. This paper plans to build on these previous findings by examining whether the political makeup of the leadership of a country determines its likelihood of being the target of a terrorist attack. I will study policy stances on different issues and their correlation with the number and intensity of terrorist attacks a country faces. The main motivation of this paper is to better understand if the policies in place affect a nations likelihood of being targeted. For example, suppose the issue of importance is support of the military. In this case, a country with a strong positive stance believes in infusing resources into the armed forces. One can imagine that a country with a strong military presence might be better able to deter terrorist attacks. In addition, terrorist organizations might fear retaliatory attacks from countries with strong militaries, which could then make the terrorist organization want to shift attacks away from those countries. Both of these effects would have the overall result of lowering terrorist attacks on countries with large militaries. On the other hand, a country that is anti-military, meaning they argue against the presence of security forces larger than necessary to maintain their borders, could illicit fewer attacks because either they are no longer a provocative target, or because their military policies4 do not offend terrorist organizations. The question becomes, which of these explanations is correct. Even if both explanations are valid, which one dominates? Additionally, this paper can help policymakers discover which policies are the most important for deterring terrorism. For instance, is military support important to terrorist organizations, or is it social welfare issues, or religious issues? Finally, this paper can also shed light on how terrorist organizations choose their targets. Few papers examine terrorist decision making, but understanding how these organizations operate is critical. 4 For instance, building military installations in foreign countries 3 2 Literature Review The most common line of research on terrorism deals with the consequences of terrorism. For instance, Abadie and Gardeazabal (2003) examine how terrorist violence affects GDP in the Basque Country. Drakos and Kutan (2003) study how terrorism affects regional tourism in mediterranean countries. Beyond that, most researchers, especially in economics, choose to examine optimal responses to terrorists. For instance, Sandler and Siqueiara (2003) examine the decision of a targeted government to quell future attacks by employing a strategy of deterrence or preemption. Additionally, Arce and Sandler (2002) examine whether or not governments should negotiate with hostage-taking terrorist organizations. Little research has been done in economics on why terrorist organizations choose certain countries to target. However, these studies are potentially the most important. If we can understand the mechanism through which terrorist organizations decide who to target, then we will be better equipped to predict and thwart future attacks. In The Strategic Logic of Suicide Terrorism, Robert Pape examines the option of terrorist organizations to employ suicide attacks as a method. Suicide attacks can be less costly for terrorist organizations. The planning that goes into a suicide mission is not as complex, because the perpetrator does not need to orchestrate escape or contingency plans. Also, the attacker can make last minute adjustments to ensure that the mission is successful. Additionally, Pape finds that suicide attacks are more lethal. While only three percent of terrorist attacks are suicide attacks, these attacks account for almost half of all deaths due to terrorism. An individual who is willing to die for their organization is more likely to ensure that their mission is completed. Finally, terrorist organizations that employ suicide attackers have an increased credibility that they will attack again, because the act of suicide implies the attacker cannot be dissuaded. Suicide attacks also evoke the most fear in society because they are deadlier than other forms of terrorism, and garner the most media attention. However, suicide attacks automatically diminish the pool of potential individuals in the organization who can carry out attacks. Pape believes that organizations utilize suicide terrorism because it is effective in coercing target governments. At the same time, it is not the only method of attack used because it can have the effect of alienating an audience who might be sympathetic to their plight or losing more moderate supporters of their cause. Additionally, Pape has examined who is most likely to be a target of suicide terrorism and finds that democratic countries are the most likely targets. He proposes this finding occurs because eliciting fear in society has the most impact in a democratic society. In these countries individuals have the power to enact change by voting for officials who 4 might have different policy stances. Terrorist organizations hope that the fear and anxiety caused by an attack, and the possibility of future violence, will cause citizens to persuade their government to make concessions. However, he does not extend this study to include other types of terrorism, even though Pape admits that suicide attacks only account for three percent of all attacks. Further, Pape does not empirically examine his claim that democracies are more likely to be targeted than any other type of government. In the international relations literature some work has been done on the characteristics of countries where terrorism is most likely to develop. In Dynamics of Terrorism, Hamilton and Hamilton build on social contagion models to determine how terrorism spreads throughout a society. They find that terrorism is easier and safer in open societies because of unrestricted travel and free press. They even find that the spread of terrorism is reversible in countries with low democracy. The unit of observation in this paper is a terrorist organization, not a terrorist attack. Of course, it is possible that the number of active terrorist organizations is not as easily discernible in countries with low civil liberties. Most of these countries suppress the freedoms of association, travel, and the press. Therefore, countries will only know about groups that either succcessfully carry out attacks and claim credit for them, or are caught while attempting an attack. Thus, the results of this study must be viewed with some skepticism. In addition, this study does not examine where terrorists are most likely to strike. While it is important to know where terrorist organizations are located, it is equally important to learn how far organizations are willing to travel in order to carry out their attacks. The political science literature has also examined terrorism. Birnir (2006) studied when a domestic group will chose to exit the political process and resort to terrorist violence against the targeted government. She finds that the longer a group is left out of the political process, the more likely they are to turn to terrorism as a way of being heard. The group does not have to be intentionally left out of the political process. It could be that the group has not been elected to office in recent years. Again this paper differs from my research because I am not looking at domestic groups. Finally, Burgoon (2006) examined terrorists responses to a coutry’s social welfare policies. He finds that countries that have more progressive social welfare policies are less likely to be targets of political violence. While this paper is more in line with my research, I will examine several issues, including some social welfare issues. Also, Burgoon’s study covers only terrorism in European countries, whereas mine will be a cross country survey. Finally, some economic modeling of the relationship between the level of ter- 5 ror attacks and some governmental policies have been examined. For instance, Frel and Luechinger (2002) argue that deterrence is not an optimal strategy to employ in fighting terrorism. With an increase in deterrence policy, governments play a more central role in the decision making process. They argue that having a centralized decision maker in both a political and economic realm can induce more terrorism because the benefit to the terrorist or carrying out an attack is higher. This paper will examine if the political party composition of different countries makes them a more likely target for terrorist organizations. For instance, does having a more conservative government, induce more or less terrorist attacks against a country. There are two ways to answer this question intuitively. First, conservative governments usually spend more on national security5 , and thus one might believe are better able to deter against attacks. On the other hand, the stringent policies put in place by a conservative government might have the opposite effect of inducing more attacks since a successful attack will now bring about more utility to a terrorist organization. The goal of this paper is to empirically examine whether the political affiliations of the leadership of a country has any effect on its vulnerability as a target to terrorist organizations. This research not only examines political party composition of the governing body, but also studies which issues are most important to terrorists in choosing their targets. I observe each political party’s stance on twelve different policy issues and then assign each country a score on each issue. Therefore, this research will go beyond simply saying that liberal or conservative governments are targeted most often. Instead, I will be able to deduce that governments who have either left or right leanings on certain issues are more likely to be targeted. A conclusion of this type can help form policy decisions of a government hoping to reduce the amount of terrorism it faces. 