ReflecT Research Paper 13/002 Exposure to Single and Multiple Risks of Youngsters in their Early Career in Britain: Continuous or Cumulative Disadvantage? © Ruud Muffels, March 2013 ReflecT PO Box 90153 5000 LE Tilburg, The Netherlands Phone: (00 31) (0)13 466 21 81 E-mail: reflect@tilburguniversity.edu, Website: http://www.tilburguniversity.edu/research/institutes-and-researchgroups/reflect/ Exposure to Single and Multiple Risks of Youngsters in their Early Career in Britain: Continuous or Cumulative Disadvantage? ABSTRACT A plethora of studies raised concerns about the rising inequality on the labour market since the mid 1980s and especially also during the current crisis. In this paper we examine how low-skilled young men and women of 16 to 35 years of age fare with respect to their income and employment security over their career using panel data for Britain covering the early 1990s to the late 2000s. The main question is whether low-skilled youngsters are able to recover from their lower entry-level of security or that their disadvantage accelerates due to being exposed to adverse events and statuses over the career? A brief review of globalization, insideroutsider, tournament and stratification theories renders some support to the idea of cumulative disadvantage. The novelty of the approach is in studying the longerterm or career effects of exposure to single and multiple life course risks. The single risk results confirm the literature that low-skilled youngsters face continuous disadvantage instead of cumulative disadvantage implying that they recover but that the gap with the high skilled is never closed. The multiple risk models however reveal a mixed picture of cumulative disadvantage with respect to employment security and continuous disadvantage with respect to income security. Keywords: cumulative disadvantage, employment security, income security, youth, unemployment, single risks, multiple risks, discrete choice models JEL Classification: J24, J28, J41, J42 1 1. Introduction A plethora of studies raised concerns about the rising inequality on the labour market since the mid 1980s and especially also during the current crisis. Globalization, insider-outsider, tournament and stratification theories suggest that particularly low-skilled youngsters face high risks on income and employment insecurity in their early career and that these risks might aggravate. Youngsters carry high risks on unemployment in the downturn and working in a low-paid insecure job in the upturn when employment rises. The main question addressed therefore pertains to how the low-skilled youngsters fare over their career using data over nearly two decades covering downturns as well as upturn periods. Are they able to recover from their initial lower income and employment security level or does their disadvantage accelerates due to being exposed to multiple adverse events and statuses over the career? The study views the career or employment trajectories of low-skilled young men and women of 16 to 35 years of age using the British Household Panel Study data covering the early 1990s to 2008-2009. A brief review of the literature learns that particularly in Europe the focus has mainly been on researching single disadvantage at group-level based on data derived from repeated cross-sections. Most studies view the short-term effects only yielding no evidence on the longer-term or career effects of multiple or cumulative disadvantage. For that reason we add to the literature in three ways. First, because we examine individual growth paths or income and employment trajectories of lowskilled youngsters based on prospective data instead of using aggregated data at group level derived from repeated cross-sectional evidence as in most studies (e.g. Berthoud 2003). Second, because we distinguish single risk and multiple risk transition state models, where the latter views the effects of the combination or accumulation of events on security outcomes. By estimating fixed-effects panel regression models we correct for unobserved (time constant) heterogeneity associated with individual differences in personality traits, motivation and effort. Third, because we focus not only on the impact of single and multiple events but also on disadvantaged statuses (e.g. unemployment or disability) following the event (job loss and health shock) implying that the occurrence and length of stay in these statuses codetermine also the effects on career-long income and employment security. In this way we obtain a better insight into the additive or 2 cumulative nature of inequality and disadvantage in Britain with respect to lowskill. The relevance of the issue for policy is clear with a view to concerns voiced especially in recessions about a lost generation of youngsters and the longer-term scarring effects on their careers. Labour markets differ in the way they adjusted to the current crises (see e.g. O’Reilly et al., 2011). The uncoordinated or liberal labour markets of the UK and the US responded through downward wage adjustment and job displacement whereas the dual labour market of the South responded through instantaneous lay-offs of unprotected workers in non-standard contracts. Youth unemployment rose therefore strongest in the Southern labour markets with a high level of insider-outsider dualism. However, also in the UK, notwithstanding its flexible labour market, youth unemployment rose unexpectedly rather strong in the current crisis. Insight in the longer-term scarring effects of single and multiple life course risks is therefore important to design successful intervention strategies. Outline In section 2 we briefly review the literature, define our conceptual model and formulate in the end some hypotheses. Then in section 3 we present some descriptive information on how low-skilled youngsters fared during the last two decades in Britain in terms of their level of income and employment security and the life course risks they faced. Do the low skilled indeed face higher single and multiple risks than the medium or higher skilled and is the position of youngsters better or worse compared to senior people? Then in section 4 we present the findings of our multivariate analyses showing to what extent low-skilled youngsters face cumulative disadvantage or not? In section 5 we end with conclusions and discussion. 