Early Retirement and the Housing “Bubble”: Preliminary Evidence May 2006 Martin Farnham University of Victoria Purvi Sevak* Hunter College Abstract We use data from the Health and Retirement Study (HRS) and the Office of Housing Enterprise Oversight to measure the effect of changes in housing wealth on retirement timing. Using cross-MSA variation in house-price movements to identify wealth effects on retirement timing, we find evidence that such wealth effects are present. We find that the rate of transition into retirement increases in the presence of positive housing wealth shocks. According to our estimates, a 10% increase in housing wealth is associated with an approximate 6% increase in the annual probability of retirement. In addition, we use data on expected age of retirement from the HRS to measure the impact of housing wealth shocks on expectations about retirement timing. Using these data, we find that a 10% increase in housing wealth is associated with retiring approximately 2 months earlier. Some evidence suggests an asymmetric response to housing wealth changes, with gains causing early retirement, but losses having little to no impact on retirement timing. *Corresponding author: psevak@hunter.cuny.edu I. Introduction House prices in the US rose by an average of 40% from 1995-2004 (Himmelberg, Mayer, and Sinai, 2005). This run-up in housing wealth produced many millionaires, increased availability of secured credit to many households, and has led to recent speculation that a housing “bubble” may be about to burst. Economists disagree on whether current pricing in US housing markets constitutes a bubble—loosely defined as a condition where asset prices exceed levels suggested by economic fundamentals. Case and Shiller (2003) present evidence suggestive of a bubble in housing markets. To the contrary, Himmelberg, Mayer, and Sinai (2005) argue that in spite of the significant runup in house prices, the user cost of housing remains within its historical range in most real estate markets, and therefore there is little evidence of a bubble. However they do note that user cost of housing is highly sensitive to increases in interest rates, so that a substantial, lasting increase in interest rates could lead to large housing price declines. Regardless of whether one believes that housing is overpriced in the US, the last decade has demonstrated that significant changes in housing wealth can occur over a relatively short period of time. History suggests that housing prices (in real terms) can also decline for significant periods of time. And whether one believes prices are set to fall due to the bursting of a bubble or due to rising interest rates, the possible effects of a decline in house prices on household and individual behavior are worth considering. Housing wealth effects are of interest to labor economists more generally because housing constitutes a large portion of the assets of a typical American family, and is therefore likely to be an important source of wealth effects on labor supply. Such wealth effects are also of direct interest to policymakers. In the US and other western countries, there has been a long-run trend towards early retirement. This trend, coupled with an increase in life expectancy, has put public pension systems under strain, due to reduced payroll tax collections resulting from early retirement. Since housing assets represent an important share of the typical US household’s total wealth, the labor supply behavior of older individuals may be closely linked to changes in housing wealth. Understanding the empirical relationship between housing wealth and labor supply is of interest to economists and is important to policymakers seeking to better understand the financial well being of older households, and those 1 seeking to forecast the fiscal balance of public pension programs. It may also be of interest to researchers studying the elderly home equity-consumption puzzle, in which older households are found to consume (goods and services) very little out of housing wealth in retirement (Venti and Wise, 2000). Changes in housing wealth should be expected to affect consumption in a way similar to other changes in permanent income. Standard lifecycle consumption theory predicts that permanent, unanticipated shocks to wealth should result in adjustment of consumption of goods and services as well leisure. Assuming well-functioning capital markets, greater wealth should increase an individual’s consumption of normal goods and services as well as their consumption of leisure, which we assume to be normal. Individuals may access increased housing wealth through financial products such as home equity loans or reverse mortgages. They may also access this wealth through informal borrowing markets. For instance, an elderly couple may intend to bequeath their home to their children when they die. If the couple experiences capital gains on their home but finds it difficult to access this newfound wealth through formal financial markets, they may turn to their children for financial assistance, on the understanding that the size of the children’s expected inheritance has risen. Or households that were targeting certain bequest levels may be able to increase consumption of goods, services, and leisure if bequest targets are met sooner than expected due to housing wealth gains. Therefore even without perfectly functioning formal financial markets, individuals may be able to access newfound housing wealth through informal capital markets that facilitate increased consumption. Of course, if such formal and informal capital markets are missing, then housing wealth changes may have little to no impact on consumption behavior. Given the existence of capital market imperfections, the presence of housing wealth effects is an empirical question. A number of studies have tested for housing wealth effects on the consumption of goods and services. To date, little if any work has been done on housing wealth effects on the consumption of leisure. In this paper we test for housing wealth effects on the timing of retirement. We use data from the 1992-2002 waves of the University of Michigan’s Health and Retirement Study (HRS). This biennial survey provides detailed data on 2 