On Business Cycle Asymmetries in ‘G5’ Countries Khurshid M. Kiani Department of Economics, 302-D Waters Hall, Kansas State University Manhattan Kansas, 66506-4001, USA Tel: +1-785-532-4581; Fax: +1-785-532-6919; E-mail: mkkiani@ksu.edu Prasad V. Bidarkota* Department of Economics, 245 Waters Hall, Kansas State University Manhattan Kansas, 66506-4001, USA Tel: +1-785-532-4578; Fax: +1-785-532-6919; E-mail: pbidarko@ksu.edu May 29, 2002 Word count: Main text – 4,658 * Corresponding author. Abstract We investigate whether business cycle dynamics in five industrialized countries are characterized by asymmetries in conditional mean. We provide evidence on this issue using a variety of time series models. Our approach is fully parametric. Our testing strategy is robust to any conditional heteroskedasticity, outliers, and / or long memory that may be present. Our results indicate fairly strong evidence of nonlinearities in the conditional mean dynamics of the GDP growth rates for Canada, Japan, and the US. For France and the UK, the conditional mean dynamics appear to be largely linear. Our study shows that while the existence of conditional heteroskedasticity and long memory does not have much affect on testing for linearity in the conditional mean, accounting for outliers does reduce the evidence against linearity. Key phrases: business cycles; asymmetries; nonlinearities; conditional heteroskedasticity; long memory; outliers; real GDP; stable distributions JEL codes: B22, B23, C32, E32 2 1 Introduction The possible existence of asymmetries in economic fluctuations is being tested extensively using aggregate macroeconomic data. While studies such as Neftci (1984), Brunner (1992, 1997), Beaudry and Koop (1993), Potter (1995), and Ramsey and Rothman (1996) conclude that there are significant asymmetries, others (Falk (1986), Sichel (1989), DeLong and Summers (1986), and Diebold and Rudebusch (1990)) have either failed to confirm these findings or have found only weak evidence supporting them. Detecting any nonlinearities that may be present in business cycles is important for several reasons. Nonlinearities imply that the effects of expansionary and contractionary monetary policy shocks on output are not symmetric. Any nonlinearities would invalidate measures of the persistence of monetary policy and other shocks on GNP that are based on linear models, including those derived from vector autoregressions (VARs). Nonlinearities would necessitate that in order to validate theories of business cycles, such as the real business cycle (RBC) theories, one would need to go beyond merely matching the first and second moments of data with the moments implied by the theories in question. Granger (1995) recommends testing for linearity using heteroskedasticity-robust tests. French and Sichel (1993) and Brunner (1992, 1997) show the existence of conditional heteroskedasticity in real GNP data. Scheinkman and LeBaron (1989) report a weakening 3 of evidence against linearity after accounting for conditional heteroskedasticity in this series. There is a growing perception that the evidence of nonlinearity reported in several studies so far may be due to the presence of outliers. Tsay (1988) demonstrates that linearity could be rejected by the presence of outliers. Blanchard and Watson (1986) demonstrate the existence of outliers in GNP data. Balke and Fomby (1994) and Scheinkman and LeBaron (1989) report weakened evidence against linearity in US real GNP data once outliers are taken into account. Several macroeconomic time series data have been characterized as fractionally integrated processes in a number of studies (Sowell, 1992b). While investigating the possible existence of asymmetries in economic fluctuations it is important to use time series models that describe both the long and short run properties of the data accurately. Most of the studies on business cycles test for asymmetries without taking into account conditional heteroskedasticity, outliers, and / or long memory. An exception is Bidarkota (2000). This study finds robust evidence of non-linearities in the conditional mean dynamics of the chain-weighted quarterly US GNP growth rates. The present study seeks to extend the analysis in Bidarkota (2000) to an examination of several developed countries. There are compelling reasons why such an extension is a worthwhile undertaking. For instance, it is of interest to know whether business cycles in 4 different countries are all alike. If they are, then this provides a serious challenge to macroeconomic theorists to develop theories of business cycles that can explain fluctuations in economic activity in different countries without relying on country specific institutional features. Documenting business cycle characteristics in different countries is a first step in this task. Also, in understanding spillover and contagion effects in international business cycles, macroeconometricians traditionally rely on linear vector autoregressions (VARs). These are convenient, simple to work with, well understood, and widely used in the literature. However, there are some new studies that attempt to build nonlinear multivariate models for studying business cycle linkages across countries (Anderson and Vahid (1998), Anderson and Ramsey (2002)). Since multivariate nonlinear modeling is complex, it is important that we document compelling evidence against linearity in international data first before venturing to build these more complicated models. This study is organized as follows. Section 2 outlines the various empirical models that are used in our investigations. Section 3 discusses some important issues related to the estimation of the models. Section 4 provides details on the data sources and some useful summary statistics on the raw data. Section 5 reports detailed empirical results on specification search and parameter estimates. Statistical tests for asymmetries and other hypotheses of interest are reported in detail in Section 6. Important conclusions that can be drawn from the results in the study are summarized in Section 7. 5 2 Non-Linear Time Series Models In this study we use three classes of models to detect the possible presence of asymmetries in real output series for the countries under investigation. These are termed CDR-Augmented, CDR-Switching, and SETAR-Switching models. Within each of these three classes of models, we entertain four different versions of the models. Model 1 incorporates stable distributions, conditional heteroskedasticity, and fractional differencing. Imposing no fractional differencing (i.e., only integer differencing) on Model 1 yields Model 2. Imposing homoskedasticity on Model 2 gives Model 3. Finally, restricting the errors in Model 3 to come from Gaussian distributions gives Model 4. Model 1 is the most general and it nests all other Models 2 through 4. Each of the three classes of models listed above is described in detail in the following three sub-sections. 