2. Theory, empirical literature and hypotheses In the literature on inequality and the life course it is often argued that people gifted with favorable traits and endowments and better access to resources profit more from the fruits of economic growth and prosperity than the less gifted ones. This idea coined by Merton (1988) as cumulative advantage (CA) means that a 3 favorable relative current position produces positive gains later on in life. It implies that inequality tend to accumulate over time (DiPrete and Eirich, 2006). Likewise, cumulative disadvantage (CDA) implies that people with a less favorable position endure future losses due to being exposed to life course risks emerging from the occurrence of adverse events or entry into disadvantaged statuses causing shortage of resources and reduced earning capacities which tend to aggravate the initial disadvantage. The idea is also known as the Matthew effect or phrased in terms as the “rich get richer” and “the poor get poorer”. Life course risks such as unemployment, a low paid job, disability or poor health are therefore not equally spread among the population but are especially faced by people already more likely to have fewer resources and therefore belonging to the lower echelons of the life chance distribution (e.g. Dannefer, 2003). Notwithstanding the existence of a rich economic and sociological literature concerning the issue of rising income inequality since the mid 1980s, there is according to DiPrete and Eirich (2006) scarcity in studies about the causes and patterns of growth of advantage and disadvantage in a broader sense over time. Viewing the existing literature a variety of causal factors for the growth in inequality and disadvantage are distinguished from the literature. Many empirical studies in the economic and sociological literature found evidence that the growth in inequality is associated with the consequences of globalization such as the lower demand for low skilled workers due to skill biased technical change and rising shares of insecure jobs associated with flexibilisation trends and increased competition (see Blossfeld et al., 2003, 2006, 2009; Muffels, 2008; Muffels & Luijkx, 2008; Muffels & Wilthagen, 2012). In the welfare state (WS) literature the role of globalization is said to be paralleled with a shift in Welfare State policies from the 1990s on according to which governments aim at downsizing its intervening and supporting role in the economy and to withdraw from market interference implying a greater reliance on the market and therewith permitting rising inequality (Leibfried & Mau, 2008). In the economic literature the insideroutsider theory gained support (Lindbeck & Snower, 1988) arguing that labour market regulations and institutions raise the transaction costs associated with hiring and firing because of which there is lack of mobility resulting in widening wage gaps between insiders and outsiders (Nickell & Wadhwani, 1990). Likewise, it is argued mainly by economists working on income dynamics that the tendency of the market to invest in low-risk activities which were gainful in the past, might 4 also contribute to the process of rising inequalities (see Ryan, 2002). This phenomenon known as path dependency implies that past states and events impact on the future career. In the empirical economic literature there is abundant evidence that the duration of past unemployment has a negative effect on future re-employment chances, known as negative duration dependency although the evidence is mixed and supported for only very particular groups (Belzil, 1995; Steiner, 2001; Böheim and Taylor, 2000; Pries, 2004). Also in sociology there is mounting interest for the career effects of past events and statuses and whether a “bad start” has long-term consequences for the careers of youngsters on the labour market (e.g. Blossfeld et al., 2006, 2009). In another branch of the economic and sociological literature it is stated that particular adverse trigger events or transitions such as unemployment or a temporary job have a “scarring” effect on the future career from which it takes long to recover. Especially in the American literature starting with Ruhm’s work (1991) a rising number of empirical studies appeared, providing support to the evidence especially on the scarring effects of (long-term) unemployment. In Europe, since the end of the 1990s the number of studies on scarring by economists and sociologists increased strongly thanks to the improved availability of longitudinal data (Dickens et al., 1999; Booth et al., 2002; Scherer, 2004; Dekker, 2007; DiPrete 2006, Gangl, 2004, 2006; Muffels, 2008). The evidence showed that e.g. part-time employment has a scarring effect on future employment and wages though the evidence is mixed how strong the effect actually is, and how long it takes for people to recover from the initial shock (Gregory & Jukes, 2001; Gallie & Paugam, 2000; Manning & Petrongola, 2008; Bardasi & Gornick, 2008; Fouarge & Muffels, 2009). Fouarge and Muffels (2009) found weak evidence for scarring of part-time work in the Dutch and German context controlling for unobserved heterogeneity but strong evidence for Britain suggesting that social norms and public support for part-time work (especially in the Netherlands but increasingly so in Germany) reduces the occupational segregation of part-time jobs improving their quality and wage prospects. In another strand of the literature psychologists point to another explanation of cumulative disadvantage that is associated with the impact of hereditary or genetic factors (ability, talent, inherited wealth) causing existing inequalities in initial endowments to sustain and to be reproduced over time. In the social stratification literature the focus has been on the impact of social or parental background pointing to the influence of social class and social-cultural or social-economic 5 explanations for changing inequality trends (Goldthorpe, 2002, Blau & Duncan, 1969, Breen et al., 2009). It is this line of reasoning that we also adopt in this paper though the focus is not on explaining intergenerational inequality as in Blau and Duncan’s status attainment model (inequality between fathers and sons and mothers and daughters) but more so on intra-generational or life course inequality trends that is between men and women belonging to the same generation but over their entire career. Reference can also be made to the so-called status maintenance (Hungerford, 2007) and tournament models (Rosenbaum, 1979) focusing on the way status and mobility in the early career has enduring effects on the later career. In Rosenbaum’s tournament model in each round people compete on particular positions or available resources on the labour market but the winners of the competition gain advantage over the losers in the next round implying that initial advantage tend to