3 Data Data for this project consists of terrorist attacks, a time series of the political makeup of targeted countries, and measures of how liberal or conservative the political parties are in different countries. The terrorism data comes from International Terrorism: Attributes of Terrorist Events (ITERATE), which is a project that collects ”characteristic data on groups, 5 The political parties in this dataset who have scores above average on support of the military were also more likely to be ranked as a right leaning party 6 events, and environments in which attacks take place.”6 ITERATE7 contains data on every transnational terrorist attack that took place from 1968 through 2004. The data on terrorist attacks takes the form of both event and fatality counts. The definition of transnational terrorism used by the ITERATE dataset is: ”The use, or threat of use, of anxiety-inducing, extra-normal violence for political purposes by any individual or group, whether acting for or in opposition to established governmental authority, when such action is intended to influence the attitudes and behaviour of a target group wider than the immediate victims and when, through the nationality or foreign ties of its perpetrators, its location, the nature of its institutional or human victims, or the mechanics of its resolution, its ramifications transcend national boundaries.8 ” This definition will guide which events will and will not be coded in the terrorism dataset. It is important to note that national boundary is loosely defined, causing some events that appear to be domestic terror on initial examination to still be coded in the dataset. For instance, while Kashmir, the Gaza Stip, and the West Bank are not listed as countries in the dataset, any attacks that cross these borders are considered transnational terror9 . There are benefits and drawbacks to using the ITERATE dataset. First, it is the most user friendly and widely used open source dataset. The dataset allows different ways of measuring terrorism, such as event or fatality counts, amount of damage done, and counts of active terror organizations. Additionally, researchers can explore different options in identifying the target of the attack, such as location or nationality of victims. For this project, I am focusing on event and fatality counts to measure the amount of terrorism and the location of the attack as a proxy for the target. One main drawback of ITERATE is that acts of domestic terror are not included. However, only one open source dataset codes domestic terror, and they have done so only since 1996. Another drawback of ITERATE is that there is a possibility of bias since the incidents are coded from public FBI files and news 6 7 This description comes from the ITERATE Codebook I recognize support from the Center for Risk and Economic Analysis of Terrorist Events (CREATE) at the University of Southern California for providing me with this dataset. This research was supported by the United States Department of Homeland Security through the Center for Risk and Economic Analysis of Terrorism Events (CREATE) under grant number N00014-05-0630. However, any opinions, findings, and conclusions or recommendations in this document are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect views of the United States Department of Homeland Security. 8 This definition comes from the ITERATE Codebook. 9 Northern Ireland is listed as a separate country in the ITERATE dataset 7 articles. Therefore, the results may only be picking up the effect of ”newsworthy” terror attacks. In the future, I hope to combine this dataset with other open source datasets in order to enhance the robustness of the results. The next portion of data needed for this project is cross-country political data from the same time period as the terrorism sample. Therefore, the makeup of the political leadership of targeted countries is gathered from 1968-2004. The number of members of the national assembly belonging to each major political party is gathered for each country during that time period. It is important that there is continuity in comparing the ideologies of political parties in different countries. Just because parties have the same, or similar, names in different countries does not mean they share the same beliefs on certain issues. Therefore, I use Kenneth Jandas Political Parties: A Cross-National Survey, which ranks political parties on twelve issues including government ownership of production, government role in economic planning, social welfare, support of the military, (supra)national integration, and protection of civil rights. These rankings give each political party an orientation score for each issue. The data is coded so that a positive score implies that the party is pro government action in that area, and is generally viewed as a leftist stance. Parties can receive a score ranging from -5 to 5. Therefore, for each issue, parties are placed on a left/right continuum. There are some potential problems with Janda’s dataset. First, not all countries are included in the study. However, the countries that are included in his research, which can be found in Table 1 were drawn from a random sample stratified by geography. The United States and United Kingdom were added to the dataset, bringing the number of countries included to 49. Janda began performing his research in the early 1960’s, before the beginning of modern terrorism. Thus, we have no worries that the countries might have been added because of the amount of terrorism they face. Another drawback is that parties that do not exist before 1978 are not coded. Finally, Janda assigns each party an issue orientation score only once for the time period we are examining. Therefore, I will not compute a new score for each party in each time period. Instead, I will assume that the issue orientation score of the party stays constant over the time period of the sample. Additionally, some of the policital parties in Janda’s dataset do not have scores for each policy. The missing policy scores were imputed. Information on how values were imputed can be found in Appendix A. Finally, for each country in Janda’s sample I have the proportion of the governing body held by each active political party. When possible I have the data for all years 1968-2004. Currently the research only examines the political makeup of the legislature/parliament/assembly as the governing body. In the future, I will add information about 8 head of state and determine how to appropriately balance the decision making capabilities of the head of state and governing body in deciding policy. Hypotheses on the predicted relationship between the number of terrorist incidents and the policy score on different issues can be found in Table 4. 