Innovation Policy Efficiency of the current policy mix for Dutch SMEs consisting of national and European measures Koen Hendriks Tilburg University Fall 2010 Abstract: In western economies, innovations more and more determine economic growth. However, with respect to innovation, a number of market failures are present which could result in an investment level that is lower than the social optimum. Also SMEs, which account for more than 60% of European and Dutch employment, have to deal with these market failures. Therefore, the government intervenes. Within the European Union, policy is designed on a national level, but also on a supra-national level. This thesis describes how the Dutch and European governments are trying to correct the market failures as present for Dutch SMEs. Also the complementary, substitutable and conflicting elements of respective the national and European programs are discussed. One of the main conclusions is that econometric analysis shows that participation in national government programs significantly increases innovativeness of Dutch SMEs, however, participation in European programs does not. Keywords: Market failures, SMEs, innovation policy, national policy, European policy efficient policy mix Innovation Policy Efficiency of the current policy mix consisting of national and European policies for Dutch SMEs Koen Hendriks ANR: 16.65.57 K.T.J.Hendriks@uvt.nl Tilburg University Tilburg School of Economics and Management Economics Department Examination committee: Prof. dr. E.E.C. van Damme Prof. dr. E. Brouwer Number of words: 24.589 1 Summary Innovations more and more determine economic growth in western economies. SMEs (Small and Medium Sized Enterprises) are an important group of companies in this sense because an overwhelming majority of firms can be characterized as a SME and in Europe this group of companies is responsible for 60% of employment. However, empirics show that SMEs participate significantly less in innovation activities. Innovation often is the result of complex and intense interaction between end users, companies, knowledge providers and the framework conditions. However, different types of market failures arise which hinder innovation. As a result, the government could intervene to correct these market failures, and it does. Both on the national and European level policy instruments are designed to promote innovation of SMEs. When looking at the government instruments, you can see that there exist many instruments that aim at correcting market failures and promoting innovation. However, one market failure is not addressed by both national and European measures, namely the market failure of a missing product market for new introduced products. Further, empirics show that SMEs participate relatively more in national programs compared to larger firms. This may be the result of the generic character of most programs. SMEs that participate in national programs are significantly more innovative. In contrast, SMEs participate significantly less in European innovation programs and SMEs that do participate are not significantly more innovative. A possible reason is the fact that European measures like the 7th Framework Program (FP7) have a high administrative burden and a low probability of success. Analyzing the policy mix for Dutch SMEs, complementary elements can be seen. For example the cooperation programs of respectively the national government and the European Union. But also substitutable elements can be found like Eurostars that can be seen as a substitute of FP7. In the future, specific innovation policy instruments for SMEs should be designed more on a national level and should also address the market failure of the missing product market for new innovative products. European policy should focus on creating good framework conditions for innovative companies and researchers. More added value can be created on a national level because the national government is better able to design policy according to the preferences and needs of SMEs. 2 Samenvatting Innovaties bepalen steeds meer de economische groei in Westerse economieën. MKB is een belangrijke groep bedrijven in deze zin omdat een grote meerderheid van de Nederlandse bedrijven kan worden geclassificeerd als een MKB1-bedrijf, verder is het MKB in Europa verantwoordelijk voor ruim 60% van de werkgelegenheid. Echter, empirie laat zien dat MKB-bedrijven significant minder participeren in innovatie dan het grootbedrijf. Innovatie is vaak het resultaat van complexe en intense interactie tussen eindgebruikers, bedrijven, kennisinstellingen en de randvoorwaarden, het zogenaamde innovatie systeem. Maar verschillende vormen van marktfalen zijn aanwezig welke innovatie van MKB-bedrijven hinderen. Daarom zou de overheid kunnen ingrijpen, en dat doet het ook. Voor Nederland worden er op nationaal en Europees niveau beleidsinstrumenten ontworpen welke innovatie van het MKB zouden moeten stimuleren. Wanneer je kijkt naar deze overheidsmaatregelen, zie je een grote hoeveelheid instrumenten welke allen op een andere manier proberen het marktfalen te corrigeren en zo innovatie to stimuleren. Echter, één vorm van marktfalen wordt niet aangepakt door beide overheden, namelijk het marktfalen van de ontbrekende markt voor nieuw geïntroduceerde producten. Verder laat empirie zien dat het MKB-bedrijf significant meer in nationale programma’s participeert vergeleken met het grootbedrijf. Dit zou het resultaat kunnen zijn van het generieke karakter van de meeste overheidsprogramma’s. MKBbedrijven die participeren in nationale programma’s zijn siginificant meer innovatief. Echter, MKB-bedrijven participeren significant minder in Europese programma’s en MKB-bedrijven die participeren zijn niet significant meer innovatief. Redenen die hieraan ten grondslag zouden kunnen liggen is het feit dat Europese programma’s zoals het 7e Kaderprogramma (KP7) een hoge administratieve last kent en een lage kans van succes voor MKB-bedrijven. De beleidsmix voor Nederlandse MKB-bedrijven laten complementaire elementen zien zoals bijvoorbeeld de samenwerkingsprogramma’s van respectievelijk de nationale overheid en de Europese Unie. Maar hiertegenover staat dat ook substitueerbare elementen te zien zijn, zoals Eurostars een substituut kan zijn voor KP7. In de toekomst zou specifiek innovatie beleid op nationaal niveau ontworpen moeten worden en zou men ook het marktfalen van de ontbrekende markt voor nieuw geïntroduceerde producten moeten aanpakken. Europees beleid zou zich meer moeten richten op het creëren van goede randvoorwaarden voor innovatieve bedrijven en wetenschappers. Meer toegevoegde waarde kan gecreëerd worden op nationaal niveau, omdat de nationale overheid beter in staat is om het beleid zo in te richten zodat het aansluit bij specifieke preferenties en behoeften van Nederlandse MKB-bedrijven. 1 Midden Klein Bedrijf 3 Preface This master thesis is the final project for receiving the Master of Science degree in International Economics and Finance from Tilburg University. In the summer of 2007, just before I decided to study economics, the subprime mortgage market in the United States crashed. The financial crisis that followed had huge consequences for economic growth in the Europe. I began to think about the underlying factors that determine economic growth on the long term, namely population growth and innovations. Since the population in Europe is ageing, innovation will more and more determine economic growth in the future. In the master International Economics and Finance I attended the seminar Competitiveness of the European Economy from prof. dr. van Damme and prof. dr. Brouwer. In this seminar we discussed the measurement of innovation and its contribution to economic growth. Also, the Lisbon strategy was mentioned. By 2010 the European countries should invest 3% of their GDP in research and development. However, most countries failed and especially SMEs lack behind. This could be the consequence of underlying market failures that restrict innovation. For the case of the Netherlands, policy is designed on national and European level to correct these market failures and to foster innovation. Since nowadays there is a lobby to transfer innovation policy more to the European level I wanted to examine how respectively the national and European government is aiming to correct the market failures present for SMEs. In addition, it seemed interesting to examine how successful these policies are and whether they create synergies with respect to each other. Writing this thesis was quite a challenge. Without support writing this thesis would be much harder and therefore I would like to take the opportunity to thank some people. First of all, I would like to thank my supervisor at Tilburg University, prof. dr. van Damme, for his valuable comments and discussions on earlier drafts. Second, my supervisors on the Ministry of Economic Affairs, Theo Roelandt and Frits von Meijenfeldt, and my supervisor at Statistics Netherlands George van Leeuwen for their input and advice. I am also grateful to my fellow students of Tilburg University. I want to thank them for the valuable discussions and further tips for research, but even more for the talks during the breaks about everything except our theses. Last but not least, I would like to thank my girlfriend, my family and friends for support during my thesis and my studies. Koen Hendriks Budel, 27 November 2010 4 Table of Contents 1 – Introduction .................................................................................................................... 7 2 – Small and Medium Enterprises (SMEs) in the Dutch economy .......................13 2.1 – Definition of SMEs ........................................................... 13 2.2 – SME’s share in the Dutch economy ......................................... 14 2.3 – Sectoral distribution of SMEs within the Dutch economy ................ 15 2.4 – Innovativeness of the Dutch SMEs compared to large enterprises ...... 16 3 – Theoretical Framework .............................................................................................23 3.1 – Innovation system ........................................................... 23 3.2 – Market failures ............................................................... 24 3.2.1 – Inadequate institutional framework ............................... 25 3.2.2 – Missing markets ..................................................... 27 3.2.3 – Externalities ......................................................... 28 3.2.4 – Market structure .................................................... 30 3.2.5 – Incomplete information ............................................. 33 3.2.6 – Bounded consumer rationality ..................................... 34 3.3 – Interaction between national and European policy ....................... 34 3.4 – Complementary versus substitutable policy instruments ................ 36 4 – Dutch innovation policy relevant for SMEs ..........................................................38 4.1 – Generic innovation policy ................................................... 38 4.1.1 – WBSO (Wet Bevordering Speur- en Ontwikkelingswerk / Law for Promotion of R&D) .......................................................... 39 4.1.2 – Credit for innovation ................................................ 40 4.1.3 – Eurostars............................................................. 41 4.1.4 – Technopartner ....................................................... 42 4.1.5 – Vouchers for innovation ............................................. 43 4.1.6 – Innovation Performance Contracts (IPCs) ......................... 44 4.1.7 – Small Business Innovation Research Program (SBIR) ............. 45 4.1.8 – Syntens ............................................................... 45 4.2 – Specific innovation policy ................................................... 46 5 4.2.1 – Innovation programs ................................................ 47 4.2.2 – International innovation ............................................ 49 4.2.3 – EG-Liason ............................................................ 50 4.3 – Empirical analysis ........................................................... 51 4.4 – Conclusion.................................................................... 54 5 – European innovation policy relevant for SMEs ...................................................60 5.1 – 7th Framework Program (FP7) ............................................. 60 5.2 – Competitiveness and Innovation Framework Program (CIP) ............ 66 5.3 – Empirical analysis ........................................................... 69 5.3 – Conclusion.................................................................... 73 6 – Analyzing the policy mix: The Dutch case .............................................................76 6.1 – Complementary elements ................................................... 76 6.2 – Substitutable elements ...................................................... 78 6.3 – Missing elements ............................................................ 79 6.4 – Empirical analysis ........................................................... 79 6.5 – Conclusion.................................................................... 84 7 – Policy recommendations ...........................................................................................85 8 – Conclusion......................................................................................................................87 References ............................................................................................................................89 Appendix A ...........................................................................................................................94 6 List of tables and figures Table 2.1 Table 2.2 Table 2.3 Table A.1 Categorical subdivision of SMEs SMEs share in the Dutch economy as of 01-01-2009 Differences between SMEs and large companies in innovation participation Differences between innovative SMEs and large companies in R&D intensity Differences between innovative SMEs and innovative large companies in share of revenue from products new to the market Budget allocation within the generic part of the Dutch innovation policy (2010) Differences between SMEs and large companies in participation in national government programs Differences in R&D intensity between SMEs that do participate in Dutch government programs and SMEs that do not participate in these programs Differences in new product introduction between SMEs that do participate in Dutch government programs and SMEs that do not participate in these programs Generic national instruments and corresponding market failures Specific national instruments and corresponding market failures Division of budget within FP7 Division of budget within CIP Differences between SMEs and large companies in participation in European government programs Differences in R&D intensity between SMEs that do participate in European government programs and SMEs that do not participate in these programs Differences in new product introduction between SMEs that do participate in European government programs and SMEs that do not participate in these programs European instruments and corresponding market failures Differences between SMEs and large companies in participation in both government programs Differences in R&D intensity between SMEs that do participate both government programs and SMEs that do not participate in both programs Differences in new product introduction between SMEs that do participate in both government programs and SMEs that do not participate in both programs Explanation of variables incorporated in this thesis Figure 2.1 Figure 2.2 Figure 3.1 Sectoral distribution of SMEs within the Dutch economy Model for a probability (probit model) The innovation system Table 2.4 Table 2.5 Table 4.1 Table 4.2 Table 4.3 Table 4.4 Table 4.5a Table 4.5b Table 5.1 Table 5.2 Table 5.3 Table 5.4 Table 5.5 Table 5.6 Table 6.1 Table 6.2 Table 6.3 7 Figure 3.2 Figure 3.3 Figure 3.4 Figure 5.1 Knowlegde and rent spillovers Relation between competition and innovation according to Schumpeter (Mark I and Mark II) and Aghion Competition, profits and efficiency Structure of the 7th Framework 8 1 – Introduction Realizing sustainable economic growth is an important goal of economic policy. One of the factors determining economic growth is productivity growth and therefore is a key element in economic policy. Long term sustainable growth is affected by economic behaviour and human actions. Research and development (R&D), innovations and human capital formation are fundamental. By developing new products, services, processes and business models, firms can become more productive (so called dynamic efficiency), which subsequently results in economic growth at the macro-level (Aghion et. al., 1998). In 2000, the European Union formulated a strategic goal for itself in the Lisbon Agenda. Together, the member states of the EU should “become the most competitive and dynamic knowledge-based economy in the world, capable of sustainable economic growth with more and better jobs and greater social cohesion” by 2010 (European Commission, 2002). In the new economic landscape, with more intense competition from emerging markets like China, India and Brazil and fast technological developments, innovations become more and more important (Peeperkorn and Verouden, 2007). To remain competitive with foreign competitors, it is important for companies to innovate. Therefore, innovation is one of the central elements of the Lisbon objective and a core feature of the knowledge-based economy, which the European Union aspires. To achieve this goal, the European Union set a target for each member state to invest 3% of its GDP in R&D by 2010 (of which 2% private R&D investments and 1% public R&D investments). Almost every country failed in achieving this target and many believe that the 3% target was too ambitious. Nonetheless, the strategy for Europe 2020 also incorporates the 3% target. Still ambitious, but in the view of the current financial crisis, innovation seems more important than ever in order to prevent a “lost decade” 2 and achieve sustainable recovery (European Commission, 2010). However, many changes will be needed (from both the private and public sector) to achieve this goal in 2020. For this thesis, I will take the Netherlands as main case. However, a problem arises when it comes to innovation. Market failures are present3 which are causing that the outcome resulting from the market is not socially optimal. These market failures restrain innovation and firms tend to invest A lost decade means that the economy suffered a permanent loss in wealth and in the potential for future growth. The better alternative is sustainable recovery which results in full return to the previous growth path and will raise its potential to go beyond. Innovation is of great importance according to the European Commission (2010). 3 The market failures present are further discussed in chapter 3, the theoretical framework. 2 9 less in R&D activities than is socially optimal. Also for small and medium sized enterprises (SMEs), these market failures result in serious restraints to invest in R&D. However, SMEs are of great importance for the Dutch economy. That is why the following of this thesis will focus on this group of companies. The government can intervene to correct this market failure. For the case of the Netherlands, both the national government and the European Union use policy measures that aim to stimulate private innovation to a socially desirable level. By its policy instruments it helps businesses to overcome the failing market. Both government layers have specific instruments that target SMEs. So, on two levels policy measures are designed to increase the innovation capacity of small and medium sized companies. This does not have to be a problem when there exists sufficient interaction between both levels of government and the two government levels aim at correcting different market failures for different target groups. Then, the policy measures of the two government layers could be characterized as complementary and could lead to synergies between government policies which would increase its efficiency (Alesina, Angeloni and Etro, 2005). Market failures present for SMEs will be better tackled in this way, which will most likely lead to an increase in the innovativeness of smaller private companies. However, also the possibility arises when both government levels focus on correcting the same market failures for similar groups of companies. In this case, the policy measures become substitutes of each other and create no added value with respect to each other. In the worst case, policy measures may even be conflicting with each other. When this is the case, there is no efficient policy mix between the national government on the one hand and the European Union on the other hand. Some market failures are not tackled and groups of companies are disregarded, which indicates some form of government failure. The aim of this thesis is twofold and therefore the research question consists of two parts. With respect to the first part, the Dutch and European policy regarding innovation will be analysed and reviewed, attempting to answer the following question: “Which market failures are present for SMEs with respect to innovation and how do national and European policy measures try to correct these market failures?” In order to provide an answer to this question, Chapter 2 will first analyse the role of SMEs in the Dutch economy to illustrate the importance of this group of companies. Also, differences between SMEs and large companies with respect to innovation will be stressed out in this chapter. Chapter 3, hereafter, will provide a theoretical framework which describes the innovation system, the market failures present for SMEs with respect to innovation and a theory regarding an efficient policy mix. Chapter 4 contains a descriptive analysis of how the Dutch innovation policy deals with these market failures and how accessible the existing measures are for SMEs. Also an empirical analysis which describes the differences between Dutch SMEs and 10 large companies with respect to participation in government programs is included. To finalize this part of the research question, Chapter 5 describes the European programs that aim to stimulate innovation within the private sector and the corresponding market failures. Also, an empirical analysis to stress differences between SMEs and large companies is added. The second part of the research question evaluates the present policy mix between on the one hand national policy measures and on the other hand European-wide programs: “How efficient is the current policy mix of national and European innovation programs?” Chapter 6 will analyze whether or not the national and European policies could be seen as complements of each other or that there exists some form of government failure. This is substantiated by an empirical analysis. Based on the previous chapters, Chapter 7 will put forward policy recommendations how the policy mix could be improved to increase its effectiveness. Finally, Chapter 8 will conclude and will summarize the answers to the research question: “How do national and European policy measures aim to correct market failures present for SMEs with respect to innovation and could the current policy mix of national and European programs be characterized as efficient?” The answer to this question is relevant for the policymakers at the Ministry of Economic Affairs and at the European Union. Possibly, some weaknesses in the policy mix between national and European innovation policy regarding SMEs are stressed. Especially in light of the upcoming budget cuts for the Dutch national government and the new European strategy Europe 2020, the recommendations could be useful. The method of analysis is partly theoretical. Off course, theory regarding SMEs and innovation is being discussed which provides the theoretical framework for this thesis. National and supra-national policy will be reviewed using this framework. The answer to question whether or not the present policy mix can be qualified as efficient also is based on a theoretical model. To link theory with practice some quantitative analysis is also included, which will make the theory more concrete. Econometric models, but also descriptive statistics are used to form a more clear picture. Questions like which companies innovate and what is the added value of national and European innovation programs will be answered, using micro-data from the CIS dataset. 11 This thesis will focus only on the Dutch case. Therefore, no conclusions can be drawn for other European countries based on this thesis. Other countries have to deal with other circumstances and have different sets of policy instruments. 