1 Go Forth and Multiply: The Effect of Religion on Family Size By Livio Di Matteo Department of Economics Lakehead University Thunder Bay, Ontario P7B 5E1 Paper Prepared for the Meetings of the Canadian Economic Association, June 6-8, University of British Columbia, Vancouver, Canada DRAFT: NOT FOR QUOTATION 2 ABSTRACT Go Forth and Multiply: The Effect of Religion on Family Size The influence of religion on family size in late nineteenth/early twentieth century Ontario is examined using a set of 7,156 census-linked probated decedents. Religion can directly shape values and attitudes towards fertility as well as provide social contacts and networks that encourage child bearing. As well, religion can indirectly affect wealth and fertility because of differences towards fertility, childrearing and education. A simple model of children in an old age security framework is presented, which is then translated into a reduced form econometric model with a comprehensive set of variables including religious affiliation. While empirical studies using historical Canadian micro-data have found only a weak relationship between religious affiliation and the number of children, these results find statistically significant relationships. However, they do not fall into the “liberal-conservative” divide of other North American studies suggesting that the effect of religion on family size and fertility is considerably more complex. 3 Go Forth and Multiply: The Effect of Religion on Family Size By Livio Di Matteo1 Introduction There is a growing literature demonstrating the importance of religion on economic behaviour and performance. In a comprehensive survey of the economics of religion, Laurence Iannaccone (1998) classifies work on the economics of religion into three areas: 1) the analysis of religious behaviour from an economic perspective 2) the economic consequences of religion and 3) the use of theological literature to criticize economics and policies. This paper is in the tradition of the second area and examines the influence of religion on fertility and by extension, family size in late nineteenth/early twentieth century Ontario using a set of 7,156 census-linked probated decedents. Most economic models of fertility and family size divide into those viewing children as investment goods and those that view them as consumer goods with little attention paid to the influence of other factors such as culture and religion. This paper presents a simple model of children in an old age security framework as inputs into old age support via bequests. This is then translated into an econometric model with a comprehensive set of confounding variables including religious affiliation. While empirical studies using historical Canadian micro-data have found a weak 1 The assistance of the Social Sciences and Humanities Research Council is gratefully acknowledged. 4 relationship between religious affiliation and the number of children, this paper finds statistically significant relationships. The classic thesis linking religion and economic performance is of course the Weber Thesis2 or Protestant Ethic Thesis which argues that the Protestant Reformation and the Protestant work ethic triggered the advent of modern capitalism and resulted in economic growth and development in Protestant societies outpacing Catholic ones.3 As a revolt against Catholic tradition, Protestantism emphasized free thought and rationality as an approach to life and supposedly helped foster wealth accumulation, profit seeking and economic growth.4 Adam Smith’s work also provides a perspective on religion’s economic impact as a device whereby individuals enhance the value of their human capital and ultimately their wealth and income.5 Smith viewed moral reputation as having a capital value and religious affiliation distributed information about the “moral character” of an individual that helped assess the potential riskiness of transactions. By providing “valuable, reliable information concerning the level of risk attached to dealings with particular individuals, religious sects both benefit their members in a tangible way and also improve the efficiency of the allocation of human resources.”6 The character of an individual could also be reflected in other lifestyle decisions such as the decision to raise a family and the number of children. Provided such differences exist, they should be reflected in differences in the number of children and their relationship to economic variables across religious groupings. See Engerman (2000). Weber (1930). 4 A substantial literature seeking to verify or refute the Weber Thesis has arisen over time.See Tawney (1926), Samuelsson (1993), Delacroix (1995), Landes (1998), Baskerville (2001), Di Matteo (2007). 5 Anderson (1988). 6 Anderson (1988: 1072). 2 3 5 Keister (2003) argues that religion can affect economic behaviour through direct and indirect effects. Religion can directly shape values and attitudes towards wealth accumulation as well as provide social contacts and networks that facilitate accumulation. As well, religion can indirectly affect wealth because of differences generated towards fertility, childrearing and education all of which can affect wealth. For modern Canada, Tomes (1985, 1983) and Meng and Sentence (1984) examine the influence of religion on earnings and the rate of return to human capital using Canadian Census data and find that human capital returns to Protestants exceeded those of Catholics and Jewish males earned more than other religious-ethnic groups. Again, one might expect that these differences could also affect family formation and fertility. In the case of more direct relationships between religious behaviour and fertility, Leasure (1982) uses the share of church seats held by various denominations in a geographic area to show that religious liberalization was a factor in reducing fertility in nineteenth century America. Liberal denominations such as Presbyterians and Quakers held more progressive thoughts with respect to family size as opposed to conservative or hierarchical religions such as Baptists, and were associated with fertility decline.7 Conservative and hierarchical faiths were more likely to suppress ideas of individual empowerment and stressed contraception and fertility limitation as tampering with God’s “be fruitful-andmultiply mandate.”8 Hacker (1999) using 1880 and 1850 IPUMS data finds that parents in nineteenth century America with a lower proportion of biblically named children also tended to have smaller families. The tendency to provide biblical names to children is interpreted as evidence of stricter adherence to religious teachings on fertility. 