4 Results Now that the political parties represented in the sample have an orientation score for each issue, each country in the sample is assigned a score for each year. The score is assigned by first calculating the sum of the stance of each party times the proportion of the governing body that party holds in that year. This value is then divided by the total proportion of the governing body accounted for by the sampled parties in that year. The country scores represent weighted average of a country’s stance on the policy issue and are assigned as follows: X scorei,j,t = stancei,p × Shareof Governmentp,j,t p X (1) Shareof Governmentp,j,t p Where p represents the political party, i represents the issue, j represents the country, and t represents the year. This calculation is done for each issue, meaning each country gets 12 scores in each year. Due to the way issue orientation scores are assigned, the unit of observation for this analysis will be a ”country-year.” In other words, the dependent variable will be the number of events (fatalities) that occur in each country in each year. In the full data set, there are just over 8,000 target-year combinations. At least one terrorist attack occurs in over 1/3 of the observations. According to Table 2 there are an average of about 1.4 incidents per target year. However, once you look at only countries where at least one terrorist incident occurred in that year, that average goes up to 5.48 incidents. To provide some background information, over the 37 year period of the sample, there are only 12,000 coded terrorist events. These events have resulted in the deaths of fewer than 20,000 individuals. Terrorists target some countries more than others. Therefore, terrorism should be an important part of the research agenda in those countries. Table 3 shows that the United States has been a favorite target for terrorist group attacks. Even 9 though few individuals were wounded or killed on US soil due to transnational terrorism before the events of 9/11, the US still faced the second highest number of attacks. The analysis presented in this paper covers two important aspects that the reader should remember. First, all of the results presented include the events of September 11, 2001. I repeated the analysis dropping 9/11 from the observations and the results did not change significantly. Second, the target of the terrorist attack is being defined as the location where the attack took place10 . This paper is interested in answering whether the political orientation of the leadership of the country affects the likelihood of that country being targeted by terrorist attacks. The twelve issues we are considering political stances on are government ownership of means of production, government role in economic planning, redistribution of wealth, social welfare, secularization of society, support of the military, anti-colonialism, supranational integration, national integration, electoral participation, protection of civil rights, and interference with civil liberties. Remember, a country receiving a net positive score on any of these issues implies that the country is in favor of government action in that area. For each of those 12 issues, the following equation was estimated: N umberof Incidentsj,t = α + βIssuei,j,t + X δj Countryj + j X γt Y eart + i,j,t (2) t where j represents the targeted country, t represents the year of the attack, and i represents the issue being analyzed. By including time dummy variables, the equation estimates the within country variation in the Number of Incidents changes in the country’s score for Issuei .The equations are also all run with Number Killed as the dependent variable11 . These equations are run on the limited sample of 49 countries from Janda’s book. Since a large number of the observations report no terrorist incidents, the underlying distribution of the data is left censored at zero. Therefore, the parameters will be estimated using a Tobit model. As can be seen in Table 5 three of the issues, government ownership 10 In the case where an attack crossed national boundaries, the end location of the attack is chosen as the target. 11 Number wounded was considered for use as a dependent variable, however, some problems exist with using it. First, more data was missing on number wounded. The technique used to calculate number killed did not work in this scenario. Therefore, when number wounded was missing, I used the calculation that the number wounded is usually 7 times larger than the number killed. Additionally, only wounded who are treated are listed as wounded. Finally, the damage done to those wounded can vary drastically from being permanently disabled to needing stitches, but having no lasting side effects. Because of these practical problems, number wounded was not used as a dependent variable. 10 of production, redistribution of wealth, and supranational integration, are statistically significant at the five percent level in both of the specifications. Additionally, anti-colonialism is significant at the 10 percent level. Adding any of these issues explains about one percent more variation than a specification with only country and time fixed effects. The regressions were also run allowing for standard errors that are clustered within the same country. Policy scores adjust slowly over time because the political process does not change quickly throughout an entire country. Therefore, it is possible that the standard errors are correlated over time in the same country. Now, we will turn to examining the meaning behind the significant issues, starting with those significant at the five percent level. The negative point estimate on government ownership of production implies that countries that favor government control face fewer terror attacks. Therefore, being a capitalist country is correlated with experiencing more terror attacks. Another significant issue was redistribution of wealth. This variable codes how parties feel about equalization of income across society. Countries with governments that are in favor of redistribution are less likely to be targeted by terrorist attacks. A study by Burgoon (2006) shows that having a more equalizing social welfare policy reduces domestic and international terrorism in Europe. The results from this paper line up with the findings of Burgoon. Supranational integration was coded by Janda as a political and economic issue, not a military one. A positive point estimate means that countries whose policies favor unions with other states are more frequently targeted by terrorists. This is especially interesting with the growth of coalition forming in recent years. Since 1995 the WTO has been formed and the number of countries joining the European Union has grown. Anti-colonialism was another significant issue, although only at the 10 percent level. This issue is harder to code, because countries can either be in a superior or subordinate position when it comes to colonialism. For countries in a superior position, the negative point estimate implies that countries who favor relinquishing control over colonies face fewer terror attacks. Likewise, for countries in a subordinate position, the negative point estimate means that countries who favor obtaining complete independence face fewer terror attacks. In order to obtain more exact estimates for anti-colonialism, it would be necessary to identify each country as either a superior or subordinate country in each year of the data set. In a baseline specification, regressing Number of Incidents on only year and country dummies, the Psuedo R2 was 0.1442. Therefore, for each of the significant policy issues, adding that issue to the equation raises the baseline specification by between 1 and 2 percent. Additionally, 11 coefficients on 10 of the year dummies were statistically significant at the five percent level12 . The significant years spanned every decade in the sample. Also of note, the point estimates, while not all statistically significant, were postive for each year between 1970 and 1995. For every since since 1995, the point estimate has been negative, implying that less terrorist activities can be explained by those years than by the base year. Since the US faces more terror attacks each year than any other country in the limited sample set, the results were also run after dropping the US from the dataset. By dropping the US, we can be sure that none of the results are driven solely by US policy. The results can be found in Table 6. Every policy issue that was significant with the US, is still significant once the US is dropped from the dataset. Interestingly, two more policies are significant once the US is dropped from the dataset. Therefore, it appears including the US in the dataset is actually dampening the affect of some of the policy scores. The two variables that are now significant are government role in economic planning and social welfare. The negative point estimate on government role in economic planning implies that countries in favor of government control over allocation of resources face fewer terror attacks. The negative point estimate on social welfare means countries in favor of universal coverage and compulsory public assistance face fewer terror attacks, which is consistent with the estimate on redistribution of wealth. Additionally these equations were run with number killed as the dependent variable, but none of the results were significant at the five percent level. This finding means that policy has little effect on the choice of how deadly to make the terrorist attack. There exist two reasons for this result. First, it is possible that there is too much noise in the number killed variable. This variable might not be as precisely measured as the number of events. First, a small percentage of the values for Number Killed were missing and had to be imputed. Additionally, in order to calculate the true number of individuals killed in an attack, researchers would have to follow news reports for at least several weeks to determine whether or not the victims who are severely wounded recover. Combined, these problems can lead to measurement error, and thus ambiguous