accumulate over time. Conceptual model To arrive at a conceptual model we pay credit to an earlier study of Bielby & Bielby’s (1992). They made a distinction between three models: cumulative advantage, cumulative disadvantage and continuous disadvantage. The first two models are already explained before. The latter model refers to the idea that when analysing e.g. gender career differences these differences might persist over time but not in a cumulative way. In that case the gender gap in career success is not widened over time because women are equally exposed to particular life course risks as men without widening the gender gap. Bielby & Bielby (1992) find little evidence for cumulative disadvantage but more for continuous disadvantage; gender gaps appeared persistent and did not decline. In our case it would imply that low skilled workers are equally exposed to particular life course risks as the high skilled and therefore not more prone to disadvantage than they initially were. In the case of continuous disadvantage the main effects are negative but the interaction effects between skill and the occurrence of the adverse event insignificant. In the case the main effect is negative but the interaction effects positive, disadvantage is declining over time and when the interaction effects are negative disadvantage associated with the occurrence of adverse events tend to increase confirming the existence of cumulative disadvantage. A similar approach was adopted in Berthoud et al. (2003), though they used the cross-sectional data of the British Labour Force 6 Survey. They focused on the effects of multiple disadvantage on unemployment for Britain by viewing the main and interaction effects of six forms of disadvantage. Their findings suggest that the effects of multiple disadvantages on unemployment reveal an additive instead of an exponential pattern that would imply the risks of unemployment to be larger and larger as the number of disadvantages increases. The additive pattern confirms that each disadvantage adds to increasing the risk on unemployment but not in an accelerating manner. Our approach is similar in that we also examine the effects of multiple disadvantage on employment but different in that we focus on the effect of multiple disadvantage on changes in income and employment security over time. A further difference associated with the cross-sectional nature of the data is that they examine disadvantaged statuses only whereas we also include events. The causality in the model runs from preferences (work-leisure) and values (economic and social) together with resources (human capital) to people’s constrained and unconstrained choices on the labour market (events and statuses) and then to the outcomes, that is income and employment security. Preferences and constraints are added as controls together with education level (medium versus high skilled), age and age squared to account for the non-linearity in the relationship between age and income and employment security and the annual unemployment rate to control for the impact of the business cycle. 3. Data and measures The paper uses data of the British Household Panel Study for the years 1991-2008. The British panel was launched in 1991 with about 10,300 individuals in 5,500 households. All individuals are interviewed. Again, sample representativeness is maintained by including split-offs and their new households. The British panel has been augmented by booster samples for Scotland and Wales in 1991 and a new Northern Ireland sample in 2001. In 2008, the latest year used in the paper, the sample size was just over 14,000. The labour market, marital and demographic history of individuals is constructed from the retrospective information gathered in the second wave (1992), supplemented with labour market and demographic information from the panel waves. A major change occurred in 2010 when the 7 BHPS panel was merged into the new United Kingdom Household Longitudinal Study (‘Understanding Society”), which included a great many additional questions, especially in the health area. The new sample size is about 100,000. The sample used for this paper consists of youngsters from 16 years to 34 years. The total sample of these youngsters covering 18 waves of data was 51,950. The sample was not restricted to youngsters below 25 years of age because the length of the period to which youngsters are exposed to risks of job insecurity during the early career associated with the process of flexibilisation of the labour market seems to be extending affecting youngsters also of 25 years and older. 3.1. Measures Dependent variables and low skill We use a measure of household income security instead of wage income security to include non-wage income sources because one of the research questions concerned the role of policies in compensating people for the risks they face. We take household income since income risks faced by one member might be compensated by additional income earned by other members. Income security is therefore defined as the income-to-needs ratio, the ratio of annual after tax household income and a minimum household income threshold below which people are considered to live in relative poverty. We took the income threshold as defined by the OECD and used by the European Union which is set at 60% of the mean equivalent household income. The equivalence scale used to compare households is the so-called modified scale which equals 1 for the head, 0.7 for the partner and 0.3 for the children. For employment security we use a rather straightforward continuous measure being defined as the number of weeks people are employed in any given year ranging from one to fifty-two. Low skill is defined according to three measures: low education derived from the international education level classification called ISCED, low socio-economic status derived from the international classification scheme called ISEI and low occupational class derived from the international EGP scheme (Erikson & Goldthorpe, 2002). The results turned out to be very similar across the three measures for which reason we only report on the ISCED measure of low skill. 