7 According to Haan (2005) conservative faiths include Anglicans, Baptists, Episcopalians, Lutherans, Mennonites, Methodists and Roman Catholics. Liberal faiths include Congregationalists, Presbyterians, Quakers and Unitarians. 8 Haan (2005: 380). 6 Fertility and Family Size in Economic History: Theoretical Approaches and Empirical Results The micro-economic approach to household behaviour, fertility and family size was pioneered by Gary Becker and yields demand functions for children as a function of price and income variables.9 The vast literature on the economic determinants of fertility subdivides into two broad approaches – one which views children as consumption goods and the other as investment or capital goods with the latter approach placing children in the role of old age support providers.10 In traditional societies, the investment motive dominated with dependence on children for old-age security a common feature of developing countries in both the nineteenth and twentieth centuries. Children in colonial North America enabled land to yield a productive return and this economic dependence on family labour provided parents with the "incentive to employ the promise of an inheritance as a control device to extract labour from their children and to ensure that their children would care for them in old age."11 The old-age security motive for fertility is commonly found in economies with underdeveloped capital markets, uncertainty about the accumulation of assets necessary for old age, absence or inefficiency of private or public old-age income security programs, confidence in the loyalty of children to their parents and the absence of well developed labour markets for women and children.12 These were all features of the 18th and early 19th century colonial North American economy. See Becker (1960, 1965); Becker and Lewis (1973). See Nerlove et. Al (1987); Fulop (1977); Shultz (1974). 11 Ransom and Sutch (1986a, 18). See also Ransom and Sutch (1986b). 9 10 12 Nugent (1985, 75-97). 7 Sundstrom and David also observed that rational parents have an incentive to raise large families because a large number of children competing for attention strengthens bargaining with respect to any one of them.13 The inheritance aimed to provide offspring with their start in life and accords with the assumption in Easterlin’s work that a farmer "seeks to provide a start in life for each of his offspring at least as good as that which his father gave to him."14 The probated decedents of nineteenth century Ontario manifested many of these characteristics of the bequest motive. Wills commonly specified the services that children were to provide for the surviving spouse and attached penalties if the deceased's wishes were not complied with.15 There is a small empirical literature on the determinants of fertility and family size in both English and French Canada. Henripin (1972) presents the classic account with estimates of macro fertility decline in Canada during the 19th and 20th centuries. McInnis (1991) uses aggregate data to examine the nineteenth century Ontario fertility decline and concludes the scarcity of paid employment outside the home made extended spinsterhood unappealing and led to the acceptance of limiting marital fertility, but does not discuss the impact of religion. 13 Sundstrom and David (1988, 166-97). 14 Easterlin (1976, 65). For example, Phillip Gage (WC #3369, 1892), a farmer, bequeathed all of his real and personal estate to his widow Mary Ann for the maintenance of herself and the children. However, he explicitly stated that: "...no child shall be entitled to such maintenance who refuses to reside with his or her mother on the Homestead farm and render such service as he or she may be capable of in the work of the house and cultivation of the land." Payment of an inheritance after the death of his widow stipulated that the children have complied with the widow's interests. (The term in brackets is a reference to the probated decedent in the probate records. It is to be read as Wentworth County Will number 1753, 1892.) 15 8 Denton and George (1970, 1973) apply cross-sectional regression techniques to a 1871 census sample of 1,100 families in Wentworth county and found demographic and urban-rural factors to be significant determinants of family size. However, occupation, religion, birthplace and ethnic origin were found to be relatively weak determinants. More recently, Haan (2005) uses a 20 percent sample of the 1881 Census of Canada and regresses fertility on age, geographic, employment, birthplace and religious variables and finds that the addition of religious variables did not contribute much to the overall fit of the models though many individual co-efficients were significant. He therefore concludes that: “the centrality of religion in the fertility transition should be called into question.”16 A Simple Model of Family Size Determination Utility maximizing individuals are assumed to live for two periods and their utility is a function of consumption across two periods.17 Utility is represented by the function U=U(C1, C2) where C1 and C2 are first and second period consumption. An endowment is available in the first period only and therefore second period consumption occurs by transferring resources across time. In the case of a world with a bequest motive, we assume that provision for second period consumption requires an agent sacrifice current consumption to acquire a wealth bequest to be passed on to offspring in return for old age support. Accumulated wealth becomes an input into the "production" of children who then provide second period consumption. An increase in total wealth results in more children and therefore greater second period consumption as depicted in Figure I. 16 Haan (2005: 405). The model that follows builds on work done by Neher (1971) and Sundstrom and David (1988). Sundstrom and David develop a model to illustrate the impact of expanding labour market opportunities on the value of children. They in turn rely on work by Neher who examined the impact of the introduction of a financial asset on old age security and fertility. 