results. Additionally, the number of people killed in an attack will be a function of not only the location, but also the timing and method of attack. It is possible that factors other than policies of the targeted governments influence these decisions. Other specifications of the empirical strategy were also considered, but did not yield significant results. First, election years were examined to check for an additional impact 12 The base year for specification is 1968, the first year of the sample 12 on terrorist attacks. The reasoning behind this argument is that when a new government comes to power, there exists some uncertainty about the policies the new government will enact. If this uncertainty exists and terrorists react to policies, than one might expect terrorist attacks to occur in the first year of a newly elected government. However, the election years were never significant. There are two possible reasons for this finding. First, it is possible that terrorist attacks continue occuring with the same frequency because the terrorist organization wants to affect the policy decisions of the new government immediately. Second, given the party that has the majority of the power, it is possible that there is little uncertainty about which policies will be enacted. Finally, terrorist organizations might be more interested in attacking governments that hold extreme views as opposed to moderate ones. A score of zero represents a country that has a moderate stance. Taking the absolute value of each score gives measure of how extreme the country is in that year. The farther the value is from zero, the more extreme the government’s stance on that issue. However, the variables significant under this specification are the same as those significant under the specification from Equation 4. 4.1 Instrumental Variable Approach Currently, the results are possibly all biased given that the the issues are potentially endogenous. This endogeneity would occur because it is possible that given terrorist attacks have occurred in the past, countries elect certain officials who will take strong stances against terrorists in the future. The chosen IV must be correlated with a country’s score on that issue but not correlated with the unexplained portion in the number of terrorist attacks that occur in the country. The best choices probably include economic variables that may explain which parties are in power but are not directly related to the the number of terrorist incidents. A good example of a variable of this sort is the unemployment rate. Since the terror data is transnational, unemployment should not be a direct explanatory variable for the number of terror attacks. However, it is true that the unemployment rate can have a significant impact on whether or not the incumbent government is elected in the future, and thus is strongly related to how the political score changes over time. Additionally, according to Cell [1974] voters often make their decisions on the basis of punishing a government whose policies they did not like instead of voting for the politicians who will maximize their expected utility. Keeping this model of voter behavior in mind, it is reasonable that high unemployment is a characteristic that motivates voters to remove current governments. Data on unemployment rates was gathered from the United Nations Yearly 13 Tables. These tables carried data on unemployment from 1969 through the present. Therefore, 1968 is dropped from the dataset when running the IV specification. However, the unemployment rate by itself is not the best instrument to use for the policy score for several reasons. First, the unemployment rate has the ability to change every time period, while the country’s policy score only changes in an election year. Additionally, unemployment does not predict which parties will be elected to power, but simply whether or not the party currently in power will continue to be in power. When unemployment climbs, the incumbent government is often blamed, and then punished by voters during the next election. Therefore, a potential instrument is an interaction between the policy score and the unemployment rate. The instrument is constructed by interacting the policy score of the incumbent government with the difference between the current unemployment rate and the average unemployment rate since the last election. This instrument is calculated as follows: Instrumenti,t = ( t−1 X 1 U nemploymentj −U nemploymentt )×P olicyScorei,LastElectionY ear n j=LastElection (3) where i represents the policy issue and t represents the year. This equation is calculated in each election year with non-election years receiving the same instrument as the previous year. By examining the average of unemployment since the last time period, voters are taking into consideration any deviations from trend that occured between election years. To check the validity of the instrument, a first stage equations was estimated as follows: P olicyScorei,j,t = δ0 + X δ1 Y eart + t X δ2 Countryj + θInstrumenti,j,t (4) j The results from this first stage can be found in Table 7. However, since the dependent variable is censored, a Two Stage Least Squares approach will not yield consistent estimates. Therefore, either a Maximum Likelihood Estimation (MLE) or a two stage Newey Minimum Chi-squared technique needs to be used. For the results that follow, MLE was performed to yield consistent and efficient estimates. The results using this specification for the instrument can be found in Table 513 . Two policies are significant under both specifications with the instrumental 13 A second specification of the instrumental variables is also calculated. This instrument is chosen by interacting the change in the unemployment rate since the last election with the policy score of the incumbent government. This instrument is calculated as follows: 14 variable. These issues are government ownership of production and secularization of society. The results show that governments who favor ownership of production face fewer terror attacks. In Hamilton and Hamilton (1983) they find that liberal democracies have more terrorist groups in their countries. These findings seem to suggest that liberal democracies also are the site of more terror attacks. One goal of terrorist organizations is to coerce target governments. Additionally, terror attacks evoke fear in society, and can alter the behavior of individuals. In liberal democracies, the attitudes of citizens should be closely mirrored by the officials elected. In other words, citizens have more power to enact change in liberal democracies than in other political frameworks. Therefore, terrorist organizations can best coerce target governments by attacking liberal democracies. Additionally, these findings imply that capitalist countries face more terror attacks. Another goal of terrorist organizations is economic destabilization. In capitalist markets there are many decision makers, as opposed to a single decision maker that emerges when the government controls commodity production. Therefore, it is possible that economic destabilization is more feasible in a country where many people are economic actors. This finding is counter to the theory suggested by Frey and Luechinger (2002) that having a decentralized governments makes the marginal benefit of terror attacks fall. Additionally, secularization of society codes whether or not governments favor monetary support of religious activities or even the establishment of a state religion. The negative point estimate on this variable implies that governments who favor the separation of church and state face fewer terror attacks. It could be that countries with more religious diversity are faced with fewer terrorist attacks from religious terror organizations. This variable also codes whether or not governments support or allow religious schools. Therefore, this variable could be showing that with fewer religious schools, fewer terrorists will come from that region, and thus, fewer attacks will happen in that country. There are several avenues through which this variable could work, and I plan to investigate them using direct measures of religious freedom in the robustness check section of the paper. Finally, two policy issues are significant under only the second instrumental variable specification. First, social welfare has a negative point estimate, implying that governments who favor universal welfare Instrumenti,t = (U nemploymentlastelectionyear − U nemploymentt ) × P olicyScorei,lastelectionyear (5) By computing the difference in current unemployment and previous unemployment the voter is looking at the total change in unemployment during the current administration. Results do not differ too much between the two specifications. I will be adding a table with this specification to the Appendix. 