demographic, financial, and labor supply characteristics of individuals who were between age 51 and 61 in 1992. Therefore the panel allows for study of a population with substantial housing wealth that is nearing retirement age. Using restricted access geocodes for the HRS, we merge house-price indices at the level of Metropolitan Statistical Area (MSA) from the Office of Federal Housing Enterprise Oversight (OFHEO) to the HRS data. This allows us to generate a proxy for changes in housing wealth that varies across MSAs. We use these data rather than HRS data on housing wealth, due to the high degree of measurement error in the HRS housing wealth data. In the findings we present here, we find evidence of economically significant housing wealth effects on retirement timing. We find that workers with greater percentage gains in housing wealth since 1992 tend to retire sooner than other workers. We also find that among non-retired workers, the expected age of retirement declines in the face of housing wealth gains. Finally, we observe an apparently asymmetric response of retirement timing to gains versus losses in housing wealth. While workers facing housing wealth gains retire earlier, workers facing losses do not appear to significantly alter their retirement timing. II. Review of Existing Wealth Effects Literature Economists have long been interested in the effects of wealth on household and individual consumption behavior. A number of studies have sought to ascertain the impact of stock market wealth on consumption of goods and services (see Poterba, 2000 for a survey). In the past two decades, several authors have tried to measure the effect of housing wealth on consumption of goods and services. Some of these studies have been done at the macro level (e.g. Bhatia 1987; Case, et al. 2005; Otto and Voss 2005). Others have used micro data to measure housing wealth effects (e.g. Skinner 1996; Engelhardt 1996; Disney, et al. 2003; Belsky and Prakken 2004; Lehnart 2004; Bostic, et al. 2005). The sharp rise in real estate markets in recent years has raised the profile of this question in the empirical wealth effects literature. Wealth effects on labor supply decisions are difficult to identify because wealth is not randomly assigned. Some of the variation in wealth reflects individual heterogeneity 3 in preferences that will also be correlated with labor supply decisions. In the context of retirement behavior, high levels of wealth could be a result of plans to retire early. All else equal, an individual who plans to retire sooner than another individual should save more during her working years, because she will have more years in retirement during which she must live off of her accumulated wealth. Alternatively, wealthy individuals may have strong tastes for work and thus retire later. Thus, cross-sectional estimates of the effect of wealth on retirement timing could be biased in either direction. The early literature suggests such a bias. In his survey of men’s labor supply, Pencavel (1986) writes, “Of the 57 different estimated coefficients on net worth…only 16 would be judged as significantly different from zero…of these 16, exactly one-half is positive and one-half is negative…this hardly constitutes a resounding corroboration of the conventional static model of labor supply.” Although voluminous, the literature has failed to find consistent evidence of wealth effects. This may partly be due to the measures of income or wealth used in these papers. Studies often used measures of unearned income, such as spousal earnings, dividends, rent, and government transfer payments, to estimate the effect of wealth on labor supply (Kosters, 1966; Ashenfelter and Heckman, 1974), but these income sources are likely to be endogenous to the individuals’ labor supply decisions. A number of more recent papers have examined wealth effects due to arguably exogenous policy changes, but continue to provide mixed results. Hurd and Boskin (1984) find that the Social Security benefit increases from 1969 to 1972 can explain a large amount of the acceleration of retirement in that period, whereas Burtless (1986), using the same data, finds that the effects were very small. Kruger and Pishke (1992) estimate the effect of reductions in benefits due to amendments to Social Security in 1977 and find no effect. A more recent study by Chan and Stevens (2004) finds that individuals’ planned retirement ages do respond to perceived changes in pensions. Several studies avoid the problem of endogeneity by making use of natural experiments. Imbens, Rubin, and Sacerdote (2001) survey lottery winners and find significant labor supply effects of winnings, particularly among individuals ages 55 to 65. A paper by Kimball and Shapiro (2001) making use of survey questions on hypothetical lottery winnings finds large responses to wealth gains. Holtz-Eakin, Joulfaian and Rosen 4 (1993) find that individuals in households that receive large inheritances are more likely to leave the labor force and less likely to enter the labor force. Though a number of papers have exploited the stock market “bubble” of the late 1990s to test for wealth effects on retirement, results are inconclusive. Sevak (2005) and Coronado and Perozek (2001) find earlier retirements among individuals who were most likely to gain from the performance of the stock market – stock holders or those with defined contribution pension plans, but Hurd and Reti (2001) find that the stock market had no significant effect on retirement. There is strong evidence that an individual’s retirement timing responds to expected changes in wealth. Accrual rates in Social Security (Coile and Gruber, 2000) and private defined benefit pension plans (Stock and Wise, 1990; Samwick, 1998) have been found to be important determinants of retirement timing. Although these effects are not referred to as wealth effects, they provide evidence of the sensitivity of retirement timing to the path of expected wealth accumulation. A related question is whether housing wealth affects the consumption of leisure. Compared to the empirical literature on wealth effects on consumption of goods and services, relatively little empirical work has been done to measure housing wealth effects on leisure. To our knowledge only