12 2 – Small and Medium Enterprises (SMEs) in the Dutch economy This chapter will analyze the role of small and medium sized enterprises in the Dutch economy. First, the definition of SMEs will be discussed to define the relevant Dutch companies for this thesis. Thereafter the role of SMEs in the Dutch economy and its innovativeness will be analyzed to create a solid base for the remaining part of this thesis. 2.1 – Definition of SMEs Long time, there was no consensus across Europe about the definition of SMEs. In the Netherlands, the most accepted definition of small and medium sized enterprises in the past decades reads: ‘small enterprise up to 10 persons engaged; medium sized enterprise between 10 and 100 persons engaged’ (Nooteboom, 1994). So, all companies ranging from 1 person until 100 persons engaged would be among the category SMEs. However, the definition of SMEs varied across member states within the European Union. And because of the fact that there exist extensive interaction between national and EU measures regarding SMEs, a common definition was perceived to be necessary in order to improve the consistency and effectiveness of the measures. Therefore, the European Commission aimed at one general definition that should apply for all member states. The following definition was drawn in 2005: ‘The category of micro, small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) is made up of enterprises which employ fewer than 250 persons and which have an annual turnover not exceeding 50 million euro, and/or an annual balance sheet total not exceeding 43 million euro’ (European Commission, 2005). The different categories are shown in table 2.1. For the following chapters of this thesis, I will apply the common definition of the European Commission as stated above, if otherwise not possible 4. Most likely, this definition will be used increasingly among member states of the EU and probably will become the standard for academic research regarding SMEs throughout Europe, as international cooperation is becoming more and more important. In addition, most of the relevant institutions are using the common definition nowadays. Among them are the Ministry of Economic Affairs and its executive body AgentschapNL, Some literature uses another definition than the common definition of the European Commission. Therefore, sometimes, I am forced to deviate from the common definition. When doing so, this will be clearly indicated. 4 13 which are responsible for the policy design regarding innovation in the Netherlands and its implementation (SenterNovem, 2006). Table 2.1 – Categorical subdivision of SMEs5 Enterprise category Headcount Turnover (or) Balance sheet total Medium-sized < 250 ≤ €50 million ≤ €43 million Small-sized < 50 ≤ €10 million ≤ €10 million Micro-sized < 10 ≤ €2 million ≤ €2 million (Source: European Commission, 2005) 2.2 – SME’s share in the Dutch economy As table 2.2 shows 99,77% of the Dutch companies can be qualified as a SME according to its size. This is a overwhelming majority and partly shows its importance for the Dutch economy. In addition, the table shows that most of the enterprises are micro-sized (91,23%), which indicates that more than 9 out of 10 companies have fewer than 10 employees. As a result, SMEs in the Netherlands account for more than 60% of total employment. This is in line with the EU average, which indicates that SMEs are of great importance for the European economy (European Commission, 2005). Because of the large number of SMEs active within the Dutch Economy, this group of companies is of great importance for the creation of employment and economic growth. Therefore, SMEs are important for the competitiveness of the Dutch economy. Lagging productivity growth within SMEs would harm the economic growth of the Netherlands since the majority of the workforce is active within these companies. Therefore, policy should not only be designed toward the needs of large enterprises (which have the ability to lobby for their interest), but should also serve the needs of SMEs. For small and medium sized companies it is harder to get in direct contact with policy makers, since as a single company they are of less importance to the Dutch economy compared to a large multinational. A SME’s network is not wide enough to involve in such lobby activities. However, also this group of companies must be served. One way to serve the needs of SMEs and to enhance productivity growth for these companies is by an appropriate innovation policy for small and medium sized enterprises. In order to qualify as a SME, enterprises must meet the headcount ceiling, and in addition they either have to meet the turnover ceiling or the balance sheet ceiling, but not necessarily both. Also relations with other enterprises are considered in the common definition of the European Commission, especially when they create financial links between companies. 5 14 Table 2.2 – SMEs share in the Dutch economy as of 01-01-20096 Number of Employment Enterprises Category Absolute Relative Absolute Relative (x1000) Medium-sized 3.240 0,45% 498 6,61% Small-sized 58.205 8,09% 1.954 25,92% Mico-sized 656.560 91,23% 2.158 28,63% Total SMEs Large enterprises 718.005 99,77% 1.685 0,23% 4.610 2.928 61,16% 38,84% Total number of 719.690 100% 7.538 100% Enterprises (Source: CBS Statline 2010 and Forecast key figures SMEs 2009) 2.3 – Sectoral distribution of SMEs within the Dutch economy As figure 2.1 shows, some differences can be seen between SMEs and large companies. Large companies are relatively overrepresented in the sectors manufacturing, transport, communication, financial services and other business services. Network effects and economies of scale can be the underlying reason for this result. For smaller companies it is not profitable to enter these markets since they have to deal with higher costs (because they cannot reap the benefits from economies of scale) and therefore cannot compete with its larger counterpart. Manufacturing can be seen as the most innovative sector 7 within the Dutch economy, which is the case for most countries (Audretsch and Feldman, 2003). This sector is characterized by a relatively high level of R&D investment, which results in a relatively high frequency of introduction of new products and processes, and incremental innovations. 6,3% of the SMEs (micro, small and medium sized For the creation of this table two datasets are used. The dataset of CBS Statline, and the statistics of Forecast key figures of SMEs, which both give an indication of the importance of SMEs in the Dutch economy as of 01-01-2009. In the data, some sectors are excluded, namely: mineral extraction, utilities, health care, education and the public sector. All of these sectors deal with the provision of public services and therefore cannot be qualified as a perfectly private company, because they also serve the public interest. Both datasets exclude the same sectors and use the same distribution of companies according to size. 7 The most innovative sector here is defined as the sector with the highest share of innovative companies (and especially frontrunners in innovation). It follows that within the manufacturing sector the share of innovative companies is highest. However, this does not necessarily mean that the manufacturing sector is more innovative than the agriculture sector e.g. Cooperation between less innovative companies could lead to highly innovative processes and services, which would indicate that despite the companies themselves are not necessarily frontrunners in innovation, the sector as whole is highly innovative. However, this is hard to measure and available data is not sufficient to measure this. 6 15 companies) are active in this sector, compared to 27,6% of the large companies. SMEs are relatively overrepresented in less innovative sectors like agriculture, construction, retail, catering, real estate and professional business services. The majority of SMEs is active within the sectors retail, professional business services, construction and agriculture. Off course, also within these sectors innovation is conducted, however in general less intense than in other sectors8. From this perspective you would expect that large companies would participate in R&D projects more frequently compared to SMEs. Figure 2.1 – Sectoral distribution of SMEs within the Dutch economy 30,00% 25,00% 20,00% 15,00% 10,00% 5,00% es us i O th er B ne ss us i ne ss Se rv ic Se rv ic es st at e Re al E Pr of es sio na lB es Fi na nc ia lS er vic un ica t io n Co m m Ca te rin g Tr an sp or t Re ta il ct io n Co ns tru an uf ac t M Ag ric ul tu re ur in g 0,00% Micro Small Medium Large Average (Source: CBS Statline, 2010 and Forecast key figures SMEs, 2009) 2.4 – Innovativeness of the Dutch SMEs compared to large enterprises To examine whether or not differences exist between SMEs and larger companies in its innovative activities, a probit model is used. The dependent variable in this model is whether or not companies have R&D activities9, the variable takes the value of one when a company does have R&D activities and 0 when this is not the case. Therefore, a linear probability model is not sufficient to estimate this model. Assumed is, that a set of factors, such as size of the company, the sector in which it is active, market structure etc. explain a company’s decision whether or not to In these sectors, the share of frontrunners in innovation is relatively low. However, this does not necessarily indicate that the sector as whole is less innovative, as explained in footnote 6. 9 I used the dummy variable R&D activities as dependent variable, because this is the simplest variable present in the dataset. For companies, it is easy to answer the question whether or not it has R&D activities and therefore, the response to this question is highest compared to other innovation indicators. Indicators like R&D expenses and R&D intensity are more difficult to measure for small companies and using this variable therefore can give a wrong conclusion about the entire sample as a result of missing values for SMEs. 8 16 participate in R&D activities. These are characterized as the independent variables in the model. (1) The set of parameters ( ) in equation (1) reflect the impact of changes in (the independent variables) on the probability that a company has R&D activities. Figure 2.2 shows what a probit model looks like in a graph. Figure 2.2 – Model for a probability (probit model) 1 0 (Source: Greene, 1993) To estimate the model with Stata, data from the Community Innovation Survey 2006 is used, which provides the most recent microdata about innovation possible. Important to note is that micro sized companies (with 1-10 employees) are excluded in the dataset, this because of a low response rate to the survey. However, no biases are expected from the exclusion of these companies. The dataset contains information from almost 10.000 Dutch companies 10 about innovation related subjects, but also more general subjects are served which makes it possible to control for certain characteristics of companies that also may have its influence on the decision whether or not to participate in innovation activities. The main variable To be precise 9.947 Dutch companies are included in the dataset from which 8.886 companies can be characterized as a SME and 2.972 conducted innovation activities. 10 17 of interest is the dummy variable which indicates whether or not a company can be characterized as a SME. The results are displayed in table 2.3. Table 2.3 – Differences between SMEs and large companies in innovation participation (1) (2) (3) (4) Constant 0,004 0,004 0,785*** 0,815*** SME Small sized company Medium sized company -0,603*** -0,201*** -0,787*** -0,394*** Control variables Manufacturing International activities Cooperation Company is part of concern Turnover Dependent variable: Innovation activity (dummy) -0,292*** -0,139* -0,458*** -0,359*** -0,463*** -0,071 -0,466*** -0,359*** -0,454*** -0,101 -0,000 -0,000 Sample: all companies present in the Community Innovation Survey (9.947) * Significant at 10% level, ** Significant at 5% level, ***Significant at 1% level The models indicated with (1) and (2) only use dummy variables which indicate the size of the firm as independent variables. However, this can over- or underestimate the impact of the independent variables on the dependent variable, whether or not a company participate in innovation activities. This is because of the fact that the respective models do not control for company specific factors which also can influence the probability a company is participating in innovation. Despite this, the models (1) and (2) give a clear indication that small and medium sized companies differ significantly from its larger counterpart in participating in innovation activities. SMEs participate significantly less in these activities. When controlling for company specific factors, as indicated by model (3) in table 2.3, small and medium sized companies still tend to differ from its larger counterpart in the probability of participating in innovation. When looking at small and medium sized companies separately, an interesting finding is shown. They participate significantly less in innovation (significant at 1% level). Also medium sized companies participate significantly less in innovation (significant at 10% level) when controlling for company specific factors. 18 When looking at the control variables in the respective models (3) and (4), some interesting conclusions can be drawn. Manufacturing companies tend to participate more in innovation activities than other companies. The same holds for companies that cooperate and have international activities. However, previous analysis stresses some interesting differences between SMEs and large companies, it does not clarify whether or not there exist any differences between innovative SMEs and innovative large companies. When SMEs do participate in R&D activities, are they more or less innovative than its larger counterparts? To answer this question, additional analysis is necessary. A subsample11 of all innovative companies is used, so all companies with no R&D activities are excluded. 2.972 companies that indicated that they conducted innovation activities are left within the sample. To check for a possible selection bias, a two-stage Heckmann test is conducted which showed that no bias is present and that exclusion of non-innovative companies from the dataset is justified. Simple linear regression models are used to examine the differences between innovative SMEs and it larger counterparts. Two different innovation indicators as dependent variables are tested to check the robustness of these indicators, namely “share of revenue from products new to the market” and “R&D intensity12”. The first is an output indicator while the second can be indicated as an input indicator. Both indicators are relative to control for differences in size and turnover. The following equations are estimated with the use of Stata and the CIS dataset. The results can be seen in table 2.4 and table 2.5, with respectively “share of revenue from products new to the market” and “R&D intensity” as dependent variables (2) (3) The first two estimated models in table 2.4 give a first indication that no significant differences exist in R&D intensity of medium sized companies compared to large companies. Small sized companies however, do tend to be more innovative than its larger counterpart. The models (3) and (4), which use control variables to control for company specific factors that also may influence a company’s innovativeness, confirm this result. Further, these control variables show that manufacturing All companies that answered the question whether they participated in innovation activities with yes are included in this subsample. Non-innovative companies are therefore excluded. 12 R&D intensity is calculated in the following way: R&D man-years/Total employees 11 19 companies13 and companies that are part of concern are less innovative. When a company is part of a concern, the possibility that R&D is conducted by another company within the concern is present. In contrast, companies that cooperate with other parties and companies that are supported by national or European government tend to be more innovative. Cooperation may lead to positive knowledge spillovers and the possibility of sharing risk and reaching economies of scale arises. This makes participating in R&D more attractive. Government support aims at correcting market failures that restrain innovation and in this sense makes it more easy for companies to participate in R&D. Other control variables represented in table 2.4 do not have a significant impact in a company’s R&D intensity. Table 2.4 – Differences between innovative SMEs and large companies in R&D intensity (1) (2) (3) (4) Constant 5,875*** 5,875*** 3,573* 3,575* SME Small sized company Medium sized company Control variables Manufacturing International activities Cooperation Company is part of concern Turnover National government support14 European government support Both national and European government support Participation in Syntens Dependent variable: R&D intensity -1,486 -2,187* -0,995 -1,901 -2,518* -1,588 -3,997*** -2,158 -3,126*** -4,128*** -0,000 -6,142*** 10,489** -8,608*** -4,001*** -2,151 -3,184*** -3,938*** -0,000 -6,137*** 10,500** -8,612*** -1,738 -1,774 Sample: all innovative companies present in the Community Innovation Survey (2.972) * Significant at 10% level, ** Significant at 5% level, ***Significant at 1% level This result may be counterintuitive, but since the variable is a control variable further research is not necessary. The counterintuitive result for the manufacturing dummy could be the result of the fact that the CIS dataset did not provide enough control variables to control for company specific factors. 14 National government support, European government support are both dummy variables. Of course, the size of the support does matter, however the Community Innovation Survey does not provide these number. Therefore, further research is necessary. 13 20 Next, the results are shown of the same regression, but with “new introduced products” as dependent variable. In contrast with the input innovation indicator R&D intensity, now an output indicator is used which measures the commercial impact of innovations. In the end, (product) innovations have to lead to the introduction of new products to the market to be economically successful. Table 2.5 – Differences between innovative SMEs and innovative large companies in share of revenue from products new to the market (1) (2) (3) (4) Constant 6,360*** 6,360*** 1,732* 1,735* SME Small sized company Medium sized company -0,521 -0,969 -0,180 -1,865** Control variables Manufacturing -1,002* International activities -2,321*** Cooperation -1,138** Company is part of concern -0,232 Turnover -0,000*** National government support -3,882*** European government support -1,491 Both national and European -3,961*** government support Participation in Syntens -1,347** Dependent variable: Share of revenue from products new to the market -2,784*** -1,363* -1,041* -2,343*** -1,208** -0,069 -0,000*** -3,899*** -1,406 -3,959*** -1,406** Sample: all innovative companies present in the Community Innovation Survey (2.972) * Significant at 10% level, ** Significant at 5% level, ***Significant at 1% level When looking at the results in table 2.5, the first two models do not show some significant differences in innovativeness of SMEs compared to large companies. But when controlling for additional company specific factors, these differences can be found. Models (3) and (4) show that medium sized companies are significantly more innovative than large companies. Small sized companies tend to be even more innovative and introduce relatively many new products. Some differences can be found in the impact of the control variables. Whether a company is part of a concern no longer has a significant impact on a company’s innovativeness. The same holds for participation in European government programs (it even turns out to have a negative impact, allthough not significantly). In contrast, international active companies tend to significantly introduce relatively many new products to the 21 market. This makes sense, since internationally active companies can pick up new, foreign technologies and trends relatively quick and introduce them to the domestic market. In addition, domestic companies can learn from foreign companies. To conclude this part, SMEs tend to participate less in innovation activities. This is an indication that market failures are more sever to SMEs compared to large companies. But when these companies do participate in innovation they are more innovative than its larger counterpart. Innovative small and medium sized companies tend to have a higher R&D intensity and introduce relatively many new products to the market. Therefore, it is important that the Dutch government aims to correct the market failures present for SMEs since they can absolutely contribute to the innovativeness of the Dutch economy. The market failures with respect to innovation as present for Dutch SMEs are discussed in the next chapter which will discuss the theoretical framework. 22 3 – Theoretical Framework The first paragraph of this chapter will discuss the innovation system. Nowadays, innovation is often the result of a collaboration between multiple parties. Hereafter, the second paragraph will cover the literature about market failures relevant for SMEs with respect to innovation and how these restrain innovation from the small and medium sized companies. Market failures can result in a level of investment in research and development that is below the socially desirable level. Then, the last paragraph will describe a theoretical model about the interaction between, on the one hand national policy, and on the other hand supra-national policy, like this is the case for the Netherlands. Policy measures can be a good instrument to overcome market failures and promote R&D activities. Important is that the policy design of both national governments and the European Union are efficient and not conflicting with each other. Optimal would be when synergies arise between both government layers. 3.1 – Innovation system Innovation often is the result of complex and intense interaction between end users, companies, knowledge providers and the framework conditions (Berner, Gilsing and Roelandt, 2001). Companies are more and more dependent of partners and knowledge providers outside their own company. Collaborations between companies and collaborations with knowledge institutions can result in positive (knowledge) spillover which affects the probability of success positively. In the past, innovation was assumed to be characterised by a linear model in which innovation was seen as a step-by-step process that starts with fundamental research and ends with commercialisation. However, nowadays the importance of interaction between actors in the innovation system cannot be ignored. Figure 3.1 shows the components of the innovation system. Besides interaction with other actors within the innovation system, other factors can be of great importance as well. For companies, the possibility to innovate depends on a lot of different factors. The framework conditions must be good, the infrastructure must ease innovation and stimulate interaction with other companies and knowledge providers. However, most importantly maybe, there must be demand for new, innovative products. Therefore, it is important that innovations are demand driven and can be commercialized. However, market failure and system failure within the innovation system can arise that hinder innovation. This will be discussed in the next paragraph. This can be a reason for the government (national 23 or supra-national) to step in and it can try to correct this market failure and let the innovation system work smoothly. However, with government intervention it is important that the social gains of intervention are bigger than the social costs. Otherwise, utility of society will go down. Figure 3.1 – The innovation system (Source: Berner, Gilsing and Roelandt, 2001) 3.2 – Market failures When market failures arise, government intervention can be legitimized15. Roughly six types of market failures can be distinguished for SMEs, within the innovation system as presented above, which hinder private R&D activities. Those are: inadequate institutional framework, missing markets, externalities, market power, incomplete information and bounded consumer rationality16. All these market As mentioned before, market failures can be a reason for the government to step in and correct the market failure. Important is however that the social gains of intervention are bigger than the social costs. Otherwise, utility of society is negatively influenced. 