Lvp5 AX-733 POLICY RESEARCH WORKING Trade Policy Reform and Poverty Alleviation PAPER 2733 How to implement trade liberalization as part of a strategy for alleviating poverty in developing countries. BernardHoekman Constantine Michalopoulos Maurice Schiff David Tarr The World Bank DevelopmentResearchGroup Trade December2001 I POLICYRESEARCH WORKINGPAPER2733 Summary findings In this paper, developed as part of the World Bank's Poverty Reduction Strategy Sourcebook, Hoekman, Michalopoulos, Schiff, and Tarr examine how to implement trade liberalization as part of a strategy for alleviating poverty in developing countries. They discuss trade policy instruments, institutions, complementary policies, sector issues, adjustment policies, and safety nets in an integrated approach to trade policy as a tool for poverty alleviation. The authors examine the patterns or models of trade policy that have been successful in alleviating poverty. They discuss the role of tariffs, nontariff barriers, contingent protection (such as safeguards and antidumping), special import regimes (such as duty drawback), export taxes, export subsidies, and traderelated institutions (such as standards, marketing, export finance, customs clearance, and regional trade arrangements). The authors also discuss policies that complement successful trade reform, including macroeconomic stability, a competitive exchange rate, flexible labor markets, competitive product markets, and policies that do not discriminate against foreigners in investment. They suggest approaches to policies and institutions in services and agriculture, key sectors in poverty reduction. They explain the roles of retraining and safety nets in dealing with the adjustment costs of trade liberalization. Finally, the authors elaborate guidelines for implementing trade reform and explain tools for assessing whether trade reform will help or harm the poor in particular sectors in the short run. This paper-a product of Trade, Development Research Group-is part of a larger effort in the group to.understand the links between trade reforms and poverty reduction. Copies of the paper are available free from the World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC 20433. Please contact Rebecca Martin, room MC3-308, telephone 202-473-9065, fax 202522-1159, email address rmartinl@worldbank.org. Policy Research Working Papers are also posted on the Web at http:/ /econ.worldbank.org. The authors may be contacted at bhoekman@worldbank.org, cmichalopoulos@worldbank.org, mschiff@worldbank.org, or dtarr@worldbank.org. December 2001. (44 pages) The PolicyResearcbWorkingPaperSeoesdisseminatesthe findingsof work in progressto encouragethe exchangeof ideasabout development issues.An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished The paperscarry the names of the authors and sbould be cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusionsexpressed in this paper are entirely those of the authors. They do not necessarilyrepresent the view of the World Bank, its Executive Directors, or the countriesthey represent. Produced by the Policy Research Dissemination Center Trade Policy Reform and Poverty Alleviation * Bernard Hoekman ** Constantine Michalopoulos * Maurice Schiff ** David Tarr ** Preparedby the DevelopmentResearchGroup,InternationalTradeTeam of the World Bankfor the PovertyReductionStrategysourcebookas a guide to help the least developedcountries employtrade policy and institutionsin their poverty reductionstrategies.Pilot studies in Cambodia,Mauritania,and Madagascarwere beingundertakenduring the summerand fall of 2001. This paper was preparedwith assistancefrom CarstenFink, FaezehForoutan,AadityaMattoo,MarceloOlarreaga,Garry Pursell,and the staff of the IMFPolicy Developmentand ReviewDepartment-in particular,GeoffreyBannister,Anne McGuirk,and KamauThugge.The report benefitedfrom helpfulcommentsand suggestionsfrom Brian Ames, Ataman Aksoy, Ishac Diwan, Philip English, Simon Evenett, Mike Finger, Jeni Klugman, Will Martin, Brad McDonald,Richard Newfarmer,Jayanta Roy, and John Wilson. Maria Kasilag provided excellentsupportin the preparationof the manuscript. DevelopmentResearchGroup, InternationalTradeTeam,WorldBank SeniorEconomicAdvisor,WorldBank Table of Contents 1 1. Introduction.......................................... 2. TradePolicyReform,Growthand PovertyAlleviation..........................................3 3. TradePolicyInstrumentsand Institutions .......................................... 4. ComplementaryPoliciesto a TradeReform......................................... 14 5. SectorIssues......................................... 19 6. Copingwith Uncertainty:The Roleof SafetyNets......................................... 