one paper has directly studied the impact of housing wealth on retirement timing. Doling and Horsewood (2003) use aggregate data from a cross-section of European countries to argue that the declines in retirement age can be attributed to increased homeownership rates. However, they do not attempt to directly measure a housing wealth effect. The housing boom of the 1990s provides an opportunity to reexamine the question of wealth effects on retirement timing. To the extent that the boom in real estate markets can be considered an exogenous shock to wealth (we discuss this further below), we can use variation in housing price changes across regions to identify a housing wealth effect on retirement timing. In addition, the housing boom itself presents potential challenges to policymakers. To the extent that individuals respond to increases in housing wealth by dropping out of the labor force, pressure on public pension systems due to declining payroll tax receipts may increase. To the extent that decisions to exit the labor force are not fully reversible, 5 then any future retrenchment in the housing market may have important impacts on the financial security of older households. To the extent that housing wealth effects on retirement timing have been large during the housing boom, the risk associated with retrenchment may also be large. Therefore, beyond providing a potential natural experiment from which to learn about wealth effects, the housing boom of the 1990s in itself represents a phenomenon worthy of study. III. Data In order to examine the effect of changes in housing wealth on the retirement timing of older individuals, we assemble a data set with observations on individual workers from the University of Michigan’s Health and Retirement Study (HRS) for the years 1992-2002 and match them to data on MSA-level house prices from the Office of Federal Housing Enterprise Oversight (OFHEO) and county-level unemployment rate data from the Bureau of Labour Statistics (BLS). The HRS contains extensive data on income, wealth, work and health status, and other individual and household characteristics of individuals near retirement age. In addition, the survey codes geographic identifiers in each wave that allow matching to the local-level data from OFHEO and BLS. An overview of the HRS data is given at http://hrsonline.isr.umich.edu/data/index.html. Because the HRS is an ongoing panel survey, construction of an analysis file can be a complex process. A baseline set of 7,650 randomly selected households with a member born between 1951 and 1961 were interviewed in 1992. Every two years, the HRS attempts to re-interview the members of this household. Though the re-interview rate is quite high (see Table 1, discussed below), in some cases a household or individual household member may refuse to conduct an interview or may be unreachable. If this is the case, the HRS continues to attempt to interview them in subsequent waves. The HRS provides a “tracker” file, which summarizes the interview status of each household member over time and facilitates the merge of multiple years of data. It includes data on whether the person was interviewed, and reasons for non-interview including whether the individual has died or is in a nursing home. 6 In each interview year, respondents answer detailed questions about current and past labor supply, health, and other topics. A designated “financial respondent” in each household provides detailed financial information on the household. This includes values of various assets, including housing, real estate, stocks, bonds, checking and savings accounts, individual retirement accounts (IRAs), small businesses, and pensions. Since housing assets are reported at the household level and cannot be attributed to one particular spouse, we measure housing wealth and all other household wealth at the household level and assume that households pool their resources. While we use an individual’s 1992 level of housing equity as a control in the specifications discussed below, we do not use measures of changes in housing wealth derived from HRS data. This is because the HRS housing wealth data are plagued with measurement error. Much of this measurement error is due to coding errors, and hence does not reflect an individual’s perception of his own housing wealth.1 As would be expected, estimation of housing wealth effects on retirement timing using these errorladen housing wealth data from the HRS typically yields coefficients of zero.2 Since year of retirement is available on an annual basis, and yet HRS surveys are conducted biennially, we annualize the dataset by imputing values of other individual characteristics for the odd-numbered years (in which respondents are not surveyed). The imputation of values is done linearly using data from the previous and next survey years. For example, values for 1995 would be imputed linearly from 1994 and 1996 survey values. Timing of retirement does not need to be imputed, because respondents report the year they retired. The stock of retirees among HRS respondents, expressed as a percentage of the analysis sample, is plotted in Figure 1. At age 52 (the youngest age of HRS respondents in our analysis sample) approximately 18% of the sample self-identifies as retired. By age 61 this has risen to around 46%. By age 71 (the oldest age of HRS respondents in our 1 While individuals have been shown to misperceive their housing wealth to a substantial degree, we might not wish to discount such errors of perception, given that an individual bases his decisions on his or her (mis)perceptions. 