17 9 The diagram in Figure I consists of four quadrants. In the first quadrant are the individual economic agent's preferences represented by indifference curves and the intertemporal consumption opportunities frontier (ICOF). The ICOF transforms consumption across time periods. Utility is maximized where the ICOF is tangent to the highest attainable indifference curves. The ICOF is derived via quadrants II-IV. Point X is the endowment point. If C1= X, then there is no surplus above first period consumption to devote to wealth accumulation for bequest purposes. When first period consumption is less than the endowment, resources are released which are saved as wealth rather than consumed. We assume a linear relationship between C1 and the accumulated wealth, which implies constant marginal costs of wealth accumulation. In the third quadrant, the acquired bequest becomes an input into the "child production function". If we assume that the goal is to provide each child with an equal target bequest, then as the accumulated bequest rises, so should the number of children. However, because of fertility limitations, the number of children rises at a decreasing rate in response to the amount of wealth and eventually reaches a biological maximum. In the fourth quadrant, second period consumption or old age support is depicted as a positive function of the number of children. However, second period consumption also rises at a decreasing rate as there are assumed to be diminishing returns to the number of children. This could be due to the temptation on the part of children to 'free ride' and neglect their obligations to their parents when there are a large number of siblings to share the task. We assume that diminishing returns offsets any tendency for increased number of children to compete for their parents affections in order to obtain a larger bequest. 10 The interaction between the bequest function, the child production function and the old age support function traces out the ICOF in the first quadrant. The maximization of utility subject to this constraint yields the optimal consumption levels C1* and C2*, as well as the size of the optimal bequest B* and the optimal number of children N*. Under the pure bequest motive, amount XC1* is not consumed in the first period and used to acquire bequest B* resulting in N* children and ultimately amount C2* of second period consumption. The number of children N is therefore a function of the amount of wealth and any shift factors that influence the relationship between wealth and children. Among these shift factors are religious affiliation. Religious affiiation can affect the relationship between foregone consumption and wealth, the relationship between wealth and child production and finally, that between the number of children and the provision of old age support. C2 11 IV I Eo C2* a N X C1* N* C1 B* II III B Figure 1 A Model of Intertemporal Consumption with Children and Bequests 12 The Data The micro-data consists of 7,156 census-linked probated decedents from all counties and districts of Ontario, Canada for the years 1892 (3,515) and 1902 (3,641).18 The data set is constructed from the probate records of the county surrogate courts and the 1891 and 1901 Census of Canada.19 Probate is an institutional process transferring property from the dead to the living making the inventory and valuation of property very important. The executor of the estate (or administrator in intestate cases) conducted the inventory,20 which legally needed to be conducted in response to a request by a legatee or creditor, though in practice, it was brought in voluntarily (Howell 1880: 325-326).21 The inventory provided wealth estimates grouped into sixteen categories22 allowing for separate estimates of real estate, financial assets and personal property. Moreover, the records list beneficiaries, which provide an estimate of living children. Analysis of the data in this paper is restricted to those variables that are common to both the 1892 and 1902 data sets. For example, father and mother’s birthplace was only available in the 1891 Census. Some variables were not part of the 1892 data collection project but were included in the data collection for 1902. These variables include year of immigration to Canada as well as mother tongue and an assortment of employment related variables. 19 Sources for the data set were: (1) Public Archives of Ontario, Surrogate Court Wills, 1892, 1902 and (2) Public Archives of Canada, Census of Canada, 1891,1901 Manuscripts. 20 Intestates are decedents without a will. 21 According to Howell’s (1880: 325-326) Probate, Administration and Guardianship “The inventory should contain a statement of all the goods, chattels, wares and merchandize, as well moveable as not moveable, which were of the person deceased at the time of his death within the jurisdiction of the court. A proper inventory should enumerate every item of which the personal estate consisted, and should specify the value of each particular. But unless by order of court, or in obedience to a citation, an inventory does not set forth the goods and chattels in detail.” It should be noted that real estate was usually recorded net of any mortgages outstanding so that the wealth figure used in this paper is a measure of net wealth. 22 The inventory categories were:(1) Household goods and furniture, (2) Farm implements, (3) Stock in trade, (4) Horses, (5) Cattle, (6) Sheep and Swine, (7) Book Debts and Promissory Notes, (8) Moneys secured by mortgage, (9) Life Insurance, (10) Bank stocks and other shares, (11) Securities, (12) Cash on hand, (13) Cash in bank (14) Farm produce, (15) Real estate, (16) Other personal property. 18 13 The number of children requires further discussion given its importance in testing the impact of religion on family size. The variable was constructed by combining results from both the probate and the census records to ensure that as many children as possible were accounted for. The census listed only children still living within the household whereas the probate records generally listed all the children who were beneficiaries of the estate. Generally, the probate estimate was larger than the census estimate except in cases where the children were very young in which case the census offered the more complete listing. The average number of children rises with age with a slowdown in the rate of increase after age 50 and that occurs in this data set suggesting that most children are being accounted for as the population ages. For example, between the age 20-29 and 50-59 categories, the average number of children per male decedent rises from 0.44 to 3.40 and then reaches 3.69 in the age 70-79 age category. Potential limitations to the use of probate records as a measure of wealth should be acknowledged.23 First, probated decedents are of higher socio-economic status and may not represent the general population but the problem of selection bias is limited since this paper focuses on the probated decedents themselves.24 A related issue is that probate wealth data may be affected by whether the individuals died unexpectedly or had been ill a long time and run down their assets. Unfortunately, cause of death information was not available in the probate records and other sources were not as reliable.25 23 Discussions of Ontario probate records as historical sources of data are contained in Elliott (1985: 125-32) and Osborne (1980: 235-47). See also Siddiq and Gwyn (1991: 103-117). 