28 7. TradePolicyReform:GuidelinesFor PovertyAlleviation...................................... 30 Appendix.Impactof Trade Reformon the Poor:A SimpleFramework.36 iii 6 1 Introduction Trade and Growth. There is a preponderanceof cross-countryevidence that trade liberalizationand opennessto trade increasesthe growth rate of incomeand output.' In addition,numerous individualcountry studiesover the past three decadessuggest that "trade does seem to create,even sustainhighergrowth"(Bhagwatiand Srinivasan1999). A country'strade policy is the key link in the transmissionof price signalsfrom the world market to the national economy. Undistorted price signals from world markets, in combinationwith the exchangerate,allow resourceallocationconsistentwith comparative advantage, thereby increasing productivity.An open trade and investment regime encouragesintegrationinto the globaltradingenvironmentand the import of diverseand 2 modemtechnologiesthat are importantfor productivityimprovements. Trade,Growthand the Poor.Growthin incomesof the poor is stronglyrelatedto overallgrowth in the economy-althoughthe relationshipdifferssubstantiallyfrom country to country.The link of overall growthto povertyalleviationhas beendemonstratedboth in 3 Trade cross country analyses (Dollar and Kraay, 2000), and for individual countries. liberalizationcan therefore be expectedto help the poor overall, given the positive associationbetweenopennessand growth. As important,the political economyof trade policyis such that in practiceit is unlikelythat the poor havemuch influenceon the pattern of protection that prevails in a country. As trade policy inherently has the effect of redistributingincome, this implies that trade policy often acts to tax the poor, and that liberalizationcan thereforedo muchto improveincomesof the poor. However,in the short run liberalizationmay have a negativeimpact on some of the poor, dependingon their sources of incomeand the impact on prices of goods and servicesthe poor consume. Thus,there is a needto examinethe impactof trade liberalizationin some detailto helpto design policies that protect those among the poor who may be adversely effected, especiallyin the shortrun. Characteristicsof the Poor. Knowledgeof how the poor obtain and how the poor spend their income is important in designing pro-poor policies. As explained at greater length in the Appendixto this chapter,trade policy will affect the welfare of the poor through what they consume and what they produce. Food is by far the most important item of expenditure.In Bangladesh,for example,food representsabout 73 percent of the total expendituresof the poor. Fuels, housing and clothing combined 4 The sale of unskilledlabor tends to be the accountfor about21 percentof expenditures. most important source of income for the poor, complementedby the value of "own consumption,"that is, the imputed value of what the poor consume from their own 5 production. ' Sachsand Wamer (1995),Dollar (1992),Edwards(1993, 1998),Ben David(1993)and Frankeland Romer (1999). Coe,Helpmanand Hoffmaister(1997)for evidenceand (Romer,1994)for a furtherdiscussion. Forexample,Srinivasan(2000)foundthat of the 17 percentagepoint reductionin the populationbelowthe povertyline over some 40 years (between1951-55and 1993-94),a 15 percentagepoint reductionis to be attributedto growthand 2 to redistributivepolicies. the 1991HouseholdExpenditureSurveyfor Bangladesh. 4From 5 In Mexico,wages from unskilledlabor represents40 to 45 percentof the incomeof the poor, and own consumptionis the next largestat 15 percent(lanchovichinaet al., 2000). 3See In general,the impacton the sourceof incomeof the poorwill be a more important determinantof the effect of liberalizationthan the effect on the pricesof their consumption. The reasonis that trade reformwill affectmanyrelativeprices, someof whichwill move in offsetting directions. In contrast, as the poor generally have limited assets, the most importantof whichis low-skilledlabor,the impacton wagesandemploymentdominates. ComplementaryPolicies and Institutions.While a liberal trade policy is necessaryfor growthand povertyreduction,it alone is not sufficientfor growth of trade. When trade reformhas been implementedin an unstablemacroeconomicenvironmentor without efforts at strengthening trade-related domestic institutions and appropriate complementarypolicies,it has ofteneither been reversedor failed to stimulategrowth. In this chapter, we will also discuss important "behind the border' reforms that should accompany trade liberalizationto effectively allow a country to integrate into world markets. This includesa regime that encouragesinvestmentand