2.1 CDR Augmented Models Beaudry and Koop (1993) estimated a standard autoregressive moving average (ARMA) model, augmented with an ad hoc nonlinear term for capturing asymmetries. This nonlinear term labeled the current depth of a recession measures the gap between the current level of output and the economy’s historical maximum level. Bidarkota (1999, 2000) extended this model by incorporating stable distributions, conditional heteroskedasticity, and long memory. In this study here we use this model. In this class of models the most general model (Model 1) can be described as follows: 6 Φ ( L)(1 − L)d ( ∆y t − µ ) = [ Ω( L) − 1]CDR t + ε t ε t | I t − 1 ~ z tc t , (1a) z t ~ i.i.d.Sα ( 0,1) c αt = b1 + b2 c αt −1 + b3 | ε t −1 |α (1b) Here, ∆y t ≡ 100 * ∆(ln GDPt ) is the growth rate of GDP, its unconditional mean is µ, d is the differencing parameter that takes on real values, Ω (.) and Φ (.) are polynomials of orders r and p respectively in the lag operator L , with Ω (0) = Φ ( 0) = 1 . The term CDR t is the current depth of recession that permits recessions to be less or more persistent than expansions depending on the parameter estimates. It is defined as CDR t = max{y t − j } j≥0 − y t . A random variable X is said to have a symmetric stable distribution Sα (δ,c) if its log characteristic function can be expressed as ln E exp( iXt ) = i δt − | ct | α . δ ∈ [−∞ , ∞ ] is the location parameter that shifts the distribution either to the left or the right along the real line, c ∈ [0, ∞ ] is the scale parameter that expands or contracts the distribution about δ , and α ∈ [0,2] is the characteristic exponent governing tail behavior. Smaller values of this exponent indicate thicker tails. When α = 2 we obtain the normal distribution. Equation 1b shows the evolution of the scales of the conditional distribution. When we set α to 2 in the model, we obtain a normal GARCH (1,1) process for the conditional variance in the volatility specification. Our Model 1b is analogous to the power ARCH model introduced by Ding, Granger, and Engle (1993), with the exception that in the 7 latter specification the distribution of z t does not depend on the characteristic exponent α. Dependence on α emerges here naturally because we are allowing for disturbances to be drawn from the stable family. Liu and Brorsen (1995) also modeled volatility of the daily foreign currency returns using stable errors. Similarly, McCulloch (1985) fitted a GARCH-stable model to bond returns using absolute values instead of α powers. When d = 0 we get a unit root in y t , but with d = −1 we end up with y t being integrated of order zero I (0). ARFIMA models with long memory are defined in terms of the rate of decay of their autocovariances, so the extension of these models to infinite variance stable shocks is not immediate. Kokoszka and Taqqu (1995) contributed significantly to the theory of fractionally differenced ARMA models with infinite-variance stable innovations. According to Brockwell and Davis (1991), a stationary casual and invertible solution to an ARFIMA model with Gaussian errors requires that | d |< 0.5 . Kokoszka and Taqqu (1995) showed that the existence of a unique casual MA (∞) representation to an ARFIMA model with stable shocks requires α (d − 1) < −1 . This implies then that d be positive when α > 1 . Moreover, for the ARFIMA model to be a solution to an AR (∞) process requires that α > 1 and | d |< (1 − 1 / α) . In order to force our estimated models to possess casual and invertible representations, we restrict α and d in Equation 1 to satisfy these constraints. 8 Although we have an ad hoc non-linear CDR t term within an otherwise standard AR framework with fractional differencing, this model is simple and parsimonious. When Ω (L) = 1 , Equation 1a reduces to an autoregressive (AR) model with non-integer differencing. Since it nests AR models, we can use the standard t-statistic or the likelihood ratio (LR) statistic to test the statistical significance of the non-linear term governing the conditional mean dynamics.1 With Ω (L) ≡ 1 + ω1L + ω2 L2 + ... + ωr Lr , when the autoregressive lag order p is 0 and r is 1, ω1 = 0 yields a random walk with drift. However, a positive ω1 implies that negative shocks are less persistent whereas a negative ω1 implies that positive shocks are less persistent. The existence of asymmetries essentially means that either the innovations are asymmetric but the impulse transmission mechanism is linear, or that the innovations are symmetric but the impulse transmission mechanism is nonlinear, or that the innovations are asymmetric and the impulse transmission mechanism is nonlinear. However, it would be hard to disentangle the asymmetric innovations from the nonlinear propagation mechanism, if they both exist in a data series. Although asymmetric α -stable distributions exist and are well defined, to determine whether asymmetries in the conditional mean dynamics of the real GDP growth rates are 1 However, the asymptotic distribution of the t-test for the significance of the non-linear CDR t term in the model given by Equation (1a) is non standard (Hess and Iwata, 1997), both when the dependent variable is non-stationary [i.e. integrated of order one I(1)], and when it is stationary [I(0)]. 9 caused by asymmetric impulses being propagated linearly or symmetric impulses being propagated nonlinearly or asymmetric impulses being propagated nonlinearly is beyond the scope of this study. Here, we are merely investigating whether asymmetries exist in the conditional mean regardless of how they can best be characterized. 2.2 CDR-Switching Models Autoregressive models with time varying parameters (Tucci, 1995), threshold autoregressive models (TAR), regime-switching models (Hamilton, 1989), and many other nonlinear models have been used to capture asymmetries. TAR models (Tong and Lim, 1980) are piecewise linear autoregressions. They are not only capable of approximating a general nonlinear time series model of the form y t = f ( y t −1 ) + ε t and capturing jump phenomenon, but they also admit limit cycles. Tsay (1988) introduces a procedure for building and testing TAR models. Beaudry and Koop (1993) also estimated a switching autoregressive moving average model with the switch governed by a restriction defined in term of the current depth of recession CDR t . In this section we use this switching model as modified by Bidarkota (2000). The most general model estimated within this class of models is as follows: In Regime 1: (1− φ1L − φ2L2 )(1− L)d (∆yt − µ1) = εt (2a) 10 ε t | I t − 1 ~ z tc t , z t ~ i.i.d.Sα ( 0,1) c αt = b1 + b2 c αt −1 + b3 | ε t −1 |α (2b) In Regime 2: (1 − φ3L − φ4L2 )(1 − L)d (∆yt − µ2 ) = εt ε t | I t−1 ~ z t γc t , (2c) z t ~ i.i.d.Sα ( 0,1) c αt = b1 + b 2ctα−1 + b3 | ε t−1 / γ |α (2d) When CDR t −1 = 0 , we get regime 1 and when CDR t −1 > 0 we obtain regime 2. The unconditional mean of the process and the AR coefficients in the two regimes are different. The parameter γ in regime 2 shows that the model has different scales in the two regimes as well. 2.3 SETAR-Switching Models This is identical to the CDR-Switching model, except for what governs switching between the regimes. When a switch is governed by restrictions that are defined in terms of the observed series y t , these models are called self-exciting threshold autoregressive (SETAR) models. Potter (1995) estimated this type of model with a single restriction for the log real GNP. The restriction is defined in terms of whether, ∆y t− d > r , where yt is log real GNP, d is the delay and r is the threshold parameter. 