16 In the existing literature, often another market failure is described, namely the market failure of public goods. But because this type of market failure is not relevant for the topic of this thesis it is disregarded here. 15 24 failures make SMEs prudent to invest in R&D and to engage in innovative projects. Important to note is that these market failures are not necessarily present for all SMEs in the Netherlands. The extent in which market failures are relevant for SMEs may depend on the sector in which the company is active, the market structure etc.. However, there is no doubt about the fact that the level of investment in R&D is too low from a social point of view (Martin and Scott, 2000). 3.2.1 – Inadequate institutional framework Intellectual Property Rights (IPRs) In the first place, companies innovate to become more competitive and to create a competitive advantage. SMEs are often active within a strongly competitive market with many competitors. In this case, innovations can give a SME the opportunity to escape competition. However, innovations might not only strengthen the company’s own competitiveness, but it might also strengthen the position of competitors in the market when innovations spill over to other companies. Therefore, it is very important that the intellectual property rights (IPRs) are protected to guarantee the benefits of innovating (Cohen, Goto, Nagata, Nelson and Walsh, 2002). A decent, accessible patent system and copyright protection is necessary to facilitate innovation for SMEs. Strong IPR protection will lead to higher economic returns to the innovator and therefore would create additional incentives to invest in R&D (Yang and Maskus, 2001). With IPR protection the innovator is shielded from competition after the innovation and can reap monopoly profits from its invention. Of course, this harms consumer welfare in the short run, but consumer welfare is likely to raise in the long run17 (Maskus, 2000). So there exists a trade-off between protecting companies from spillovers on the one hand and protecting consumers from high prices on the other hand. Additionally, decent intellectual property right protection would make SMEs less prudent to invest in R&D and it would enable SMEs to access external finance more easily18. This is caused by the fact that the economics gains from innovating and therefore the expected returns from the investment are more certain. Protection of intellectual property rights is of course of great importance in the case of drastic innovations, but also incremental and process innovations will benefit from a decent IPRs protection. There exists a trade-off in the sense that IPRs generate monopoly profits that reduce consumer welfare in the short-run, but are necessary to provide adequate payoffs to innovations. Dynamic efficiency in the long run is achieved by allocative inefficiency in the short run. 18 Investments in R&D activities are often accompanied with great uncertainty. Therefore, investors might prefer more conservative investment opportunities. IPRs protection increases the expected returns from R&D investment and therefore increases the willingness of investors to invest in R&D activities, which often involve more risk. 17 25 Cooperation with external agents As paragraph 3.1 showed, for innovation activities SMEs often cooperate with external agents. Cooperation may be necessary because of mainly two reasons. First, they might simply do not have the funds to finance the R&D project alone. Second, the knowledge required is not all present within the company. Especially, for SMEs that participate in innovation incidentally and which often do not have a systematic R&D department this might be the case. Therefore, it may be helpful for small and medium sized companies to cooperate with other companies and knowledge institutions (Sánchez González and Herrera, 2008). By cooperating with external sources, companies can grasp economies of scale and/or knowledge spillovers and share the risk involved (Workgroup innovation and applied research, 2010). Possible types of agents with which companies can cooperate in R&D projects are: customers and suppliers, competitors, public R&D agents. Asymmetric information between the company on the one hand and customers and suppliers on the other hand makes cooperation between these groups hard. Companies do not know exactly the needs of customers and suppliers, and customers and suppliers often have no complete information about the capabilities and goals of the company. Cooperation between competitors is hindered by the fact that the gains of innovating have to be shared with competitors, therefore the gains from innovation may spill over (Nooteboom, 2008). Additionally, because companies do not have complete information about its competitors’ activities, it is hard to find suitable cooperation partners. The institutional structure of research centres and universities (public R&D agents) result in other priorities of these agents than commercialising their knowledge (Boschma, Frenken and Lambooy, 2002). Public R&D agents, therefore, are reluctant to cooperate with SMEs despite the fact that such institutions play an important role in developing technological innovations. When they do cooperate with private companies, they often approach only the large companies (Veugelers and Cassiman, 2005). In order to promote more cooperation between different types of agents, the institutional framework has to ease cooperation, rather than hinder the process. International cooperation In addition, because of the fact that the European Union consists of 27 member states and each member states has a different culture, legal system, language etc. it is hard for SMEs to cooperate with foreign agents (Garrett, 1992). Especially since most of the SMEs often do not have any international activities and experience, these companies are reluctant to cooperate with companies from other countries. Since knowledge and technology goes beyond borders, such cooperation often might be necessary to optimize R&D projects. Social and economic barriers between regions within Europe (but of course also outside Europe) prevent the reception and assimilation of external innovation internationally (Rodriguez-Pose and Crescenzi, 26 2006). Therefore, differences in the institutional design between member states of the European Union should be smoothed. 3.2.2 – Missing markets Capital market SMEs often do not have sufficient funds to finance R&D projects, therefore they have to attract external finance. However, a capital market to finance R&D investments for small and medium sized firms can be “missing”. External investors are often reluctant to invest in (risky) R&D projects of SMEs. Beforehand, the expected future returns are highly uncertain and therefore a lot of risk is involved (Carpenter and Petersen, 2002). For banks and private investors it is hard to assess whether or not an innovative project will be successful or not and what the expected returns will be. In the case of SMEs, this risk often is not covered by sufficient collateral and/or a reputation which discourages outside investors (Harris and Robinson, 2001). Larger firms face less difficulties in accessing (external) finance (Workgroup innovation and applied research, 2010). Even when the expected net present value (NPV) of a R&D project is positive, investors still might be reluctant to finance the project19. (4) 20 Like equation (4) shows, the net present value depends on the probability of success, the expected net cash flows during the project, the duration of the project and the discount rate. When the gains from the project will pay out in the distant future, the collateral is not sufficient, or the likelihood of success is low, investors will be reluctant to invest. The risk involved and the corresponding uncertainty of the project involved is a decisive factor in the decision making process of investors. Often, asymmetric information about the project is the basis for uncertainty and The standard finance theory predicts that when the NPV of a project is positive it is beneficial to invest in the project. The discounted expected benefits then are larger than the initial investment. However, when the returns are highly uncertain investors still might be reluctant to invest in a project of which the NPV is positive. 20 The discount rate is the rate of return that could be earned on an investment in the financial markets with similar risk. 19 27 therefore the reluctance of external investors to finance (risky) R&D projects of SMEs, but also larger firms. New product markets Drastic innovations lead to new, to customers unfamiliar, products which have to be introduced to the product market, which means that the product has to be commercialized. Therefore, customers have to get informed about the existence and functionality of the product, otherwise demand for the product will not be sufficient to be profitable (Harris and Robinson, 2001). Incremental and process innovations on the other hand do not have to cope with this problem, simply because changes to the final product are little and demand for the product is already present. On contrast, drastic innovations are unfamiliar to the customers and have to be introduced to the market. As chapter 2 showed, compared to large companies, SMEs are responsible for relatively many product introductions (Gilbert, 2006). To commercialize the new product, potential consumers have to be informed about the product, which often results in a great struggle for the company. Consumers do not have any information about the product and therefore is reluctant to buy the product. On the other hand, preferences and needs of consumers are often unknown for companies. This means that it is hard to tune the product to the needs of its potential customers. Asymmetric information and bounded consumer rationality are key to this problem. As a result, the company has to put in a lot of effort to inform the consumer and develop a marketing strategy to convince the consumer about the functionality and quality of their product. This, however, can be very time- and money consuming which SMEs cannot afford and may hinder their R&D activities. 3.2.3 – Externalities Like mentioned in paragraph 3.2.1 it is important for companies to be able to extract some profits from the innovation. Otherwise, companies would not have any incentive to innovate. However, some of the gains from innovations may spill over to other. This can be in the form of knowledge spillovers from the innovative company to competitors. Knowledge can be seen as a quasi-public good and companies can imitate the innovation or use the knowledge for other innovative projects. However, when an innovation succeeds, the innovative company is also most likely to steal some of its competitors business. So the effect to the competitors can either be negative (in case of a large business stealing effect) or positive (in case of knowledge spillovers with high benefits). In addition, some of the gains from innovations may also spill over to a company’s customers (consumers and other producers). The value for money of the products increases, and customers’ welfare increases. These are the rent spillovers as indicated in figure 3.2. As figure 3.2 shows, the social benefits from the innovation are greater than the private benefits to the firm (Baker, 28 2007). Spillovers that affect society’s welfare but not the company’s profits are not incorporated in the company’s utility function (Ogawa and Wildasin, 2007). Consequently, privately owned firms are likely to underinvest in R&D activities. Figure 3.2 – Knowlegde and rent spillovers (Source: CPB, 2002) As equation (5) and (6) show society’s utility is higher compared to the utility from the innovative company as a result of an innovation. So, the social gains from innovation are higher than the private gains of innovation . This is a result of the rent spillovers and the knowledge spillovers that characterize innovative projects (as can be seen in figure 3.2). Finally, this will result in underinvestment in R&D by private firms, since the externalities are not incorporated in the firm’s utility function. (5) (6) 29 Knowledge spillovers to other companies have to be prevented or have to be incorporated in the company’s utility curve (Workgroup innovation and applied research, 2010). In this way, the market could achieve the socially optimal level of R&D investment. Decent intellectual property right protection could secure some of the monopoly profits to companies and increases the expected return of the project (Czarnitzki and Toole, 2009). Another way to overcome externalities is by cooperation between companies. By cooperating, knowledge may spill over from one company to another, but the knowledge (and the corresponding benefits) remains with the collaborating group of companies. In this way, companies can incorporate spillovers in their decision making regarding innovation. 3.2.4 – Market structure Competition and innovation The relation between competition and innovation has been broadly analysed by Schumpeter. However, Schumpeter developed two contradicting views in his career on how market structure and innovation may have its influence on each other. The first view (Mark I) is based on the fact that smaller firms might have more incentives to innovate than large firms. For large firms, the risk exists that the new products would cannibalize their monopoly profits (Gilbert, 2006). When a large incumbent is able to exert market power and therefore make positive profits, a new, innovative product could replace the old product and evaporate its profits, this is called the replacement effect. A smaller, or new company does not have to deal with this problem of evaporating its own profits. Small firms are often active in more competitive markets and therefore make little or no profits, so they have nothing to lose. Cannibalizing its own profits is neither an issue for a new company. Therefore, drastic innovations that replace old products tend to come from small, and/or new companies that do. In addition, small firms have more market share to gain by innovating compared to large established firms (Peeperkorn and Verouden, 2007) and could escape competition by innovating. The incentives to innovate depend on the differences between pre-innovation and post-innovation profits, they are likely to be higher for smaller firms. This view is also well-known as Arrow’s view and predicts a positive relation between innovation and the level of competition, as figure 3.3 shows (Mark I). Contradicting, the second view (Mark II) suggests that large firms will invest more in R&D, and therefore will be more innovative, than smaller firms. Large companies often can benefit from economies of scale, which lowers the costs per unit produced. In addition, larger companies often can exert some market power, which means that they can sell their products above marginal costs. This results in positive profits. As a result, large companies have the possibility to use their profits to invest in risky, 30 large scale R&D projects. Small and medium sized companies often are active in a more competitive market, which indicates that their profits are lower or that they just break-even. Therefore, SMEs have fewer opportunities to invest in R&D, simply because they have fewer resources to invest. Because of the risk involved with R&D, SMEs might be more induced to commit their scarce resources to less risky projects, which provide more certainty about its future returns. Additionally, large firms might have incentives to innovate because they are better able to capture the benefits of the R&D program, because they are more likely to exert some market power and earn monopoly rents (Gilbert, 2006). Innovations also enable the monopolists to maintain their market position (Brouwer, Poot and van Montfort, 2008). This view suggests that monopolies are not necessarily bad, but promote dynamic efficiency (Peeperkorn and Verouden, 2007). Therefore, the relation between innovation and the level of competition should be negative, as can be seen in figure 3.3 (Mark II). Figure 3.3 – Relation between competition and innovation according to Schumpeter (Mark I and Mark II) and Aghion The last decade, an additional theory was developed. Instead that the relation between the level of competition and innovation should be characterized as simply negative or positive, this view suggests that the relation is characterized by an inverted U-curve. In this model competition may increase the incremental profit from innovating, labeled the “escape-competition effect,” but competition may also reduce innovation incentives for laggards, labeled the “Schumpeterian effect.” The balance between these two effects changes between low and high levels of competition, generating an inverted-U relationship. In case of weak competition an increase in competition would increase innovation because of the escape effect, the firm’s efficiency does affect its profitability. But in case of intense competition an 31 increase in competition would lead to less innovation. The incentives for laggards are little to catch up, its profits are almost zero anyway, the Schumpeterian effect. Whether or not a company decides to innovate is the result of the difference between postinnovation and preinnovation rents of incumbent firms as illustrated by figure 3.421. As a result, intermediate levels of competition would be optimal for firms to participate in innovation activities (Aghion, Bloom, Blundell, Griffith and Howitt, 2005), the escape-competition effect than dominates the Schumpeterian effect. Figure 3.4 – Competition, profits and efficiency SMEs, which are often active in fully competitive markets, may be harmed by the fact that they do not have the necessary resources for innovation. This may be one of the reasons why the level of R&D investment of SMEs is below the socially desirable level. Therefore, some form of market power is necessary to reach dynamic efficiency in the long run (Schumpeter, 1942). However, competition is also necessary to give companies the incentives to innovate, to ‘escape’ competition (Arrow, 1962). These conflicting statements are characterized by Aghion’s inverted U-shaped relation between competition and innovation. Entry barriers Often, R&D projects are characterized by high sunk costs which could be a barrier for SMEs to participate in such projects. Large firms on the other hand face less difficulties in financing R&D projects, as discussed in 3.2.2. In this way, the high sunk 21 Assumed is that innovations are step-by-step and not leapfrogging. 32 costs that go along with R&D projects can work as an entry barrier for small and medium sized companies to participate in R&D (Van Dijk and Van Hulst, 1988). One way to overcome this problem is by join forces. When companies would cooperate in R&D projects, together they could finance the sunk costs of the R&D project and later on reap the benefits. In this way they could also participate in R&D projects with high sunk costs and stay competitive against larger firms. In addition to the high sunk costs that characterize R&D projects, also economies of scale can cause entry barriers for SMEs. Technological conditions in some markets create economies of scale which mean that large companies can reach costs advantage when realizing high outputs. Because large firms in these markets have a cost advantage, small firms cannot enter the market profitable (Barber, 2009). They are not able to sell their new innovative products in these markets, since competitors can sell their ‘old’ products for low prices. Also, incumbents can use foreclosure strategies to prevent that a competitor can profitably introduce a new product. 3.2.5 – Incomplete information Roughly four forms of incomplete information which hinder investments in R&D activities can be described. First, for companies, the probability of success is hard to estimate beforehand. As a result, companies do not have complete information about the returns of the project in the future. Off course, this often holds for all types of investment, however in the case of R&D investment additional uncertainty is involved and the investment necessary is often high (Kline and Rosenberg, 1986). There is no comparison with other projects possible, so it is hard to form expectations and may cause prudence with respect to investments in R&D. Incomplete information and risk aversion may lead to investment in more conservative and certain investments instead of risky R&D projects. Second, also banks and private investors face the problem of incomplete information for financing R&D projects of companies. These parties also have to deal with uncertainty about the future returns. Additionally, external investors have little knowledge about the technology and business processes involved which causes even greater uncertainty. For these agents, it is even harder to form expectations about the probability of success of the project. Partly, this is one of the reasons why a sufficient capital market is missing to finance R&D projects of SMEs. As explained in paragraph 3.2.2 large companies can overcome these problems by offering collateral and a reliable reputation. Third, the probability of success is partly determined by the commercialization of the new products. However, for small companies consumer preferences are often hard to predict which makes it hard for these companies to fit the products to consumer needs. Finally, to reap the gains from innovations the new products have to be sold, however consumers are often 33 not familiar with these new products which makes them reluctant to purchase the products. Therefore, it is often hard to be the first-mover since companies have to put in a lot of effort to commercialize the product and reap the benefits from the innovation. The probability of success and therefore the expected returns are very uncertain in this case. Together, these four forms of incomplete information can result in a great struggle for SMEs to find external finance to finance R&D projects and to commercialize their new products. Important to note is that incomplete information is closely related to the missing markets as described in paragraph 3.2.2. 3.2.6 – Bounded consumer rationality As explained in paragraph 3.2.2, new product developers have to commercialize their innovation to create demand for their products. However, at first, most of the consumers are reluctant to purchase unfamiliar, new products. Consumers tend to wait for reviews about new products before buying it themselves, especially this is the case for the more expensive goods. When the product has proved itself in terms of quality and functionality, more and more consumers will be willing to buy the product. A decent marketing strategy may be helpful in this case. This shows that consumers do not always act rational. It can be very hard to create demand for innovative products of good quality and high functionality because of this phenomenon. For SMEs this may be a serious problem since their marketing budget is relatively small and consumers remain unfamiliar with the product. This may affect the probability of default. 3.3 – Interaction between national and European policy Market and system failure can be a reason for government intervention. The condition is however that the social benefits of this intervention are greater than the social costs. Governments can challenge market failures with policy instruments. However, in the case of the member states of the European Union multiple levels of government exist. Off course, there is the national government which designs its policy towards its own preferences. In addition, with the creation of the European Union there is also a supra-national government which forms policy for all its member states. However, the harmonization of policies across the union may conflict with specific national preferences (Alesina, Angeloni and Etro, 2005). On the other hand, merging and coordination policy instruments across borders can generate economies of scale and can prevent underprovision of policy instruments. 