competition,including openness to foreign direct investment(FDI), so that business services are supplied at competitive prices, and macroeconomicpolicies that encourage stable prices and a competitivereal exchangerate.6 Althoughthe poor are very diverse,they frequentlywork in the rural sector and in the urban informalsector.Thus, policiesthat affect agricultural and labormarketsare importantcomplementsto trade reformfor the poor. Political Economyof Protectionand the Poor. Even when trade reform will benefit the poor and the economybroadly,it will often be resisted.The sectors with the highest protectionknow they receive concentratedgains from protectionand they will oppose the reform. The expansionof exports following reform is likely to be spread throughoutthe economy,often with new and sometimesunexpectedindustriesarising.It is oftendifficult to identifyfutureexportsand exporters.Thus,the employmentand income gains from reform are likely to be diffuse. The same is true for the consumerswho will gain from the reform through lower prices and greater choice.The diffuse nature of the gainsto consumersand producersexplainswhy thosewho opposeliberalizationoftenare dominant in the political lobbying.Redistributiveeffects of trade reformcan be a major factor impedingthe launch of welfare-improvingpolicychanges(Rodrik,1998). Abstractingfrom fiscal revenueconsiderations,barriersto trade are typicallyput in place to protect domestic producersfrom internationalcompetition,and usually benefit powerfulinterest groups,not the poor. Non-tariffbarriersare especiallyperniciousin this regard as they result in the transferof rents from consumersbroadly,includingthe poor, to licenseholders.Such rents arise becausethe restrictionon importsresultsin domestic prices that are above the world price. Whereas in the case of a tariff the government collects the revenue that is implied by the differencebetweenthe world price and the tariff-inclusivedomestic price, in the case of non-tariff barriers this implicit revenue is capturedby those who havethe right (holdthe license)to import.There is evidencethat in developing countries such rents are a major source of inefficiencyfrom rent-seeking activity(Krueger,1974),i.e., from the spendingof real resourcesto obtainimport licenses and influencepolicy in general. These license holders are often among the wealthiest members of society. Thus, in addition to the inefficiency costs of trade protection, protectionwill often transfer incometowardthe rich and away from the poor. Indeed, in 6 One view, representedby Rodriguezand Rodrik (2000), is that there is a strong associationbetween exportsand growth,but that we are unableto be sure whetherthis associationis a consequenceof exports causingoutputgrowth,or of the two beingjointly determinedby the strengthof countries'institutions.Evenif we were to acceptthis agnosticview, the resultingpolicy prescriptionis a relativelycomprehensiveapproach to developmentthat includesimprovementof a range of institutionsalongwith tradeliberalization. 2 percentageterms the effect of trade reformon the incomesof those who currentlygain and those who currentlylose from reform can easily be a multipleof the economy-wide welfaregainsfrom liberalization.This is becausetrade policyis inherentlya redistributive policy. Structureof this Chapter.In the next sectionof this chapterwe describe briefly the experiencewith successfultrade policyreformand discussadjustmentcosts and the implicationsfor the poor. Section III discussesand evaluatesthe principaltrade policy instrumentsand institutions.In sectionIV the most importantcomplementarypoliciesare discussedand evaluated.Giventhe importanceof agricultureand businessservicesfor a poverty reduction strategy that employs trade, these sectors are accorded special treatment in section V. General and trade policy specific safety nets are discussed in section VI. We brieflysummarizethe principalpoints in a successfulstrategyfor using trade for poverty reductionin the last section.The appendixprovides a frameworkfor thinkingaboutthe impacton the poorfrom a trade reformin the shortand the longrun.7 2 Trade Policy Reform, Growth and Poverty Alleviation 2.1 Models of Successful Trade Integration and Poverty Reduction In the last 40 years of the 20Qh century,severalcountrieshave been highly successfulin increasingincomesand reducingpoverty.Most notable,has beenthe experienceof the South-EastAsian economies,especiallySingapore,Hong Kong, Japan,Taiwan (China) and Korea. In the final 15 years of the century,Chile and Mauritiusalso saw remarkable increasesin income.All of these countriesdramaticallyincreasedtheir exports (andtrade to GDP ratio), raisedincomesand reducedpovertyand