2 As an example of how poor the housing wealth data in the HRS are, we found that from 1992-2002, the median cumulative increase in housing wealth was just 1.06%. Clearly this deviates dramatically from the overall housing market experience of the typical American household over that period of time. 7 sample) this percentage has reached nearly 100%. Transitions into retirement by age, expressed as percentage of the analysis sample, are shown in Figure 2, where we see that transitions into retirement accelerate as individuals enter their fifties. There is a spike in retirement transitions around age 62, presumably corresponding to the start of eligibility for Social Security benefits, and a subsequent spike at 65. Transitions into retirement then taper off after age 65. Table 1 illustrates our sample selection. We focus on men because men of this generation tend to have had a stronger attachment to the labor force than women. Since retirement may be an ill-defined concept for someone who works mostly in the home, we focus our analysis on men, for whom we expect retirement to be better defined. In the first survey wave (1992) 4,605 men born between 1931-1941 were selected to be surveyed. These men show up in the sample every year thereafter, though their data may be missing due to attrition for various reasons. The sample remaining in the workforce (non-retired) declines over time, as would be expected. Of these non-retired individuals, those who remain in the sample and report working also decline over time. Further sample reductions occur when we limit workers to those who are not self-employed, those who are homeowners, those who have not moved to date, and those for whom the HRS has valid county codes (and hence can be matched to local unemployment data). While our sample selection may appear quite severe, once we limit the sample to men, most further sample selection involves removal of individuals to whom our empirical question does not apply. Questions of housing wealth effects on retirement timing clearly do not apply to non-homeowners or non-workers. These groups account for the vast majority of the observations we omit from our analysis. We also omit selfemployed individuals because we expect their behavior with respect to retirement timing to differ substantially from that of wage and salary workers. We currently omit movers from our sample. Future work will address movers, as they may be particularly responsive to housing wealth shocks in cases where they have the option to move to areas with a lower cost of living. We may also extend the analysis to include women. Summary statistics for our analysis sample are given in Table 2. The analysis sample includes male workers who are not self-employed, who are from a home-owning household, and who have not yet moved since 1992. The mean age of respondents in our 8 sample is 59 years. The mean level of home equity (in 2002 dollars) in 1992 is $77,000, among HRS respondents in our sample. According to OFHEO data matched to HRS individuals, the average cumulative percent change in house value in the sample is 14.4%. The mean unemployment rate in counties where HRS respondents live is 6% over the sample period. Table 3 gives a more detailed distribution of the household wealth levels and changes. The median level of home equity in 1992 was $56,000. The median change in house value since 1992, was 8.5%. Note that figures in Table 3 encompass observations between 1992 and 2002. Considering only changes in house value between 1992 and 2002, the mean and median changes are 54% and 50%, respectively (not shown in Table 3). IV. Empirical Strategy Measuring housing wealth effects on retirement timing is subject to a number of challenges. First, housing wealth may be correlated with local labor market conditions. Local home values may reflect current or future labor market opportunities, which may also be correlated with retirement timing. If older individuals delay retirement in the face of high wages and if high wages are capitalized into local house values, then failure to control for local labor market conditions may lead to downward bias in estimates of wealth effects. As a result, in the specifications reported below we control for the worker’s wage and for the local (county-level) unemployment rate. Second, housing wealth, defined as the value of equity in one’s home, is likely to be endogenous. Households, to the extent they can liquidate equity in their home through borrowing, may be able to adjust their housing wealth in ways correlated with their preference for leisure. Households anticipating early retirement may engage in less liquidation of home equity for other consumption purposes than households anticipating later retirement. To the extent that home equity or changes in home equity reflect active management of one’s housing wealth, these measures may reflect expected retirement timing of households. This would potentially lead to upward bias in measurement of housing wealth effects. As a result, rather than measuring the effect of changes in home equity on retirement timing, we measure the effect of changes in house value on 9 retirement timing. Since, among non-movers, these are arguably exogenous changes in household wealth, estimation of housing wealth effects based on change in house value should not be subject to this upward bias. Third, self-reported data on house values, while providing variation in wealth at the individual level, is subject to classical measurement error. This will lead to downward bias in the estimates of wealth effects on retirement timing. Initial work with the HRS self-reported house value data suggests that measurement error is severe. An extensive discussion of mismeasurement in self-reported data on house values can be found in Engelhardt (2005). As a result of the measurement error obviously present in the HRS, we have chosen to use OFHEO house price indices at the MSA level, which are matched to HRS data using restricted-access geocodes. Fourth, the permanent income hypothesis suggests that the response of consumption to changes in wealth should be greatest for permanent, unexpected changes in wealth. In a standard model of lifetime consumption, the consumption path (whether of goods and services or leisure) is predetermined and therefore unresponsive to expected wealth shocks. Furthermore, to the extent that individuals are lifetime consumption smoothers, changes in wealth that are only transitory should have a smaller effect on lifetime consumption than changes in wealth that are permanent. There is substantial long-term variation in the rate of house price appreciation across metro areas in the US (Gyourko, Mayer, and Sinai, 2004). This suggests that expectations of capital gains on housing should vary across metro areas. Properly isolating unexpected and permanent changes in housing wealth is important for correctly measuring wealth effects on