34 (7) Income Public spending of country Preferences of country Spillovers In a decentralized setup, each country would maximize its own utility function as characterized by equation (7). As the equation shows, a country’s utility does not depend only on its own actions, also actions of other countries can influence its utility. Some of the country’s public spending spills over to other countries. In the case of innovation policy this could be in the form of knowledge spillovers, or for example companies using their vouchers for innovation abroad (see 4.1.4). The utility that foreign countries derive from these spillovers is not incorporated in the domestic country’s utility function. However, also some positive spillovers arise for country , since a part of foreign public spending spills over to country . But since the preferences can differ between countries, these spillovers are not necessarily evenly distributed. As a result, when the provision of public spending is regulated decentralized, there is underprovisioin of policy instruments. An international union could incorporate these spillovers in its utility function. The most extreme option for the international union is complete centralization of policy making. The national governments lose their authority and all the decision are taken on supra-national level. It is not difficult to judge that, when countries differ in preferences strongly, this option is far from optimal (Alesina et al., 2005). Also when the number of countries in the union is large and heterogeneity is high, entirely centralized policymaking is not optimal. The countries that are far from the median country in terms of preferences suffer the most. So, completely decentralized policy making is not optimal, and also centralized policy making is not efficient in case of different preferences. A combination between centralized and decentralized policy making have to be found, a so called flexible union. In such a union, there is centralized policy making which is financed by all the member states together. In addition, each member state can choose whether or not to form additional national policy, this will especially be decided on by countries that differ substantially from the median country (in terms of preferences). Compared to completely centralized and decentralized policy making, utility increases because on the one hand the centralized aspect of a flexible union incorporates the spillovers in the union’s utility function and on the other hand 35 countries can design policy according to their own preferences. This is showed by equation (8). (8) Public spending of country , decided by country Public spending decided by the union Preferences of country Spillovers Number of countries in the union The optimal policy mix within an international union therefore is when the union sets the basic conditions for policy and that individual countries can supplement this policy towards their own preferences. 3.4 – Complementary versus substitutable policy instruments When policy is designed on two levels, one runs the risk that policy instruments can be substitutable. Policy instruments can be considered to be substitutes when the following equations hold. (9) Participation in Dutch innovation programs Participation in European innovation programs Relative costs of Dutch innovation programs22 The relative costs of innovation programs are determined by the ratio between the added value of the programs and the effort it takes to participate in innovation programs. When the added value 22 36 Relative costs of European innovation programs Mentioned equations show a positive cross elasticity of demand. When the relative costs of participating in an European innovation program increases23, companies will participate more in Dutch innovation programs. The relative costs are determined by a variety of factors like the administrative burden, the level of subsidy etcetera. For complementary instruments, different equations have to hold: In contrast to the substitutable policy instruments, complementary policy instruments show a negative cross elasticity of demand. When the relative costs of participating in a national policy instrument decreases, companies will logically participate more in the national program. But as a result of the complementary nature of the instruments, companies will also be more inclined to participate in European policy instruments. This could be the result of synergies that might arise. increases (e.g. the subsidy increases), the relative costs decrease. The same holds when the administrative burden increases (it takes more effort to participate in innovation programs). 23 When the relative costs of an European innovation program increases, automatically the relative costs (compared to the European program) of the Dutch innovation program will decrease. 37 4 – Dutch innovation policy relevant for SMEs Government intervention can be economically justified when market failures are present, however the social benefits of intervention must outweigh its social costs. In the previous chapter we have seen that SMEs have to cope with several market failures that restrain innovation. As a result, the (private) R&D investments generated by the market could be less than socially desirable. While innovation more and more determines economic growth for most western countries, there is an important role for the government to play. This chapter will describe the Dutch innovation policy which aims at stimulating private investments in R&D. The Dutch policy consists of a generic part and a specific part, these two will be separately discussed in the following paragraphs. Hereafter, in paragraph 4.3 the differences between Dutch SMEs and large companies in participation in Dutch government programs will be discussed. Also the impact of participation on the innovativeness of SMEs will be discussed. This will be done by using econometric analysis on the CIS dataset. 4.1 – Generic innovation policy The generic part of the Dutch innovation policy has as its main goal to let more companies participate in innovative projects. Because the policy instruments of the generic part of innovation policy are broad and accessible to practically all companies that want to participate in innovation, the costs of implementing such policy are low. Participating companies and their project do not have to be screened and/or monitored, because all companies are allowed to participate in the programs. So, screening and monitoring costs are low for the Dutch government in the case of generic instruments. Additionally, the chance of government failure is less present since the innovation programs of the generic part are less tailored. The chance that such instruments do not ‘fit’ a company is smaller. On the other hand, some dead weight loss might arise. Because of the openness of the generic policy instrument, some companies might participate in innovation programs of the government, while these companies might not necessarily need government support. The open character of the generic part of the Dutch innovation policy makes this part accessible for most SMEs. Any company that has the intention to develop R&D activities can participate in one of the national programs. On the other hand, large companies benefit more from specific measures, because often large companies have specific preferences. Therefore, tailored measures, that fit the needs of the 38 company, are preferred by large companies. Smaller sized companies benefit from accessible measures with a low administrative burden, like the generic instruments offer. The fact that the generic part dominates the specific part in the Netherlands, and therefore the innovation policy is more skewed towards the needs of SMEs, might indicate that market failures are believed to be more severe for SMEs compared to the larger companies. The total budget for the generic part is €665 million, compared to €349 million for the specific innovation policy in 2010. Table 4.1 shows how this budget is allocated between the individual programs. Table 4.1 – Budget allocation within the generic part of the Dutch innovation policy (2010) Instrument Absolute budget Relative budget (x million) WBSO Credit for innovation Eurostars Technopartner Vouchers for innovation IPCs SBIR Syntens € 547 € 40 €1 € 24 € 14 €9 € 30 82,3 % 6,0 % 0,2 % 3,6 % 2,1 % 1,4 % 0,0 % 4,5 % Total € 665 100% (Source: Workgroup Innovation and Applied Research, 2010) As table 4.1 shows, the generic innovation policy consists of many policy instruments targeting the different segments of SMEs. Next, the policy instruments as designed by the Ministry of Economic Affairs and AgentschapNL will be shortly discussed and the concerning market failures they want to correct will be indicated. 4.1.1 – WBSO (Wet Bevordering Speur- en Ontwikkelingswerk / Law for Promotion of R&D) Most of the budget for the generic part of the Dutch innovation policy is spent on this law, namely €547 million (from the total €665 million available for the generic part). The WBSO is a fiscal instrument which makes R&D activities fiscally more attractive and has two facilities to achieve this. First, when a company has R&D employees, they have to pay less wage tax. 50% from the first € 220.000 R&D wages can be subtracted from the taxes to pay and 18% from the remaining R&D wages. 39 Second, as introduced in 2009, there are additional arrangements for starting companies and sole proprietors. These companies can subtract € 12.031 from the taxes to pay (when they have R&D employees) and can subtract 64% from the first € 220.000 R&D wages from the taxes instead of 50%. The maximum amount that companies can subtract from their taxes which they have to pay is € 14 million. By the facilities, the labour costs associated with R&D investments are partly compensated by this instrument. In this way, R&D projects are becoming less expensive and therefore SMEs will be more willing to invest in such projects. However, the condition is that a company has to have R&D employees and therefore companies that do not conduct R&D systemically and do not have R&D employees cannot benefit from the measure. The evaluation of this instrument shows that especially for SMEs the added value of the program is large. This is mainly caused by the fact that the accessibility of the program is high, the application is relatively easy and the administrative burden is relatively low. In 2009, 16.620 companies participated in the WBSO which is an increase of 23,5% compared to 2008 (13.450 companies participated). This increase in participation is due to several reasons. First, the budget of the WBSO has increased and is increasing further in 2010. Second, the financial crisis has caused that capital is less accessible for companies, therefore companies are more likely to participate in government programs which makes R&D projects less expensive. Especially SMEs increased their participation, particularly micro sized companies (with less than 10 employees) because of the additional facilities introduced in 2009 for self proprietors and starting companies. The market failure the WBSO aims to correct is in the first place the capital market failure. By lowering the costs of mostly expensive and relatively risky R&D projects, it becomes more feasible for SMEs to finance such projects by themselves. However, for most of the R&D projects external investors remain necessary to finance the project. While the WBSO is lowering the costs of an R&D project and therefore it increases its expected future returns, external investors might be more willing to invest in such a project. By lowering the private costs of innovative projects for SMEs the companies might be less reluctant to invest in R&D. As a result, SMEs will be less hindered by the externalities involved and will invest more in R&D projects. 4.1.2 – Credit for innovation Possibly the most important barrier for SMEs that discourages innovation is the lack of external finance. As explained in chapter 3, investors might be more reluctant to finance R&D projects of SMEs compared to larger companies. Small and medium sized companies which want to perform R&D projects, which include technological 40 and therefore also financial risks, face significant difficulties to finance their project using the capital market. The credit for innovation has as main goal to finance these risky R&D projects that do have commercial potential, that otherwise would not have been financed. This instrument is only intended for SMEs and in 2009 81 companies applied for such a credit. From these 81 application, 26 are approved and the budget of € 37,5 million was totally utilized. Only SMEs that cannot finance their R&D activities from own resources are eligible for a credit. The credit is limited to 35% of the total costs of the project and the maximum amount of the credit is €5 million. Off course, the credit has to be paid back, but only when the project has commercial or technical success. Only upward risk for the companies is involved since in case of failure of the project, the credit does not have to be paid back. The interest rates a company has to pay are dependent of the corresponding risk, but lower compared to market rates. The credit for innovation overcomes the problem of the missing capital market for SMEs to finance their risky R&D project. Also SMEs themselves can be very reluctant to perform a R&D project with high risk involved since failure can result in bankruptcy for the company. The set up of this instrument is excluding the downward risk of an R&D investment and only leaves the upward risk. As a result, companies can finance their R&D projects and the risk of bankruptcy of extreme losses in case of failure is ruled out. 4.1.3 – Eurostars Eurostars is an international program in which 32 countries 24 participate, the 27 member states of the European Union and some additional countries. Most of the countries that participate in Eurostars make funds available to finance R&D projects initiated by SMEs. The projects have to be initiated by at least two parties of at least two different participating countries and no requirements about subjects are present. The international component of the program is therefore strongly present. The target group of the program is SMEs and knowledge institutions. One small or medium sized high-tech company is leading the project. To qualify as a high-tech company, a company has to spend at least 10% of its revenue of FTEs to R&D. Another condition is the fact that the participating SMEs have to finance 50% of the project and the duration of the project has to be at max 3 years. 2 years after the project the product, service or process has to be introduced into the market. Dutch SMEs that participate in Eurostars are supported by subsidies from the Dutch Belgium, Bulgaria, Cyprus, Denmark, Germany, Estonia, Finland, France, Greece, Hongary, Iceland, Ireland, Israel, Italy, Croatia, Latvia, Lithuania, Luxemburg, The Netherlands, Norway, Austria, Poland, Portugal, Romania, Slovenia, Slovakia, Spain, Czech Republic, Turkey, United Kingdom, Sweden, Switzerland 24 41 government. The percentage for research activities is 45% and for development activities 35%. The total subsidy for Dutch SMEs that participate in one project is € 500.000. While it is an international program, the national governments are financing the main part of it and support the participation of domestic companies. The EU steps in, in the form of bonuses for successful projects which means that practically the EU is co-financing the program. However, the program has a strong national character, since the national governments play an important goal in financing the program and supporting the participating companies. Eurostars promotes international cooperation between SMEs. Since knowledge is not bound by borders, this may increase the probability of success of R&D projects. SMEs often are reluctant to look across borders for possible cooperation, however the most suitable companies may be in foreign countries. By stimulating such cooperation, positive knowledge spillovers may arise in addition to economies of scale. Additionally, companies are able to share the risks involved with other companies by cooperating. Altogether, this will make it more beneficial for Dutch SMEs to invest in R&D, together with international partners. Also, cooperating with other partners enables SMEs to incorporate some of the knowledge spillovers in their utility function. Knowledge may spill over from one partner to the other, however, the gains of the innovation remain within the partnership. This will increase the initial investment level of SMEs in R&D. 4.1.4 – Technopartner It cannot be denied that new, high-tech companies (technostarters) often are responsible for drastic innovation and therefore are important for the innovative strength of a country (Six Fingers, 2009). However, often barriers arise for starting an own business and participating in R&D projects. Technostarters can be seen as pioneers with respect to innovation in the sense that they want to convert their technological knowledge into marketable products or services. Therefore, it is important that the business climate for technostarters is favourable and that they are stimulated to start a business. Incumbent companies and knowledge institutions can play an important role. With their experience, they can accompany technostarters in starting a business. Technopartner is stimulating such cooperation which makes it more easy for technostarters to start its own business. Cooperating companies are subsidized for guiding technostarters, providing equipment, conducting research and for applying 42 for patents. However, another struggle for technostarters is finding venture capital to finance risky R&D projects. Technostarters often do have the necessary knowledge for R&D projects, financing however is more difficult since it concerns new businesses that do not have any own resources and also do not have a reputation on which it can lean. Therefore, Technopartner is co-financing R&D projects of technostarters. The government steps in in the form of doubling the initial investment of financial institutions which leads to risk sharing of investors and better funding opportunities of technostarters. In addition, the government can provide a TechnoPartner Label which means that the government guarantees some percentage of the loan which makes investors less reluctant to invest in technostarters. Finally, there is a Business Angel Program that increases access to informal venture capital of wealthy private investors. Providing capital is not the only role of a business angel, it can also provide a solid network, management experience and technological knowledge which can make life more easy for technostarters. However Technopartner is not targeting all SMEs in the Netherlands, it is targeting a very important group of SMEs since these companies are often responsible for drastic innovations and contribute to the innovative strength of the Netherlands. Technopartner is trying to make it more easy for a starting company to penetrate the market with an innovative product. Often, competition and lack of venture capital is hindering such penetration of the market. By cooperating with other companies and knowledge institutions, introducing financial instruments and setting up a Business Angel Program, these market failures are more or less corrected. 4.1.5 – Vouchers for innovation A voucher for innovation is a coupon by which companies (partly) can finance research at a research institute. There are private vouchers, public vouchers and patent vouchers. Private vouchers have to be used by private knowledge institutions, public vouchers have to be used by public knowledge institutions (like universities and research institutions) and patent vouchers can be used for covering the costs of patent applications. The vouchers can also be used abroad and in this sense it also stimulates international cooperation. A company can apply for maximal two vouchers a year. A distinction is made between large and small vouchers. Large vouchers have a value of € 7.500, but the SME has to cover 1/3 of the costs (€ 2.500). Small vouchers have a value of € 2.500 and the SME does not necessarily have to contribute to the costs. In the first months of 2010, 8.285 vouchers are issued, hence the budget for 2010 (€ 14 million) now already is totally used. 43 Because an entrepreneur beforehand does not necessarily has to formulate a research question, this instrument is very accessible for SMEs. However, the goal of the project always have to be to improve products, processes, services or the organization itself. In this way, the interaction between on the one hand SMEs and on the other hand knowledge institutions is stimulated. Research institutions are very important for the creation of knowledge, but off course the gains from this knowledge creation can only be reaped when this knowledge is commercialized. That is why it is important that businesses and research institutions cooperate and in this way be able to reap the gains from innovations. Cooperation with knowledge institutions can improve the innovative strength of SMEs, simply because more knowledge will be available. Vouchers stimulate such cooperation. . Vouchers ease the cooperation between SMEs and knowledge institutions by providing an adequate institutional framework. It aims at decreasing the degree of asymmetric information between SMEs and knowledge institutions. Relevant technologies and important trends can be picked up more early in this way, which increases the probability of success for a R&D project. In addition, by the international component of the voucher scheme also international cooperation is stimulated. 4.1.6 – Innovation Performance Contracts (IPCs) The Innovation Performance Contracts stimulate groups of SMEs (groups of companies between 15 and 35) to cooperate on a multiannual basis. They can cooperate to perform a collective R&D project or to strengthen a project of an individual company. By cooperating knowledge could spillover from one company to another which finally increases the ‘know-how’ of the companies. This results in a greater innovativeness of these companies, since the required knowledge in this way is in-house or present by one of the cooperating companies. Off course, it is logical that especially the cooperation of companies that have substantive consistency is stimulated. So, companies which are in the same sector, region etcetera. The IPCs consists of two parts, the pre-IPC phase (preparation phase) and the IPCphase (executive phase). The preparation phase is intended for identifying innovation strategy and to determine an innovation strategy. The maximum length of this phase is 1,5 years. For this phase, in 2010 a budget of € 1 million is present and 47 projects were submitted of which 13 were approved. In the executive phase, the innovation plans are actually implemented and has a maximal duration of 3 years. A condition for obtaining subsidy is that otherwise it would not be possible to implement the project (for example because of the high risk involved and reluctance 44 of private investors). For participating in this phase, 50 projects were submitted of which 20 projects were approved. Together, these 20 projects obtained subsidies worth € 38,1 million. Also this policy instrument aims at promoting cooperation between SMEs. As discussed above, this may result in synergies like knowledge spillovers and economies of scale. In addition, cooperating companies are more inclined to internalise the externalities involved with innovation. Companies can share the costs of R&D projects and can bundle their strengths. Cooperating with other companies can strengthen a company’s innovative and competitive strength. 