11 The most general model estimated within this class of models is as follows: In Regime 1: (1− φ1L − φ2L2 )(1− L)d (∆yt − µ1) = εt ε t | I t −1 ~ zt ct z ~ iid (3a) Sα (0,1) c αt = b1 + b2 c αt −1 + b3 | ε t −1 |α (3b) In Regime 2: (1 − φ3L − φ4L2 )(1 − L)d (∆yt − µ2 ) = εt ε t | It −1 ~ zt γct z ~ iid (3c) Sα (0,1) c αt = b1 + b 2ctα−1 + b3 | ε t−1 / γ |α (3d) When ∆y t −2 > 0 , we get regime 1 and when ∆y t −2 ≤ 0 , we get regime 2. 3 Estimation Issues As mentioned earlier, Beaudry and Koop (1993) simply included an additive nonlinear term in a standard autoregressive moving average (ARMA) model to capture asymmetries in business cycles with the assumption that the shocks are normally distributed. Although addition of a nonlinear term in a standard autoregressive moving average framework is ad hoc, it does not impose any estimation problems. Bidarkota 12 (1999, 2000) used this model without any moving average terms but with errors having a more general stable distribution, conditional heteroskedasticity, and long memory. As in Bidarkota (1999, 2000), we do not consider any moving average (MA) terms in the specification of the model. Maximum likelihood estimation of mixed ARMA models with stable errors poses a challenge, although the Whittle estimator (Mikosch et al, 1995) and minimum dispersion estimators (Brockwell and Davis, 1991) have been used in this context. We restrict ourselves to symmetric stable distributions here for a technical reason. We use the computational algorithm due to McCulloch (1996) to obtain stable densities for maximum likelihood estimation of our models. This algorithm works only when errors are symmetric. However, Nolan (undated) has developed computational routines for maximum likelihood estimation of models with stable distributions. For the estimation of ARFIMA models the exact full information maximum likelihood (ML) method of Sowell (1992a) may be adopted if the errors are iid normal. But for the more complicated non-normal conditionally heteroskedastic models here, we use the conditional sum of squares (CSS) estimator. Baillie et al (1996) also used the conditional sum of squares (CSS) method, originally proposed in the context of AFRIMA models by Hosking (1984), to estimate their ARFIMA-GARCH models, with normal and Student-t errors. The CSS procedure is equivalent to the full information MLE asymptotically. Baillie et al (1996) discussed 13 some properties of the CSS estimator in the context of ARFIMA models, particularly with respect to its bias. They noted that not only does the CSS estimator do well when they compared with it Sowell’s (1992a) exact MLE but also that it is computationally feasible for more complex models. Essentially we fit an ARMA model to the series (1 − L) d ( ∆y t − µ) that is obtained by expanding the differencing operator (1 − L)d with the binomial expansion, and truncating the infinite series at the first available observation. The CSS estimator is discussed for ARMA models in Box and Jenkins (1976). 4 Preliminary Data Analysis 4.1 Data Sources We obtained quarterly GDP data from the International Financial Statistics (IFS) CDROM (September 2001) for Canada, France, Japan, the United Kingdom (UK), and the United States of America (USA).2 The dataset spans the period from 1957:1 to 2000:4 for all countries except France for which the data begins in 1970:1. Table 1.1 provides 2 Initially, we tried working with all the G7 countries that include, in addition to the above five countries, Germany and Italy. However, Germany poses a unique problem on account of its reunification. It’s GDP increased by 35.43 percent in 1991:1. Data for Italy showed an inexplicable spike of 87.5 percent annualized quarterly growth rate in 1970:1. Consequently we decided to exclude these two countries from our analysis. 14 further details on the dataset used for each country. Figure 1 plots the logarithmic GDP series and Figure 2 plots the annualized quarterly growth rates. 4.2 Summary Statistics Table 1.2 provides some useful statistics on the raw data and Table 1.3 summarizes preliminary statistical inferences for some interesting hypotheses. The average annualized quarterly GDP growth rates range from 2.44 to 8.84 percent, with the average growth rates for all countries being significantly positive. UK has the lowest and Japan has the highest growth rate. The quarterly (annualized) standard deviations range from 2.40 for France to 7.80 for Japan. Skewness measures range from –0.54 for France to 0.64 for Japan, being statistically significant for all countries except Canada. Excess kurtosis measures range from 0.14 for Canada to 2.85 for the UK, with significant fat tails found in UK, US, and Japan (marginal). The Jarque-Bera test rejects normality for all countries except Canada. These preliminary results are subject to some qualification because the tests are based on the assumption that the growth rates are iid. As will be evident later, this assumption is not appropriate. The Augmented Dicky Fuller (ADF) test indicates unit roots in levels (with constant and time trend) for all countries but not in growth rates (with constant only). The only 15 exception is Japan for which the test fails to reject unit roots in growth rates with a constant term only but does reject with constant and time trend. Goldfeld-Quandt test fails to reject homoskedasticity in all countries and the Lagrange Multiplier (LM) test detects autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity (ARCH) only in Japan. 5 Empirical Results 5.1 Specification Search An extensive specification search for each country was conducted for the four versions (Model 1 through Model 4) of each of the three classes of models described in section 2. For the CDR-Augmented class of models, the specification search was done over all parameterizations with lag orders for the autoregressive and CDR t terms of three or less for parsimony. For the two classes of switching models, namely the CDR-Switching and SETAR-Switching models, the search was done with the autoregressive lag polynomials in the two regimes restricted to be of orders (3,3), (2,2), (1,1), or (0,0). The best parameterizations for each version within each class of models are selected for each country by the minimum Schwarz Bayesian criterion. The chosen parameterizations are reported in Tables 2.1, 2.2, and 2.3 for CDR-Augmented, CDR-Switching, and SETAR-Switching models, respectively. The table also reports the number of parameters 16 in the models, the maximized log-likelihood values, and the values of the Akaike information (AIC) and Schwarz Bayesian (SBC) criteria, respectively. Since the AIC is well known to yield relatively over parameterized specifications of models in general, we choose the versions selected by the minimum SBC criterion in what follows. These selected versions of the models are reported in Table 2.4. 