retirement timing. In the current draft, we do not address this particular challenge, though we discuss this point in the context of anticipated further work in our concluding remarks. The first basic specification we use in this preliminary analysis is a linear probability model of entry into retirement. We use this model primarily for the sake of ease of interpretation, and because it allows us to difference out unobserved heterogeneity by inclusion of fixed effects. For this basic specification, we use the following model of entry into retirement: 10 (1) ' DitRETIRE = Wi,1992 ! + "#HPI i,t $1992 + Xit' % + uit . DRETIRE is a dummy variable equal to 1 if individual i retires at time t and equal to zero otherwise. W is a vector of household wealth variables. Measures of household wealth include housing wealth, business wealth, and other wealth in 1992. Inclusion of these variables is intended to form a combined measure of permanent income at the start of the sample period. ΔHPI, the variable of primary interest, denotes change in housing wealth. It is measured as the cumulative percent change in housing wealth since 1992, calculated from the OFHEO MSA-level house price indices. Changes in housing wealth are measured in percentage terms, rather than in dollar terms. We choose this specification of the wealth variable because we expect that relative changes in housing wealth matter more than absolute changes. In other words, a $50,000 increase in housing wealth will probably have a larger impact on the retirement timing choice of someone with a $100,000 home in 1992 (for whom it is a 50% increase in housing wealth) than someone with a $1,000,000 home in 1992 (for whom it is only a 5% increase). To be precise, a 5% cumulative change in housing wealth would be denoted as “5” in the data. X is a vector of control variables, including individual-level characteristics, household characteristics, and measures of local labor market conditions. Controls included in our specifications include age, years of education, race, lagged marital status, a lagged indicator of poor health, and lagged log wage. We also include year fixed effects and controls for lagged industry and lagged occupation. In some specifications we add the county-level unemployment rate and state fixed effects. Estimates of this model are performed on the analysis sample described in Section III, using OLS. Standard errors are clustered at the individual level to account for the fact that we have multiple observations on individuals. Results from this specification are given in Table 4. Another way to consider the effect of changes in housing wealth on retirement timing is to exploit data in the HRS on expected age of retirement. Workers in each survey wave of the HRS are asked at what age they intend to retire. Since worker expectations vary at a greater frequency than actual retirement status (transition to 11 retirement can only occur given the way we structure our analysis sample), we may be able to measure housing wealth effects on retirement timing with greater precision using these data. In addition, the use of retirement expectations allows us to observe responses to housing wealth effect before actual retirement occurs. This eliminates the problem of right censoring that occurs with individuals in our sample whose future retirement (beyond the sample period) may, in fact, be affected by housing wealth changes, but whose retirement we never observe. This right censoring could be expected to lead to downward bias in our estimates of wealth effects on actual retirement transitions. The annual within-individual variation expected retirement age also allows for inclusion of individual-level fixed effects, which may reduce bias due to unobserved individual heterogeneity. To estimate the impact of housing wealth changes on expected retirement timing—namely expected retirement age—we estimate variants of the following empirical model of expected retirement age: (2) ' E[Ageitretire ] = Wi,1992 ! + "#HPI i,t $1992 + Xit' % + vit Right-hand-side variables are the same as in Equation (1). The left-hand-side variable is the age, in years, at which the respondent (at time t) expects to retire. Estimates of this model are performed on the analysis sample described in Section III, using OLS. Standard errors are clustered at the individual level to account for the fact that we have multiple observations on individuals. Results from this specification are given in Table 5. Results of a specification that includes individual fixed effects are given in Table 6. V. Estimation Results Table 4 gives estimates of equation (1), the model of transition into retirement. The estimated coefficient on the cumulative house-price-change variable in Column 1 is 0.0006 and is statistically significant at the five-percent level. The magnitude of the coefficient estimates suggests that a 10% increase in housing wealth leads to an increase of 0.006 in the annual retirement probability. Given a base retirement probability of 0.108 12 in our analysis sample, this amounts to a 5.5% increase in the annual retirement probability for a 10% gain in house value. Addition of the county-level unemployment rate has little impact on the estimated wealth effect, as can be seen in Table 4, Column 2. Addition of state fixed effects, increases the magnitude of the coefficient on housing wealth change so that it implies that a 10% increase in house prices results in a 6.5% increase in the probability of retirement. This estimate is statistically significant at the ten-percent level. Overall, results in Table 4 are consistent with the presence of a housing wealth effect on retirement timing. It is interesting to note that there appears to be an asymmetric response by individual workers to housing gains versus housing losses. Appendix Table 1 uses the same specifications as in Table 4, but splits the measure of cumulative percent change in house prices since 1992 into a measure cumulative percent increase and a measure of cumulative percent decrease. Studies in the housing mobility literature (e.g. Engelhardt, 2005) have found that households respond asymmetrically to housing wealth gains and losses. Typically, studies find that declines in house prices lead to reduced mobility, while