are now active participantsin the global trading environment.On the other hand,there are no examplesof countriesthat have significantlyreduced povertywithoutsignificantlyincreasingtheir exports.Although export expansionis the commonelementto all the successstories of poverty reduction, there are considerabledifferencesin the modelsof trade policythat these countrieshave adopted.The successstoriesmay be groupedinto three broadcategories: * Economy-wideTrade Liberalization.Countries like Hong Kong, Singapore and * Chile adoptedvery liberal trade regimes.These countriesavoidednon-tariff barriers. HongKongand Singaporepracticedfree trade (zerotariffs),while Chile employedlow uniformtariffs. Protectionwith OffsettingPoliciesfor Exporters.Somecountriesthat experienced rapid growthin trade and GDP did so in the contextof trade regimescharacterizedby significantimportcontrolson the domesticmarket.Korea,Taiwan(China) and Japan (in the early stages) are the main examples. The key to understandingthese experienceshas to do with lookingat all the factors that affect competitivenessand the incentivesto producersto sell in the domesticversusthe export market.Protection ' Spaceconstraintspreventa detaileddiscussionof manyof the subjectsaddressedin this chapter.Morein-depthtreatments of tradepolicyfroma development perspective canbe foundon the websitewww.worldbank.org/trade and in two recentcompilations: McColluch,Wintersand Cirera(forthcoming) -andHoekman,Englishand Mattoo(forthcoming). TheWorldBanksite also offersaccessto toolsthatcan be usedto assistin thedesignof tradereforms,andcross-country dataon tradepoliciesthatare usefulfor benchmarking purposes. Specifictoolsthatfocuson the impactof reformonthepoorarestillbeingdeveloped andwillbepostedonceavailable. 3 * creates incentivesto produceand sell to the domesticmarket,i.e., protectioncreates a bias against exports. Indeed, protectionof intermediateproducts and services creates a serious handicapto export industriesbecauseit raisestheir costs to levels that are higherthan those of their potentialcompetitorsin world markets,and they are discouragedthrough the impact of protectionon the real exchange rate. But these countries managedelaborate systemsthat offset the bias against exports (Box 1). The experiencesof nearlyall other developingcountrieswith high protectionof their domestic markets are quite different. Notably,the institutionsneeded for effective implementationof duty drawbacksystemshave been shownto be weak in most subSaharaAfrican countries(WorldBank,2000c).This suggeststhat the Koreanmodelis not relevantfor most developingcountriesin that it is too difficult to manageand too easily taken over by special interestswhowill obtainrents. Protection with Export ProcessingZones. In a protected trade regime that discouragesexports, export processingzones (EPZs) may be used to partly place exporterson a footing equal to producersfor the domesticmarket.While very many countries have introducedEPZs,few have actuallysucceededin stimulatingexports substantiallyand on a sustainablebasis through this mechanism(see below). The experienceof Mauritiusin the last 15 years of the 20t century,however,provides an exampleof a countrythat expandedexportssignificantlyand reducedpovertythrough EPZs in a trade regimethat was not liberaloverall.Exportersin an EPZ havetariff free access to intermediateinputs and often have fewer regulatory constraintson their actions. As a result they may are able to compete on a footing almost equal to producersfor the domesticmarket.Althoughthere is a role for EPZs in countrieswith institutional constraints (Watson, 2000), there are potential piffalls in establishing successfulEPZs (see below). Box 1. How KoreaOvercamethe Anti-ExportBias of ProtectiveTradePolicies Duringthe 1960sand 1970sespecially,Korea had relativelyhigh importtariffs and also used non-tariffbarriers,but both exportsand the economygrew very rapidly.In principle,tariffs imposea bias againstexports by making productionfor the home market more profitable.Korea managedan elaboratesystem that offset the bias against exports.Two of the most importantmechanismsused by Koreawere dutyfree access to intermediatesused in productionfor export (temporaryadmission) and capital subsidies to exporters. Korea managed a very efficient temporary admission system (supplementedin the 1980s by an efficient duty drawback system) which allowedtariff free access to intermediateinputs for exporters (and 'indirect' exporters).Also importantwas that exporters(and indirectexporters)had preferred access to working capital at interest rates that were considerablylower than the interest rates paid by firms supplying the domestic