5.2 Parameter Estimates Tables 3.1, 3.2, and 3.3 contain parameter estimates for the best parameterizations of the most general versions (Model 1) within each of the three classes of models, namely, the CDR-Augmented, CDR-Switching, and SETAR-Switching models. The estimates are presented for all countries analyzed in this study. In Table 3.1 the estimates of the unconditional mean µ range from –0.028 percent per quarter for Japan to 0.905 percent per quarter for Canada. The value of the characteristic exponent α ranges from virtually 2 for Canada and Japan to a low of 1.734 for the UK. This is understandable given that fat tails were found in Table 1.2 to be most prominent in the UK and absent in Canada. The volatility persistence parameter b 2 is estimated to be between 0.827 for the US to 0.936 for Canada. The ARCH parameter b 3 takes values from 0.026 for Canada to 0.055 for the UK. The sum of the GARCH parameter estimates b 2 + b 3 takes values of 0.962 for Canada to a low of 0.877 for the US. The fractional 17 differencing parameter d is estimated to be between -0.464 for the US and 0.499 for Japan. The estimates of the autoregressive (AR) parameters range from 0.784 for the US to a low of –0.389 for Japan. The best models selected within this class of models for Canada and the UK have no AR terms. In Table 3.2, the parameter estimates of the unconditional mean in regime 1 µ1 are close to the values of µ reported in Table 3.1 for the CDR-Augmented model, except for Japan. The estimates of the unconditional mean in regime 2 µ 2 vary between –2.65 for Japan to 2.76 for the US. For all countries, excepting Japan, regime 1 is associated with lower mean growth rates than regime 2. For Japan, this is reversed. The estimates of the characteristic exponent α are very similar to those reported in Table 3.1. The estimates of the volatility persistence parameter b 2 are uniformly higher and the estimates of the ARCH parameter b 3 are uniformly lower in this case than the values of the corresponding parameters reported earlier in Table 3.1. For all countries excepting Japan, the scale ratio γ in regime 2 is estimated to be between 0.914 (for the US) and 0.961 (for France). For Japan, this parameter is estimated to be 1.08. Given that for all countries (excepting Japan) regime 1 is associated with lower growth rates, this means that for all countries including Japan lower mean GDP growth rate regimes are associated with relatively higher volatility. 18 Only Japan has AR terms (of first order only) appearing in the best parameterization within this class of models. The estimates of the AR parameters in both regimes are negative. For the SETAR switching model estimates reported in Table 3.3, no single regime is necessarily associated uniformly across all countries with lower growth rates. Furthermore, the parameter estimates also suggest that low mean growth rate regimes are no longer necessarily associated with relatively higher volatility. All other parameter estimates, however, are generally similar to the values reported earlier for the CDRAugmented and CDR-Switching models. 6 Hypotheses Tests We performed four types of hypotheses tests on the estimated models. The first is a test for normality. The second is a test for homoskedasticity. The third tests for the possible presence of long memory. The last is a test for linearity in the conditional mean. The following sub-section describes the various tests and sub-section 6.2 provides empirical results on the hypotheses tests. 6.1 Description of Various Tests 6.1.1 Test for Normality 19 We performed a normality test based on the value of α . If α equals 2, normality results. If the value of a is less than 2, then the model is non-normal stable. This test compares the likelihood ratio (LR) statistic for two models with identical parameterizations. Since the null hypothesis for this test lies on the boundary of admissible values for α , the LR test statistic does not have the usual χ 2 distribution asymptotically. Therefore, the test here is based on small sample critical values generated by Monte Carlo simulations reported in McCulloch (1997, Table 4, panel b). 6.1.2 Test for Homoskedasticity The second test is a test for homoskedasticity. Under the null of homoskedasticity, the GARCH parameters b 2 = b 3 = 0 . The test is based on the likelihood ratio test statistic. Since b1 and c0 end up being trivial transformations of one another under the null hypothesis, it is not clear whether the LR test statistic asymptotically has 2 or 3 degrees of freedom. We base our statistical inference on critical values derived conservatively from the χ32 distribution. 6.1.3 Test for Long Memory The null hypothesis is d = 0 implying that the logarithm of GDP has a unit root. The alternative of d ≠ 0 implies that the logarithm of GDP is described as a fractionally differenced series. Depending on the estimates of d that are obtained, the logarithm of GDP could be a stationary or a non-stationary series, with or without long memory. See Baillie (1996) for an extensive survey on fractionally differenced processes. The test is 20 once again based on the likelihood ratio. Model 1 is the unrestricted model and Model 2 is the restricted model with d restricted to zero. The test statistic is distributed as the χ12 since we have only one restriction here. 6.1.4 Test for Linearity in Conditional Mean The last is a test for linearity in the conditional mean. While the three tests above are performed alternatively using the various versions within all the three classes of models, the test for linearity in the conditional mean is done using different versions of the models within only the two classes of switching models. This is because the minimum SBC criterion ends up selecting among the four different versions of the CDRAugmented class of models a version and a parameterization that does not include the additive CDR term for any of the countries except France (see Tables 2.4 and 2.1). Footnote 1 reports some added difficulty in testing for the significance of the CDR term with a standard t-test or an LR test. Depending on the versions of the two classes of switching models used, we end up testing for linearity successively using homoskedastic Gaussian models, homoskedastic stable models, GARCH stable models, and long memory GARCH stable models. Under the null hypothesis of linearity in conditional mean, the unconditional means in the two regimes µ 1 and µ2 are equal, the scale ratio γ is equal to one, and the corresponding autoregressive coefficients in the two regimes, if present in the specific parameterizations of the model versions used in the test, are equal. If the null hypothesis is not rejected then 21 we only have one regime (linear conditional mean dynamics). If not, then we have two distinct regimes describing the GDP growth rates. 