15 face fewer terror attacks. This finding is in line with the finding of Burgoon (2006) even when the analysis has been extended beyond Europe. Finally, the negative point estimate on protection of civil rights means that governments with progressive anti-discrimination policies face fewer terror attacks. Again, this could be true because these governments produce fewer ”home-grown” terrorists, and that could cut back on the number of terror attacks in a country. Approximately one-third of the attacks in the ITERATE database take place in the home country of one of the attackers. Therefore, diminishing the number of home grown terrorists can reduce the number of attacks in a country. The instrumental variable specification was run again after dropping the US from the dataset. The results do not differ from the results on the full dataset. They can be found in Table 6. In order to examine the magnitude of the change in the number of incidents with small changes in policy scores, I calculated the elasticity with respect to each of these issues. Keep in mind that policy scores are coded on the range from -5 to 5 and thus, a 10 percent change in a party score will only move the party score at most 0.5 points from it’s previous point. Elasticity scores were calculated for significant variables under both specifications. Changing the score for government ownership of production by 10 percent leads to a 7 – 17.9 percent change in the number of terror attacks. For the level of secularization in society, the number is a 9.2 percent change in the number of attacks with a 10 percent change in the policy score. Therefore, a 10 percent change in these given policy variables could yield a change in the number of terror attacks by 0.3 – 0.76 attacks in a year. 4.2 Regression Discontinuity Design So far, the policy score of a country has been treated as variable that affects the number of incidents in a uniform and continuous manner. However, it is plausible that the relationship between the policy score and the number of incidents is not uniform. For instance, in the US moving from 40 to 42 percent Democrat is much different than moving from 49 to 51 percent Democrat. Therefore, one should allow for the possibility that at some break point, small changes in the actual policy score of a country can lead to large swings in the potential policies enacted. Regression Discontinuity Design (RDD) will allow me to better capture these complexities. This method fits the data well because the probability of facing additional terrorist incidents changes discontinuously with the policy score of a country. The first order of business is choosing the cut-off score for each policy issue. As a first pass at this problem, I allowed the break point to be equal to the median score for that issue of all the political parties in Janda’s book. Countries with a policy score above the median political party will 16 recieve a 1 while 0 will be coded for all other countries. Then, the following equation will be estimated: X X N umberof Incidentsj,t = α+ηAboveM ediani,j,t +βIssuei,j,t + δj Countryj + γt Y eart +i,j,t j t (6) where j represents the targeted country, t represents the year of the attack, and i represents the issue being analyzed. Therefore η represents the change in intercept that occurs when the average party in a country is more in favor of government action on Issuei than the median party in the sample. Results from this estimation can be found in Table 6. In a Tobit framework, this dummy variable is signification for two policy scores: social welfare and protection of civil rights. The point estimate for the actual issue scores is negative for both of these variables, meaning that governments who favor action on these policies face fewer terror attacks. However, the point estimate for η is positive for these policies. For instance, governments in favor of protecting civil rights experience fewer terror attacks. This result is expected, as can be seen in Table 4. However, when a country’s policy score on civil rights rises, we see a fall in terror incidents until the country score for civil rights climbs above the median score. Then, we see a one time jump in the number of terror incidents. This blip is abated if the policy score for protection of civil rights continues to rise, since the point estimate on the slope parameter is negative. Again, it is important to correct for endogeniety using an instrumental variable approach and Maximum Likelihood Estimation. The same interaction between the unemployment rate since the last election and the policy score of a country during its last election will be utilized as an instrument for Issue again. The results from this estimation can be found in Table 6. While the point estimates on Issue are quite similar to those under a continuous instrumental variable approach, the dummy variable that allows for a discontinuous effect of issue scores on number of incidents is statistically significant under three different policy scores: government ownership of production, government role in economic planning, and secularization of society. As expected, an increase in the score for government ownership of production leads to a reduction the number of terror attacks. However, when a country’s average score outstrips the median party score, a one time jump in the number of terror attacks occurs. In order for the overall downward trend to offset this effect, the policy score for government ownership of production would have to be 1.45 points higher than the median score. An increased score on government role in economic planning has a negative, but 17 imprecise, relationship with the number of terrorist incidents. Therefore, when the average score for government role in economic planning climbs above the median score, there is a persistent negative shock to the number of terror attacks. The negative relationship between an increased government role in economic planning and the number of terrorist incidents is expected since economic destabilization is more easily achieved. Finally, similar to the IV approach countries more in favor of state sponsored religion face fewer terror attacks. However, when a country crosses the median score threshold, they should experience a one time increase in the number of terror attacks. In order for the overall downward trent to offset this effect, the policy score for secularization of society must be 1.34 points higher than the median score. This section provided some evidence that the underlying relationship between policy scores and the number of terrorist incidents is not continuous over the entire distribution of policy scores. Therefore, regression discontinuity design is an appropriate technique to deal with these issues. However, while RDD did provide evidence of a discontinuous relationship between the two variables, the overall results of the estimation did not change drastically. Therefore, RDD simply provided a better understanding of how the variables are related. In the future, different specifications of the breakpoint for RDD will be examined. 4.3 Robustness Checks Since the results above were obtained on a limited sample set, it is prudent to test the robustness on the full sample of observations. Therefore, I will use more direct measures of the variables found to be significant to determine the mechanism through which they affect the number of terrorist attacks. To directly measure the level of secularization in society, I will use estimates of the number of religions represented by at least 10 percent of the population, along with other measures of religious practice. I believe these more direct measures offer a suitable check since the parameters can be estimated on the full model. Additionally, the direct measures enable us to check the implementation of policy instead of just the political leanings of the governing body. In order to test for the level of secularization in society, I gathered information on the different religions represented within the population of each country. Unfortunately, this information is not available for each year of my sample. Currently, I have gathered data from 2001. I plan to run the regressions in two ways. I will examine both the total number of attacks in a country in relation to the religious composition in 2001 and I will also run the tests using only the number of attacks in that country in 2001. In the meantime, I plan 18 to supplement the data with religious composition in additional years. The regression will take the following form: N umberof Incidentsj = α + βReligiousP racticej + j,t (7) where j represents the country. The level of religious practice will also be measured in several different ways. First, the number of religions represented by more than 10 percent of the population and the total number of religions represented in a country will be counted. These variables will capture the level of religious diversity in a country. Additionally, both the percentage of people who are coded as nonreligious and the percentage of citizens who practice new