4.1.7 – Small Business Innovation Research Program (SBIR) By this research program, the Dutch government outsources socially relevant innovation research. Possible themes are for example dike monitoring, green energy and nature-friendly working. The government especially invites SMEs to participate in the program. Research and innovation in these themes is not necessarily profitable, however is of great social importance. Therefore the government is promoting such research by financing the costs involved. Of great importance is the commercialization of the knowledge, since practical applicability is the main goal. Most likely, the themes of SBIR will become more important in the future. By investing in research now, the Netherlands could be increasing its competitive strength in the future. At the same time, the innovation capacity of the companies involved is increased. The SBIR is providing a new market that promotes innovation that is of great social importance. Often, such a market is missing since economically, such research and innovation may not be beneficial and involves a certain amount of risk. Often, possibilities that involve less risk are present (like fossil fuel instead of green energy) and as a result there are no incentives to invest in such research and innovation. And when these incentives do exist, it is often hard to finance such projects because of the risks involved. The Dutch government aims at correcting these market failures using the SBIR. 4.1.8 – Syntens Syntens is a nationwide network which aims to promote innovation by providing information, giving advice and support companies. It does this by personal advice, organizing workshops for companies, and by creating “innovation groups”. This are groups of experts, scientists and companies that together work on an innovative 45 project. In this way it wants to increase the cooperation between companies in innovative projects, advice companies about the commercialization of innovative ideas and inform companies about trends. Syntens particularly is targeting Dutch SMEs and in 2010 (Januray – August) already 13.763 companies are served. The consultancy costs for the companies are free, and on behalf of the government. Syntens has 15 establishments which are spread across the Netherlands. By promoting cooperation between companies in R&D projects it tries to provide an adequate institutional framework which eases cooperation. Together, companies may achieve economies of scale and/or knowledge spillovers and in this way they will be able to compete with larger companies. Cooperation also forces the cooperating companies to internalise the externalities associated with R&D projects. Gains from innovations may spill over to other companies, but when you are cooperating with these companies the gains from the innovation will remain inside the project participants. As a result, cooperating companies will be more inclined to invest more in R&D projects. Also it aims to overcome the problem of missing new product markets. By informing the companies about relevant trends and consumer needs, the new products will be more tuned to consumer preferences. In this way it tries to overcome asymmetric information between companies and competitors on the one hand and companies and consumers on the other hand. 4.2 – Specific innovation policy Besides the generic innovation policy of the Dutch government, also specific innovation policy is implemented in the Netherlands. The main goal of this policy is to stimulate cooperation between companies, and between companies and knowledge institutions. The rationale behind this specific policy for innovation is that some sectors and geographic areas are characterized by high spillovers and enhance the competitiveness of the Dutch economy. These sectors and areas require focus and mass (in terms of budget). When targeting these sectors, because of the high spillovers many companies will benefit from the policy instruments. The added value of the specific policy instruments will be higher for the companies involved, compared to the generic policy instruments. On the other hand, resulting from the specific character of the policy instruments, the costs of implementing and monitoring such policy are high compared to the generic innovation policy instruments. In addition, because the instruments are sector specific and tailor made for these sectors, the chance of government failure is higher compared to the generic policy part. The chance that the government will make the wrong choices is higher. However, the costs and the chance of government failure may be higher, the probability of dead weight loss is lower. Since the instruments are tailored to specific sectors and therefore not accessible to all companies, the chance that companies use the instruments while they do not specifically need the instruments 46 is smaller. The accessibility of the specific policy instruments is lower and therefore only the companies that need the instruments will participate. Because of the fact that the specific innovation policy of the Dutch government is targeting specific (strong) sectors and geographic areas, not all the companies can benefit from these policy instruments. Often, the sectors and geographic areas of the specific policy are built around strong multinationals that are important for the Dutch economy. Therefore, compared to the generic innovation policy instruments, the specific innovation policy instruments are less accessible for SMEs. The sectors which the specific policy instruments of the Dutch government is targeting are the following (Ministry of Economic Affairs, 2006): ï‚· ï‚· ï‚· ï‚· ï‚· High-tech systems and materials Flowers and food Water Creative industry Chemical industry These sectors are the key sectors of the Dutch economy and are believed to have a strong impact on the growth potential of the Dutch economy. That is why they require additional attention. By targeting these sectors, the Dutch economy can strengthen its strengths it and can differentiate itself from other economies. Next, the policy instruments of the specific innovation policy of the Dutch government and the corresponding market failures are discussed. 4.2.1 – Innovation programs Throughout the Netherlands ecosystems of large companies, SMEs and knowledge institutions exists which are active within sectors in which the Netherlands is excelling. These ecosystems are close partnerships which are focused on innovation. Together with the private companies and knowledge institutions the Dutch government is investing in these ecosystems. For 2010, the budget of the innovation programs was €283,4 million, which is the main part of the specific innovation budget. Because the sectors the programs are targeting are that important for the competitiveness of the Dutch economy, these programs are likely to have a strong impact on the growth potential of the Dutch economy (when implemented efficiently). 47 Innovation programs are strategic partnerships consisting of companies and knowledge institutions. Together, they have to formulate a demand driven vision and strategy. Then, an external strategic board have to give an advice to the Ministry of Economic affairs whether or not to support this program. When positive, funds will be granted to this innovation program. Striking for the innovation program is the fact that the companies and knowledge institutions have to cooperate and must take the first step. Important to get a positive advice from the external board is that the innovation strategy must be demand driven. It is important that innovations can be commercialized and in that way improve the competitiveness of the participating companies and knowledge institutions. For each strong sector, which is important for the competitiveness of the Dutch economy, a separate innovation program is designed to target each of these sectors specifically. In the past, the following innovation programs are realized: ï‚· ï‚· ï‚· ï‚· ï‚· ï‚· ï‚· ï‚· ï‚· ï‚· ï‚· Food and nutrition delta Hightech automotive systems Innovation process chemical industry Life sciences and health Logistics and supply chains Maritime industry Materials Point One (nano technology, embedded systems and mechatronics) Water technology Service innovation and ICT (Creative industry) Cooperation between companies and knowledge institutions make the participating parties internalise some of the externalities present. The innovation programs also make it possible for small firms, with little funds, to participate in innovative projects, because the costs are can be shared with many other parties. Because of the large scale of the project, also small firms can benefit from economies of scale. In addition, the government is stepping in as well, which makes it more easier for companies to finance such projects (especially for small companies 25). By participating in an innovation program, companies share knowledge with each other and with knowledge institutions. The degree of asymmetric information between these companies will decrease because of cooperating. Positive knowledge spillovers will contribute to the success of the project and will take away part of the uncertainty regarding the project. As explained, for small companies it is often more difficult to finance risky R&D projects because of lack of collateral and reputation. By cooperating with larger companies and knowledge institutions, costs can be shared and external funders will be less prudent to finance such projects. Because of large companies which good reputations are stepping in, the whole project can benefit from this reputation. 25 48 4.2.2 – International innovation Knowledge goes beyond borders, and in a globalized economy it is more and more important for companies to look beyond borders. That is why the Dutch government is promoting companies to cooperate not only with domestic companies, but also with foreign companies. To do so, this instrument is divided into three pillars; Eureka, industrialized countries and emerging markets. Together, the three pillars have a budget of €9,2 million in 2010. For all three pillars, there are no specific requirements for the subject of the innovationproject. However, some requirements about the process are present. The innovation project must result in a commercial product, within three or five years after the completing the R&D project, the product must be commercialized. Also, there must be a technological innovation and must generate economic value for participating Dutch companies. An external board reviews the submitted proposals, and the proposals with the highest quality will be supported by the Dutch government. As mentioned, the Netherlands is participating in Eureka, a network of 38 countries. The Dutch government supports companies and knowledge institutions which participate in international innovation collaborations. Eureka is focused on demand driven research and development projects, and is accessible for both large and smaller companies. In addition, participation of knowledge institutions is welcomed to bridge the gap between academic theory and industrial practice. The second pillar, industrialized countries, focuses on cooperation with companies from other industrialized countries that have many knowledge in technology or countries that could be a interesting market for Dutch companies. The selected countries are Canada, Japan, Singapore and the United States. When Dutch companies want to develop a product or service together with a partner from one of these countries, the Dutch Government is willing to support this process financially. Finally, the pillar emerging market is aiming at promoting the cooperation between Dutch parties and parties from emerging markets in R&D projects. In addition, this project tries to position Dutch companies better in emerging markets. The same as with the industrialized countries, a selection of emerging markets has been made. The selected countries are Brazil, China, India, Indonesia, Malaysia, Thailand, SouthKorea and South-Africa. Likely, the economic role of these countries will increase in the future. Therefore, it is good for Dutch companies to position themselves better in these countries. Companies that want to cooperate with parties from the selected countries are supported financially (by subsidies), but also politically. This means that the Dutch government negotiates with the emerging market about improving 49 the relationship between the countries and therefore indirectly the conditions for Dutch companies. Both SMEs and large companies can participate in these programs. However, the subsidy rate differs between the groups of companies. For research activities large companies obtain a subsidy of 35% and for development activities this rate is 25%. For SMEs, this rate is 10% higher which means 45% for research activities and 35% for development activities. The maximal amount of subsidy for a project with companies from emerging markets is € 500.000 and for a project with an Eureka country or another industrialized country is € 750.000. The degree of asymmetric information between companies from different countries is often higher than between companies from the same country. Cultural differences and differences in language implies additional asymmetric information and uncertainty. The program international innovation tries to overcome this form of market failure. By cooperating internationally and trading knowledge internationally, positive spillovers might arise in the form of knowledge spillovers, economies of scale and risk sharing. 4.2.3 – EG-Liason EG-Liason is focussing on Dutch companies or knowledge institutions that participate in European innovation programs regarding innovation. Its main focus are the participants of the framework program of the European Commission (see 5.1), but EG-Liason can also be usefull for participants of other European programs (Eureka, Eurostars). EG-Liason informs and advises Dutch companies and knowledge institutions that participate or want to participate in an European innovation program. Especially for SMEs this can be helpful, since participating in European innovation programs can be very timeconsuming and the administrative burden is often high. Therefore, it can be a great struggle for SMEs to participate in such programs, and EG-Liason tries to make European innovation programs more accessible. EG-Liason aims at making European innovation programs more accessible for Dutch companies and knowledge institutions. Often, the institutional structure of these programs makes it very timeconsuming to participate in the programs. EG-Liason tries to overcome this problem and aims to ease the process of participating in European innovation programs. 50 4.3 – Empirical analysis Now that the Dutch instruments to promote R&D activities of SMEs are introduced, it is interesting to look at whether or not there exist differences between Dutch SMEs and large companies in participation in government programs. To examine this possible difference, a probit regression model is used. This because of the fact the respective dependent variable is a dummy variable which takes the value of 1 when a company is participating in a national government program. As independent variables, off course variables which indicate whether or not a company is characterized as a SME are included. In addition, control variables are included to control for other company specific aspects which also can have its impact on participation in government programs. Again, data from the CIS dataset is used and the results are showed in table 4.2. Table 4.2 – Differences between SMEs and large companies in participation in national government programs (1) (2) (3) (4) Constant -0,658*** SME Small sized company Medium sized company -0,009 -0,658*** -1,280*** -1,280*** -0,169** -0,050 -0,053 -0,173** -0,167** Control variables Manufacturing -0,467*** -0,467*** International activities -0,528*** -0,528*** Cooperation -0,191*** -0,191*** R&D intensity -0,005*** -0,005*** Dependent variable: Participation in national government programs (dummy) Sample: all companies present in the Community Innovation Survey (9.947) * Significant at 10% level, ** Significant at 5% level, ***Significant at 1% level The results show four estimated models. Models (1) and (2) do not use control variables and only look at the effect of firm size on participation in Dutch government programs that stimulate R&D activities. No significant effects can be found in these models. In models (3) and (4) however, that do use control variables to control for other company specific characteristics, significant effects can be found. These models show that SMEs participate significantly more in Dutch government programs compared to its larger counterpart. This can be the result of the fact that in the Netherlands the generic innovation policy part dominates the specific 51 innovation policy part. In previous paragraphs we have seen that the generic part is more favourable for SMEs, because these instruments are easily accessible and have an open and broad character. The differences between small and medium sized companies are not worth mentioning and are not economically significant. In contrast, the control variables do show some interesting effects. Manufacturing companies tend to participate more in Dutch government programs. The same holds for companies that do have international activities, cooperate with other companies and have a high R&D intensity. However, the last three effects can also be the result of reversed causality since the R&D programs of the Dutch government promote international activities, cooperation and R&D activities. But since these variables are not of main interest, no further tests are necessary to investigate the causality between the respective variables. SMEs tend to participate more in Dutch government programs compared to large companies, but do these government programs foster innovation activities of Dutch SMEs? That is an interesting question which following analysis will try to answer. To answer this question a subsample of SMEs is used from the CIS dataset, which allows to only capture the effect for SMEs. Simple linear regression is used to examine the differences between SMEs that participate in Dutch innovation programs and SMEs that do not participate in these programs. To check the robustness of the outcome, two innovation indicators are used as dependent variable. The same as in chapter 2, these indicators are “R&D intensity” and “share of revenue from products new to the market”. The results of the analysis are shown in tables 4.3 and 4.4. Model (1) as represented in table 4.3 show that SMEs that do participate in Dutch government programs have a higher R&D intensity compared to companies that do not participate in such programs. This is a first indication that the Dutch government programs succeed in correcting market failures present for SMEs. Companies that do participate in national government programs invest relatively more in R&D. But in addition, the R&D intensity of those companies is even higher than the R&D intensity of companies that participate in European programs and of companies that participate in both European and national programs. Model (2), when controlled for company specific factors, confirms this conclusion and shows some additional effects of variables on R&D intensity of SMEs. SMEs that are active as a manufacturing company tend to have a lower R&D intensity, the same holds for companies that are part of a concern. In contrast, cooperating companies tend to have a higher R&D intensity. Whether a company is active internationally, does not have a significant impact. Also no significant differences in R&D intensity are present between small and medium sized firms. 52 Table 4.3 – Differences in R&D intensity between SMEs that do participate in Dutch government programs and SMEs that do not participate in these programs (1) (2) Constant ,355*** 6,121*** National government support -6,879*** Control variables: European government -1,252 support Both national and European -6,623** government support Manufacturing International activities Cooperation Company is part of concern Small sized company Dependent variable: R&D intensity -7,719*** -1,725 -6,442** -6,013*** -1,870 -3,504*** -3,768*** -0,895 Sample: all SMEs present in the Community Innovation Survey (8.886) * Significant at 10% level, ** Significant at 5% level, ***Significant at 1% level Next, the results are shown of the same regression, but with “new introduced products” as dependent variable. In contrast with the input innovation indicator R&D intensity, now an output indicator is used which measures the commercial impact of innovations. The main results of table 4.4 are in line with the results from table 4.3. SMEs that do participate in Dutch government programs that aim at stimulating R&D significantly tend to introduce relatively more new products to the market than SMEs that do not participate. Again, a confirmation that the Dutch programs succeed in correcting some of the market failures that restrain innovation. The nice thing about using an output indicator as dependent variable is that this analysis shows that participating in national government programs actual leads to relatively more newly introduced products. Companies succeed relatively more in commercialization of innovations. This is even higher for small sized companies compared to medium sized companies. In this sense, the Dutch government programs are more successful than its European counterpart for SMEs. Participating SMEs in European programs tend to introduce relatively less new products, although insignificantly. The control 53 variables in table 4.4 reflect the same picture as in table 4.3, although some have other significance levels. Table 4.4 – Differences in new product introduction between SMEs that do participate in Dutch government programs and SMEs that do not participate in these programs (1) (2) Constant 4,355*** 3,425*** National government support -5,122*** -4,829*** Control variables: European government -0,711 -0,862 support Both national and European -2,625* -2,026 government support Manufacturing -1,651*** International activities -1,886*** Cooperation -2,038*** Company is part of concern -0,078 Small sized company -1,326** Dependent variable: share of revenue from products new to the market Sample: all SMEs present in the Community Innovation Survey (8.886) * Significant at 10% level, ** Significant at 5% level, ***Significant at 1% level To conclude this section , both the input and the output indicator indicate that SMEs that participate in national innovation programs are more innovative than SMEs that do not participate in the programs. This is an indication that the Dutch government programs (partly) succeed in correcting the market failures that restrain innovation. However, one must consider the possibility of reverse causality. It could be the case that more innovative SMEs participate more in Dutch government programs in general, a case of self-selection. 4.4 – Conclusion The Dutch innovation policy consists out of a generic part and a specific part and aims to correct the market failures as present. In the Netherlands, the generic part 54 dominates the specific part in terms of budget allocation (€665 million vs. €349 million). The open character and the general measures of the generic part makes its instruments accessible for many SMEs. In contrast, the specific instruments of the Dutch innovation policy targets specific groups of companies and therefore not all SMEs are able to benefit from these measures. The specific policy instruments especially target the strong sectors of the Dutch economy and international cooperation between companies. Table 4.5 gives a good overview about the national programs and which market failures they aim to correct. The darker the colour green, the more important the corresponding market failure is within the program and indicates the relevance of the program for SMEs. The generic part of the Dutch innovation policy is especially targeting the capital market failure, the degree of incomplete information and stimulates cooperation. The market failures that restrict international cooperation are hardly tackled at all. The same holds for the missing market for new products and the problem of bounded consumer rationality. For the market failures that have to do with international property right protection and competition, the Dutch government does not have any authority. The European Union is designing legislation in these fields, therefore the Dutch government cannot target these market failures specifically. The specific part is also targeting the capital market failure, the degree of incomplete information and stimulates (international) cooperation. However, the main difference is the fact that specific groups of companies are targeted by the specific part of the Dutch innovation policy. By stimulating cooperation between these groups of companies, the innovativeness of the sector will increase which enhances its competitiveness. The same as holds for the generic part, the specific part of the Dutch innovation policy does not tackle the market failures of the missing market for new products and the problem of bounded consumer rationality. This means that the Dutch innovation policy does not correct these market failures at all. The empirical analysis showed that Dutch SMEs participate relatively more in Dutch government programs compared to its larger counterpart. This may be the result of the fact that in the Netherlands the generic part dominates the specific part. Additionally, the empirics showed that the Dutch government programs have a significantly positive effect on the innovativeness of the Dutch SMEs. Both the R&D intensity and the introduction of new products are significantly higher when SMEs participate in national programs. This is an indication that the Dutch government succeeds in correcting (some) of the market failures present for SMEs. Next, the European innovation policy will be discussed. 