6.2 Empirical Results on Hypotheses Tests Hypotheses tests for normality, homoskedasticity, long memory, and linearity in conditional mean were performed as elaborated in the earlier sub-section. The empirical results of the various hypotheses tests listed above are reported in Tables 4.1, 4.2, and 4.3, respectively, for the CDR-Augmented, CDR-Switching and SETAR Switching models. All tests are based on the likelihood ratio (LR) test statistic. For each of the three tables, a different test is reported in the various rows of the first column. For each such test, the numbers in the five rows in the other columns for that test are the LR test statistics for the five countries arranged alphabetically in ascending order. P-values are reported in parentheses. All statistical inferences are drawn at the five percent significance level. 6.2.1 Results on Normality The test for normality easily rejects for the UK and the US. The evidence is somewhat weaker for France and Japan. For Canada, however, the test fails to reject normality overwhelmingly. The test results are largely unchanged when we account for conditional heteroskedasticity and long memory. 6.2.2 Results on Homoskedasticity 22 From the three tables, it is clear that when we test for homoskedasticity using Model 2, all countries except France show strong evidence against homoskedasticity. France strongly fails to reject homoskedasticity. The statistical inferences remain unchanged when we go from 5 to 10 percent significance level. Also, there are no changes in the inferences when we do the tests after accounting for long memory with Model 1. 6.2.3 Results on Long Memory The test for d = 0 strongly rejects in all countries with all three classes of models except for the UK with SETAR Switching models. The statistical inferences are the same at the 5 and 10 percent significance level. However, it is important to note that Sowell’s (1992b) Monte Carlo simulations suggest that the true small sample p-values may be higher than the asymptotic χ12 p-values. Typically, GDP data tend to be largely uninformative about the nature of their long run properties and it is generally hard to rule out trend stationarity, unit roots, as well as fractional differencing from these data series. 6.2.4 Results on Linearity in Conditional Mean Canada, Japan, and the US show fairly strong evidence against linearity in the conditional mean dynamics of the GDP growth rates. Accounting for conditional heteroskedasticity and long memory seems to be relatively unimportant when testing for linearity. However, accounting for outliers decreases the evidence against linearity. Statistical inferences are not affected much when we change the significance level of the test from 10 to 5 percent. 6.3 Discussion of Results on Hypotheses Tests 23 Our results on nonlinearity in the conditional mean for the US are in line with Bidarkota (2000). This shows that the evidence against linearity in mean for the US is robust to changes in the sample period. Koop and Potter (2001) investigate whether nonlinearities could arise from structural instability. Blanchard and Simon (2001) show a slowdown in the variance of US economic activity suggesting a possible structural change in the early 1980s. We do not account for this possibility in this study. Diebold and Inoue (2001) demonstrate that spurious evidence of long memory may be found in a series that undergoes occasional structural change. This is analogous to the spurious evidence of unit roots in a series with occasional breaks (Perron, 1989). Our results on long memory are subject to this caveat. 7 Conclusions We used three classes of models, namely, the CDR-Augmented models, CDR-Switching models, and SETAR-Switching models for testing asymmetries in the conditional mean dynamics of GDP data in five industrialized countries. Our approach is fully parametric. Our time series models account for the possibility of conditional heteroskedasticity, outliers, and long memory in the data series. 24 Our results indicate fairly strong evidence of nonlinearities in the conditional mean dynamics of the GDP growth rates for Canada, Japan, and the US. For France and the UK, the conditional mean dynamics seem to be largely linear. Our study shows that the Switching models capture non-linearity better than the CDRAugmented models. Accounting for conditional heteroskedasticity and long memory is relatively unimportant when testing for linearity. However, accounting for outliers decreases the evidence against linearity. Our results also indicate that the GDP series for all countries excepting France reject homoskedasticity. Long memory appears to be pervasive. While normality is strongly rejected for the US and the UK, the evidence is somewhat weaker for France and Japan, and overwhelmingly in favor of normality for Canada. 25 Table 1.1: Data Description Canada France Japan UK USA Quarterly Real GDP Quarterly Real GDP Quarterly Nominal GDP Quarterly Real GDP Quarterly Real GDP Sample Period 1957:12000:4 1970:12000:4 1957:12000:4 1957:12000:4 1957:12000:4 Sample Length 176 124 176 176 176 Data Series Notes on Table 1.1 1. We obtained the quarterly seasonally adjusted GDP data for all countries from the September 2001 edition of the International Financial Statistics (IFS) CD-ROM. 2. We used nominal GDP for Japan because seasonally adjusted data was only available for the nominal series and not for the real series on the IFS CD-ROM. 26 Table 1.2: Summary Statistics Canada France Japan UK USA 0.91 0.63 2.21 0.61 0.83 (p-value for mean = 0) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) Standard Deviation 0.97 0.60 1.95 1.05 0.95 Skewness 0.17 -0.54 0.64 0.36 -0.44 (0.49) (0.01) (0.00) (0.03) (0.01) 0.14 0.48 0.57 2.85 1.26 (0.32) (0.14) (0.06) (0.00) (0.00) 0.21 7.16 14.15 62.8 17.16 (0.89) (0.03) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) Levels (constant + trend) -2.24 -2.25 -1.83 -1.39 0.14 First Differences (constant only) -4.59 -3.99 -1.80 -4.64 -4.83 Orders of Significant Autocorrelations (at 5% level) Orders of Significant Partial Autocorrelations (at 5% level) Goldfeld-Quandt Test 1-3 1,2 3 1,2 1,11 1,2 3,8,16,31 1,2 24.81 20.1 36.21 14.72 13.67 (p-value for homoskedasticity) (1.00) (1.00) (0.99) (1.00) (1.00) 0.01 0.00 24.51 0.01 0.03 (0.91) (0.95) (0.00) (0.91) (0.85) Mean (p-value for skewness = 0) Excess Kurtosis (p-value for excess kurtosis = 0) Jarque-Bera Test (p-value for normality) ADF Test for Unit Roots LM Test for ARCH (p-value for no ARCH effects) 1-10, 12, 13, 16 1-5,8,9 27 Notes on Table 1.2 1. All statistics reported are for quarterly growth rates defined as 100∆ log y t , except the ADF test in levels for which the test statistics are for log levels log y t . 