24 An attempt can be made to adjust the data for potential biases using the estate multiplier technique. See Siddiq and Gwyn (1991: 103-17), and Di Matteo and George (1992: 453-483). 25 A noted scholar of Ontario’s civil registration of vital events statistics writes that: “For years after 1869 Ontario’s civil registration of vital events was unsatisfactory. Although its legislative provisions surpassed Quebec’s, Ontario was less successful in obtaining registrations...the registrar-general estimated that registrations for 1870 captured only a fifth of the province’s deaths...” By 1893, reported death rates for municipalities ranged from 26 to 2 per thousand. See Emery (1993: 32-34). 14 Second, the presence of estate taxes may provide incentive for an executor or administrator to underestimate inventoried wealth but in Ontario the presence of estate taxes provided little reason to underestimate the value of the estate for almost all decedents. There were no succession duties in Ontario until July 1, 1892 when the Succession Duty Act (Statutes of Ontario, 55 Vict., Cap. 6, 1892) came into effect, and even then the Act allowed for numerous exemptions.26 A final concern is the extent of inter vivos transfers, meaning that an unknown portion of wealth may have been transferred during life and is unaccounted for by the probate records. Generally, the property liable to duty was quite comprehensive and after 1896, it included property vested jointly with interest to survivor. The Succession Duty Act applied even to property “voluntarily transferred by deed, grant or gift made in contemplation of the death of the grantor or bargainor, or made or intended to take effect, in possession or enjoyment after such death...”27 if they were made in the 12 months preceding death. Moreover, after 1896, donatio mortis causa , that is, goods and possessions delivered in apprehension of death, were also clearly defined as property liable to duty.28 Such transfers are considered a problem if estate taxes present an obstacle to terminal wealth transmission but the evidence for Ontario suggests that they should not be given the exemptions. 26 The Succession Duty Act did not apply: (1) To any estate the value of which, after payment of all debts and expenses of administration, does not exceed $10,000; nor (2) To property given, devised or bequeathed for religious, charitable or educational purposes; nor (3) To property passing under a will, intestacy or otherwise, to or for the use of the father, mother, husband, wife, child, grandchild, daughter-in-law, or son-in-law of the deceased, where the aggregate value of the property of the deceased does not exceed $100,000 in value. Revisions to the Act in 1897 (Revised Statutes of Ontario (1897), Cap. 24) kept the $100,000 exemption value but it was later reduced to $50,000 in 1907 (5 Edw.VII, c.6, s.6) which is well after the period of these two cross-sections. 27 A report on the Succession Duty Act in the Welland Tribune (April 1, 1892: 2) asserted that: “The act provides for evasion by transfers before death, although the fear of revival makes such attempts very rare.” 28 There is a drop in average other personal property in Ontario between 1892 and 1902 that is quite large but can be attributed to outliers. For example, in the four Niagara region counties in 1892, Wentworth County reports the two largest amounts of other personal property $66,500 by Thomas Myles, a coal merchant, and $23,522 by Jacob Zingsheim, a furniture manufacturer. These two individuals represent almost half the average value of other personal property in 1892. The maximum amount in 1902 in these four counties is $15,000 reported by one Thomas Bates, a brewer. 15 The construction of the data set proceeded by recording onto standardized data collection forms those estates probated in the years 1892 and 1902. Individuals were then linked back to census returns in order to obtain additional information.29 Those individuals who died prior to the taking of the census or were non-Ontario residents with property in one of the counties were omitted from the census tracing procedure.30 For 1892, a total of 4,925 estates were taken down of which 4,236 were traceable and 3,515 successfully traced for a success rate of 83 percent. For 1902, a total of 4,969 estates were taken down of which 4,233 were traceable and 3,64631 successfully traced for a success rate of 86 percent. A list of variables is provided in Table 1. Table 2 and Figures 2-3 overview key data characteristics and the relationship between religious affiliation and wealth. Figure 1 paints a picture of the regional distribution of probated decedents by religious affiliation while Figure 2 illustrates the distribution of birthplace by religion. Roman Catholics are especially concentrated in Eastern Ontario, Anglicans in the Golden Horseshoe region, Presbyterians in Huronia and Baptists in Western Ontario. Figure 2 presents further evidence on religious affiliation and place of birth. Anglicans were mainly English or Canadian born while Roman Catholics were mainly Irish or Canadian born. Presbyterians were the most likely to be born in Scotland while the Baptists and the Methodists were the most likely to be Canadian born. 29 For a full account of data collection, see Di Matteo (1997). Some of these omitted probated decedents were residents of other provinces of Canada, the United States and Britain but with property in Ontario. Other omitted individuals were Ontario residents who died before the taking of the census (in April) and therefore would not have been recorded in the Census schedule of the living. There often was a lag between the date of death and the probating of the estate. For example, in some intestate cases, time was expended searching for a will. As well, there were sometimes complicated intestate estates with incomplete administrations. For example, an individual could die intestate and the surviving spouse apply for administration of the estate and in turn die leaving the administration incomplete. If there were no surviving children or none resident in the immediate vicinity, it could take many months to apply for probate and settle the estate. 