religions will be utilized as independent variables. A measure of the percentage of people who are not religous can relay how important religion is in the daily actions of the government. The percentage of people practicing new religions could show how open the country is to new religious ideas, and thus also captures a type of religious freedom. The results from each of these regressions can be seen in Table 8. Two of the variables are significant at the five percent level in this robustness check. Those two variables were the total number of religions and the number of religions represented by at least 10 percent of the population. The point estimate on the total number of religions is positive, implying that countries with more religions represented within their population have more terror attacks. However, the point estimate on the number of religions represented by at least 10 percent of the population was negative. At a first glance, these estimations appear to be at odds with each other. So an additional specification was run as follows: N umberof Incidentsj = α + βT otalReligionsj + ηOver10P ercentj + j,t (8) The point estimates are similar in this specification, as can be seen in Table 8. Therefore, it is not just having a broad range of religions represented that can reduce terrorism. Instead, it is having a population that actively practice different religions, where no one religion is strictly dominant, that reduces terrorism. In other words, countries with some equality in the number of followers across several religions face fewer terrorist attacks. This fits with the results found earlier, that countries with no state religion face fewer terror attacks. It would be interesting to examine if this result is driven by the number of attacks carried out by religious terror organizations. 19 5 Future Work The question of this paper, whether the policies put into place by a countries leaders effect the number of terrorist attacks that country faces, can easily be asked in reverse. In other words, it would be interesting to explore whether experiencing terrorist attacks can affect the leaders who citizens will elect in the future. People have hypothesized that terrorists do consider the timing of elections when planning their attacks. For instance, many people believe that the Madrid bombings in 2004 affected the outcome of the election. Therefore, it would be interesting to discover if the targets react to these attacks in the way that terrorists expect. Again, an instrumental variable approach would need to be taken in order to reduce endogeneity because of reverse causation. In this case, the IV will have to be a variable that is related to terrorist attacks in a target country but does not explain which parties are elected in the targeted countries. Additionally, the enaction of policy and terror attacks could be happening through simultaneous processes. Therefore, another planned extension is to delve into the interplay between the enaction of policy and the timing of terrorist attacks using a simultaneous equations model. Using this simultaneous equations model, I will be able to better estimate how each of these variables effects the other on a longer time horizon. Finally, the fact that secularization of society is a significant issue can raise future research questions. Mainstream media has introduced the argument that secular schools have the potential of creating future terrorists14 . This line of argument is addressed in Krueger and Maleckova (2003). The authors find that terrorists in the Middle East are actually more educated than the rest of the population in their home countries. However, they have no way of coding whether or not individuals go to radical religious schools. Therefore, there is no information on the type of education the terrorists are receiving. Using the coding from Janda, I can determine in what years countries favor the establishment, and even funding, of religious schools. Then, I can examine how support for religious schools in a country correlates with both the number of terror organizations active in the country and the number of active terrorists from that country. While this research would not perfectly address the concerns raised in Kruger and Maleckova, it could help determine the role of religious education in fostering future terrorists. 14 US News and World Report article title ”An Education on Muslim Integration” 20 6 Conclusion The goal of this paper was to answer whether the political orientation of the leadership of a country determines its likelihood of being targeted by terrorist attacks. The motivation for this project was threefold: to build on previous literature discussing which countries are targeted most often, to determine which policies are important to terrorist organizations, and to understand the mechanism through which terrorists choose their targets. First, the previous literature in the field found that terrorist organizations are more likely to target democracies with suicide bombings and less likely to target governments with strong social welfare policies. This paper built on that work examining how terrorist attacks were related to 12 different policy issues. Additionally, this study encompassed a larger geographical area than most previous studies. The countries involved in the analysis were chosen from a random sample stratified by geography with countries from each continent represented. Finally, in addition to a cross country sample, the observations also cover a time period from 1968–2004, with the end result being a rich panel dataset from which to draw conclusions. The second goal of this paper was to determine which policies are important to terrorist organizations in picking their targets. Since Janda’s sample covered political party stances on 12 different issues, countries in this sample received orientation scores for each of the twelve issues in each year of the sample. Since the regressions were run on each issue separately, we were able to determine how each issue affects the likelihood of an event. Two issues were determined to be significant in explaining the number of terrorist attacks. These issues were: government ownership of production and secularization of society. Additionally, small changes in policy scores on these issues lead to large changes in the number of incidents a country faces. A 10 percent change in any of these policy scores could influence the number of terror attacks in a country by anywhere between 0.3 and 0.76 attacks in a given year. Finally, the third goal was to uncover information about the mechanism through which terrorist organizations choose their targets. A robustness check on the full dataset revealed that countries with multiple religions represented by at least 10 percent of the population are the target of fewer terrorist attacks. Additionally, further analysis of the data revealed that the relationship between a country’s policy score and the number of terror incidents that country faces is not continuous. Future robostness checks will be performed to unveil the mechanism through which policy and terror attacks are related. 21 References Alberto Abadie and Javier Gardeazabal. The economic costs of conflict: A case study of the basque country. American Economic Review, 93(1):113–132, March 2003. Daniel Arce and Todd Sandler. Counterterrorism: A game theoretic analysis. Journal of Conflict Resolution, pages 183–200, April 2005. Daniel Arce and Todd Sandler. An evolutionary game approach to fundamentalism and conflict. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, March 2003. JoAnna Birnir. The paradox of political terrorism in democracy and institutional alternatives. 2006. Brian Burgoon. On welfare and terror. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 50(2):176–203, 2006. Donald C. Cell. Policy influence without policy choice. Journal of Political Economy, 82(5): 1017–1026, 1974. Konstantinos Drakos and Ali M. Kutan. Regional effects of terrorism on tourism in three mediterranean countries. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 47(5):621–641, October 2003. Bruno S. Frey and Simon Luechinger. Terrorism: Deterrence may backfire. URL http://search.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstracti d = 359823. 2002. Lawrence C. Hamilton and James D. Hamilton. Dynamics of terrorism. International Studies Quarterly, 27(1):299–305, March 1983. Matthew Hanson and Martin Schmidt. The impact of coalition offensive operations on the iraqi insurgency. 2007. James J. Heckman. Sample selection bias as a specification error. Econometrica, 47(1): 153–162, January 1979. Kenneth Janda. Political Parties: A Cross National Survery. The Free Press, New York, 1980. Alan Krueger and Jitka Maleckova. Education, poverty, and terrorism: Is there a causal connection? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17(4):119–144, 2003. Harvey E. Lapan and Todd Sandler. To bargain or not to bargain: That is the question. American Economic Review, 78(2):16–21, May 1988. 