2. P-values for statistics pertaining to skewness, excess kurtosis, Jarque-Bera, Goldfeld-Quandt, and the LM test for ARCH are reported in parentheses below the test statistics. 3. Optimal lag order for the ADF tests is chosen using the minimum SBC criterion. Asymptotic critical values at the 10% significance level for the model with constant, and with constant and time trend, are -2.57 and -3.13, respectively. 4. Optimal lag order for the LM test is chosen using the minimum SBC criterion. 28 Table 1.3: Summary of Statistical Inferences Canada France Japan UK USA Nonzero Mean Y Y Y Y Y Skewness N N Y Y N Fat Tails N N N Y Y Non-Normality N Y Y Y Y Levels (constant + trend) First Differences (constant only) Y Y Y Y Y N N Y N N Homoskedasticity Y Y Y Y Y ARCH Effects N N Y N N Unit Roots 29 Notes on Table 1.3 1. Y indicates presence of, and N indicates absence of, the characteristic listed in the first column of the corresponding row. For example, N for USA in the second row indicates absence of skewness. These inferences are based on the statistics and p-values reported in Table 1.2. 3. All statistical inferences are done assuming a 5 percent level of significance. 30 TABLE 2.1: Specification Search - CDR-Augmented Models Model 4 Model 3 Model 2 Model 1 (1,0) (2,1) (3,0) (0,0) (1,0) (1,0) (2,1) (3,0) (0,0) (1,1) (1,0) (2,1) (3,0) (1,0) (1,0) (0,0) (2,0) (1,0) (0,0) (1,0) 3 5 5 2 3 4 6 6 3 5 7 9 9 7 7 7 9 8 7 8 Log likelihood -231.10 -106.31 -308.26 -252.12 -224.23 -231.07 -105.28 -301.97 -240.44 -218.70 -219.01 -105.28 -281.87 -219.84 -209.63 -219.30 -107.27 -282.45 -219.73 -207.33 AIC 468.21 222.62 626.52 508.24 454.46 470.14 222.57 615.93 486.87 447.39 452.01 228.56 581.74 453.68 433.26 452.60 232.55 580.90 453.45 430.66 SBC 477.65 236.52 642.23 514.54 463.90 482.73 239.24 634.78 496.32 463.13 474.04 253.65 610.02 475.71 455.29 474.63 257.63 606.04 475.48 455.84 Model parameterization selected by minimum SBC criterion Number of parameters 31 Notes on Table 2.1 1. For each item listed in the first column, the five rows in the subsequent columns for that item denote the corresponding statistics for the five countries Canada, France, Japan, UK, and USA in that order. 2. The most general model is Model 1. We get Model 2 by imposing d = 0 . Imposing homoskedasticity on Model 2, we get Model 3. Setting α = 2 in Model 3 yields Model 4. 32 TABLE 2.2: Specification Search – CDR-Switching Models Model 4 Model 3 Model 2 Model 1 (1,1) (2,2) (2,2) (0,0) (1,1) (1,1) (1,1) (3,3) (0,0) (1,1) (1,1) (1,1) (3,3) (0,0) (1,1) (0,0) (0,0) (1,1) (0,0) (0,0) 6 8 8 4 6 7 7 11 5 7 10 10 14 8 10 9 9 11 9 9 Log likelihood -227.18 -108.92 -306.92 -249.50 -213.74 -226.95 -112.54 -295.19 -238.63 -210.32 -211.11 -112.30 -269.70 -218.04 -202.42 -212.22 -108.83 -274.89 -216.05 -201.03 AIC 466.35 233.85 629.83 507.00 439.48 467.90 239.07 612.38 487.26 434.64 442.21 244.61 567.4 452.08 424.84 442.44 235.67 571.79 450.09 420.06 SBC 485.20 256.08 654.92 519.57 458.33 489.89 258.53 646.87 502.97 456.63 473.63 272.40 611.30 477.21 456.25 470.72 260.68 606.28 478.37 448.34 Model parameterization selected by minimum SBC criterion Number of parameters Notes on Table 2.2 1. As in Table 2.1. 33 TABLE 2.3: Specification Search – SETAR-Switching Models Model 4 Model 3 Model 2 Model 1 (0,0) (2,2) (3,3) (3,3) (1,1) (0,0) (1,1) (3,3) (2,2) (0,0) (0,0) (1,1) (3,3) (0,0) -- (0,0) (0,0) (1,1) (0,0) (1,1) 4 8 10 10 6 5 7 11 9 5 8 10 14 8 -- 9 9 11 9 11 Log likelihood -231.08 -107.20 -303.93 -243.15 -214.09 -231.08 -110.97 -297.60 -235.93 -219.47 -228.60 -110.86 -273.23 -217.57 -- -217.49 -109.46 -275.13 -216.37 -199.64 AIC 470.17 230.38 627.86 506.30 440.19 472.17 235.95 617.20 489.85 448.94 473.20 241.71 574.45 451.14 -- 452.98 236.92 572.27 450.75 421.28 SBC 482.20 252.62 659.22 537.71 459.04 487.88 255.40 651.69 518.12 464.65 498.33 269.51 618.35 476.27 -- 481.25 261.93 606.76 479.02 455.83 Model Parameterization selected by minimum SBC criterion Number of parameters Notes on Table 2.3 1. As in Table 2.1. 2. The symbol “--“ denotes missing numbers because the numerical algorithm for maximization of the log likelihood function failed to converge. 34 TABLE 2.4: Model Selection Canada France Japan UK USA Minimum AIC M2 M3 M1 M1 M1 Minimum SBC M2 M4 M1 M1 M2 Minimum AIC M1 M4 M2 M1 M1 Minimum SBC M1 M4 M1 M2 M1 Minimum AIC M1 M3 M2 M1 M1 Minimum SBC M1 M4 M1 M2 M1 CDR-Augmented CDR-Switching SETAR-Switching 35 Notes on Table 2.4 1. For each country and within each class of models, the best versions among all Models 1 through 4 (M1 to M4) are selected and reported in the table. 2. Model selection is done alternatively by two different criteria – the minimum Akaike information criterion (AIC) and the Schwarz Bayesian criterion (SBC). 3. AIC = T ln( RSS) + 2n , where n in the number of estimated parameters and T is the number of usable observations. 4. SBC = T ln( RSS ) + n ln( T) , where n in the number of estimated parameters and T is the number of usable observations. 36 Table 3.1: Parameter Estimates - CDR-Augmented Models Canada (0,0) France (2,0) Japan (1,0) UK (0,0) USA (1,0) 0.905 (0.253) 0.652 (0.092) -0.028 (1.029) 0.675 (0.099) 0.825 (0.028) d 0.266 (0.058) -0.379 (0.233) 0.499 (0.000) 0.145 (0.064) -0.464 (0.209) α 1.999 (0.000) 1.931 (0.074) 1.999 (0.000) 1.734 (0.109) 1.867 (0.095) c0 1.016 (0.200) 0.319 (0.218) 2.313 (0.879) 1.102 (0.427) 1.252 (0.594) b1 0.000 (0.000) 0.010 (0.017) 0.018 (0.009) 0.002 (0.004) 0.017 (0.015) b2 0.936 (0.039) 0.856 (0.171) 0.889 (0.031) 0.861 (0.049) 0.827 (0.084) b3 0.026 (0.020) 0.041 (0.051) 0.038 (0.017) 0.055 (0.024) 0.050 (0.029) φ1 0.614 (0.236) -0.389 0.063 φ2 0.285 (0.149) -107.20 -282.15 Model Parameterization µ Log Likelihood -219.30 0.784 (0.163) -219.93 -207.33 37 Notes on Table 3.1 1. Parameter estimates are reported for the best model specification for version 1 within the class of CDR-Augmented models as determined by the minimum SBC criterion. 2. The most general CDR-Augmented model (Model 1) can be written as: Φ ( L)(1 − L)d (∆y t − µ ) = [Ω ( L) − 1]CDR t + ε t (1a) ε t | I t−1 ~ z t c t , z t ~ i.i.d.Sα ( 0,1) c αt = b1 + b2 c αt −1 + b3 | ε t −1 |α (1b) 38 Table 3.2: Parameter Estimates - CDR-Switching Models Canada (0,0) France (0,0) Japan (1,1) UK (0,0) USA (0,0) µ1 0.906 (0.280) 0.560 (0.255) 0.299 (1.072) 0.721 (0.130) 0.702 (0.314) µ2 1.631 (0.746) 1.205 (0.599) -2.653 (3.424) 0.830 (0.259) 2.760 (0.977) d 0.279 (0.062) 0.281 (0.088) 0.499 (0.000) 0.157 (0.069) 0.292 (0.070) α 1.999 (0.000) 1.941 (0.141) 1.999 (0.000) 1.781 (0.126) 1.908 (0.089) c0 0.914 (0.103) 0.473 0.140 2.020 (0.461) 1.178 (0.402) 0.996 (0.337) b1 0.000 (0.000) 2.1e-11 (0.000) 0.007 (0.005) 4.6e-9 (0.004) 1.4e-7 (0.006) b2 1.014 (0.010) 1.014 (0.044) 0.965 (0.009) 0.930 (0.055) 0.963 (0.047) b3 0.000 (0.000) 1.03e-11 (0.022) 0.000 (0.000) 0.049 (0.025) 0.032 (0.019) Model Parameterization φ1 -0.355 (0.070) -0.703 (0.209) φ3 γ Log Likelihood 0.943 (0.020) 0.961 (0.060) 1.080 (0.039) 0.938 (0.029) 0.914 (0.043) -212.22 -108.83 -274.89 -216.04 -201.03 39 Notes on Table 3.2 1. Parameter estimates are reported for the best model specification for version 1 within the class of CDR-Switching models as determined by the minimum SBC criterion. 