8 Life course risks Life course risks are defined as adverse events and statuses: events are unemployment, a health drop of 2 points or more on the health satisfaction scale ranging from one to 7, job displacement or being laid off last year from the employer due to being dismissed or declared redundant, becoming disabled (‘health limits type or amount of work’), early retirement, divorce or separation from marriage and the birth of another child. Disadvantaged statuses are being long-term unemployed, having a bad health or being disabled (health limitations for work), retired, lacking employer related training, being underworked, occupying a temporary job and being a lone parent or single. A bad hours match is defined in the BHPS as that people are unable to work the hours they wish, that is that they worked more (overworked) or less than they prefer (underworked). We expect a negative association with employment and income security only for being underworked because we suspect that people who work longer hours have a stronger position on the labour market and therefore being more employment secure. People working more hours than they wish work possibly longer hours and therefore will earn more income because of which they are more income secure. Controls Controls are added to control for the non-linear effects of age on income and employment security and for the differences in education level and job tenure. Because low skill is one of our variables of interest we included a dummy for medium skill with high skill as reference group. The three levels are based on the ISCED scores with ISCED levels 1 and 2a for the low skilled, 2b and 2c for intermediate level and 3a,4,5 for the high skilled. We also included controls for differences in preferences and values or life goals between people. In the BHPS a number of questions were asked on the importance of certain aspects in life such as success in a job, what people can afford, living an independent life, importance of having children, a partner, friends, a good health, and owning a house. Based on principal components analysis we constructed two variables measuring the economic dimension (‘success in job’, to afford things and ‘living an independent life’), and the social dimension (‘’importance of partner’, importance of children’ and ‘importance of friends’). We did not weigh the factors with the factor loadings 9 but just took the aggregated scores on the variables belonging to the two dimensions. 4. The empirical model The idea of cumulative disadvantage requires knowledge about the pattern of change or the functional or mathematical form of the relationship between disadvantage and outcome over time. Disadvantage might refer to current disadvantage or past disadvantage and might impact on the current outcome level as well on its growth, resulting hence in many alternative functional specifications. In their review of the cumulative advantage literature, Diprete and Eirich (2006) distinguish various specifications such as path-dependent cumulative disadvantage in which the current outcome is dependent on previous outcomes, cumulative exposure in which the growth in outcome is dependent on the continuous exposure to a particular status and the status-resource interaction model in which current or past status affects through its impact on current resources the current outcome level but not its growth. In sociology, life course oriented studies viewed the impact of particular life events such as divorce, job loss or disability on future outcomes. Within a life cycle or life course framework life events are critical for understanding the ongoing diversification of life courses in Western societies. In the life course framework not only the occurrence and frequency of events matter but also their timing, duration and sequence. Since the focus is on cumulative disadvantage we view the long-term impact of the combination of life course risks on peoples’ career outcome. Since most people are exposed to one to three lifecourse risks and few people to more than three risks during the observation period many combinations tend to have very few observations. For that reason we did not examine the impact of all possible combinations but viewed the impact of exposure to a variety of single risks (single risk model) as well as to the combination or sum of risks over the observation period (combination or multiple risk model). The specification of the model The formal (empirical) model according to this framework results in the formulation of a single risk (1) and combination or multiple risk model (2): 10 Yit 0 1 zit 2 zit2 1 X it 2Cit 1sit Eit 2 sit Sit i it , E S e 1 s 1 Yit 0 1 zit z 1 X it 2Cit 1sit Eit 2 sit Sit i it , 2 2 it (1) (2) where Yit represents the outcome variable being either income security or employment security and where the two zit terms are derived from the Mincerian human capital framework (Mincer, 1974). They measure the time varying human capital variables such as age and age squared. The quadratic term makes the equation non-linear with respect to zit. The vector X it contains the other time varying human capital variables such as tenure, skill level, occupational class and social class and the Cit vector the controls (age, age squared, gender, household size, number of children, unemployment rate). The sit measures our skill status variable which is interacted with each single event Eit and status Sit (single risk model) but also with the sum of all life course events Eit and life course statuses Sit (multiple risk model) to account for accelerating or cumulative effects over time, where E and S point to the total number of events and statuses. The model can be estimated as a fixed effects panel regression model in which the i represents the unobserved heterogeneity part and finally it the disturbance term. The specification is a modified version of the status-resource interaction model formulated by DiPrete & Eirich (2006). Models are estimated with the main effects of disadvantage, represented by the various single risks, and the inclusion of interaction terms between low skill and the single risks. For the ‘multiple risk model’ we add interaction terms between low skill and the number of events and statuses. We focus on young people between the age of 16 and 35 and we ran separate models for young males and females since we judged their career trajectories to be very different for various reasons. One of these reasons are the differences in career preferences (see Hakim, 2002) and caring duties by gender because of which women face higher risks on fragmented careers and intermittent spells of unemployment and of ending up in so-called fragmented or ‘patchwork careers’ (Mills & Blossfeld, 2006; Fenton and Dermott, 2006). 