31 Five of these individuals did not have age recorded and therefore for analysis, the final number for 1902 is actually 3641. 30 16 In terms of composition of religious affiliation, in 1892 approximately 20 percent of the decedents are Anglican, 11 percent are Roman Catholic, 27 percent Presbyterian, 5 percent Baptist, 29 percent Methodist and 8 percent All Other Religions. The All Other Religions category comprises an assortment of mainly Protestant groups such as Lutherans, Mennonites, Congregationalists and Salvation Army. By 1902, the proportion of Anglicans had dropped to 18 percent, Roman Catholics had risen to 12 percent while Presbyterians, Baptists, Methodists and All Other Religions remained approximately the same. The religious affiliation of the probated decedents for 1892 and 1902 broadly matches that of the province as a whole according to the Census. However, there are relatively more Presbyterians and Anglicans and substantially fewer Roman Catholics in the data set compared to the province as a whole while the proportion of Baptists and Methodists in the data set parallels the Census closely. This higher proportion of Anglicans and Presbyterians and the lower proportion of Roman Catholics in the data set may result from the greater tendency of individuals of higher socialeconomic status to probate and the possibility that the census-linkage process may also have favoured those of higher socio-economic status. It also may reflect the age distribution of the population particularly in 1902 where Anglicans and Presbyterians had higher average ages at death at 62.2 and 62.3 respectively while Roman Catholics had the lowest at 59. The highest average wealth in 1892 is reported by Anglicans, followed by Presbyterians, All Other Religions, Methodists, Baptists and finally Roman Catholics. Between 1892 and 1902, there is a drop in average wealth for Anglicans, Presbyterians, Baptists and Methodists but not for Roman Catholics. The drop for Anglicans is particularly steep and in 1902 their average wealth is actually below that for Roman Catholics. Indeed, in 1902, Roman Catholics have the highest average wealth. This drop in wealth was also noted for Toronto by Darroch (1983a,b) using assessment 17 roll data, who attributes it to inflation in real estate values during the 1880s that was ended by the severe recession of 1891 which hit the Toronto-Hamilton area quite hard. Interestingly enough, Anglicans were particularly concentrated in the Golden Horseshoe region, which may explain why their wealth was impacted particularly hard by the recession of the 1890s.32 With respect to other characteristics, Roman Catholics were the least likely to be literate while Baptists were the most likely to be Canadian Born. It should also be noted that between 1892 and 1902, the proportion of male probated decedents declined for all groups except Baptists who saw an increase. The declining proportion of male decedents over time reflects greater property ownership by women in the wake of legal changes of the 19th century. The Married Women's Real Estate Act, 1873, allowed married women to dispose of real estate as if unmarried while The Married Woman's Property Act, 1884, enabled a women to dispose of any real or personal property as if unmarried.33 All religious groups report a decline in the average number of children per probated decedent between 1892 and 1902. In 1892, the greatest number of children was reported by decedents of Other Religions at 3.7, which include Quakers, Congregationalists and other assorted Protestant sects. This figure is followed by Methodists at 3.5, Presbyterians at 3.4, Roman Catholics at 3.3, Baptists at 3.2 and finally Anglicans at 3.0. For 1902, this pattern changes with Other Religions reporting 3.4 children, Roman Catholics next at 3.0, then Methodists at 2.9, Baptists at 2.8, Presbyterians at 2.7 at Anglicans at 2.6. Based on the conservative-liberal ranking of religious denominations used 32 Given the high rate of 19th century inequality and the dispersion that characterizes wealth data, these results may be affected by the presence of outliers, so median wealth figures are also presented in Table 2. In 1892, the highest median wealth was for Anglicans followed by Presbyterians, Methodists, Other Religions, Baptists and finally Roman Catholics. Between 1892 and 1902, all religions report a decline in median wealth with the exception of Presbyterians who see a slight increase and become the highest median wealth holders followed by Anglicans. This result suggests that the high average wealth of Roman Catholics in 1902 was driven by the presence of extreme observations. 33 See also Inwood & Ingram (2000), Baskerville (1999) and Chambers (1997). 18 in other studies, these results do not necessarily conform to the expected result. While the more liberal Presbyterians do report a lower average number of children, in both years, the more conservative Anglicans are at the bottom. At the same time, Roman Catholics, Baptists and Methodists do tend to have larger numbers of children. Resolution of the possible confounding relationships between children, religion, wealth and other variables requires a regression approach. Model and Results A determinants approach is a route to modeling family size whereby variables are categorized into choice and non-choice variables with the remaining variation a function of random forces.34 Choice variables are characteristics an individual can vary like occupation, place of residence, marital status, children and to a lesser extent, literacy and religion.35 Non-choice variables are unalterable individual characteristics such as age, gender and birthplace. When religion is used as an independent variable in family size determinant regressions, we are examining whether more liberal religious denominations – in this case defined as Presbyterians and Other Religions – have lower family sizes and fertility than more conservative and hierarchical denominations which in this paper are defined as Baptists, Anglicans, Methodists and Roman Catholics. 