55 56 Table 4.5a – Generic national instruments and corresponding market failures Market failure WBSO Syntens IPCs Vouchers Credit Technopartner Eurostars SBIR IPRprotection Institutional framework Missing markets Externalities Market structure Cooperation International cooperation Capital market New product market Externalities Competition Entry barriers Incomplete information Consumer rationality 57 Table 4.5b – Specific national instruments and corresponding market failures Market failure Innovation InternaEG-Liason programs tional innovation IPRprotection Institutional Cooperation framework International cooperation Capital market Missing markets New product market Externalities Market structure Externalities Competition Entry barriers Incomplete information Consumer rationality 58 59 5 – European innovation policy relevant for SMEs Besides the innovation policy of the Dutch government as described in chapter 4, also the European Union is stimulating innovation of private companies. This chapter describes the policy of the European Union that aims at stimulating innovation. The European policy nowadays consists of two pillars, namely the 7 th framework program and CIP. These two parts will be separately discussed in the following paragraphs. In the previous chapter we already have seen some instruments with an international character, namely Eurostars and the Eureka network. However, these instrument are mainly financed by the governments of the member states and therefore are characterized as national instruments. The 7 th framework program and CIP are completely financed by funds of the European Union and therefore are characterized as European instruments. However, indirectly, also these instruments are financed by contribution of individual member states to the Union. After describing these instruments, an empirical analysis will be discussed which will analyze the differences between Dutch SMEs and large companies in participation in European programs. Also the added value of participation in these programs will be analyzed for SMEs. 5.1 – 7th Framework Program (FP7) The 7th framework program for research and technological development is the successor of the 6th framework program and the program concerns the period from 2007-2013. For this period, the European Commission has reserved a budget of €50,5 billion, which means a large increase in budget with respect to the 6 th framework program26. This budget is spent for a large share on subsidies to finance research, development and demonstration projects. Besides the increase in budget, the 7th framework program also claims to be more flexible and easier accessible with less administrative burdens. However, especially SMEs still complain about the great administrative burden of the framework program and the low probability of success. Participants from the Netherland are expected to receive €3 billion from the total €50,5 billion budget. This is equal to roughly 5,9% of the total budget, which is a relatively high share compared to its GDP (the Netherlands is responsible for 5,6% of the GDP of the EU). The most important Dutch participants are TNO, GTI, universities, Philips, Unilever and Stork. Large companies and knowledge The budget of the 7th framework program increased with 41% with respect to the budget of the 6th framework program. 26 60 institutions are overrepresented in the 7th framework programme. However, also Dutch SMEs do participate, but to a small extent. In total, 10.853 Dutch parties participated in the cooperation program (see below) of KP7, including 1.606 SMEs which is slightly less than 15%. Main complaints of SMEs are the high administrative burden and the low probability of success. It is simply not worth all the trouble. Participation is as follows. The European Commission issues a call for a project proposal. Requirements for the proposal are laid down in the specific call. Then, a consortium of at least three companies, knowledge institutions and/or experts have to be formed from at least three different countries. Together, they have to submit a project proposal which will be evaluated based on the criteria as stressed out in the specific call. The proposal that pass this first step go forward to further evaluation. The average rate of success for Dutch SMEs that want to participate in the framework program is 22,4%. Which means that, for a SME, four out of five project proposals are not successful, and therefore do not receive any funds from FP7. The international character of FP7 is important, it has to be a complement to national innovation programs, not a substitute. Therefore, the projects have to be transnational. Actors from different member states have to cooperate in these projects to qualify for funding through the framework programme. However, exceptions are made when it concerns groundbreaking scientific research that could be of a great impact for the competitiveness of the European economy. Because of the increased importance of cooperation between all the actors within the innovation system and the trend of globalization, it is important that companies, knowledge institutions and researchers join forces nationally, but also internationally. The 7th framework programme is stimulating this cooperation within the European Union. Actors that can participate in projects from the framework programme are companies (SMEs but also large companies), knowledge institutions and individual researchers from European member states but also from other countries27. So, also parties from countries outside the European Union can participate in the framework program. Indeed, such cooperation are even stimulated because of the fact that such collaborations could strengthen the competitiveness of European companies in other countries and because some challenges are of a global nature. By cooperating across borders, the European Union is trying to achieve two important strategic objectives through the framework program. It wants to strengthen the scientific and technological basis of the European industry. In Of course, an actor from one of the member states of the European Union has to be part of the project. Otherwise, the European Commission will not finance the project. 27 61 addition, it wants to increase the competitiveness of the European industry and stimulating research. Within the 7th framework program there exist five specific programs that each target a specific component of the program. This structure is well displayed by figure 5.1. In addition, table 5.1 gives an overview about the distribution of the budget between the specific programs. Figure 5.1 – Structure of the 7th Framework Program (Source: European Commission, 2010) Cooperation program: For Dutch SMEs the specific program for cooperation is by far the most important, because the cooperation program is best suited for companies. Not surprisingly, SMEs are relatively more represented in this specific program compared to the other programs within FP7. As will be explained, the people and ideas programs specifically target individual researchers and are therefore less applicable for SMEs. 62 Table 5.1 – Division of budget within FP7 Specific program Budget Percentage (x billion) € 32,413 64% € 6, 12% € ,935 4% € 9, 5 18% € 3,475 7% Cooperation program Health Food, agriculture, fisheries and biotechnology Information and communication technologies Nanosciences, nanotechnologies, materials and new production technologies Energy € 2,35 5% Environment € ,89 4% Transport € 4, 6 8% Socio-economic sciences and humanities € ,623 1% Security € ,4 3% Space € ,43 3% Ideas program € 7,51 16% People program € 4,75 9% Capacities program € 4,097 8% Joint Research Centre € 1,751 3% Total € 50,521 100% (Source: European Commission, 2010) Cooperation is the core of the framework program and therefore it covers two thirds of the total budget (€32,4 billion). This specific program stimulates cooperation in research that is transnational and is meant for companies, knowledge institutions and individual researchers. At least, three partners from three different countries have to participate in a project. Often, the number of participating parties is high and the duration of the project is long. The cooperation program is divided into ten specific themes that are believed to be of great importance for the European economy (now or in the future). The European Commission has determined the following key scientific and technology areas in which it aims to gain leadership in. ï‚· ï‚· ï‚· ï‚· ï‚· ï‚· ï‚· ï‚· ï‚· ï‚· Health Food, agriculture, fisheries and biotechnology Information and communication technologies Nanosciences, nanotechnologies, materials technologies Energy Environment (including climate change) Transport (including aeronautics) Socio-economic sciences and the humanities Space Security and new production Each theme within the cooperation program is operated autonomously, but interaction between different themes is allowed and stimulated. Projects within 63 different themes can undertake joint activities and make joint calls for funding. In the themes “nanosciences, nanotechnologies, materials and new production technologies” and “energy” SMEs are relatively overrepresented within FP7. Ideas program: Within this program scientific excellence is stimulated, only groundbreaking research will be financed within this program. There are no specific themes determined as in the cooperation program, the research can cover each conceivable subject. Another contrast compared to the cooperation program is that transnational cooperation is allowed but is not obliged to be eligible for funding. All individual teams, leaded by a principal investigator, can apply for funding by the 7th framework program. Because projects within the ideas program have to be investigator-driven projects, they are free from political priorities. As a result, new and promising areas of research can further be explored. The budget for the ideas program is considerably smaller than the budget of the cooperation, namely €7,5 billion intended exclusively for individual researchers and is therefore not applicable for SMEs. This specific program is implemented by the European Research Council (ERC). People Program: In addition to the ideas program, also the people program is targeting individual researchers. By the people program the European Commission is supporting the mobility and the career development of researchers within the European Union but also researchers of countries outside the EU. For this program, a budget of €4,7 billion is available over the period 2007-2013. This seems small compared to the cooperation program, however compared to the 6th framework program it means an increase in budget of 50%. The rationale behind the people program is that the quantity and quality of scientific researchers is important to promote innovation and promote investments in research by public and private entities. This specific program will be implemented through the following actions. ï‚· Initial training of researchers to improve young researchers ï‚· Life-long training and career development ï‚· Industry-academia partnerships to promote mobility and knowledge sharing ï‚· International actions to attract talent from outside Europe and promote research collaboration with researchers from outside the EU ï‚· Specific actions to remove obstacles for mobility 64 Again, this specific program is not directly targeting SMEs and other companies. However, companies may benefit indirectly when the quantity and quality of European researchers increases. Through knowledge sharing and spillovers, companies may benefit from this increase of the knowledge base within Europe which fosters innovation. The same holds for the ideas program. Capacity Program: With €4,1 billion, the smallest budget of the specific programs within the 7 th framework program. The program aims at optimizing the innovation and research capacities within Europe. The capacity program includes to following activities. ï‚· Improve and optimize the use of research infrastructure like databanks, laboratories and communication networks. ï‚· Research for the benefit of SMEs to strengthen the innovative capacity of SMEs. Outsourcing of research activities by SMEs is supported, even as participation in the cooperation program of FP7. ï‚· Regions of knowledge by promoting the development of research-driven clusters across Europe. ï‚· Developing the research potential of Europe’s convergence regions (especially new member states). ï‚· Improve the relationship between science and society to get the public more acquainted with science. ï‚· Promote international cooperation within the European Union but also with countries outside the EU. Logically, Dutch SMEs will benefit from the research for SMEs since this measure provides favourable conditions for SMEs compared to larger firms. But also the other measures from the capacity program may indirectly strengthen the innovative strength of SMEs, while not targeted directly. Non-Nuclear research actions by the Joint Research Center (JRC) The Joint Research Center conducts research to support the European Union’s policy making technologically and academically with a budget of €1,8 billion. Because this specific program is not relevant for SMEs, further elaboration about the JRC is not necessary. In the first place, the 7th framework program is stimulating international cooperation. In addition, it promotes interaction between knowledge institutions on the one side and companies on the other side. To stand against companies from established countries like the USA and Japan, but also from emerging markets like China and Brazil, it is important that European parties join forces to remain 65 competitive on a global scale. Knowledge diffusion and commercialization of this knowledge is key in this process, the 7th framework program is promoting this. By cooperating, participating parties can achieve economies of scale, share the risk involved and can internalise some of the externalities involved with innovation. As stressed out, knowledge may spill over to other parties, but when you, as a company, cooperate with these parties, the knowledge remains within the respective project, but also the gains resulting from this knowledge. The participating parties are supported financially by subsidies and are able to share the risk of the project, so financing (risky) R&D projects becomes less of a problem. The 7th framework program aims at achieving an institutional framework that, among other, stimulates cooperation of companies (SMEs and large companies) and knowledge institutions internationally (the cooperation program). However, FP7 is dominated especially by large companies and knowledge institutions. For SMEs, the administrative burden and the low probability of success are great barriers to participate in the framework program. Sadly, the framework program fails at achieving an institutional framework for SMEs that promotes international cooperation. FP7 therefore fails in correcting the present market failures for SMEs in many cases28. Indirectly, the 7th framework program might be of use for SMEs. By providing good framework conditions for researchers, the quality and quantity of research might increase which indirectly may benefit SMEs, when this generated knowledge is transferred to SMEs within Europe (the ideas, people and capacities programs). 5.2 – Competitiveness and Innovation Framework Program (CIP) With a budget of roughly €3,6 billion the budget of the Competitiveness and Innovation Framework Program is significantly smaller than the 7th Framework Program’s budget. This budget is spread over a period which runs from 2007 until 2013. Table 5.2 gives a clear overview about how this budget is distributed among the specific programs within CIP. CIP is specifically targeting the small and medium enterprises within Europe. It aims at increase the competitiveness of European SMEs by supporting innovation, providing better access to finance and delivering business support services. In addition, CIP has some specific components which encourage the use of ICT, the use of renewable energy and energy efficiency. Within the Competitiveness and Innovation Framework Program there exist three operational programmes, which each have its specific objectives. The following Off course, there are SMEs that participate in the 7th framework program successfully. But, the probability of success for SMEs is slightly higher than 20% and therefore 4 out of 5 SMEs participate in FP7 unsuccessfully. For most SMEs, market failures are not corrected by the framework program. 28 66 three programs will be further discussed: the Entrepreneurship and Innovation Program (EIP), the information Communication Technologies Policy Support Program (ICT PSP) and the Intelligent Energy Europe Program (IEE). Entrepreneurship and Innovation Program (EIP): EIP supports innovation of SMEs in the European Union by multiple actions and instruments. Together, a budget of €2,17 billion is available to implement these three actions and instruments, which is 75% of the total budget of the Competitiveness and Innovation Framework Program. First, the program aims at making finance for SMEs more accessible. The financial instruments of EIP target companies in each phase of their lifecycle. So, starters but also established SMEs are eligible for financial support. Also, investments in innovation are supported. Here, eco-innovation29 plays a special role and gets additional attention. This is implemented by the European Investment Fund and selected financial institutions using financial instruments. With a budget of €1,1 billion it aims at generating €30 billion of new finance for up to 400.000 SMEs within Europe. Instruments like venture capital and guarantees are used to stimulate entrepreneurship and innovation of SMEs. Second, cross border cooperation is stimulated by an “Enterprise Europe Network”. Also CIP recognizes the importance of cross border cooperation with other companies and knowledge institutions. Therefore the Entrepreneurship and Innovation Program supports companies that want to cooperate with foreign companies and/or knowledge institutions by providing guidance and information through national networks of service centres30. It informs SMEs about the European legislation, business cooperation opportunities and funding opportunities (public programs and/or private funding). This European network is financed by a budget of €320 million concerning the period 2007-2013. Indirectly, a third action is undertaken by EIP to support SMEs’ innovative activities. Namely, it provides support for national policymaking and it gives companies and public bodies the opportunity to exchange good practice on innovation policy. It provides research about the latest trends and developments in technologically important sectors. In this way, it helps national governments to design innovation policy which suits the needs of SMEs and large companies. To finance this research and analytical tools, a budget of €650 million is available. Product, process and service innovations that reduce environmental impacts, prevent pollution or achieve a more efficient and responsible role of natural resources. 30 For the Dutch case, this service is provided by Syntens and AgentschapNL. Syntens is the organization that supports companies in the Netherlands which aim at develop innovation activities. AgentschapNL is implementing the Dutch innovation policy. 29 67 Information and Communication Technologies Policy Support Program (ICT PSP): Still, ICT has considerable potential to drive growth and jobs in Europe. Compared to the USA, diffusion and implementation of ICT in company products, services and processes can be improved. This partly explains the increasing gap in productivity (growth) between the United States and European member states. Better implementation of ICT could boost the innovative capacities of SMEs. To achieve this, pilot projects which test innovative ICT based services in real settings are financed by ICT PSP. SMEs can apply for such pilot projects. Especially, the use of ICT to challenge socio-economic problems like ageing and energy efficiency is stimulated. In addition, SMEs are given the opportunity to join networks to share their experiences and build consensus with respect to ICT related activities. For ICT PSP, a budget of €730 million is available for the period 2007-2013. Intelligent Energy Europe Program (IEE): With a budget of €730 million, the European Commission is trying to remove market barriers, change behaviour and create more favourable business environment for increasing energy efficiency and the use of renewable energy. The program launches calls for project proposals to which SMEs (but also other companies and publicly organizations) can apply. When admitted, the funding covers up 75% of the involved costs. From 2007, over 3.000 organizations have participated in such projects across Europe. The aim of the projects is to use energy more efficient and to promote the use of renewable energy. Eco-innovation is stimulated in this way which enhances the competitiveness of the participating companies but also contributes to the challenges associated with climate change. In addition, part of the budget is spent on research concerning energy efficiency and renewable energy. Table 5.2 – Division of budget within CIP Specific program Entrepreneurship and Innovation Program Financial instruments Enterprise Europe Network Eco-innovation ICT Policy Support Program Intelligent Energy Europe Program Total Budget Percentage (x million) € 2.170 59,8% € . 30,3% € 32 8,8% € 65 17,9% € 730 20,1% € 730 20,1% € 3.630 100% (Source: European Commission, 2010) Most of the budget of CIP is being spent on the financial instruments to ease the access to finance of SMEs. With the financial instruments the European Commission is trying to tackle the market failure of the missing capital market for (risky) R&D projects of SMEs. Further, the program is fostering the innovativeness of SMEs by 68 promoting ICT implementation and innovation related to socio-economic challenges like energy and health. Also, financial support is provided for SMEs around these themes. Finally, with the Enterprise Europe Network CIP is promoting cooperation between companies and knowledge institutions across borders. It provides information about opportunities for SMEs and in this way it tries to decrease the degree of asymmetric information31. Interaction may lead to economies of scale, risk sharing and positive knowledge spillovers spillovers. By cooperating, externalities can be internalized within the R&D project. However, correcting the market failure of a missing capital market remains the most important goal of the Competitiveness and Innovation Framework Program. 5.3 – Empirical analysis As mentioned in the previous paragraphs, especially FP7 is not very accessible for SMEs. A high administrative burden and a low probability of success make SMEs reluctant to participate in the 7th framework program. CIP in contrast especially targets SMEs but faces the problem of a relatively small budget. Therefore, it is interesting to look at whether or not there exist differences between Dutch SMEs and large companies in participation in European government programs. To examine this possible difference, a binary logistic regression is used. This because of the fact the respective dependent variable is a dummy variable which takes the value of 1 when a company is participating in an European government program. As independent variables, off course variables which indicate whether or not a company is characterized as a SME are included. In addition, control variables are included to control for other company specific aspects which also can have its impact on participation in government programs. Models (1) and (2) give a first indication between the differences in participation in European government programs between SMEs and large companies. It turns out that SMEs indeed participate less in European programs compared to larger companies. This can be seen of a confirmation that for SMEs participating in FP7 is hard because of the high administrative burden and low probability of success. And since FP7 is dominating CIP in terms of budget, this effect will dominate on European level. No relevant difference between small and medium sized companies can be noted. When controlling for other company specific factors, these results do not change much. Still, SMEs tend to significantly participate less in European programs and no noteworthy differences between small and medium sized companies are present. From the control variables, only the dummy variable for It informs SMEs about European legislation public funding opportunities (like FP7), private funding opportunities, current trends, cooperation opportunities, available research. In this way, CIP is aiming to decrease the degree of asymmetric information among SMEs about innovation policy, funding, cooperation and available research. 