11 5. Descriptive results In this part we first present some descriptive evidence on the exposure of young people to various single career or life course risks (single risk) and the combination or accumulation of risks (multiple risk) by skill-level and gender. Single risks by skill-level To obtain a first insight into the exposure to disadvantage we present in Table 1 evidence on a variety of (in)security indicators: employment insecurity (>=39 weeks unemployed in last year), income insecurity (household income below 60% of median household income), low pay (wage below 2/3 of median gross wage), subjective job insecurity (score lower than 6 on scale from 1 to 10) and low subjective well-being (below 4 on scale from 1 to 7). The low-skilled young generation is more exposed to employment and income insecurity, low pay, and a low SWB compared to the intermediate or high-skilled. Further, two remarkable observations can be made. First, subjective job insecurity of the low skilled is about equal to that of the high skilled which might be related to the low employment protection levels (low EPL) of British workers. Second, three in four low-skilled young females are exposed to low pay, meaning that their wage is below twothirds of the median wage of all male and female workers. Low skilled young females also exhibit a much higher level of household income insecurity but also employment insecurity. Two-thirds of the low skilled females is employment insecure against only one in four of the high skilled. Table 1 also shows the prevalence of particular events such as unemployment, disability (health limitations at work), divorce or separation, dismissal, a drop in health of two points of more on a scale ranging from one to ten, a move into a non-standard job, which can be a temporary job or a move into self-employment as an own account worker and the birth of a child. 12 Table 1: Descriptive information on outcome and risk variables by skill-level Skill-level (N=51,950) Employment insecurity (>=13 weeks unemployed) Income insecurity (<60%median eq. HH income) Subjective job security (<6) Low-pay (<0.67 median gross wage) Low SWB (<=4) Events Unemployment event Disability event Health drop Divorce/separation Childbirth Laid-off last year Entry non-standard job Statuses Disabled (‘health limits work’) LT Unemployed last year Underworked Training employer Temporary job Lone parent Single Gender Low Medium High All Male Female 0.39 0.66 0.31 0.41 0.18 0.24 0.29 0.39 Male Female 0.36 0.58 0.19 0.27 0.11 0.14 0.20 0.28 Male Female 0.25 0.21 0.23 0.19 0.26 0.22 0.24 0.20 Male Female Male Female 0.27 0.74 0.28 0.36 0.27 0.50 0.25 0.24 0.08 0.21 0.23 0.20 0.21 0.42 0.25 0.24 Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Female 0.07 0.08 0.05 0.05 0.07 0.08 0.01 0.02 0.08 0.11 0.05 0.02 0.07 0.07 0.04 0.07 0.03 0.03 0.06 0.07 0.01 0.01 0.05 0.07 0.03 0.01 0.08 0.09 0.03 0.07 0.02 0.03 0.06 0.06 0.01 0.01 0.07 0.08 0.02 0.01 0.06 0.07 0.04 0.07 0.03 0.04 0.06 0.07 0.01 0.01 0.06 0.08 0.03 0.01 0.08 0.08 Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Female 0.12 0.13 0.10 0.04 0.34 0.37 0.13 0.07 0.08 0.05 0.04 0.22 0.15 0.08 0.06 0.07 0.02 0.01 0.24 0.24 0.22 0.19 0.11 0.10 0.03 0.10 0.19 0.13 0.05 0.07 0.02 0.01 0.17 0.14 0.37 0.36 0.08 0.09 0.01 0.06 0.21 0.15 0.07 0.08 0.03 0.01 0.24 0.23 0.25 0.22 0.10 0.09 0.03 0.11 0.19 0.13 Source: BHPS, 1991-2008 The prevalence of disadvantaged statuses The incidence of these events is very low and ranges from less than one per cent for divorce or separation to eight percent for females experiencing an 13 unemployment event or a health shock. The low skilled are two times more likely to experience an unemployment, job displacement or disability event than the high skilled showing high levels of inequality by skill-level in Britain. However, the incidence of having a disadvantaged status, as shown in Table 1, is substantially higher, ranging from one per cent of the low-skilled females in long-term unemployment last year, to thirty-four per cent of the low-skilled females being underworked. Again, the likelihood of a disadvantaged status is far more pronounced for the low-skilled compared to the high skilled. The likelihood of becoming disabled (health impairment at work) is twice as high for the low-skilled young men but in the case of long-term unemployment even five times as high for this group. Low-skilled youngsters are also much less likely to receive a training compared to the high skilled. Low-skilled females are five times less likely to receive training than high-skilled females. Multiple risks by skill-level In Figures 2a and 2b we show the proportion of people combining two or more events or three or more disadvantaged statuses such as an unemployment event and a health drop, or working in a non-standard job, being underworked and receive any training. 0.7 0.7 Males Low skill 0.6 Females Low skill 0.6 Females Medium skill Males Medium skill 0.5 0.5 Females High skill Males High skill 0.4 0.4 0.3 0.3 0.2 0.2 0.1 0.1 0 0 Cum LCE (.=2) Cum LCS (>=3) Cum LCR (>=2,3) Cum LCE (.=2) 16-34 Cum LCS (>=3) Cum LCR (>=2,3) 35-59 Cum LCE (.=2) Cum LCS (>=3) 16-34 Cum LCR (>=2,3) Cum LCE (.=2) Cum LCS (>=3) Cum LCR (>=2,3) 35-59 Figure 2: Cumulative life course risks (LCEV=events; LCST=statuses; LCR=risks) by age, gender and skill-level 14 Most people experience any adverse event but when they experience an event, most of the time it is the only one. Only 3% of young men and 5% of young women experience 2 or more adverse events. For the low skilled it is about one per cent more. The prevalence of multiple disadvantaged statuses is however much higher. About one in three young men are exposed to three or more disadvantaged statuses but among the low-skilled men the percentage is 10% higher. The young low-skilled women however fare much worse over the career. More than 60% of the low-skilled young women are exposed to at least three disadvantaged statuses or multiple risks whereas this percentage is much lower for the low-skilled generations after them, those between 35 and 60 years of age (less than 40%). 6. Single and multiple risk model estimation results The results of the GLS fixed effects panel regression model are presented in Table 2 to 4. In Table 2 and 3 we report on the findings of the single-risk models for the life course events and the statuses, respectively. In Table 4 the findings for the multiple-risk models are presented. The fixed-effects models study the factors which explain the changes in security levels over time and, hence, over peoples’ careers as a function of changes in human capital endowments, changes in employment or marital status and the experiencing of a multiple set of events. Only time varying variables are withheld in the model. This implies that we correct for unobserved heterogeneity caused by the impact of time constant unobserved factors such as motivation, efforts, personality traits etc. These effects are captured in the individual effects term of the model and separately estimated as one of the variance components (σμ). Since we have data over eighteen years, the youngsters at 16 years of age in 1991 are followed over their career up to the time that they become thirty-five. For the seventeen years old and so forth the observation period is shorter. The results confirm largely the picture obtained from the descriptive results. 