gains have no effect on mobility. This can be for reasons of nominal loss aversion or equity constraints. Since residential mobility and retirement tend to be somewhat correlated, we were interested to see whether housing losses lead to reduced probability of retirement, while gains had no effect.3 As Appendix Table 1 demonstrates, we find the opposite effect. Gains increase the annual probability of retirement on the order of 7.5%, while losses have no statistically significant effect on retirement timing. This finding deserves further investigation, but on the surface suggests that workers have more flexibility to retire early than they do to retire late. Turning now to the question of wealth effects on expected age of retirement, Table 5 gives estimates of Equation 2. Equation 2 models expected retirement age as a function of changes in housing wealth. Note that the sample size shrinks to 6478. This is due primarily to the fact that while our analysis sample includes observations of 3 Mobility and retirement tend to be correlated because many households postpone moves (especially long-distance moves) until retirement. Moving to a retirement destination prior to retirement would require an impractical job search in many cases. 13 households immediately following retirement, such households obviously do not report an expected age of retirement. Results in Column 1 suggest that a 10% cumulative increase in house prices since 1992 leads to a decline in expected retirement age of 0.2 of a year (2.4 months). Inclusion of the county unemployment rate and state fixed effects do not substantially change our findings, as can be seen in Table 5, Columns 2-3. In all cases, the estimated housing wealth effects are statistically significant at the ten-percent level. Results of re-estimation of Equation 2 with individual-level fixed effects are given in Table 6. Here we see that while the magnitude of the wealth effect coefficient declines somewhat, it remains statistically significant. These coefficient estimates imply that a 10% increase in housing wealth leads to approximately a 2 month decline in expected retirement age. Again, inclusion of county-level unemployment rate has little effect on our estimates. As in the case of actual retirement transitions, it appears that housing gains and losses have an asymmetric impact on expected retirement age. Appendix Table 2 uses the same specifications as in Table 5, but splits the measure of cumulative percent change in house prices since 1992 into a measure cumulative percent increase and a measure of cumulative percent decrease. Estimates suggest that while individuals respond to housing wealth increases by reducing their expected retirement age, they do not increase their expected retirement age in response to housing wealth decreases. VI. Conclusion and Further Work In this preliminary work we find evidence of modest housing wealth effects on retirement timing. We find that the annual probability of retirement rises by 5.5-6.5% for a 10% cumulative increase in house prices. Gains in house price appear to have a greater effect on transitions into retirement than losses. We also find evidence that expectations about retirement timing are affected by cumulative changes in housing wealth. Our estimates suggest that a 10% increase in house prices leads individual workers to reduce their expected retirement age by 2-2.5 months. While extrapolating to bigger housing gains requires caution, our findings raise 14 the possibility that individuals in areas with large house-price gains may have substantially revised their retirement timing as a result of housing wealth shocks. Our findings suggest that the run-up of housing prices over the last decade may have had important impacts on labor supply in a number of housing markets. It also suggests that a sudden decline in house prices could reverse this process to some extent, as households reverse their plans for early retirement. There are a number of potential problems with this preliminary analysis. We omit movers from our analysis sample. Movers may have a greater ability to access housing wealth gains. Those making local moves may be able to trade down, thus liquidating some of their gains. Those making longer distance moves may be able to liquidate even more of their gains, if they move to areas with lower housing costs. Thus, further analysis will consider the behavior of movers, and treat the retirement and residential mobility choices as joint decisions. We have not yet developed a way to properly measure unexpected gains in housing wealth. Since many gains may be anticipated, failure to separate expected from unexpected gains may reduce measured wealth effects. In further work, we also plan to address the issue of expected versus unexpected housing wealth gains. Since expected gains in housing wealth should not affect consumption of leisure (in the absence of borrowing constraints), estimates of wealth effects are likely to be attenuated if we fail to correctly measure unexpected gains. Fairlie and Krashinsky (2006) use Current Population Survey (CPS) Outgoing Rotation Group (ORG) files to generate MSA-level measures of house price appreciation. Following Hurst and Lusardi (2004) they regress house price changes at the MSA level on changes in state and local economic indicators and demographic variables and include four years prior appreciation in an MSA’s housing prices to further capture anticipated housing gains. They use residuals from this regression as proxies for unanticipated house price appreciation at the MSA level. A similar approach could prove useful as we proceed with this work. Finally, we plan to explore the mechanism by which house-price gains lead to earlier retirement. For instance, are households accessing new housing wealth through financial markets, as in the case of home equity borrowing? Or, if households are saving for bequests, do housing gains allow them to reach bequest targets sooner and hence 15 allow their members retire earlier? Or can individuals in households with larger housing gains retire earlier because they realize they can rely on children (whose expected bequests have risen) to serve as substitutes for precautionary saving? We hope to provide some answers to these questions in further work on this project. 