31 69 cooperation has a positive and significant impact on participation in European programs. However, this also could be the result of reverse causality since European programs especially stimulate cooperation between companies. The other control variables do not have a significant impact on participation in European programs. Table 5.3 – Differences between SMEs and large companies in participation in European government programs (1) (2) (3) (4) Constant -1,821*** SME Small sized company Medium sized company -0,382*** -1,821*** -1,998*** -2,000*** -0,339*** -0,377*** -0,385*** -0,329** -0,345** Control variables Manufacturing -0,143 -0,143 International activities -0,056 -0,055 Cooperation -0,221* -0,223* R&D intensity -0,001 -0,001 Dependent variable: Participation in national government programs (dummy) Sample: all companies present in the Community Innovation Survey (9.947) * Significant at 10% level, ** Significant at 5% level, ***Significant at 1% level The results from table 5.3 have showed that SMEs participate significantly less in European programs compared to large companies. But how about the Dutch SMEs that do participate in these programs? Are they more innovative than the SMEs that do not participate in European programs? European innovation programs namely are aiming at correcting the market failures that restrain innnovation. Previous paragraphs have shown that they particularly aim at promoting cooperation between companies and correcting the capital market failure. As a result, participating SMEs should be more innovative than SMEs that do not participate in European programs. To see whether this is the case, a subsample from the CIS dataset is used which captures all SMEs represented in the dataset, so large companies are excluded. Simple linear regression is used to examine the differences between SMEs that participate in Dutch innovation programs and SMEs that do not participate in these programs. To check the robustness of the outcome, the same as in chapter 4, two innovation indicators are used as dependent variable. Namely, “R&D intensity” and “share of revenue from products new to the market”. The results of the analysis are shown in tables 5.4 and 5.5. 70 Table 5.4 show that, with and without the use of control variables, participation in European government programs has no significant impact on the R&D intensity of Dutch SMEs. SMEs that participate in European programs tend to have a higher R&D intensity, although the difference is not significant. So, first, SMEs tend to participate significantly less in European programs and second, when SMEs do participate, this leads to no significant increase in innovativeness. This is an indication that European programs do not succeed in correcting the market failures present for Dutch SMEs. When looking at the control variables, some characteristics of Dutch SMEs do tend to have a significant impact on its R&D intensity. The same as in chapter 4, manufacturing companies and companies that are part of a concern tend to have a lower R&D intensity. In contrast, cooperating companies do have a higher R&D intensity. Also participation in Dutch government programs leads to a higher R&D intensity. European participation, however, does not. Other control variables do not have a significant impact on a SME’s R&D intensity, for example no significant difference can be found between small and medium sized companies. Table 5.4 – Differences in R&D intensity between SMEs that do participate in European government programs and SMEs that do not participate in these programs (1) (2) Constant 4,355*** 6,121*** European government support -1,252 Control variables: National government -6,879*** support Both national and European -6,623** government support Manufacturing International activities Cooperation Company is part of concern Small sized company Dependent variable: R&D intensity -1,725 -7,719*** -6,442** -6,013*** -1,870 -3,504*** -3,768*** -0,895 Sample: all SMEs present in the Community Innovation Survey (8.886) * Significant at 10% level, ** Significant at 5% level, ***Significant at 1% level R&D intensity is not significantly influenced by participation in European programs. European instruments do not lead to significant higher investments in R&D. But 71 perhaps differences can be found in output indicators, like new introduced products to the market. The effect of European programs on this output indicator is displayed in table 5.5. Again, no significant differences between Dutch SMEs that do participate and Dutch SMEs that do not participate in European programs can be found. Both models, with and without control variables, give this result. However, in terms of innovative output the European programs tend to perform even worse. The programs tend to have a negative impact on new introduced products, however not significant. In contrast, international activities, cooperation and participation in national programs have a significant positive effect on new introduced products. The table also shows that small sized company tend to introduce relatively more new products compared to medium sized companies. Again, manufacturing companies are found to be less innovative than companies which are active within other sectors. Table 5.5 – Differences in new product introduction between SMEs that do participate in European government programs and SMEs that do not participate in these programs (1) (2) Constant 4,355*** -3,425*** European government support -0,711 -0,862 Control variables: National government -5,122*** -4,829*** support Both national and European -2,625* -2,026 government support Manufacturing -1,651*** International activities -1,886*** Cooperation -2,038*** Company is part of concern -0,078 Small sized company -1,326** Dependent variable: share of revenue from products new to the market Sample: all SMEs present in the Community Innovation Survey (8.886) * Significant at 10% level, ** Significant at 5% level, ***Significant at 1% level To conclude this section, in contrast with the national programs, European programs do not have significant impact on the innovativeness of Dutch SMEs. Both 72 for input and output indicators, no significant differences can be found between participating and not participating SMEs. One could say that European programs do not increase the innovativeness of Dutch SMEs, but one should not forget the possibility of reverse causality. It could be the case that less innovative SMEs tend to participate more in European programs compared to more innovative firms. A form of self-selection could be present. 5.3 – Conclusion To foster innovation and correct market failures for SMEs related to innovation the European Commission implements two programs which run from 2007-2013. The Competitiveness and Innovation Framework Program (CIP) is specifically targeting SMEs and mainly is trying to correct the market failure of the missing capital market for R&D projects. In addition, it promotes cooperation between companies and knowledge institutions across borders and provides information to decrease the degree of asymmetric information. With this program, the European Commission is reaching a large amount of SMEs (roughly 400.000). Besides CIP, SMEs can also participate in the 7th Framework Program of the European Commission which promotes mainly cooperation between companies, knowledge institutions and researchers across Europe and creates good framework conditions for individual researchers. Compared to CIP, FP7 is focusing more on research compared to innovation. Therefore, this program is for a large amount dominated by large companies and knowledge institutions. Within the cooperation program (a specific program within FP7), the participation rate of Dutch SMEs is slightly less than 15%. This is mainly caused by the fact that the administrative burden is high and the probability of success is low. Therefore, participating in FP7 is too much trouble for SMEs. As a result, the 7th Framework Program does not succeed in correcting the market failures concerned with innovation for most SMEs. However, the fact that Dutch SMEs do participate (1.606 SMEs for the period 20072010) is indicating that for those companies, FP7 does generate added value. Table 5.6 gives a good overview about the two European programs and which market failures they aim to correct. The darker the colour green, the more important the corresponding market failure is within the program. CIP is mainly focussing on the capital market failure. And because CIP is supporting companies in every stage of “their life” it is also supporting starting companies and companies that want to commercialize new products. Therefore, also the market failures of entry barriers and the missing product markets is reduced. In addition, international cooperation is promoted, by an European network of advisors. These provide information about current trends, cooperation opportunities and so on. As a result, the amount of 73 incomplete information among SMEs is reduced and cooperation is promoted. Cooperation lead to risk sharing, economies of scale and positive knowledge spillovers. Externalities can be internalized in this way, since negative externalities can be shared and positive externalities remain within the project. The lighter colours of the 7th Framework Program indicate that in most cases FP7 is not successful in correcting the market failures relevant for SMEs. This is mainly caused by the high administrative burden and the low probability of success for SMEs. However, the SMEs that do participate are stimulated to cooperate abroad. The same as with CIP, this will lead to risk sharing, economies of scale and positive knowledge spillovers. These companies are supported financially, which makes it less difficult to finance R&D projects. Table 5.6 – European instruments and corresponding market failures Market failure FP7 CIP IPR-protection Institutional framework Cooperation International cooperation Capital market Missing markets Externalities New product market Externalities Competition Market structure Entry barriers Incomplete information Consumer rationality 74 As the table shows, the European programs especially aim at correcting the market failures corresponding with international cooperation, incomplete information and the missing capital market. In chapter 4 we have seen, that the national programs also target these market failures. This can be an indication that these market failures are restraining private investments in R&D the most. In contrast, the market failures corresponding with cooperation with domestic parties, new product markets and bounded consumer rationality are not addressed by the European innovation instruments. The same holds for international property right protection, and market failures that have to do with the market structure. However, these market failures are addressed by other European legislation. European competition law is aiming to ensure fair competition that will promote allocative, productive efficiency but certainly also dynamic efficiency. In addition, competition law tries to prevent that other companies raise entry barriers against new, innovative competitors. For the case of international property rights protection, the European Union has set up guidelines for the member states to ensure international property rights of companies within the EU. The empirical part showed that Dutch SMEs participate significantly less in European innovation programs. This can be the result of the fact that FP7 is dominating the European “toolbox” and is characterized by a high administrative burden and a low probability of success. In addition, participating in European innovation programs has no significant effect on the innovativeness of these companies. The European programs therefore do not succeed in correcting the market failures present for the Dutch SMEs. Next, the policy mix of European and national measures will be assessed for the Dutch case. 75 6 – Analyzing the policy mix: The Dutch case As described in chapter 4 and 5, for the case of the Netherlands, both the national government and the European Union use policy measures that aim at stimulating private innovation to a socially desirable level 32. This does not have to be a problem when there exists sufficient interaction between both levels of government and the two government levels aim at correcting different market failures for different target groups. Then, the policy measures of the two government layers could be characterized as complementary and could lead to synergies between government policies which would increase its efficiency (Alesina, Angeloni and Etro, 2005). Market failures present for SMEs will be better tackled in this way, which will most likely lead to an increase in the innovativeness of smaller private companies. However, also the possibility arises that both governments levels focus on correcting the same market failures for similar groups of companies. In this case, the policy measures become substitutes of each other and create no added value with respect to each other. In the worst case, policy measures may even be conflicting with each other. In this chapter, the complementary elements, the substitutable elements and the missing elements and the weaknesses of the policy mix for the Netherlands will be analyzed according to the theoretical framework in chapter 3. This will be substantiated with an empirical analysis in paragraph 6.4. 6.1 – Complementary elements When elements of national and European instruments are complementary, the respective elements strengthen each other. When the relative costs of one program decreases, not only participation in that program increases, but also within the complementary program. This could enhance the possibilities of Dutch SMEs to participate in R&D projects. As a result, companies become more innovative and competitive. The complementary elements of the Dutch and European instruments will be discussed below. In the first place, the national and European programs complement each other in the field of cooperation. The national programs are mainly focusing on cooperation between domestic parties (IPCs, vouchers, Syntens and the innovation programs) while the European programs are stimulating international cooperation between parties (FP7 and CIP). Cooperation between companies, knowledge institutions and researchers is important. Positive knowledge spillovers can arise, even as the 32 The same holds of course also for other member states 76 possibility of risk sharing and achieving economies of scale. Logically, national government are not that willing to stimulate international projects, since part of the gains from these projects spill over to other countries. However, international cooperation between different actors within the innovation system is becoming more and more important. The economy is becoming more and more globalized and knowledge is not bounded by borders. In addition, emerging markets also become more and more innovative and therefore competitive. Consequently, it is important that parties in Europe join forces and bundle their strengths to remain competitive to their foreign counterparts. So national and European focus on a different field of cooperation and are in that way complementary. When the relative costs of participating in national cooperation program decrease, participation in these programs will increase. However, also participation in international cooperation programs may increase. Some companies are reluctant to cooperate with other companies and when they get acquainted with cooperating by participating in national programs, they are also more likely to participate in international programs. In addition, by participating in either of the programs, SMEs get familiar with the regulation and administration that corresponds with the programs. Participating in the complementary program than gets more “easy” which decreases its relative costs. Also, by participating in national programs their network will increase and the chance that they get in touch with international companies increases. In this sense, the national innovation programs and the 7th Framework Program are complementary. But also the 7th Framework Program and the national program international innovation is complementary in the sense that FP7 is stimulating cooperation within the European Union and international innovation also promotes cooperation with countries outside the EU. Secondly, the 7th Framework Program creates good framework condition for European researchers. In addition, researchers are stimulated to involve in research that is also of value of companies and specifically SMEs. As a result, the quality and quantity of research increases which also has a positive effect for SMEs. Small and medium sized companies are in this way more inclined to cooperate with researchers and knowledge institutions. Consequently, the knowledge within SMEs will increase which will increase their innovativeness. So, when more researchers and knowledge institutions will participate in FP7 because of a decrease in relative costs, eventually also SMEs will benefit. Last, EG-Liason and Syntens are providing information for SMEs which want to participate in European program. Since EG-Liason and Syntens are national programs, these can be seen as complements of respectively the 7th framework program, CIP and the national programs. By informing SMEs about their possibilities to participate in national and/or European programs it wants to optimize their innovative capacities. When it gets more easy to participate in either Syntes and EG- 77 Liason, SMEs will be more inclined to participate in these programs. As a result, these companies will be more informed about the respective innovation programs that fit their preferences and needs. Consequently, participation in these programs will also increase. In addition, Syntens and EG-Liason also complement each other because they are related to each other in the sense that they can redirect companies to each other. When participation in Syntens increases, as a result of lower relative costs, then it is also more likely that Syntens will redirect more companies to EGLiason. Together, the complementary parts of the national and the European innovation policy should strengthen each other and enlarge the possibilities of Dutch SMEs. 6.2 – Substitutable elements Off course, beside complements, instruments also can be substitutes from each other. When national and European programs target the same group of companies and use the same measures companies can substitute one program for the other. When the relative costs of one program are increasing, companies will substitute this program for another program. Also, there is no use in participating in both programs. This is roughly the case for Eurostars, the program international innovation and the 7th Framework Program. Both programs aim at stimulating international cooperation between companies. However, Eurostars specifically targets SMEs and the 7th framework program is also accessible for larger companies. So, in this sense, the programs are not a substitute for each other. SMEs that want to participate with other SMEs across borders can participate in Eurostars and SMEs that also want to participate with larger companies and knowledge institutions abroad can join FP7. Theoretically, the programs would be complements from each other. Sadly, in practice this turns out not to be the case. FP7 is not accessible for SMEs because of the high administrative burden and low probability of success. For many SMEs therefore it is not attractive to participate in this program. The practice shows that SMEs substitute participation in FP7 for participation in Eurostars or in the program international innovation. These are national instruments that are more accessible for SMEs and more or less reach the same goal, promoting international cooperation. The fact that the relative costs of participating in FP7 are high (high administrative burden and low probability of success) results in the possibility that SMEs substitute this program for a program like Eurostars. It must be noted that there are Dutch SMEs that participate in FP7 successfully, but evaluations show that Eurostars is received to be more successful and more easily accessible for SMEs across Europe. 78 Other instruments that can be seen as substitutes from each other are the credit for innovation (national instrument) and the financial instruments of CIP. When it becomes less attractive to participate in for example the credit for innovation (the credit decreases), companies will be more inclined to participate in financial instruments of CIP. Both instruments aim at correcting the capital market failure in providing capital for risky R&D projects. So, when a Dutch SMEs is in difficulty in finding sufficient capital for its research and development, it can choose between a national program and an European program. It would be better, when there was just one program that would provide capital for risky R&D projects of SMEs. Than, economies of scale could be reach and it would be more clear for companies. Now, so many programs exists to boost innovation (national and European) that it is sometimes hard for companies to keep it clear which program targets which problem. 6.3 – Missing elements One missing element of the policy mix for the Dutch case can be mentioned. The first conflicting element is that both the national policy instruments and the European policy instrument pay little attention to the market failure of the introduction of new products to the market. Often, a product market for new, innovative products is missing and consumers in the first place are reluctant to buy these products (bounded consumer rationality). Therefore, the costs of introducing a new product and get the market acquainted with the products are high. Products have to be finetuned to consumer’s needs and a marketing strategy has to be executed. Practice shows that in some cases the costs of this process are often even higher of the costs of the research and development process. Chapter 4 and 5 show that the Dutch and European innovation instruments are especially focussing on lowering the costs of research and development and less on the costs of commercializing of innovation. Off course, it is important that innovations are commercialized. Otherwise, the benefits of these innovations cannot be reaped and do not contribute to the economic success of the company. More simple, when an innovation cannot be commercialized, the innovation failed and the respective investment has to be depreciated. Therefore, more attention is needed in the future for this part of the innovation process. 6.4 – Empirical analysis The empirical parts of the chapters four and five have showed that Dutch SMEs tend to participate more in national programs compared to European programs. In addition, national programs tend to have a positive effect on a SME’s innovativeness, while for European programs no significant impact could be found. But this chapter 79 tries to answer a different question. Does the interaction between both programs create added value? Is it beneficial for Dutch SMEs to participate in both national and European programs? Apparently it does, since some fraction of the Dutch SMEs participate in both programs, although a small fraction (1,3% of total SMEs represented in the CIS dataset). For these SMEs participation in both programs is beneficial, since otherwise they simply would not do so. But do there exist differences with large companies in this sense? To examine this possible difference, again, a probit regression model is used. This because of the fact the respective dependent variable is a dummy variable which takes the value of 1 when a company is participating in both programs. As independent variables, of course variables which indicate whether or not a company is characterized as a SME are included. In addition, control variables are included to control for other company specific aspects which also can have its impact on participation in government programs. Table 6.1 – Differences between SMEs and large companies in participation in both government programs (1) (2) (3) (4) Constant -1,276*** SME Small sized company Medium sized company -0,447*** -1,276*** -1,773*** -1,770*** -0,360*** -0,512*** -0,401*** -0,384*** -0,345*** Control variables Manufacturing -0,120 -0,120 International activities -0,204** -0,203** Cooperation -0,516*** -0,512*** R&D intensity -0,002** -0,002** Dependent variable: Participation in national government programs (dummy) Sample: all companies present in the Community Innovation Survey (9.947) * Significant at 10% level, ** Significant at 5% level, ***Significant at 1% level Table 6.1 shows that compared to large companies, Dutch SMEs tend to participate significantly less in both government programs. Within the group of SMEs also differences in participation can be found. Compared to medium sized companies, small companies tend to participate even less in both government programs. Again, this could be the result of the high administrative burden and low probability of success of FP7 that dominates the European toolbox in the field of innovation policy. In contrast, companies with international activities, companies that cooperate with other parties and companies that have a high R&D intensity tend to participate significantly more in both government programs. But in this case, this could be the result of reverse causality since both government programs have the goal to 80 increase (international) cooperation between companies and its innovation investments. But since it concerns control variables in this case, no further investigation is necessary. Table 6.2 – Differences in R&D intensity between SMEs that do participate both government programs and SMEs that do not participate in both programs (1) (2) Constant 4,355*** 6,121*** Both national and European government support -6,623** Control variables: National government -6,879*** support European government -1,252 support Manufacturing International activities Cooperation Company is part of concern Small sized company Dependent variable: R&D intensity -6,442** -7,719*** -1,725 -6,013*** -1,870 -3,504*** -3,768*** -0,895 Sample: all SMEs present in the Community Innovation Survey (8.886) * Significant at 10% level, ** Significant at 5% level, ***Significant at 1% level Now it appears that Dutch SMEs tend to participate less in both national and European government programs compared to large companies, it is interesting to look at the effect of participation in both programs on the innovativeness of Dutch SMEs. The same as in chapter 4 and 5, two innovation indicators are used to measure a company’s innovativeness. One input indicator (R&D intensity) and one output indicator (share of revenue from products new to the market). Simple linear regression is used with the innovation indicators as dependent variables. As independent variables, the dummy variables of participation in government programs are included and other control variables. To be able to only capture the effect of this participation for SMEs, a subsample is used which excludes all large companies from the sample. 