15 Single risk models Table 2 presents the single risk model. The social and economic values exert hardly any significant effect on employment and income security. There is a positive employment and a negative income security effect of economic values (such as striving for success in the career) for women. Social values (importance of family, friends and children) have only a small negative effect on women’s employment security. The human capital variables show strong negative effects, such as the variable for low-skill and medium-skill, but also of job tenure on particularly employment security. The latter finding is remarkable since it means that longer tenure negatively affects the employment security of young males and females. The investments in skill formation do apparently pay-off for the career with a view to the higher level of income and employment security. Life course events The main effects of events on income and employment security show a mixed picture. The experience of a disability event has a negative effect on employment security but only for men and not for women. For young women an unemployment event in the last year might even improve their employment security, because they quickly regain employment compared to not-working women. Most young men and women recover very quickly from being laid-off in the previous year by finding new employment. Further inspection shows that the effect is negative for those who did not regain employment and became unemployed. Childbirth has a negative effect on young women’s employment security and especially on young women’s and men’s income security. Interactions of events with low skill Most of the interaction effects of the events with low skill, shown in Table 2, are insignificant except for the negative interaction effect of an unemployment event on young males’ employment security and the positive interaction effect of childbirth on income security. The negative interaction effect of unemployment combined with an insignificant main effect in the males’ model merely shows that the low skilled are more likely to experience such an event but not that the effects are accelerating. 16 Table 2: Estimation results of single risk GLS panel regression model on employment and income security of young people 16-34 years Model I. Events interaction model Employment security Income security Males Females Males Females Values Social values -0.375 Economic values 0.201 Human capital (ref.: high skilled) Low skill -3.114 Intermediate skills -4.657*** Tenure current job -0.454*** Events Disability event -1.088 Health drop 0.386 Unemployment event 0.208 Laid-off last year 1.643** Entry non-standard job -0.406 Divorced/Separation event 0.254 Child birth -0.143 Interactions: Low-skill*Events (ref. med/high skilled) Events Disability event -1.425 Drop subjective health 0.279 Unemployment event -3.351* Being laid-off last year -0.135 Entry non-stand. Job -0.707 Divorce/separation event -2.64 Child birth -0.657 Constant -64.278*** R2 0.173 N 22193 σμ 14.978 σє 12.894 Ρ 0.574 -0.708* 1.392*** 0.015 -0.001 -0.02 -0.027 -8.448*** -7.005*** -0.579*** -0.212* -0.302*** -0.003 -0.393*** -0.539*** -0.008** 0.434 0.436 2.899*** 2.884*** -0.417 0.781 -4.450*** -0.059 -0.031 -0.082** 0.052 -0.003 0.520*** -0.512*** -0.003 -0.015 0.012 0.067 -0.077*** -0.440*** -0.367*** -0.674 -1.399 1.437 4.577 2.654 -2.838 0.662 -37.789*** 0.113 26575 17.711 15.734 0.559 0.062 -0.059 0.116* -0.066 -0.034 -0.272 0.224*** -1.929*** 0.07 22372 1.238 0.927 0.641 0.01 0.006 0.031 0.167 0.044 0.153 0.218*** -0.592 0.096 26791 1.217 0.886 0.654 Source: BHPS, 1991-2008 The positive interaction effects of childbirth on income security combined with the negative main effects show that low-skilled young people are compensated at least partly for the initial negative income effects later in the career (declining disadvantage). Disadvantaged statuses Most of the effects, shown in Table 3, are significant and strongly negative such as for unemployment, disability and lack of employer-related training. However, with 17 one exception, that is for young women employed in a non-standard job. Especially, among young women, a temporary job seems to be salient for employment security compared to women not working, possibly because women have low chances to obtain secure employment. Divorced or separated women are able to improve their employment security possibly because they need to work for their living after divorce but their household income security is negatively affected. Unemployed, underworked and disabled young men and women show a significant lower level of employment and income security over their career than youngsters at work or youngsters working the hours they prefer. Interactions of disadvantaged statuses with low skill The interaction effects with disadvantaged statuses show again that most of the interaction effects are insignificant or positive, except for the negative interaction effect of low skill with in-living children for women’s employment security. Low skilled young women with children face cumulative disadvantage with a view to their employment security chances later in the career (main effect - 9.543+interaction effect -3.971=-13.151 weeks employed). However, they appear able to recoup from the initial disadvantage in terms of household income security later on in the career but only partly (main effect -0.306 +interaction effect 0.162=-0.144 or -14.4%). Hence, young women never fully recover from the reduced income security after divorce. Positive effects are found for young men lacking employer-related training showing that the initial disadvantage with respect to employment security is partly compensated later in the career (-3.885+1.237=2.648 weeks). They also fully recover from the reduced income security due to lack of training (-0.088+0.150=+0.062 or +6.2%). For young females the reduced employment security (-6 weeks) and income security (-7%) due to lack of training is not compensated later in the career. Again, the positive interaction effect with a non-standard job shows that the low-skilled young women are for their employment security very much dependent on non-standard work either as temporary worker or as freelance or own-account worker. 