2 The most general CDR-Switching model (Model 1) can be written as follows. In Regime 1 when CDR t −1 = 0 : (1− φ1L − φ2L2 )(1− L)d (∆yt − µ1) = εt , ε t | I t − 1 ~ z tc t , (2a) z t ~ i.i.d.Sα ( 0,1) c αt = b1 + b 2ctα−1 + b3 | ε t −1 |α (2b) In Regime 2 when CDR t −1 > 0 : (1 − φ3L − φ4L2 )(1 − L)d (∆y t − µ2 ) = ε t , ε t | I t−1 ~ z t γc t , (2c) z t ~ i.i.d.Sα ( 0,1) c αt = b1 + b 2ctα−1 + b3 | ε t−1 / γ |α (2d) 40 Table 3.3: Parameter Estimates - SETAR-Switching Models Parameters Model Parameterization Canada (0,0) France (0,0) Japan (1,1) UK (0,0) USA (1,1) µ1 0.966 (0.247) 0.811 (0.207) -0.233 (1.034) 0.743 (0.106) 0.830 (0.023) µ2 1.201 (0.704) 0.281 (0.404) 5.872 (6.079) 0.503 (0.283) 0.685 (0.035) d 0.254 (0.066) 0.228 (0.079) 0.499 (0.000) 0.125 (0.066) -0.473 (0.000) α 1.999 (0.000) 1.960 (0.140) 1.999 (0.000) 1.772 (0.122) 1.897 (0.086) c0 1.160 (0.353) 0.419 (0.132) 1.554 (0.347) 1.052 (0.385) 0.895 (0.278) b1 0.000 (0.000) 7.4e-86 (0.000) 0.005 (0.005) 3.1e-9 (0.027) 0.000 (0.000) b2 0.910 (0.051) 1.040 (0.057) 0.970 (0.009) 0.916 (0.056) 0.964 (0.021) b3 0.051 (0.037) 2.7e-9 (0.019) 0.000 (0.000) 0.053 (0.027) 0.022 (0.012) φ1 -0.398 (-0.067) -0.254 (0.444) φ3 γ Log Likelihood 0.940 (0.085) -217.49 0.888 (0.082) -109.46 1.161 (0.063) -275.97 0.769 (0.060) 0.486 (0.158) 0.913 (0.066) -216.37 0.929 (0.064) -199.64 41 Notes on Table 3.3 1. Parameter estimates are reported for the best model specification for version 1 within the class of SETAR-Switching models as determined by the minimum SBC criterion. 2. The most general SETAR-Switching model (Model 1) can be written as follows. In Regime 1 when ∆y t − 2 > 0 : (1− φ1L − φ2L2 )(1− L)d (∆yt − µ1) = εt , ε t | I t − 1 ~ z tc t , (3a) z t ~ i.i.d.Sα ( 0,1) c αt = b1 + b 2ctα−1 + b3 | ε t −1 |α (3b) In Regime 2 when ∆y t − 2 ≤ 0 : (1−φ3 L −φ4L2 )(1− L)d (∆yt −µ2 ) = ε t , ε t | I t−1 ~ z t γc t , (3c) z t ~ i.i.d.Sα ( 0,1) c αt = b1 + b 2ctα−1 + b3 | ε t−1 / γ |α (3d) 42 TABLE 4.1: Hypotheses Tests – CDR-Augmented Models Model 4 LR ( α = 2 ) LR (no GARCH) LR ( d = 0 ) Model 3 Model 2 Model 1 0.06 2.06 12.58 23.36 8.26 0.00 0.54 6.72 20.34 4.96 0.00 0.00 16.28 18.62 4.38 24.3 (0.00) 0.02 (0.99) 40.20 (0.00) 41.16 (0.00) 83.74 (0.00) 21.16 (0.00) 1.32 (0.72) 35.78 (0.00) 41.24 (0.00) 15.96 (0.00) 17.88 (0.00) 34.10 (0.00) 55.66 (0.00) 17.22 (0.00) 4.60 (0.03) 43 Notes on Table 4.1 1. The table presents likelihood ratio (LR) test statistics and their associated p-values in parentheses. 2. For each item reported in column 1, row one in column 2 and subsequent columns for that item presents statistics for Canada, row two for France, row three for Japan, row four for the UK, and row five for the USA. 3. LR ( α = 2 ) is a test for normality. The distribution of the test statistic in this instance is not standard χ 2 because the null hypothesis is on the admissible boundary of α . However, critical values at the 10% and 5% significance level are available through Monte Carlo simulations from McCulloch (1997, Table 4, panel b). These are 0.243 and 1.120, respectively. 4. LR (no GARCH) is a test for homoskedasticity. The null hypothesis is b 2 = b3 = 0 . Under this null, b1 and c0 are trivial transformation of one another. As such, it is not clear whether the LR statistic has asymptotic χ 2 distribution with two or three degrees of freedom. We report conservative χ 23 p-values in parentheses. 5. LR ( d = 0 ) is a test for the absence of long memory. 44 TABLE 4.2: Hypotheses Tests - CDR-Switching Models Model 4 LR ( α = 2 ) Model 3 Model 2 Model 1 0.46 0.16 15.44 21.74 6.84 4.12 2.56 0.78 58.18 4.80 0.00 5.22 0.00 22.52 11.44 31.68 (0.00) 0.48 (0.92) 50.98 (0.00) 40.66 (0.00) 15.80 (0.00) 12.66 (0.01) 0.00 (1.00) 55.72 (0.00) 44.92 (0.00) -- LR (no GARCH) LR ( d = 0 ) LR (one regime) 22.42 (0.00) 19.84 (0.00) 35.68 (0.00) 36.32 (0.00) 19.07 (0.00) 5.86 (0.00) 2.15 (0.14)) 16.36 (0.00) 2.72 (0.26) 7.5 (0.06) 6.22 (0.10) 1.30 (0.72) 13.56 (0.00) 0.98 (0.61) 11.30 (0.01) 13.12 (0.00) 1.46 (0.69) 24.34 (0.00) 4.46 (0.11) 0.00 (1.00) 10.68 (0.00) 0.10 (0.95) 14.20 (0.00) 4.16 (0.00) 13.44 (0.00) 45 Notes on Table 4.2 1. The table presents likelihood ratio (LR) test statistics and their associated p-values in parentheses. 2. For each item reported in column 1, row one in column 2 and subsequent columns for that item presents statistics for Canada, row two for France, row three for Japan, row four for the UK, and row five for the USA. 3. LR (one regime) is a test for linear conditional mean dynamics. The null hypothesis is µ1 = µ2 , γ = 1, and the corresponding autoregressive coefficients in the two regimes are equal. 4. See notes 3-5 in Table 4.1. 5. The symbol “--“ denotes missing numbers because the numerical algorithm for maximization of the log likelihood function failed to converge. 46 TABLE 4.3: Hypotheses Tests – SETAR-Switching Models Model 4 LR ( α = 2 ) Model 3 Model 2 Model 1 0.00 2.80 12.66 14.44 2.98 0.00 0.00 0.38 13.76 -- 0.00 4.74 0.00 46.20 12.12 11.50 (0.17) 0.22 (0.97) 48.74 (0.00) 40.20 (0.00) -- 18.74 (0.00) 0.00 (1.00) 75.82 (0.00) 41.26 (0.00) -- LR (no GARCH) LR ( d = 0 ) LR (one regime) 22.22 (0.00) 12.96 (0.00) 56.38 (0.00) 2.40 (0.12) -7.74 (0.01) 5.58 (0.23) 3.54 (0.62) 9.00 (0.00) 6.80 (0.08) 7.76 (0.02) 4.46 (0.22) 2.96 (0.71) 4.74 (0.32) 9.92 (0.01) 1.28 (0.53) 4.34 (0.23) 17.28 (0.00) 5.46 (0.14) -- 0.14 (0.93) 1.06 (0.59) 46.54 (0.00) 3.52 (0.32) 14.58 (0.00) 47 Notes on Table 4.3 1. The table presents likelihood ratio (LR) test statistics and their associated p-values in parentheses. 2. For each item reported in column 1, row one in column 2 and subsequent columns for that item presents statistics for Canada, row two for France, row three for Japan, row four for the UK, and row five for the USA. 3. LR (one regime) is a test for linear conditional mean dynamics. The null hypothesis is µ1 = µ 2 , γ = 1 , and the corresponding autoregressive coefficients in the two regimes are equal. 4. See notes 3-5 in Table 4.1. 5. The symbol “--“ denotes missing numbers because the numerical algorithm for maximization of the log likelihood function failed to converge. 48 8 References Anderson, H.M. and F. Vahid (1998). “Testing Multiple Equation Systems for Common Nonlinear Components.” Journal of Econometrics, 84: 1-36. Anderson, H.M. and J.B. Ramsey (2002). “U.S. and Canadian Industrial Production Indices as Coupled Oscillators.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 26: 33-67. Baillie, R.T. (1996). “Long Memory Processes and Fractional Investigation in Econometrics.