8.886 Dutch SMEs are left within the subsample, 1.061 large companies are excluded. The results are shown in table 6.2 and 6.3. 81 It is good to see that Dutch SMEs that participate in both government programs tend to have a significant higher R&D intensity compared to SMEs that do not participate in any government program. However, compared to companies that only participate in national government programs, SMEs that participate in both government programs have a lower R&D intensity. So, in terms of R&D intensity, no added value is created by participating in an European program when a company is already participating in a national program. The other way around this is the case. When a company is participating in an European program, no significant increase in R&D intensity is to be expected, but when this company decides also to join national programs, R&D intensity is expected to rise. But this cannot be the result of complementary since then, the R&D intensity of companies that participate in both programs should be higher than the R&D intensity of companies that only participate in national programs. The added value of national programs over European programs is only generated because of the fact that European programs do not have a significant impact on a company’s innovativeness. In addition, also the variables “cooperation” and “company is part of concern” have a significant effect on a company’s R&D intensity. The same as in chapter 4 and 5, also the impact of government programs on an output indicator is examined. Table 6.3 shows the results of this analysis. Also this table shows that companies that participate in both government programs are more innovative than companies that do not participate in any government program. However, when controlling for other company specific factors, like is done in model (2), this difference is not significant. So, companies that do participate in both government program do not introduce significantly more new products to the market than companies that do not participate in any government programs. In contrast, participating in only national programs does lead to significantly more introduced products. So, in terms of new introduced product as output indicator, participating in the European program when you are already participating in the national programs has no added value. Companies tend to not increase the introduction of new products. In contrast, the table shows a reverse effect, relatively less new products are introduced when participating in both programs. However, the table shows that companies better participate in both programs than participating only in the European program, than the introduction rate of new products is even lower than the rate of companies that do not participate in any program at all. 82 Table 6.3 – Differences in new product introduction between SMEs that do participate in both government programs and SMEs that do not participate in both programs (1) (2) Constant -4,355*** -3,425*** Both national and European government support -2,625* -2,026 Control variables: National government -5,122*** -4,829*** support European government -0,711 -0,862 support Manufacturing -1,651*** International activities -1,886*** Cooperation -2,038*** Company is part of concern -0,078 Small sized company -1,326** Dependent variable: share of revenue from products new to the market Sample: all SMEs present in the Community Innovation Survey (8.886) * Significant at 10% level, ** Significant at 5% level, ***Significant at 1% level To conclude, Dutch SMEs participate significantly less in both programs compared to larger companies. This is mainly caused by the fact that European programs are not very accessible for SMEs because of the high administrative burden and low probability of success. However, table 6.2 and 6.3 shows that participating in both programs does not create added value for Dutch SMEs. When added value would be generated, the innovativeness of SMEs that would participate in both programs would be higher than the innovativeness of SMEs that participate in only one program or none programs. However, the innovativeness (both in terms of input and output indicators) of SMEs that only participate in national programs is higher than the innovativeness of SMEs that participate in both programs. This is an indication that the Dutch and European innovation programs are not entirely complementary. When this would be the case, synergies would arise and added value was generated. However, the tables indicate otherwise. This is especially due to the low impact of participating in the European programs on the innovativeness of the Dutch SMEs. 83 6.5 – Conclusion This chapter showed that the policy mix for the Dutch case shows some complementary elements, some substitutable elements and some an important missing element. European programs are complementary to Dutch programs in the field of promoting cooperation. European programs focus on international cooperation and the Dutch programs focus mainly on national cooperation. Also Syntens and EG-Liason are complementary. These complementary elements should enlarge the innovativeness of companies that participate both in the Dutch programs and in the European programs. But, also substitutable and missing elements of the policy mix are present. FP7 has high administrative burden and a low probability of success for Dutch SMEs and therefore has little impact on the innovativeness of Dutch SMEs. Therefore, Dutch SMEs in practice often choose to participate in other national programs (like Eurostars). So, FP7 is substitutable for national programs. Also the financial instruments of the national and European innovation policy are to some extent substitutable. Concerning the missing element, both the national and European policy pay little attention to the market failure of the missing product market. The empirical analyses in paragraph 6.4 show some interesting findings. In the first place, Dutch SMEs participate significantly less in both programs compared to large company. And in the second place, when SMEs do participate in both programs, the innovativeness of these SMEs is smaller than the innovativeness of companies that only participate in the Dutch programs. No added value over the national programs is generated by participating in the European programs too. In this sense, the programs cannot be seen as complements. Next, policy recommendations for respectively the Dutch government and the European will be presented. 84 7 – Policy recommendations In the previous chapters, the Dutch and European instruments that aims at promoting R&D investments of Dutch SMEs are discussed. Additionally, the complementarity of these instruments has been assessed. This assessment showed some serious weaknesses in the policy mix for the Dutch case. Three major flaws are present, which should be improved in the future to promote the innovativeness of the Dutch SMEs. First, neither the national nor the European policy instruments pay attention to the market failure of the missing product market for new introduced products. In the first place, SMEs (and also other companies) innovate to become more profitably and to be able to reap the benefits of innovating, products have to be commercialized. The assessment of the Dutch and European instruments showed that especially costs associated with research and development are lowered by participation in government programs. However, the costs associated with commercialization of products can also be a great barrier to participate in innovation activities. Therefore, new financial instruments should be introduced to lower the costs of commercializing products, or existing financial instruments would have to be adjusted in a way that also the costs of commercializing products is lowered. This would preferably be arranged on the national level, so that each government can design the respective instruments towards its own preferences. Second, in the future the European Union should focus more on generic measures and should entrust the specific policy measures to the individual member states. The 7th Framework Program therefore should not focus on specific sectors but should promote international cooperation of companies for all sectors. Specific national programs that target “strong” sectors within an economy, should also allow international cooperation with foreign “strong” sectors. Specific policy instruments that target specific sectors should be entrusted to national governments so that they can design the policy measures towards the preferences of the respective economy. The European Union should focus on generic measures that improve the institutional structure and the framework conditions that ease innovation. Examples are, legislation that secure property rights and promote completion, improving the functioning of the single European market (for example labour mobility of researchers) etc. Also, generic instruments that have a clear international character or instruments that may benefit from economies of scale can be arranged on European level. One could think of measures that promote cooperation within 85 European borders and financial instruments that benefit from the large European capital market. Third, while currently especially the 7th Framework Program can be characterized as too specific for the European level, another problem arises with respect to this program. The administrative burden is way too high for SMEs which is causing that the program currently is dominated by large companies and knowledge institutions. In the future, the European program should improve its accessibility for SMEs by decreasing the administrative burden. Making the program more generic like suggested above should already help, since less strict requirements would be necessary to participate in the program. This is particularly important to reach SMEs and increase their innovativeness as well. 86 8 – Conclusion Innovations of companies nowadays more and more determine economic growth in western economies. However, market failures are present that hinder companies from participating in innovative activities. A special group of companies in this context are SMEs. Small and medium sized companies are responsible for roughly 60% of European employment and therefore play a crucial role in the development of economic growth. But empirical analysis shows that compared to large companies (with more than 250 employees) SMEs participate significantly less in R&D activities. For SMEs, different types of market failures are present that restrain innovations. Government intervention could (partly) correct these market failures which would lead to more innovation activities of SMEs, and consequently more economic growth and an increase in welfare. However, this is only the case when the benefits of government intervention are larger than the costs of intervention. This thesis focuses on the Netherlands. For the Dutch case, policy is designed both on the national level and on the European level. Both government layers have designed generic policy instruments and specific policy instruments that aim at correcting market failures and therefore should promote R&D activities of SMEs. Empirical analysis shows that SMEs significantly participate more in the Dutch innovation programs compared to larger companies. This could be the result of the fact that the Dutch innovation policy consists largely of generic measures. Empirical results indicate that participation in national programs significantly increases the innovativeness of Dutch SMEs. Companies that participate in national innovation programs have a higher R&D intensity and introduce relatively many new products to the market. However, important to note is that this also could be the result of selfselection and further research is necessary. Also, further research is necessary by including more control variables and by replacing the dummy variables for participation in government programs by absolute values. Regarding European policy measures empirical analysis shows that Dutch SMEs participate significantly less in European programs compared to its larger counterpart. This effect is caused by the high administrative burden for companies that participate in European programs and the low probability of success. Participating therefore can be too costly for SMEs. In contrast with the national 87 programs, small and medium sized companies that do participate in European programs are not more innovative than companies that do not participate in such programs. This result is remarkable since more and more people suggest that innovation policy should be designed on European level instead. However, empirical analysis shows that this may be not a good idea. When looking at the policy mix of national and European measures some important things can be noticed. Some market failures are not addressed by the policy measures. The market failure of missing product markets for new products is not tackled by policy measures. Also substitutable elements are present within the policy mix which is not desirable. European innovation policy in the future should become more generic and easy accessible for companies. It should create decent framework conditions and a good business environment. Hereafter, national governments should have the opportunity to design its policy towards the specific preferences of its companies. Currently, the European innovation policy is too specific and is in some sense conflicting with national instruments because some programs can be classified as substitutes from one another. In addition, because of the fact that policy is designed for 27 member states, European policy measures can not be in line with preferences of all the respective member states. This is endorsed by the theory of Alesina et al. and is confirmed by the empirical analysis. The empirical analysis showed that national policy measures create more added value for SMEs compared to European measures. National policy instruments are more in line with preferences of Dutch SMEs. Even SMEs that participate both in European and national programs are less innovative than SMEs that only participate in national programs. This brings me to the following policy recommendation. European policy instruments in the future should become more generic and should focus on creating decent framework conditions for innovative SMEs. Nowadays, European measures are too specific and have a high administrative burden. Specific policy measures should be designed on a national level. This is in contrast with the opinion of many people nowadays who want to design innovation policy more and more on an European level. Also, it is important that the market failure of missing product markets for new introduced products is addressed. Economic success depends on successful commercialization of innovations. 88 References Aghion, P., Howitt, P., Brant-Collett, M., García-Peñalosa, C. (1998). ‘The endogenous growth theory.’ Massachusetts Institute of Technology Aghion, P., Bloom, N., Blundell, R., Griffith, R., Howitt, P. (2005). ‘Competition and innovation: an inverted-U relationship.’ The Quarterly Journal of Economics, May 2005 Arrow, K.J. (1962). ‘Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for invention.’ Pages 609-625 from the book ‘The rate and direction of inventive activity: economic and social factors.’ Princeton University Press Alesina, A., Angeloni, I., Etro, F. (2005). ‘International unions.’ The American Economic Review, Vol. 95, No. 3, June 2005 Audretsch, D.B., Feldman, M.P. (2003). ‘Knowledge spillovers and the geography of innovation.’ Prepared for the handbook of Urban and Regional Economics, Vol. 4 Baker, J.B. (2007). ‘Beyond Schumpeter vs. Arrow: How antitrust fosters innovation.’ June 2007 Barber, J. (2009). ‘Setting the scene.’ Six countries Programme, New Economic Ground for Innovation Policy, 14-09-2009 Berner, R., Gilsing, V.A. and Roelandt, T.J.A. (2001). ‘Grondslagen voor vernieuwing van het innovatiebeleid.’ Pages 73-84 from the book ‘Nederland kennisland? Kennis en innovatie: uitdagingen voor het economisch beleid.’ by Gradus, R.H.M.J., Kremers, J.J.M. and Van Sinderen, J. Boschma, R.A., Frenken, K. and Lambooy, J.G. (2002). ‘Evolutionaire economie. Een inleiding.’ 89 Brouwer, E., Poot, T., van Montfoort, K. (2008). ‘The innovation threshold.’ Economist, Vol. 156, No. 1, March 2008 De Carpenter, R.E., Petersen, B.C. (2002). ‘Capital markets imperfections, high-tech investment, and new equity financing.’ Economic Journal CBS Statline (2010). ‘Overview of Dutch enterprises according to size and sector as of 01-01-2 9.’ Last update: 12-01-2010, downloaded on 11-05-2010 Cohen, W.M., Goto, A., Nagata, A., Nelson, R.R., Walsh, J.P. (2002). ‘R D spillovers, patents and the incentives to innovate in Japan and the United States.’ Research Policy 31 (2002) 1349–1367 Centraal Plan Bureau (2002). ‘De pijlers onder de kenniseconomie. Opties voor institutionele vernieuwing. The Hague Czarnitzki, D. and Toole, A.A. (2009). ‘R D investment under uncertainty: the role of R D subsidies and patent policy.’ Pages 193-214 from the book ‘The new economics of technology policy.’ by Foray, D. Dijk, J.W.A. van and Hulst, N. van (1988), ‘Grondslagen van technologiebeleid.’ Economisch Statistische Berichten, 73(3674) European Commission (2005). ‘The new SME definition: user guide and model explanation.’ Enterprise and Industry publications European Commission (2010). ‘Europe 2 2 : A European strategy for smart, sustainable and inclusive growth.’ Brussels, 03-03-2010 European Commission (2010). ‘The 7th framework program (FP7).’ 18-06-2010 European Commission (2010). ‘The competitiveness and innovation framework program (CIP): Increasing competitiveness through innovation.’ European Communities (2002). ‘Innovation tomorrow.’ Innovation papers no. 28, DG Enterprise, EUR 17052 90 Forecast key figures SMEs (2009). ‘Employment as of downloaded on 11-05-2010 -01-2 9.’ 09-12-2009, Garrett, G. (1992). ‘International cooperation and institutional choice: the European Community’s internal market.’ International Organization 46, Spring 1992 Gibcus, P., de Jong, J.P.J. (2008). ‘Innovatiepiramide: een segmentatie van het MKB.’ EIM, October 2008 Gilbert, R.J. (2006). ‘Competition and innovation.’ Journal of Industrial Organization Education Harris, R. and Robinson, C. (2001). ‘A critical review of empirical research on hindrances to business development and productivity growth and the relative importance of different constraints on UK business.’ Research project on DTI industrial support policies, Final report Kline, S.J. and Rosenberg, C. (1986). ‘An overview of innovation.’ Pages 275-306 from the book ‘The positive sum strategy. Harnessing technology for economic growth.’ by Landau, R. and Rosenberg, N., National Academy Press Martin, S., Scott, J.T. (2000). ‘The nature of innovation market failure and the design of public support for private innovation.’ Research Policy 29 (2000) 437-447 Maskus, K.E. (2000). ‘Intellectual property rights in the global economy.’ Institute for International Economics Ministry of Economic Affairs (2006). ‘Investing in innovation programs (Investeren in innovatieprogramma’s).’ Ministry of Economic Affairs (2010). ‘Positioning: the SME innovation pyramid (Positionering: de MKB innovatiepiramide).’ 11-05-2010 Nooteboom, B. (1994). ‘Innovation and Diffusion in Small. Firms: Theory and Evidence.’ Small Business Economics 6: 327-347, 1994 91 Nooteboom, B. and Stam, E. (2008). ‘Micro-foundations for innovation policy.’ Amsterdam University Press Ogawa, H., Waldasin, E.G. (2007). ‘Think locally, act locally: Spillovers, spillbacks, and efficient decentralized policymaking.’ American Economic Review Ogus, A. (2004). ‘W(h)ither the economic theory of regulation? What economic theory of regulation? Chapter 2 from the book ‘The politics of regulation: Institutions and regulatory reforms for the age of governance’ by Jordana, J. and Levi-Faur, D. Peeperkorn, L. and Verouden, V. (2007). ‘The economics of competition.’ Chapter 1 from the book ‘EC Law and Competition’ by Faull, J. and Nikpay, A., 29-032007 Rodriguez-Pose, A., Crescenzi, R. (2006). ‘R D, spillovers, innovation systems and the Genesis of regional growth in Europe.’ Bruges European Economic Research Papers, No. 5, October 2006 Sánchez Gonzáles, G., Herrera, L. (2008). ‘Cooperation for innovation: the impact on innovatory effort.’ Fundacion de las Cajas de Ahorros, Documento de Trabajo, No. 409/2008 Schumpeter, J.A. (1942). ‘Capitalism, socialism and democracy.’ SenterNovem (2006). ‘SMEs definition based on EG-ordinances 70/2001 and 364/2004 as on January 6, 2006 (MKB-definitie gebaseerd op EG-verordeningen 7 /2 en 364/2 4 zoals deze op 6 januari 2 6 gelden).’ Six Fingers (2009). ‘A view to innovation: a fresh look on innovation in the Netherlands (Het oog op innovatie: een frisse blik op innovatie in Nederland).’ DBMI Market Research and Innovation Solow, R.M. (1956). ‘A contribution to the theory of economic growth.’ The Quarterly Journal of Economics 92 Timmer, M., O’Mahony, M., van Ark, B. (2007). ‘EU KLEMS Growth and productivity accounts: an overview.’ March, 2007 Veugelers, R., Cassiman, B. (2005). ‘R D cooperation between firms and universities. Some empirical evidence from Belgian manufacturing.’ International Journal of Industrial Organization, Vol. 23 (2005) 355-379 Workgroup Innovation and Applied Research (2010). ‘Review report: Dutch policy regarding innovation and applied research.’ April 2010 Yang, G., Maskus, K.E. (2001). ‘Intellectual property rights, licensing, and innovation in an endogenous product-cycle model.’ Jounal of International Economics 53 (2001) 169-187 93 Appendix A1 – Explanation of CIS Dataset Community Innovation Survey dataset 9947 companies 8886 SMEs 2972 innovative companies Table A.1 - Explanation of variables incorporated in this thesis 33 Variable SME Type Dummy Small sized company Dummy Medium sized company Dummy Manufacturing Dummy International activities Dummy Cooperation Dummy Company is part of concern Turnover National government support Dummy European government support Dummy Both national and European government support Dummy Continuous Dummy Explanation 1 = ‘Company has between 10-25033 employees’ 0 = ‘Otherwise’ 1 = ‘Company has between 10-50 employees’ 0 = ‘Otherwise’ 1 = ‘Company has between 50-250 employees’ 0 = ‘Otherwise’ 1 = ‘Company is active within the sector manufacturing’ 0 = ‘Otherwise’ 1 = ‘Company is participating in international activities’ 0 = ‘Otherwise’ 1 = ‘Company is cooperating with other parties to innovate’ 0 = ‘Otherwise’ 1 = ‘Company is part of a concern’ 0 = ‘Otherwise’ The company’s turnover in 2006 1 = ‘Company is participating in national innovation programs and receives financial support’ 0 = ‘Otherwise’ 1 = ‘Company is participating in European innovation programs and receives financial support’ 0 = ‘Otherwise’ 1 = ‘Company is participating in both national and European innovation programs and receives financial support’ 0 = ‘Otherwise’ Micro sized companies (companies with 1-10 employees) are not incorporated in the Community Innovation Survey, since response from these companies is often very low. 94 Participation in Syntens Dummy R&D intensity Continuous Share of revenue from products new to the market Continuous 1 = ‘Company is receiving information w.r.t. innovative activities from the government’ 0 = ‘Otherwise’ (Input) innovation indicator Total R&D manyears / Total employees (Output) innovation indicator Percentage of total revenue that is the result of new introduced products to the market 95