market. The developmentand enforcementof these policiesover a long period requiredstrong political will supported by a broad national consensus, and a highly competent administration. Source: Based on Westphal and Kim (1977), Westphal (1991) and Rhee, RossLarson and Pursell (1984). These studies provide a full treatment of the mechanismsemployedby Korea to provideexporterswith incentivesto offset the bias of the tariffs. In practice, the most practicalway of stimulating trade and opening up to the internationaleconomy is through liberal trade regimes, rather than through a complex 4 structure of protection and export incentives.As a practical matter, duty drawback mechanismsare ineffectivein most of the least developedcountries.Thus, a regimewith high protectionwill diminish exports and growth. Moreover,differentiatedstructuresof protectionand subsidizationcreate opportunitiesfor elites and powerfulproducergroups to capturetrade policyfor their specialinterests.This lobbyingfor protectionand subsidies engenderscorruptionand inefficiencieswhich, in the end hurt the poor. These problems can be avoided by simple and transparentprotectionregimesof low uniformtariffs. For low income countries with weak trade related institutions, EPZs can be an effective vehicle to promoteexport production,not only because they allow duty-free access to importedinputs, but becausethey providea meansto deal with infrastructureand public sectorservice-relatedweaknessesthat impedeinvestment(Watson,2000). Z;;s =Costs of Trade Liberalization: Impact on the Poor Trade reform may not be implementeddue to politicaldynamicsor a fear of adjustment costs. A recent review of over 50 empiricalstudies of adjustmentcosts by Matusz and Tarr (2000)found that all the evidencesupportsthe view that the adjustmentcoststo the economyare very small in relationto the benefitsof trade liberalization.For example,a retrospectivestudy of trade reform in 19 developingcountriesby Papageorgiou,Choksi and Michaely (1990) concluded that trade liberalizationdid not generally result in decreased employment,even in the short run. Compared with the pre-liberalization period, manufacturingemploymentwas larger one year subsequentto the completionof liberalizationin all but one of the twelve countriesfor which data was reported. In fact, manufacturingemploymentwas higher in twelve of thirteencasesduring the liberalization period comparedwith the levels registeredprior to liberalization.Parker et al. (1995) and Harrison and Revenga(1995) performedsimilar but less extensivestudies with similar resultsfor marketeconomies. Althoughfurther evidenceis neededto generalizethese resultsfully to developing countries-most of the literature has focused on industrializedcountry experienceLiedholmand Meade (1995)found there were very high-start up rates (twentypercent) for mediumand small enterprises(MSEs) in six African economiesand the Dominican Republic,where MSEs account(as they do elsewhereas well) for a significantportionof total employment.The high start-uprates,wherethe businessenvironmentis supportive, suggestthat entrepreneursin these countriesare quick to respondto new opportunities, making speedy adjustmentto trade reform quite likely. Looked at another way, the magnitudeof dislocationcausedby liberalizationis unlikelyto be significantlylarger than dislocationsassociatedwith the everydayworkingsof the economyin manycountries. Private adjustmentcosts can be substantialor very small dependingon whether displacedworkerswere earningrents in their initial positionand whethermarketsfunction reasonablywell. The poorare not likelyto be earningrentsor they would not be poor. The evidence shows that adjustment costs are typically short term and terminate when workers find a job, while the benefits of trade reformcan be expectedto grow with the economy.In developingeconomies,trade liberalizationshould favor labor since exports will typically be labor intensive.Significantwithin-industryshiftstypicallyoccur after trade liberalization,which tend to minimizethe dislocationof factors of production.Moreover, the duration of unemploymentfor most industriesis not high, especiallywhere workers were not earning substantialrents in the originaljob. Finally, in many industries normal labor turnover exceeds dislocationfrom trade liberalization,so that downsizing where necessarycouldbe accomplishedwithoutcausingmuch unemployment. 