16 References Ashenfelter, Orley C. and James J. Heckman (1974). “The Estimation of Income and Substitution Effects in a Model of Family Labor Supply.” Journal of Labor Economics, 17(4), p757-783. Bostic, Raphael, Stuart Gabriel and Gary Painter (2005). “Housing Wealth, Financial Wealth, and Consumption: New Evidence from Micro Data.” manuscript, University of Southern California. Burtless, Gary (2000). “How Would Financial Risk Affect Retirement Income Under Individual Accounts?” An Issue in Brief; Center for Retirement Research at Boston College (5). Case, Karl E. and Robert J. Shiller (2003). “Is There a Bubble in the Housing Market?” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, v2003, n2. Chan, Sewin and Ann Huff Stevens (2004), “Do Changes in Pension Incentives Affect Retirement? A Longitudinal Study of Subjective Retirement Expectations.” Journal of Public Economics, v88(7-8): p1307-1333. Coile, Courtney C. and Jonathan Gruber (2000). “Social Security and Retirement” NBER Working Paper #7830. Coronado, Julia Lynn and Maria Perozek, "Wealth Effects and the Consumption of Leisure: Retirement Decisions During the Stock Market Boom of the 1990s," Unpublished Manuscript, 2001. Disney, Richard, Andrew Henley and David Jevons (2003). “House price shocks, negative equity and household consumption in the UK in the 1990s,” manuscript, University of Wales Aberystwyth. Doling, John and Nick Horsewood (2003). “Home ownership and early retirement: European experience in the 1990s.” Journal of Housing and the Built Environment. Vol. 18, p289-308. Engelhardt, Gary V. (2005). “Nominal Loss Aversion, Housing Equity Constraints, and Household Mobility: Evidence from the United States.” Journal of Urban Economics (forthcoming). Engelhardt, Gary V. (1996). “House prices and home owner saving behavior.” Regional Science and Urban Economics, 26, p313-336. Fairlie, Robert W. and Harry A. Krashinsky (2006). “Liquidity Constraints, Household Wealth, and Entrepreneurship Revisited.” manuscript, UC Santa Cruz. 17 Gyourko, Joseph, Christopher Mayer, and Todd Sinai (2004). “Superstar Cities.” Columbia Business School and Wharton School working paper. Himmelberg, Charles, Christopher Mayer, and Todd Sinai (2005). “Assessing High House Prices: Bubbles, Fundamentals and Misperceptions.” NBER Working Paper #11643. Holtz-Eakin, Douglas, David Joulfaian, and Harvey S. Rosen (1993). “The Carnegie Conjecture: Some Empirical Evidence,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108 (2), p413-435. Hurd, Michael D. and Michael J. Boskin (1984). “The Effect of Social Security on Retirement in the Early 1970s.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 99(4), p767790. Hurd, Michael D. and Monika Reti, “The Effects of Large Capital Gains on Work and Consumption: Evidence from Four Waves of the HRS” RAND Report for the U.S. Department of Labor, October 2001. Imbens, Guido W., Donald B. Rubin, and Bruce Sacerdote (2001). “Estimating the Effect of Unearned Income on Labor Supply, Earnings, Savings, and Consumption: Evidence from a Survey of Lottery Winners.” The American Economic Review 91(4), p778-795. Kezdi, Gabor and Purvi Sevak (2004). “Economic Adjustment of Recent Retirees to Adverse Wealth Shocks.” Michigan Retirement Research Center Working Paper. Kimball, Miles and Matthew Shapiro (2003). “Labor Supply: Are the Income and Substitution Effects Both Large or Both Small?” University of Michigan Unpublished Manuscript. Kosters, M. (1966). “Income and Substitution Effects in a Family Labor Supply Model.” Rand Corporation Report #P-3339. Krueger, Alan B. and Jorn-Steffen Pischke (1992). “The Effect of Social Security on Labor Supply: A Cohort Analysis of the Notch Generation,” Journal of Labor Economics 10(4), p412-437. Pencavel, John. “Labor Supply of Men: A Survey.” In Handbook of Labor Economics, Vol. 1. Edited by Orley C. Ashenfelter and Richard Layard. North Holland: Elsevier Science B.V. 1986. Poterba, James M. (2000). “Stock Market Wealth and Consumption.” The Journal of Economics Perspectives, Vol. 14, No. 2, p99-118. 18 Samwick, Andrew A. (1998). “New Evidence on Pensions, Social Security, and the Timing of Retirement.” Journal of Public Economics 70(2), p207-236. Sevak, Purvi (2005). “Wealth Shocks and Retirement Timing: Evidence from the Nineties.” Hunter College Working Paper. Skinner, J. S. (1996). “Is housing wealth a sideshow?” Advances in the Economics of Aging, National Bureau of Economic Research Report, p241-268. University of Chicago Press. Stock, James H. and David A. Wise (1990). “Pensions, the Option Value of Work, and Retirement.” Econometrica 58(5), p1151-1180. Venti, Steven F. and David A. Wise (2000). “Aging and Housing Equity.” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper #7882. 19 Figure 1. Percent HRS Respondents In Analysis Sample Who Have Transitioned to Retirement, 1992-2002 100% 90% 80% 70% % Retired 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% 52 54 56 58 60 62 Age 20 64 66 68 70 Figure 2. Percent of HRS Respondents in Analysis Sample, by Age at Which they First Retire 25% 20% % Retiring 15% 10% 5% 0% 52 54 56 58 60 62 Age 21 64 66 68 70 Table 1. Sample Selection Among Male HRS Respondents Born Between 1931 and 1941 Year 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 Eligible Men 4,605 4,605 4,605 4,605 4,605 4,605 4,605 4,605 4,605 4,605 4,605 Total 50,655 Not Retired at Working at Not SelfHomeowner t-1 t-1 Employed at t-1 at t-1 Has Not Moved 1992-2002 Has No Missing Data 3,357 3,154 2,911 2,691 2,445 2,231 2,023 1,813 1,655 1,495 3,120 2,942 2,377 2,179 1,835 1,647 1,368 1,187 960 825 2,494 2,343 1,883 1,709 1,444 1,290 1,065 909 731 614 1,965 1,843 1,475 1,328 1,171 1,038 868 741 595 499 1,965 1,717 1,358 1,154 1,012 859 700 578 454 353 1,934 1,668 1,294 1,102 963 781 672 524 430 348 23,775 18,440 14,482 11,523 10,150 9,716 22 Table 2. Summary Statistics for Analysis Sample Age Years of Education Hispanic Black Married (t-1) Poor Health (t-1) Log Wage (t-1) Retiree Health Ins (t-1) Expected Retirement Age Home Equity in 1992 Business Equity in 1992 Other Wealth in 1992 Cumulative House Price Index Change Since 1992 County Unemployment Rate Mean 58.90 12.64 0.07 0.12 0.90 0.12 2.75 0.62 63.46 