34 A similar approach is outlined for the determinants of wealth by Pope, “Households,” pp. 152-55 It should be acknowledged that in 19th century Canada, religious affiliation was likely a “path dependent” process that was based on the religion of parents. As a result, the religion variable as an independent variable may not only capture the effect of religion on traits and characteristics that influence on economic activity or different social/cultural networks but also parental endowments of belief systems and networks. According to John Porter (1968: 511) , “religion tends to be ‘inherited’ much as sex and eye colour are inherited and carried around throughout life, and it becomes a determining factor in education, health, marriage, occupation and so forth.” 35 19 Equation one below sets the general form of the regression with the number of children (C) as a function of a vector of socio-economic variables Zi that include dummy variables for religious affiliation (See Table 1). (1) C = f(Z1….Zi) Anglicans are the omitted variable for comparison purposes because of the tendency for Anglicans to be viewed as the establishment Church in 19th century Ontario. Essentially, the hypothesis to be tested is whether religious affiliation variables are statistically significant determinants of family size. The regression estimation technique is ordinary least squares and two models are estimated: (1) A simple OLS regression of the number of children on a set of variables including wealth and religious affiliation. (2) A fitted wealth OLS approach in which wealth is regressed on a set of variables and the fitted wealth values are then used in the child regression.36 The fitted wealth approach is utilized because of the potential for bi-directional causality between wealth and children as well as the fact that similar variables can be the determinants of both wealth and children. As well, the child regressions are run only for probated decedents who at the time of death were married, widows or widowers thus omitting 877 single decedents. The results for both approaches are presented in Table 3 and the wealth regression used in the fitted wealth estimates reported in Appendix 1. The results in Table 3, using the instrumental variable estimation technique, suggest that after controlling for age, wealth, gender, birthplace, farmer as occupation, urbanization, marital status, literacy, and time, there was an impact of religious affiliation on the number of children. Relative to Anglicans, Roman Catholics had 0.77 more 36 Essentially a two-stage least squares approach. 20 children, Presbyterians had 0.41 more, Baptists had 0.69 more, Methodists had 0.67 more and all other religions had 0.87 more. These results suggest that after controlling for a wide variety of factors, Anglicans reported the smallest families while Roman Catholics and Other Religions (Congregationalists, Quakers, Lutherans, etc…) had the largest families. After Anglicans, the next smallest families were by Presbyterians, then Methodists and finally Baptists. While there are statistically significant differences in family size according to religious denominations, they do not fall into the “liberal-conservative” divide of other North American studies. However, effects on the number of children also come from the variables dealing with time, farmer occupational status, urbanization and literacy. For example, being literate is associated with 0.33 fewer children versus being nonliterate, while decedents who were farmers had 1.48 more children than non-farmers. Relative to 1892, decedents in 1902 had 0.19 fewer children. Meanwhile, urban dwellers had 1.12 fewer children than non-urban dwellers. One interesting difference in the fitted estimates as opposed to the basic OLS result is that male probated decedents reported 1.32 fewer children than female probated decedents in the fitted wealth result whereas there is no significant difference in the basic OLS estimate. Why male decedents might report smaller families than female ones in the fitted regression is a puzzling question. There may be life cycle effects that are being better captured by the fitted regression. For example, a greater proportion of males relative to females are married whereas a larger proportion of females reported being widowed as opposed to males being widowers.37 The data reveals that the average age of married men was 61.1 years while that of married women was 52.9 years and the average age of widowers was 73.4 years while that of widows was 68.4 years. The gender variable may be capturing the effects of a younger married male population 37 Approximately 19% of males in this data set were widowers and 70% were married. Approximately 53% of females in this data set were widows and 31% were married. 21 relative to an older female widowed population. However, females in general died at a younger average age than males in this data set making it possible that some other influence may be generating this result. Conclusion This paper examines the influence of religion on family size in late nineteenth/early twentieth century Ontario using a set of 7,156 census-linked probated decedents. Religion can affect economic behaviour through direct and indirect effects. For example, religion can directly shape values and attitudes towards fertility as well as provide social contacts and networks that encourage child bearing. Also, religion can indirectly affect wealth because of differences towards fertility, childrearing and education. While empirical studies using historical Canadian micro-data have found only a weak relationship between religious affiliation and the number of children, this paper finds statistically significant relationships. However, they do not fall into the “liberal-conservative” divide of other North American studies suggesting other factors may be interacting with religion to generate an effect on fertility. Each religious group may indeed have had its own unique internal dynamic with respect to views on family size and fertility. 