22 Edward F. Mickolus, Todd Sandler, Jean M. Murdock, and Peter A. Flemming. International Terrorism: Atrributes of Terrorist Events Data Codebook, July 2002. Robert Pape. The strategic logic of suicide terrorism. American Political Science Review, 97:343–361, 2003. Daniele Paserman and David A. Jeager. Israel, the palestinian factions and the cycle of violence. American Economic Review, 96(2):45–49, May 2006. Todd Sandler and Walter Enders. The Political Economy of Terrorism. Cambridge University Press, Boston, 2005. Todd Sandler and Kevin Siqueira. Global terrorism: Deterrence versus preemption. URL http://gemini.econ.umd.edu/cgi-bin/conference/download.cgi?dbn ame = lasm2003paperi d = 64. 2003. Alex Schmid and Albert Jongman. Political Terrorism: A New Guide to Actors, Authors, Concepts, Data Bases, Theories, and Literature. Transaction Books, Amsterdam, 1988. D. Thistlethwaite and D. Campbell. Regression-discontinuity analysis: An alternative to the ex post facto experiment. Journal of Educational Psychology, 51:309–317, 1960. Jeffre M. Wooldridge. Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data. The MIT Press, cambridge, Massachusetts, 2002. 23 A Missing Data Problems with missing data occured in both the terrorism and political data. Below I will discuss how I dealt with these issues. First, there were about 200 (or less than two percent of the sample) attack observations that had an unknown country as the location of attack. These observations were dropped from the dataset. In the future I hope to be able to add some of these observations back into my dataset by utilizing news stories from the day of the attack. Once these observations are dropped, I have a full dataset of event counts in each country in each year because each entry is now an observation of a terrorist event. However, I was also interested in measuring how the political orientation can affect the intensity of attacks, so a measure of fatalities as a dependent variable was also necessary. For about 100 observations the number killed in the attack was unknown. While this represents a very small portion of my final sample, dropping these observations is not advisable in case the reason they were missing data was not random. In some cases, dropping these observations would mean dropping the only terrorist attack that occured in that location in that year. For some of the observations, the number killed could be gleaned from news reports15 . For the remaining observations with missing data, I examined what was known about each of these attacks. For each of these datapoints, full information on the year, country, and type of attack was available16 . Therefore, using full dataset to run a Tobit model where number killed was a function of these three characteristics, I was able to impute the number killed in each of the attacks with missing data. Missing data was a larger problem with the political party data. Janda’s sample covers almost 200 political parties and 12 different issues. About 1/3 of the parties in his sample have a score for every issue. Additionally, 1/2 of the parties have a score for at least 11 issues. For analysis, it will be favorable for each party to have a score for each issue. However, it is not prudent to give a party missing a score on one issue the average score of that issue. For instance, assume that the issue is government ownership of production and the score is missing for a communist party. The average score for this issue is approximately 0.50, implying that the country is moderate, with only a slight disposition towards government ownership of production. This assumption would likely be incorrect. Therefore a new system for imputing scores must be developed. Using the countries with scores for every issue, we can determine how the issues are related to each other. In this 15 The events of 9/11/2001 had missing values for number killed. I pulled the total number killed used in this study from the US State Department 16 Type of attack refers to whether it was a bombing, suicide attack, kidnapping, etc. 24 system, we run a regression where Issue i is a function of the other 11 issues such that Issuei = f (Issue−i ). The equations had R2 ranging from 0.15 to 0.77 and usually at least four of the other issues were statistically significant at the five percent level. These equations were then used to impute the missing scores. However, since approximately half of the parties were missing scores for at least two issues, these equations will need to be tweaked. For instance, assume that two issues (A and B) are missing the issue orientation score. For a party missing these two scores, in order to compute the value of the missing score for issue A I used the average of score B as a proxy for score B in the equation. Thus, the equation now looks like: n 1X IssueA = α + β IssueB + f (Issuec−l ) n i=1 (9) In the future, I am interested in calculating these missing values more precisely17 . In order to do so, I plan on repeating the process described above to solve for score A and B, but using the values of scores A and B calculated from the above equations in the previous period instead of using an average. This process would be repeated until the missing scores converged to their ”true” value. For the scores to converge to a true value, the parameters in the equation must be on the interval (-1,1), which they all are. While missing data is an issue in this project, imputing the scores is a better solution than dropping the observations completely, because it is possible that there is a systematic reason for why some of the data is missing. B Check for Underreporting Even though the results show that countries with lower civil liberties experience fewer terrorist attacks, there are reasons to doubt the validity of that assessment. Since the terrorism data comes from news reports, it is possible that countries with low civil liberties are better able to keep terrorist attacks out of the media. In The Political Economy of Terrorism, Sandler and Enders argue that utilizing event counts is the best way to overcome the bias from 17 Likewise, in order to compute the value of the missing score for Issue B, I used the average of score A as a proxy for score A in the equation in the following manner: n IssueB = αb + βb 1X IssueA + g(Issuec−l ) n i=1 25 (10) underreporting in countries with low civil liberties. Their argument is that event counts work better than studies that look at active terrorist groups because it is harder for the media to hide an attack than it is for the government to hide a group. However, I was still interested in determining if underreporting was a large issue in this dataset. In order to test for underreporting, I extend the argument made by Sandler and Enders. Countries with low civil liberties will not be able to hide an event that was actually carried out as planned as easily as they would be able to hide an attack that was thwarted, either in the planning or execution stage. The ITERATE dataset has a variable that codes each attack as a tactical success (6) or failure (0) from the point of view of the terrorist organization. According to my hypothesis, if there is underreporting of terrorist attacks in countries with low civil liberties, than the relationship between logistic success and civil liberties should be positive and significant. Since ITERATE codes tactical success on a 0–6 scale, it is practical to use an ordered probit to estimate the relationship between success and civil liberties. However, to use an ordered probit, the underlying distribution of the tactical success variables must be uniformly distributed. The vast majority of the events were tactical successes, thus skewing the underlying distribution. However, if we look only at events that were not complete tactical successes (on the 0–5 range) then the distribution more closely fits. Since it is difficult not to report an attack that takes place, it is reasonable to drop those observations when determining if underreporting bias exists. In other words, underreporting probably does not exist on events that actually took place. The results show that the civil liberties parameter is positive and significant at the 10 percent level. Hence, our positive coefficient implies that countries with more censorship are likely to have underreporting of terrorist attacks that were not carried out successfully; however, the precision attached to this estimate is low. Therefore, to test the robustness of these results, I ran two more specifications of this equation. First, instead of running an ordered probit, I ran a simple logit where 1 represents a completely successful attack and 0 represents any attack that is not carried out as the terrorists’ planned. Second, I ran an ordered logit after combining some of ITERATE’s specifications. I assigned a 0 to any attack that was stopped in the planning stages according to their system; a 1 to any attack that was carried out with errors or thwarted in the execution stage; and a 2 to any attack that was carried out successfully. These two specifications both yielded no statistically significant relationship between civil liberties and tactical success, implying that there is not underreporting bias in the dataset. From analyzing the results of these three specifications, we can assume that while underreporting might be a problem, it 26 is likely not a large problem. It is possible to find rankings of countries civil liberties. Freedom house is an agency that measures the level of civil liberties in a country on a 1–7 scale each year. Unfortunately, these measures do not cover the same time period as the terrorism sample. If these freedom scores could be ascertained for the time period of the sample, then the regressions can be run separately for each category of civil liberties. Then, any changes in the parameters of interest between regressions can be tied to a possible difference in reporting in these countries. Additionally, a nested regression can yeild similar results. These are options to investigate in the future to further discover how prevelant underreporting is in this dataset. 