76,811 13,892 92,589 14.37 0.06 Sample Size 9,716 23 Standard Deviation 3.48 3.19 0.26 0.33 0.29 0.33 0.58 0.49 4.90 77,218 145,843 249,467 19.37 0.03 Table 3. Detailed Distribution of Selected Financial Variables Home Equity in 1992 Business Equity in 1992 Other Wealth in 1992 Cumulative % Change in House Price Index Since 1992 Mean 76,811 13,892 92,589 14.37 Sample Size 9,716 24 25th Percentile 30,500 0 13,000 2.17 Median 56,000 0 37,600 8.54 75th Percentile 100,000 0 91,750 23.03 Table 4. OLS Estimates: Effect of Changes in House Prices on Transition to Retirement Years of Education Hispanic Black Married (t-1) (1) -0.001 (2) -0.001 (3) -0.001 (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) -0.006 -0.005 -0.006 (0.013) (0.013) (0.015) -0.014 -0.014 -0.013 (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) -0.036 ** (0.012) Poor Health (t-1) 0.027 Has Retiree Health Ins. (t-1) ** %Δ House Prices (t-1992) 0.009 0.009 (0.008) 0.085 -0.042 ** N R-squared ** * 0.084 * (0.051) ** -0.042 0.026 ** (0.012) 0.078 -0.041 0.024 (0.014) 0.00063 ** 0.00070 (0.0003) (0.0004) -0.040 -0.055 (0.113) (0.134) 0.108 9,716 0.077 0.108 9,716 0.077 0.108 9,716 0.081 ** Denotes statistical significance at the 5% level and * at the 10% level. Robust standard errors are in parentheses. 25 ** (0.014) 0.022 ** ** (0.055) (0.015) 0.00064 ** (0.006) 0.022 County Unemployment Rate % Retiring 0.027 (0.006) (0.015) (0.0003) Age and Year Dummies Industry and Occupation Codes County Unemployment Rate State Fixed Effects 0.029 (0.007) 0.027 ** (0.011) 0.009 (0.012) Other Wealth (1992, $1000s) ** (0.007) (0.051) Business Equity (1992, $1000s) 0.027 -0.037 (0.011) (0.011) (0.006) Home Equity (1992, $1000s) ** (0.012) (0.011) Log Wage (t-1) -0.036 * * Table 5. OLS Estimates: Effect of Changes in House Prices on Expected Retirement Age (in years) Years of Education Hispanic Black Married (t-1) Poor Health (t-1) Log Wage (t-1) (1) 0.114 ** Home Equity (1992, $1000s) Business Equity (1992, $1000s) Other Wealth (1992, $1000s) %Δ House Prices (t-1992) ** (3) 0.103 (0.037) (0.037) (0.037) -0.084 -0.193 -0.739 (0.379) (0.392) (0.459) -0.374 -0.385 -0.333 (0.234) (0.235) (0.248) 0.385 0.390 0.341 (0.291) (0.29) (0.3) -0.201 -0.196 -0.179 (0.215) (0.215) (0.215) -0.588 ** (0.188) Has Retiree Health Ins. (t-1) (2) 0.115 -0.715 -0.585 ** (0.187) ** -0.716 -0.636 ** -0.706 (0.159) (0.156) -1.619 -1.609 -1.658 (1.315) (1.313) (1.336) -0.077 -0.076 -0.073 (0.421) (0.418) (0.454) 0.048 0.056 -0.022 (0.256) (0.257) (0.253) (0.006) County Unemployment Rate ** -0.020 ** -0.017 (0.006) (0.007) 3.127 -0.522 (3.478) (4.383) Age and Year Dummies Industry and Occupation Codes County Unemployment Rate State Fixed Effects Mean Expected Retirement Age 63.5 6,478 0.203 63.5 6,478 0.204 63.5 6,478 0.215 N R-squared ** Denotes statistical significance at the 5% level and * at the 10% level. Robust standard errors are in parentheses. 26 ** (0.188) (0.159) -0.020 ** ** ** Table 6. Household Fixed Effects Estimates of Effect of Changes in House Prices on Expected Retirement Age (in years) Married (t-1) Poor Health (t-1) Log Wage (t-1) Has Retiree Health Ins. (t-1) %Δ House Prices (t-1992) -0.005 -0.006 (0.472) (0.472) -0.259 -0.259 (0.24) (0.24) -0.094 -0.094 (0.223) (0.223) -0.062 -0.062 (0.144) (0.144) -0.015 (0.007) County Unemployment Rate ** -0.015 ** (0.007) -0.64866 (6.385) Mean Expected Retirement Age N R-square 63.5 6,483 0.039 63.5 6,483 0.038 ** Denotes statistical significance at the 5% level and * at the 10% level. Robust standard errors are in parentheses. 27 Appendix Table 1. OLS Estimates: Effect of Increases and Decreases in House Prices on Retirement Transition Years of Education Hispanic Black Married (t-1) (1) -0.001 (2) -0.001 (3) -0.001 (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) -0.008 -0.006 -0.006 (0.013) (0.014) (0.015) -0.013 -0.012 -0.013 (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) -0.036 ** (0.012) Poor Health (t-1) Log Wage (t-1) Has Retiree Health Ins. (t-1) 0.029 ** % Increase in House Prices (t-1992) % Decrease in House Prices (t-1992) 0.030 0.009 0.009 0.009 (0.007) (0.007) (0.008) 0.086 -0.043 ** 0.027 ** (0.006) * 0.086 * (0.051) ** -0.042 0.026 ** (0.012) 0.077 -0.040 0.023 0.024 (0.014) 0.00083 ** 0.00081 (0.0003) (0.0003) (0.0004) 0.00050 0.00055 -0.00007 (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) -0.056 -0.061 (0.114) (0.134) 9,669 0.078 9,669 0.078 9,669 0.082 % Retiring N R-squared ** Denotes statistical significance at the 5% level and * at the 10% level. Robust standard errors are in parentheses. 28 ** (0.014) (0.015) ** ** (0.055) 0.023 0.00084 ** (0.006) (0.015) County Unemployment Rate Age and Year Dummies Industry and Occupation Codes County Unemployment Rate State Fixed Effects ** (0.011) 0.027 ** (0.011) (0.011) (0.012) Other Wealth (1992, $1000s) 0.029 -0.038 (0.011) (0.051) Business Equity (1992, $1000s) ** (0.012) (0.006) Home Equity (1992, $1000s) -0.037 * * Appendix Table 2. OLS Estimates: Effect of Increases and Decreases in House Prices on Expected Retirement Age Years of Education Hispanic Black Married (t-1) Poor Health (t-1) Log Wage (t-1) (1) 0.117 ** Home Equity (1992, $1000s) Business Equity (1992, $1000s) Other Wealth (1992, $1000s) % Increase in House Prices (t-1992) % Decrease in House Prices (t-1992) ** (3) 0.106 (0.037) (0.037) (0.037) -0.073 -0.193 -0.753 (0.378) (0.392) (0.458) -0.396 * -0.410 * (0.238) (0.249) 0.396 0.403 0.356 (0.29) (0.29) (0.3) -0.196 -0.190 -0.171 (0.215) (0.215) (0.215) -0.586 ** -0.715 -0.582 ** (0.187) ** -0.716 -0.634 ** -0.712 (0.159) (0.155) -1.644 -1.635 -1.644 (1.322) (1.32) (1.334) -0.089 -0.089 -0.096 (0.42) (0.417) (0.451) 0.045 0.054 -0.035 (0.256) (0.257) (0.254) ** -0.023 ** -0.023 (0.008) (0.008) (0.008) 0.002 -0.001 -0.019 (0.016) (0.016) (0.016) 3.487 -0.125 (3.515) (4.416) County Unemployment Rate Age and Year Dummies Industry and Occupation Codes County Unemployment Rate State Fixed Effects Mean Expected Retirement Age 63.5 6,477 0.204 63.5 6,477 0.204 63.5 6,477 0.215 N R-squared ** Denotes statistical significance at the 5% level and * at the 10% level. Robust standard errors are in parentheses. 29 ** (0.187) (0.159) -0.023 ** -0.353 (0.237) (0.188) Has Retiree Health Ins. (t-1) (2) 0.117 ** **