22 Bibliography Anderson, G. M. (1988) “Mr. Smith and the Preachers: The Economics of Religion in the Wealth of Nations,” Journal of Political Economy, vol.96, 1066-1088. Baskerville, P. (2001) “Did Religion Matter? Religion and Wealth in UrbanCanada at the Turn of the Twentieth Century: An Exploratory Study,” Histoire sociale-Social History, 67, 61-96. Baskerville, P. (1999) "Women and Investment in Late-nineteenth Century Urban Canada: Victoria and Hamilton, 1880-1901," Canadian Historical Review, 80, 2, 191-218. Becker, G.S. (1960) “An Economic Analysis of Fertility,” NBER Demographic Change in Developed Countries (Princeton, Princeton University Press). Becker, G.S. (1965) “A Theory of the Allocation of time,” Economic Journal, 75, 493-517. Becker, G.S. and G.H. Lewis (1973) “On the Interaction Between the Quantity and Quality of Children,” Journal of Political Economy, 81, 279-288. Chambers, L. (1997) Married Women and the Law of Property in Victorian Ontario, Osgoode Society for Legal History, University of Toronto Press. Darroch, A.G. (1983a) “Early Industrialization and Inequality in Toronto,1861-1899” Labour/Le Travailleur, 11, 31-61/ Darroch, A.G. (1983b) “Occupational Structure, assessed Wealth, and homeowning during Toronto’s Early Industrialization, 1861-1899” Histoire sociale/Social History, 16, 381-410. Delacroix, J. (1995) “Religion and Economic Action: The Protestant Ethic, the Rise of Capitalism, and the Abuses of Scholarship,” J. Sci. Study Rel., 34:1, 126-127. Denton, F.T. and P.J. George (1970) “An Exploratory Statistical Analysis of Some Socio-Economic Characteristics of Families in Hamilton, Ontario, 1871” Historie Sociale-Social History, No. 5, April, 16-44. Denton, F.T. and P.J. George (1973) “The Influence of Socio-Economic Variables on Family size in Wentworth County, Ontario 1871: A Statistical Analysis of Historical Micro-data” Canadian Review of Sociology and Anthropology, 10(4), 334-345. Di Matteo, L. (2007) “The Effect of Religious Denomination on Wealth: Who Were the Truly Blessed? Social Science History, 31,3, 299-341. Di Matteo, L. and P.J. George (1992) "Canadian Wealth Inequality in the Late Nineteenth Century: A Study of Wentworth County, Ontario, 18721902," Canadian Historical Review, LXXIII, 4, 453-483. 23 Easterlin, R.A. (1976) “Population Change and Farm Settlement in the Northern United States,” Journal of Economic History, 36, 45-83. Elliot, B.S. (1985) "Sources of bias in nineteenth-century Ontario wills," Histoire sociale-Social History, 18, 125-132. Emery, G. (1993) The Facts of Life: The Social Construction of Vital Statistics, Ontario 1869-1952. Montreal. McGill-Queen's. Engerman, S. (2000) “The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism,” Project 2001: Significant Works in Twentieth-Century Economic History, http://www.eh.net/booktreviews/library/engerman.shtml. Fulop, M. (1977) “A Survey of the Literature on the Economic Theory of Fertility Behaviour,” American Economist, 21, 5-13. Haan, M.D. (2005) “Studying the Impact of Religion on Fertility in Nineteenth-Century Canada,” Social Science History, 29:3, 373-411. Hacker, J.D. (1999) “Chid naming, religion, and the decline of marital fertility in nineteenth-century America,” History of the Family, 4, 334-65. Henripin, J. (1972) Trends and Factors of Fertility in Canada. 1961 Census monograph. Ottawa: Statistics Canada (originally published in French, 1968). Howell, A. (1880) The Law and Practice as to Probate, Administration and Guardianship in Surrogate Courts. Toronto: Carswell. Iannaccone, L.R. (1998) “Introduction to the Economics of Religion,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXVI, 3, 1465-1496. Inwood, K. and S. Ingram (2000) "The Impact of Married Women's Property Legislation in Victorian Ontario," The Dalhousie Law Journal, 23, 2. Keister, L.A. (2003) “Religion and Wealth: The Role of Religious Affiliation and Participation in Early Adult Asset Accumulation,” Social Forces, 82(1): 175-207. Landes, D.S. (1998) The Wealth and Poverty of Nations. New York: Norton. Leasure, J.W. (1982) “La baisse de la fecondité aux Etats-Unis de 1800 a 1860,” Population, 37, 607-22. McInnis, R.M. (1991) "Women, Work and Childbearing: Ontario in the Second Half of the Nineteenth Century," Histoire sociale/Social History, XXIV, 237262. Meng, R. and J. Sentence (1984) “Religion and the determination of earnings: further results,” Canadian Journal of Economics, XVII, 3, 481-488. Neher, P. (1971_ “Peasants, Procreation and Pensions,” American Economic Review, 61, 380-389. Nerlove, M., A. Razin and E. Sadka (1987) Household and Economy: Welfare Economics of Endogenous Fertility. (New York: Academic Press). 24 Nugent, Jeffrey B. (1985) "The Old-Age Security Motive for Fertility" Population and Development Review, 2, 75-97. Osborne, B.S. (1980) “Wills and Inventories: Records of Life and Death in a Developing society,” Families, 19, 235-47. Pope, C.L. (1989) “Household on the American Frontier: The Distribution of Income and Wealth in Utah 1850-1900,” In D.W. Galenson (Ed.), Markets in History: Economic Studies of the Past, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 148-189. Porter. J/ (1968/1965) The Vertical Mosaic. An Analysis of Social class and Power in Canada. Toronto: University of Toronto Press. Ransom, R.L. and R. Sutch (1986a) "The Life-Cycle Transition: A Preliminary Report on Wealth-holding in America," Paper Prepared for the Tenth University of California Conference on Economic History, Laguna Beach, California, May 2-4. Ransom, R.L. and R. Sutch (1986b) "Did Rising Out-Migration Cause Fertility to Decline in Antebellum New England? A Life Cycle Perspective on Old Age Security Motives, Child Default, and Farm Family Fertility," CIT Social Science Working Paper No. 610. Samulesson, K. (1993) Religion and Economic Action: The Protestant Ethic, the rise of Capitalism, and the abuses of Scholarship. Toronto: U. of Toronto Press. Shultz, T.D.ed. (1974) Economics of the Family, Marriage, Children and Human-Capital, NBER Conference Report (Chicago: University of Chicago Press). Siddiq, F.K. and J. Gwyn (1991) “The Importance of Probate Inventories in Estimating the Distribution of Wealth,” Nova Scotia Historical Review, 11: 103-17. Sundstrom, W.A. and P.A. David (1988) “Old Age Security Motives, Labour Markets, and Farm Family Fertility in Antebellum America.” Explorations in Economic History 25, 166-97. Tawney, R. (1926) Religion and the Rise of Capitalism. New York: Harper and Row. Tomes, Nigel (1985) “Religion and the Earnings function,” American Economic Review, 75, Papers and Proceedings, 245-250. Tomes, Nigel (1983) “Religion and the rate of return on human capital: Evidence from Canada,” Canadian Journal of Economics, 16, 122-138. Weber, M. (1958/1930) The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism. New York: Free Press. 