27 Albania Table 1: Countries in Janda Burkina Faso, Upper Volta Australia Burma Austria Congo-Brazzaville Bulgaria East Germany Cambodia Ghana Canada Indonesia Central African Republic Iran Chad Lebanon Cuba Malaysia Denmark Portugal Dominican Republic Sudan Ecuador Togo El Salvador France Greece Guatemala Guinea Hungary Iceland India Ireland Kenya Luxembourg Netherlands New Zealand Nicaragua Paraguay Peru Sweden Tunisia Turkey Uganda United Kingdom United States Uruguay USSR (Russia) Venezuela 28 Table 2: Descriptive Statistics Mean Mean |Incident Number of Incidents 1.379 5.48 Total Killed 1.813 7.203 Total Wounded 3.674 14.596 Country Incidents Table 3: Top 10 Countries Country Killed Country Lebanon 847 United States 3100 United States 4565 United States 701 Lebanon 1310 Israel 3726 (West) Germany 666 Iraq 938 Iraq 2457 United Kingdom 665 Israel 836 United Kingdom 2317 France 639 USSR (Russia) 678 Lebanon 1895 Columbia 467 Angola 477 USSR (Russia) 1285 Greece 413 Columbia 473 France 1270 Argentina 390 Pakistan 376 Saudi Arabia 1191 Italy 383 Kenya 278 Pakistan 1137 Israel 348 Cambodia 276 (West) Germany 1015 29 Wounded Table 4: Hypotheses - Incidents will Increase with Changes in Policy of Predicted Sign Policy Positive Estimate Negative Estimate Govt Prod With many economic actors, economic destabalization is more easily achieved. Govt Econ With many economic actors, economic Plan destabalization is more easily achieved. Redistribute High income inequality could lead to a dis- Wealth affected portion of the population turning to terrorism. Social Welfare Secular Soci- Religious terror organizations from a mi- Those in the majority religion could rebel ety nority party could rebel against state con- against allowing for a separation of church trol of the majority religion and state. Electoral Par- Attacks against democracies are more suc- Former political groups might turn to ter- ticipation cessful because voters are afraid of fu- ror as a way for their voices to be heard. ture attacks and have the ability to enact changes in policies. Support Mili- Countries with strong militaries have Countries with strong militaries are better tary more bases abroad, which might upset ter- able to deter against attacks, and would ror organizations. be better prepared to retaliate. Anticolonialism Subordinate countries employ terrorism Rogue elements of subordinate countries to gain independence. could turn to terrorism to undermine the acceptance of the colonial power. Suprantional Joining these unions can be seen as either Integration ”westernizing” or trying to spread one’s influence, which could in turn upset terror organizations. National Inte- Minority groups could be left out fo the gration political process, thus inducing them to resort to terror. Protect Civil Minority groups who feel discriminated Rights against could resort to terror. Interfere Lib- People want to rebel against governments Terror attacks are harder to carry about erties that infringe upon their civil liberties. because there is less free exchange of information. 30 Govt Prod Table 5: Results - Number of Incidents Tobit Estimates IV Estimates 2 Estimate Constant Adj R Estimate Constant -1.553∗∗ 13.660 0.1458 -15.509∗∗ -19.370 (0.546) Govt Econ Plan -0.650 (5.007) 16.905 0.1444 16.425 0.1470 17.677 0.1447 (0.716) Redistribute Wealth -2.079∗∗ -1.053 -0.319 0.368 16.138 0.1443 -0.252 14.850 0.1443 -1.585∗ 17.644 0.1443 15.896 0.1450 19.419 0.1456 -0.818 -0.628 16.419 0.1444 0.487 -10.099 10.263 -46.465 -10.369 -0.083 -0.589 3.951 -36.810 10.810 (35.801) 18.629 0.1446 17.588 0.1405 (0.437) Interfere Liberties 3.135 (3.951) (0.774) Protect Civil Rights -25.489 (12.190) (0.512) National Integration -30.457∗∗ (8.564) (0.825) Suprantional Integration 1.325∗∗ 9.949 (9.839) (0.458) Anticolonialism -3.299 (6.806) (0.408) Support Military 4.618 (4.956) (0.561) Electoral Participation -0.854 (3.185) (0.708) Secular Society 12.425 (4.678) (0.560) Social Welfare -7.316 -7.215 29.515 (4.965) (0.463) -11.616 (10.504) 31 -23.095 Govt Prod Table 6: Results - Number of Incidents US Dropped Tobit Estimates IV Estimates Estimate Constant Adj R2 Estimate Constant -1.471∗∗ 15.242 0.1474 -6.070∗∗ 2.079 (0.512) Govt Econ Plan -1.210∗ (1.872) 16.083 0.1463 17.027 0.1489 (0.659) Redistribute Wealth -2.002∗∗ -1.510∗∗ -0.505 21.112 0.1447 0.368 14.332 0.1456 12.019 0.1458 -0.338 15.411 0.1457 -1.597∗∗ 17.795 0.1466 0.363 15.979 0.1467 -.354 13.824 0.1456 15.578 0.1458 0.318 -28.164 Not Concave — -1.844 5.567 -.684 3.414 15.527 0.1416 -5.569 10.545 (3.573) (0.399) Interfere Liberties 6.496 (3.539) (0.709) Protect Civil Rights -26.007 (1.883) (0.469) National Integration -30.157∗∗ (—) (0.751) Suprantional Integration 1.057∗∗ 7.230 (16.999) (0.417) Anticolonialism -0.916 (8.213) (0.408) Support Military 4.684 (1.159) (0.522) Electoral Participation -0.777 (2.304) (0.645) Secular Society 13.364 (4.076) (0.509) Social Welfare -6.563 -7.615 8.870 (4.965) (0.422) -5.888 (5.663) 32 -12.321 Govt Prod Table 7: Results - First Stage Estimation Instrument Constant Country Year 0.0179∗ ∗ ∗ -1.624 Yes Yes Adj R2 0.9563 (0.0034) Govt Econ Plan 0.0634∗ ∗ ∗ 0.805 Yes Yes 0.9563 -0.104 Yes Yes 0.9090 1.176 Yes Yes 0.9298 -1.131 Yes Yes 0.9635 4.022 Yes Yes 0.9146 5.010 Yes Yes 0.9605 -0.329 Yes Yes 0.9470 -2.251 Yes Yes 0.8762 -0.216 Yes Yes 0.9551 3.303 Yes Yes 0.9721 -1.872 Yes Yes 0.9559 (0.0030) Redistribute Wealth 0.0308∗ ∗ ∗ (0.0041) Social Welfare 0.0122∗ ∗ ∗ (0.0026) Secular Society 0.0151∗ ∗ ∗ (0.0027) Electoral Participation -0.0045∗∗ (0.0022) Support Military -0.0091∗∗ (0.0032) Anticolonialism 0.0066∗∗ (0.0027) Suprantional Integration 0.0184 (0.0041) National Integration 0.0028 (0.0020) Protect Civil Rights 0.0098∗ ∗ ∗ (0.0022) Interfere Liberties 0.0067 (0.0023) 33 Govt Prod Govt Econ Plan Constant Above Median Issue Estimate Country-Year Adj R2 -0.674 -0.656 -1.464∗∗ Yes 0.1458 -2.982 Redistribute Wealth -62.559 Social Welfare 1.387 Secular Society -6.221 Electoral Participation Support Military Anticolonialism -5.077 -6.094 -0.935 Suprantional Integration -22.710 National Integration Protect Civil Rights Interfere Liberties -9.027 -7.311 -64.210 (2.467) (0.655) 1.286 -0.820 (3.262) (0.836) 0.730 -2.178 (—) (—) 5.444∗∗ -1.712∗∗ (2.751) (0.776) -1.766 -0.083 (2.712) (0.670) -1.346 0.698 (2.471) (0.834) -3.199 0.311 (2.211) (0.601) -0.094 -1.574∗ (2.631) (0.871) -1.697 1.749∗∗ (2.348) (0.779) 1.237 0.404 (2.499) (1.138) 5.629∗∗ -1.261∗∗ (2.720) (0.532) 1.879 0.201 (—) (—) 34 Yes 0.1444 Yes 0.1470 Yes 0.1455 Yes 0.1444 Yes 0.1444 Yes 0.1447 Yes 0.1450 Yes 0.1457 Yes 0.1445 Yes 0.1455 Yes 0.1406 Constant Above Median Issue Estimate Country-Year -3.147 32.991∗∗ -22.195∗∗ Yes Govt Prod Govt Econ Plan 12.513 Redistribute Wealth 4.437 Social Welfare 6.505 Secular Society Electoral Participation -44.868 -2.307 Support Military -5.488 Anticolonialism -5.632 Suprantional Integration 2.824 National Integration 6.886 Protect Civil Rights 21.652 Interfere Liberties 195.643 (11.750) (7.594) -17.041∗∗ -7.511 (7.165) (4.614) 0.879 -1.026 (7.709) (4.673) 13.161 7.984 (11.490) (7.984) 66.883∗∗ -49.161∗∗ (19.210) (14.232) -4.389 2.454 (15.780) (7.299) -11.922 4.486 (7.915) (0.4.326) 35.184 -20.628 (41.112) (24.631) 2.977 -1.042 (8.456) (5.189) 16.808 -18.760 (12.331) (14.201) 8.746 -7.477 (7.811) (5.151) -185.636 82.843 (364.840) (162.232) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Table 8: Robustness Check - Secularization of Society Num over 10 Percent Total Religions Nonreligious New Religions Constant Estimate -0.811∗∗ 3.284 0.0209 (0.383) Estimate 0.365∗∗ 0.450 0.0408 (0.139) Estimate 0.013 1.962 0.009 (0.034) Estimate -0.047 2.060 0.0016 (0.092) Estimate -0.938∗∗ (0.377) R2 0.404∗∗ 1.732 0.0763 (0.138) 35