18 Table 3: Estimation results of single risk GLS panel regression model on employment and income security of young people 16-34 years II. Statuses interaction model Employment security Males Females Values Social values Economic values Human capital(ref.: high skilled) Low skill Intermediate skills Statuses: Tenure current job Bad health Div/separated (ref. married) Long-term unemployed last year Disabled Underworked No employment-related training Have kids Non-standard job Lone parent Single person Interactions: Low skill*Statuses Bad health Divorced/Separation Status LT unemployed last year Disabled Underworked No Training Inliving children Non-standard job Lone parent Single person Constant R2 N σμ σє Ρ Income security Males Females -0.302 0.116 -0.258 0.797** 0.025 -0.019 -0.008 -0.049** -2.691* -2.625*** -5.929*** -3.669*** -0.421*** -0.208*** -0.346*** -0.288*** -0.319*** -0.427*** -0.831 -0.787 0.499 2.985*** 23.806*** -17.818*** -2.705*** -0.445 -5.326*** -7.549*** -3.885*** -5.656*** -1.176*** -9.543*** 4.136*** 6.830*** 0.066 -2.123** -3.570*** -3.784*** 0.001 -0.026 0.264*** -0.002 -0.01 -0.306*** -0.267*** -0.145*** -0.088*** -0.097*** -1.068*** 0.019 0.065 -0.693*** -0.221*** -0.059** -0.119*** -0.066*** -1.090*** -0.032 -0.313*** -1.004*** 0.031 -0.128 0.096 0.07 0.066* 0.150*** 0.344*** -0.074 0.002 0.343*** -0.065 0.230** 0.102 0.111** 0.111*** 0.062 0.162** 0.023 0.03 0.16 1.097*** 0.246 27342 1.089 0.883 0.603 1.737*** 0.337 32279 0.998 0.823 0.595 1.515 0.063 -5.759** -4.053 3.078* 6.289*** -0.749 -0.434 -0.24 3.120*** 1.237* -1.231 -0.5 -3.971** -3.181*** 2.978** -1.363 0.783 0.494 0.179 88.249*** -38.631*** 0.422 0.33 27307 32243 12.024 14.681 12.772 15.283 0.47 0.48 Note: The models are estimated with inclusion of controls: age, age squared and annual unemployment rate interacted with periood Source: BHPS, 2001-2009 19 Multiple risk models Table 4 summarizes the findings of the multiple-risk models. The accumulation of life course events exerts a negative effect on income security of young males and females but the interaction effects with low skill are positive suggesting declining disadvantage. They are smaller in size and therefore do not fully compensate for the initial income loss. The effects of the accumulation of disadvantaged statuses on income and employment security are strongly negative. The interaction effects with low skill are negative for young men’s employment security, meaning that the initial disadvantage of the low skilled (-3 weeks) is aggravated (with another -1.5 week). The positive interaction effects on income security show once again that the initial disadvantage of the low skilled is declining over the career. The multiple risks model combining the cumulative events and statuses model confirm cumulative disadvantage on low skilled men’s employment security but reduced disadvantage on income security. Whereas the single risk model highlights continuous disadvantage, the multiple risk model indeed highlights cumulating disadvantage for low-skilled young men. Table 4: Estimation results multiple-risk GLS panel regression models on employment and income security, youngsters 16-34, BHPS Employment security Model I. Events EVENTS Lowskill*EVENTS R2 Model II: Statuses STATUSES Low skill*STATUSES R2 Model III: Risks RISKS Lowskill*RISKS R 2 N Income security Male Female Male Female 0.186* -0.149 -0.059*** -0.064*** -0.25 0.19 0.028** 0.043*** 0.258 0.155 0.056 0.083 -3.025*** -3.966*** -0.267*** -0.316*** -1.579*** 0.53 0.134*** 0.157*** 0.329 0.251 0.151 0.255 -2.209*** -3.019*** -0.218*** -0.254*** -1.000*** 0.441 0.112*** 0.131*** 0.309 0.228 0.135 0.223 27699 32555 28051 32982 Notes: * p<0.10, ** p<0.05, ***p<0.001; Models are estimated with the social and economic values, human capital variables (low skill, medium skill, tenure) and the controls (age, age squared, interaction unemployment rate and period) included. Source: BHPS, 1991-2008 20 7. Conclusions The conclusions of the paper are therefore very straightforward. Low-skilled young British men and especially young British women are more than their better skilled peers exposed to life course risks jeopardizing their income and employment security over the career. Especially, low-skilled young women in Britain are confronted with unfavourable employment perspectives and reduced income security. However, we find no evidence whatsoever of aggravating disadvantage over the career since hardly any significant negative interaction effects between the events or the statuses and low skill were observed except for the employment security of low skilled young women with children. The latter finding confirms hypothesis 3 on the ‘scarring’ effects of disadvantage, not necessarily being cumulative, and the gender-based inequality patterns. The findings also confirm the literature, but contradict the first hypothesis on cumulative disadvantage, since for most of the low-skilled young people on the labour market, the career perspectives are characterized by continuous disadvantage. Peoples’ life chances seem more affected by persistent sources of inequality embedded in social stratification processes in society than by an accelerating likelihood of becoming disadvantaged over the career due to a heightened exposure to life course risks exerting an cumulative negative impact on people’s careers. This confirms hypothesis 4 that most of the career effects are additive and not multiplicative. However in the final part our multiple risk models show that the picture becomes different if we depart from the single risk framework and consider the effects of the accumulation of adverse life course events and statuses in a multiple-risk framework. Exposure to a combination of various disadvantaged statuses results for the low-skilled young men and women in a mixed picture of cumulative disadvantage on employment security and continuous disadvantage on income security. The latter results provide various challenging avenues for public policy and further scrutiny. The current crisis appear to have affected especially the position of youngsters on the labour market, but in general seem to have widened the dispersion in employment and income security or inequality, asking for public policy to tackle the insider-outsider cleavage many countries confront. The methodology 21 adopted here using long-running panel-data appears particularly valuable for evaluating the causes and consequences of the current crisis. The data of the British Household Panel Study and the much larger “Understanding Society” data provide a rich and unique data source to study these issues in further detail also for the years after 2008 and to provide a better understanding of the causes and severe consequences of the crisis for society. References Bardasi, E., & Gornick, J. C. (2008). Working for less? Women's part-time wage penalties across countries. Feminist Economics, 14(1), 37-72. Belzil, C. (1995). Unemployment Insurance and Unemployment Over Time: An Analysis with Event History Data. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 77(1), 113-126. Bielby, W. T. and D. D. Bielby (1992), Cumulative Versus Continuous Disadvantage in an Unstructured Labor-Market - Gender Differences in the Careers of Television Writers, Work and Occupations 19:366-386. Berthoud, R. (2003). Multiple disadvantage in employment. A quantitative analysis. Essex, University of Essex: 45. Berthoud, R. (2008). Disability employment penalties in Britain, Work Employment and Society, 22:129-148. Böheim, R., & Taylor, M. P. (2000). The Search for Success: Do the Unemployed find Stable Employment? Essex: University of Essex, Institute for Social and Economic Research. Booth, A. L., Francesconi, M., & Frank, J. (2002). Temporary jobs: Stepping stones or dead ends? Economic Journal, 112(480), F189-F213. Brekke, I. and A. Mastekaasa (2008). Highly educated immigrants in the Norwegian labour market: permanent disadvantage? Work Employment and Society, 22:507-526. Breen, R., Luijkx, R., Muller, W., & Pollak, R. (2009). Nonpersistent Inequality in Educational Attainment: Evidence from Eight European Countries. American Journal of Sociology, 114(5), 1475-1521. 22 Dannefer, D. (2003). Cumulative advantage/disadvantage and the life course: Cross-fertilizing age and social science theory. Journals of Gerontology Series B-Psychological Sciences and Social Sciences, 58:S327-S337. DiPrete, T. A., & Eirich, G. M. (2006). Cumulative advantage as a mechanism for inequality: A review of theoretical and empirical developments. Annual Review of Sociology, 32, 271-297. Erikson, R., & Goldthorpe, J. H. (2002). Intergenerational inequality: A sociological perspective. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 16(3), 31-44. Fenton, S. and E. Dermott (2006). Fragmented careers? Winners and losers in young adult labour markets. Work Employment and Society, Vol. 20:205221. Fouarge, D., & Muffels, R. (2009). Working Part-Time in the British, German and Dutch Labour Market: Scarring for the Wage Career? Journal of Applied Social Science Studies (Schmoller’s Jahrbuch), 129, 217-226. Gallie, D. (1994). Are the unemployed an underclass? Some evidence from the social change and economic life initiative. Sociology, 28(3), 737-757. Gallie, D. (2007). Welfare regimes, employment systems and job preference orientations. European Sociological Review, 23(3), 279-293. Gangl, M. (2002). Changing labour markets and early career outcomes: labour market entry in Europe over the past decade. Work Employment and Society, 16:67-90. Gangl, M. (2006). Scar effects of unemployment: An assessment of institutional complementarities. American Sociological Review, 71(6), 986-1013. Goldthorpe, J. H. (2002). Globalisation and social class. West European Politics, 25(3), 1-28. Gregory, M., & Jukes, R. (2001). Unemployment and subsequent earnings: estimating scarring among British men 1984-94. Oxford: University of Oxford. Hakim, C. (2002). Lifestyle preferences as determinants of women's differentiated labor market careers." Work and Occupations 29:428-459. Leibfried, S., & Mau, S. (2008). Welfare States: Construction, Deconstruction, Reconstruction. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. Lindbeck, A., & Snower, D. J. (1988). The insider-outsider theory of employment and unemployment. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. 23 Manning, A., & Petrongolo, B. (2008). The part-time pay penalty for women in Britain. Economic Journal, 118(526), F28-F51. Mincer, J. (1974). Schooling, Experience, and Earnings. New York: Columbia University Press. Merton, R. K. (1988). The Matthew Effect in Science, Cumulative Advantage and the Symbolism of Intellectual Property, Isis, 79:606-623. Muffels, R., A. Wilthagen (2012). Flexicurity: A New Paradigm for the Analysis of Labor Markets and a Metaphor for Policies Challenging the ‘Trade-Off’ Between Flexibility and Security. Sociology Compass. Vol. 6 (10): 1-15 Muffels, R. (2012). Low Skill, Life Course Risks and Disadvantage in the Early Career: Youth Income and Employment Security in the British, German and Dutch labour Market. GUSTO Working Papers WP3, Tilburg University, pp. 42. Muffels, R. (Ed.) (2008). Flexibility and Employment Security in Europe. Labour Markets in Transition. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, p. 407. Muffels, R. and Luijkx, R. (2008). Labour market mobility and employment security of male employees in Europe: ‘Trade-off’ or ‘flexicurity’? Work, Employment and Society, 22, 221–241. Luijkx, R., & Wolbers, H. J. (2009). The Effects of Non-Employment on Early Work-Life on Subsequent Employment Chances of Individuals in The Netherlands. European Sociological Review, 25(6), 647-660. Nickell, S., & Wadhwani, S. (1990). Insider Forces and Wage Determination. Economic Journal, 100(401), 496-509. O'Reilly, J., D. Lain, M. Sheehan, B. Smale, and M. Stuart (2011). Managing uncertainty: the crisis, its consequences and the global workforce, Work Employment and Society, 25:581-595. Pissarides, C. (1992). Loss of skill during unemployment and the persistence of employment shocks. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107, 1371-1391. Preis, M. J. (2004). Persistence of Employment Fluctuations: A Model of Recurring Job Loss. Review of Economic Studies, 71, 193-215. Rosenbaum, J. E. (1979), Tournament mobility: Career patterns in a Corporation, Administrative Science Quarterly, 24 (2), 220-241. Ryan, P. (2001). The School-to-Work Transition. The Journal of Economic Literature, 39(1), 34-92. Ruhm, C. J. (1991). Are workers permanently scarred by by job displacement? American Economic Review, 81(1), 319-325. 24 Scherer, S. (2004). Stepping-stones or traps? The consequences of labour market entry positions on future careers in West Germany, Great Britain and Italy. Work Employment and Society, 18(2), 369-394. Standing, G. (2011), Responding to the crisis: economic stabilisation grants, Policy and Politics, 39:9-25. Steiner, V. (2001). Unemployment persistence in the West German labour market: negative duration dependence or sorting? Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 63(1), 91-115. 25