25 Figure 2 Distribution of Ontario Decedents (1892 and 1902) by Religion and Region 0.60 0.50 0.40 NORTHERN WESTERN HURONIA EASTERN GOLDEN 0.30 0.20 0.10 S N G IO D O RE LI ET H ER TH BA PT IS IS T T N IA ER BY T PR ES M O RO M AN AN CA G TH LI O CA LI C N 0.00 26 Figure 3 Birthplace Distribution by Religion for Ontario Decedents (1892 and 1902) 0.70 0.60 0.50 ENGLISH IRISH SCOT USA OTHBRTH CANBORN 0.40 0.30 0.20 0.10 N S T T ER M ET RE L H IG O D IO IS PT IS BA N IA YT ER ES B PR O TH RO M AN AN CA TH G LI CA O LI C N 0.00 27 Table 1: Dataset Variables VARIABLE WEALTH AGE SEX TEST URBa ENGLISH IRISH SCOT USA CANBORN OTHBRTH OCC1b OCC2F OCC2NF OCC3 OCC4 OCC5 OCC6 MARRIED WIDOWER WIDOW SINGLE PRESB CATHOLIC BAPTIST METH ANGLICAN OTHREL LITERATE CHILDN YEAR1902 NORTHERN WESTERNc EASTERN HURONIA GOLDEN DEFINITION Wealth ($) Age at death in years. 1 if male, 0 otherwise 1 if testate, 0 otherwise 1 if urban resident, 0 otherwise. 1 if born in England or Wales, 0 otherwise. 1 if born in Ireland, 0 otherwise. 1 if born in Scotland, 0 otherwise. 1 if born in United States, 0 otherwise. 1 if born in Canada (Ont, Que or Maritimes), 0 otherwise. 1 if born in any other place, 0 otherwise. 1 if Katz Category I, 0 otherwise 1 if Katz Category II and a farmer, 0 otherwise 1 if Katz Category II and a non-farmer, 0 otherwise 1 if Katz Category III, 0 otherwise 1 if Katz Category IV, 0 otherwise 1 if Katz Category V, 0 otherwise 1 if Katz Category VI, 0 otherwise 1 if married, 0 otherwise 1 if widower, 0 otherwise 1 if widow, 0 otherwise 1 if single, 0 otherwise 1 if Presbyterian, 0 otherwise 1 if Roman Catholic, 0 otherwise 1 if Baptist, 0 otherwise 1 if Methodist, 0 otherwise 1 if Church of England, 0 otherwise 1 if any other religion, 0 otherwise 1 if decedent could read and write, 0 otherwise Number of children reported. 1 if year of probate is1902, 0 otherwise. 1 if Northern Ontario, 0 otherwise 1 if Western Ontario, 0 otherwise 1 if Eastern Ontario, 0 otherwsie 1 if Huronia, 0 otherwise. 1 if Golden Horseshoe, 0 otherwise. 28 NOTES TO TABLE 1 a Urban is defined as a resident of a city, town or village. b These are socio-economic occupational status categories with OCC1 as the highest, OCC5 as the lowest and OCC6 as an unclassifiable (See Katz, 1975, 343-348). Category OCC1, for example contains lawyers, merchants, doctors, etc...Categories OCC2F includes farmers while OCC2NF contains minor government officials and small businessmen. Category OCC3 includes skilled tradesmen such as blacksmiths while OCC4 contains barbers and restaurant workers. Category OCC5 is mainly unskilled labour while OCC6 is unclassifiable containing mainly women. c The counties in each regional dummy are as follows: NORTHERN- Renfrew, Districts of Muskoka and Parry Sound, Sudbury-Nipissing, Algoma, Manitoulin, Kenora and Rainy River and Thunder Bay; GOLDEN HORSESHOE- Wentworth, Lincoln, Welland, Peel, Halton, York; WESTERN- Haldimand, Norfolk, Elgin, Kent, Essex, Lambton, Middlesex, Oxford, Brant; HURONIA-Waterloo, Perth, Huron, Wellington, Bruce, Grey, Simcoe, Dufferin; EASTERN-Ontario, Victoria and Haliburton, Durham and Northumberland, Peterborough, Hastings, Prince Edward Lennox and Addington, Frontenac, Leeds-Grenville, Dundas-Glengarry-Stormont, Prescott and Russell, Carleton, Lanark. 29 TABLE 2: SELECTED STATISTICS BY RELIGIOUS AFFILIATION ANGLICAN ROMAN PRESBYTERIAN BAPTIST METHODIST CATHOLIC OTHER RELIGION 1902 Census Distribution (%) 1892 Census Distribution (%) 16.9 18.3 17.9 16.9 21.9 21.4 5.3 5.0 30.5 30.9 7.5 7.4 1902 Decedent Distribution (%) 1892 Decedent Distribution (%) 18.2 20.2 12.1 10.8 27.3 27.1 5.4 4.9 28.6 28.9 8.4 8.2 Mean Wealth ($): 1902 1892 6629 10810 7311 5554 6896 7770 4373 5660 5342 5891 7093 6900 Median Wealth ($): 1902 1892 2821 3200 2193 2400 3180 3150 2402 2937 2752 3033 2389 3000 Average Real Estate ($): 1902 1892 2508 4881 2526 3060 2634 3338 2252 2898 2471 3087 2877 2639 Median Real Estate ($): 1902 1892 900 1500 1000 1200 1000 1500 1000 1500 1000 1200 675 1000 Average Financial Assets ($): 1902 1892* 3516 4770 4256 1658 3372 3276 1662 1752 2380 2123 2941 3541 Median Financial Assets ($): 1902 1892* 500 479 328 115 704 450 200 403 469 277 614 405 Percent Reporting Real Estate Ownership 1902 1892 70 74 72 75 71 74 76 75 69 75 65 75 Percent of Wealth Held as Real Estate: 1902 1892 42 47 48 54 41 47 51 52 44 50 39 47 30 TABLE 2: CONTINUED ANGLICAN ROMAN PRESBYTERIAN BAPTIST METHODIST CATHOLIC OTHER RELIGION Average Age: 1902 1892 62.2 60.5 59.0 61.4 62.3 61.8 61.8 60.6 61.5 60.5 63.4 63.0 Percent Male: 1902 1892 67.8 74.0 70.8 76.5 70.1 77.4 71.4 68.0 70.5 78.2 74.1 79.1 Percent Literate: 1902 1892 94.9 91.5 81.0 77.8 96.3 93.2 97.4 91.3 94.3 90.9 88.9 93.4 Average Number Of Children: 1902 1892 2.6 3.0 3.0 3.3 2.7 3.4 2.8 3.2 2.9 3.5 3.4 3.7 Percent Canadian Born 1902 1892 41.3 33.6 55.7 36.2 46.1 31.0 66.8 52.3 61.0 47.0 42.2 39.4 * Excluding Prince Edward County 1892 which only recorded real estate and total assets. 31 TABLE 3: REGRESSION RESULTS DEPENDENT VARIABLE: CHILDN Fitted Wealth OLS Regression Variables AGE agesq URB SEX canborn occ2f married catholic presb baptist meth othrel literate yr1902 wealthhat _cons Coef. Basic OLS REGRESSION T-Statistics 0.08679 -0.00078 -1.12690 -1.32331 -0.60240 1.48490 0.05291 0.77001 0.40573 0.69079 0.66543 0.86735 -0.32554 -0.18620 0.00018 0.93428 Number of obs F( 15, 6259) R-squared Adj R-squared 6.06 -6.59 -13.42 -12.61 -8.22 15.66 0.67 6.46 4.32 4.40 7.07 6.76 -2.79 -2.92 25.68 2.05 6275 91.87 0.1804 0.1785 TStatistics Coef. AGE agesq URB SEX canborn occ2f married catholic presb baptist meth othrel literate yr1902 wealth _cons 0.15699 -0.00118 -0.46196 0.04158 -0.21737 0.86797 -0.02459 0.50022 0.27224 0.16266 0.20532 0.58987 0.21847 -0.42824 0.00001 -1.76490 Number of obs F( 15, 6259) R-squared Adj R-squared 10.65 -9.67 -5.52 0.44 -2.89 9.02 -0.30 4.01 2.77 1.00 2.12 4.40 1.81 -6.46 4.26 -3.79 6275 44.67 0.0967 0.0945 32 APPENDIX 1 WEALTH REGRESSION FOR GENERATING FITTED WEALTH ESTIMATE (WEALTHHAT) DEPENDENT VARIABLE: WEALTH Estimation Technique: OLS VARIABLES Coef. T-statistic AGE agesq URB SEX CHILDN english irish scot usa othbrth occ1 occ3 occ4 occ5 occ6 occ2nf married catholic presb baptist meth othrel 246.9711 -1.8171 3439.092 1651.328 574.6054 -1393.243 -1731.985 -1493.08 992.4122 -2821.057 11419.62 -1641.521 -4246.661 -4333.027 -2386.898 1575.19 -455.935 -805.4971 -702.0591 -2628.809 -2598.302 -867.0859 2.21 -1.89 4.54 0.42 4.99 -1.51 -1.88 -1.34 0.55 -1.65 10.14 -1.31 -2.01 -2.1 -0.61 1.22 -0.67 -0.7 -0.71 -1.75 -2.94 -0.66 VARIABLES TEST literate northern western huronia eastern yr1902 _cons Coef. T-statistic 3785.449 2405.84 -3922.71 -4153.463 -4903.461 -3351.611 -943.9071 -4739.626 Number of obs F( 29, 7126) R-squared Adj R-squared 5.29 2.17 -2.13 -4.69 -5.4 -3.81 -1.57 -0.88 7156 15.46 0.0592 0.0554 33