“ Journal of Econometrics (Annals), 73(1): 5-59. Baillie, R.T., C.F. Chung, and M.A. Tieslau (1996). “Analyzing Inflation by the Fractionally Integrated ARFIMA-GARCH Model.” Journal of Applied Econometrics, 11(1): 23-40. Balke, N.S. and T.B. Fomby (1994). “Large Shocks, Small Shocks and Economic Fluctuations: Outliers in Macroeconomic Time Series.” Journal of Applied Econometrics, 9(2): 181-200. Beaudry, P. and G. Koop (1993). “Do Recessions Permanently Change Output”? Journal of Monetary Economics, 31:149-163. Bidarkota, P.V. (1999). “Sectoral Investigation of Asymmetries in the Conditional Mean Dynamics of the Real US GDP.” Studies in Nonlinear Dynamics and Econometrics, 3(4): 191-200. Bidarkota, P.V. (2000). “Asymmetries in the Conditional Mean Dynamics of Real GNP: Robust Evidence.” The Review of Economics and Statistics, 82(1): 153-157. Blanchard, O.J. and J. Simon (2001). “The Long and Large Decline in U.S. Output Volatility.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1: 135-174. Blanchard, O.J. and M.W. Watson (1986). “Are Business Cycles All Alike?” In R.J. Gordon (Ed.), The American Business Cycle: Continuity and Change. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press, 123-179. Box, G.E.P. and G.M. Jenkins (1976). Time Series Analysis, Forecasting and Control, San Francisco, CA: Holden-Day. Brannas, K. and J.G. De Gooijer (1994) “Autoregressive-Asymmetric Moving Average Models for Business Cycle Data.” Journal of Forecasting, 13: 529-544. Brockwell, P.J. and R.A. Davis (1991). Time Series: Theory and Methods, SpringerVerlag, New York. 49 Brunner, A.D. (1992). “Conditional Asymmetries in Real GNP: A Semi-nonparametric Approach.” Journal of Business & Economics Statistics, 10(1): 65-72. Brunner, A.D. (1997). “On the Dynamic Properties of Asymmetric Models of Real GNP.” The Review of Economics and Statistics, 79: 321-326. DeLong, J.B. and L.H. Summers (1986). “Are Business Cycles Symmetrical?” In R.J. Gordon (Ed.), The American Business Cycle: Continuity and Change. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press, 166-179. Diebold, F.X. and A. Inoue (2001). "Long Memory and Regime Switching." Journal of Econometrics , 105, 131-159. Diebold, F.X. and G.D. Rudebusch. (1990). “A Nonparametric Investigation of Duration Dependence in the American Business Cycle.” Journal of Political Economy, 98: 596616. Ding, Z., C.W.J. Granger, and R.F. Engle (1993). “A Long Memory Property of Stock Market Returns and a New Model.” Journal of Empirical Finance, 1:83-106. Elwood, S.K. (1998). “Is the Persistence of Shocks to Output Asymmetric?” Journal of Monetary Economics, 41: 411-426. Falk, B. (1986). “Further Evidence on the Asymmetric Behavior of Economic Time Series Over the Business Cycle.” Journal of Political Economy, 94(5): 1096-1109. French, M.W. and D.E. Sichel (1993). “Cyclical Patterns in the Variance of Economic Activity.” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 11(1): 113-119. Granger, C.W.J. (1995). “Modelling Nonlinear Relationships Between ExtendedMemory Variables.” Econometrica, 63(2): 265-279. Hamilton J.D. (1989). “A New Approach to the Economic Analysis of Nonstationary Time Series and the Business Cycle.” Econometrica, 57(2): 357-384. Hess, G.D. and S. Iwata (1997). “Asymmetric Persistence in GDP? A Deeper Look at Depth.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 40: 535-554. Hosking, J.R.M. (1984). “Modeling Persistence in Hydrological Time Series Using Fractional Differencing.” Water Resources Research, 20(12): 1898-1908. Kokoszka, P.S. and M.S. Taqqu (1995). “Fractional ARIMA with Stable Innovations.” Stochastic Processes and their Applications, 60: 19-47. Li, W.K. and A.I. McLeod (1986). “Fractional Time Series Modeling.” Biometrika, 73(1): 217-221. 50 Liu, S.M. and B.W. Brorsen (1995). “Maximum Likelihood Estimation of a GARCHStable Model.” Journal of Applied Econometrics, 10(3): 273-285. McCulloch, J.H. (1985). “Interest-Risk-Sensitive Deposit Insurance Premia: Stable ACH Estimates.” Journal of Banking and Finance, 9: 137-156. McCulloch, J.H. (1997). ”Measuring Tail Thickness in Order to Estimate the Stable Index a: A Critique.” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 15(1): 74-81. Mikosch, T., T. Gadrich, C. Kluppelberg, and R.J. Adler (1995). “Parameter Estimation for ARMA Models with Infinite Variance Innovations,” Annals of Statistics, 23(1): 305326. Neftci, S.N. (1984). “Are Economic Time Series Asymmetric Over the Business Cycle?” Journal of Political Economy, 92(2): 307-328. Nolan, J.P. (undated). Program for maximum likelihood estimation of parameters for general (non-symmetric) stable distributions, mle.ps at http://www.cas.american.edu/~jpnolan. Perron, P. (1989). “The Great Crash, the Oil Price Shock and the Unit Root Hypothesis.” Econometrica, 57: 1361-1401. Potter, S.M. (1995). “ A Non-Linear Approach to U.S. GNP.” Journal of Applied Econometrics, 10: 109-125. Koop, G. and S.M. Potter (2001). “Are Apparent Findings of Nonlinearity Due to Structural Instability in Economic Time Series?” Econometrics Journal, 4: 37-55. Ramsey, J.B. and P. Rothman (1996). “Time Irreversibility and Business Cycle Asymmetry.” Journal of Money Credit and Banking, 28: 1-21. Scheinkman, J.A. and B. LeBaron (1989). “Non-Linear Dynamics and GNP Data.” In W.A. Barnett et al. (Eds.), Economic Complexity: Chaos, Sunspots, Bubbles, and Noninearity, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 213-227. Sichel, D.E. (1989). “Are Business Cycles Asymmetric? A Correction.” Journal of Political Economy, 97(5): 1255-1260. Sowell, F. (1992a). “Maximum Likelihood Estimation of Stationary Univariate Fractionally Integrated Time Series Models.” Journal of Econometrics, 53: 165-188. Sowell, F. (1992b). “ Modeling Long-Run Behavior With the Fractional ARIMA Model.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 29: 277-302. 51 Tong, H. and K.S. Lim (1980). “Threshold Autoregression, Limit Cycles and Cyclical Data.” Journal of the Royal Statistical Society (Series B), 42(3): 245-292. Tsay, R.S. (1988). “Nonlinear Time Series Analysis of Blowfly Population.” Journal of Time Series Analysis, 9(3): 247-263. Tucci, M.P. (1995). “Time Varying Parameters: A Critical Introduction.” Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 6: 237-260. 52 Figure 1 Plot of Logrithmic Real GDP over Time Canada France 5 5 4.5 4.5 4 4 3.5 3 1950 1975 2000 2025 3.5 1970 1980 1990 Japan 2000 2010 UK 14 5 13 4.5 12 11 4 10 9 1950 1975 2000 2025 2000 2025 USA 9.5 9 8.5 8 7.5 1950 1975 3.5 1950 1975 2000 2025 Figure 2 Plot of Real GDP Growth Rates Over Time Canada France 0.04 0.02 0.01 0.02 0 0 -0.01 -0.02 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 -0.02 1970 1975 1980 Japan 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 UK 0.15 0.06 0.04 0.1 0.02 0.05 0 0 -0.05 1950 -0.02 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 1990 2000 2010 -0.04 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 USA 0.04 0.02 0 -0.02 -0.04 1950 1960 1970 1980 54