5 It is difficult to disentanglethe effects of trade liberalizationfrom other events occurringsimultaneously,but generallymanufacturingemploymentincreasedsubsequent to the trade liberalization.Thus, while it is necessaryto apply caveats to most of the individualstudies, the collectiveweightof their evidencesuggeststhat adjustmentcosts are low relativeto the gainsfrom trade liberalization.Nonetheless,the extreme poor may be incapableof sustainingeven short periodswith adverseadjustmentcosts, and there may be selectedpoor groupsthat do not gain, while some of those that gain may lose in the short run. In order to minimizeadjustmentcosts and help make trade reform work most effectively for the poor, complementarypolicies are necessary. One important complementarypolicyfor the poor is an efficientsocial safety net (discussedbelow).In general, attaining and sustaining a high rate of economic growth is a key factor in improvingoutcomesfor the poor over time. NKM9-.6t , Emma The first step in designinga strategyto use trade policyfor growthand poverty alleviation is to understandhow the trade regimeworks.This involveslearningof the importanceof non-tariff barriers,includingwho gets the licenses and permits.What is the structure of the tariff and includingits dispersion,exemptionsand rebates?Howmuch revenuecomes from tariffs? What policies are in place which may tax or subsidizeexports?Are traderelated institutions, such as standards organizations,export finance and marketing facilities adequateto support an expansionof exports? Does the pattern of protection favor the incomeof the poor or a segmentof the poor, and may policies be designedto assistthe poorduringthe transition? In this section we describe the principal trade policies and institutions that are employedto influencethe flow of goodsand servicesand suggesthow to evaluatethese. We discusscomplementarypoliciesin later sections. Non-tariff barriersinclude mechanismssuch as quotas, licensesand monopolyrights to import.When these mechanismsare in placefor reasonsother than for health or safety they are the most perniciousof trade barriersin terms of their harmto growth and poverty alleviation.Partly this is because non-tariff barriers encouragecompeting interests to lobbyto obtainthe valuablelicensesto import.This competinglobbyingactivity(knownas urent-seeking") wastesvaluableresources. Non-tariffbarriersalso lack transparency,and thereby may allow protectionto go relativelyunnoticed.As discussedabove, the political economyof protectionsuggeststhat importcontrols(and sometimesexport controls)are usuallyput in placeto benefitpowerfulinterestgroups,not to help the poor. Most low-incomedevelopingcountrieshave differentiatedtariff structureswith significant tariff escalation(Michalopoulos,1999).The main reasonsincludefiscal objectives,import substitution motivationscombined with the political weight of vested interests. Tariff escalationis a problemsince it affordshigh"effective"protectionto final goods producers, thereby discouraging the development of intermediate industries. Exporting of intermediateproductsis an importantway for developingcountriesto participatein the modernglobaleconomy;butthese activitiesare discouragedby the escalationof tariffs. 6 A uniformtariff conveysa numberof advantages(Tarr, 2001),the most important of whichis that if the tariff is uniform,the gainsto industrylobbyingare much smaller(and may be negative), creating a kind of free-rider problem for the lobbying industry and dramaticallyreducesthe incentiveto lobbyfor protection.Chile,which has had a uniform tariff since 1979,is a dramaticcase in point.In Chile,in 1998,the legislatureconsidereda progressivereductionof the uniformtarifffrom 11 to 6 percent,to be accomplishedby one percent per year reductionsthough2003. Chileanindustrygroups supporteda reduction of the tariff, which passed the Chilean legislature. Evidently, uniform tariffs led industrialiststo concludethat a reductionwas in their collectiveinterest. A uniformtariff greatlysimplifiescustomsoperations,eliminatesa numberof ways used to avoid paying the tariff, and should help reduce corruption (which may have positivespillovereffectsinto other dimensionsof governmentactivity)and save on scarce administrativeresources.There will also be a direct saving of resourcesfrom reduced lobbying for higher protection, and an associated gain from encouraging scarce entrepreneurialtalent to be employedmore productivelyin the creation of better and cheaper products.Overall,the level of protectionis likely to be lower as the incentiveto lobby for higher tariffs is attenuated.Many of these factors are pro-poor as they greatly reducethe scopefor the exerciseof powerand rent-seeking. Customs and other officials in low-incomecountries have tended to argue that althoughuniformtariffs look good in theory,implementingsuch a structureis not feasible in practice. This is frequentlya covert argumentfor continued protectionof particular sectors. In fact, in addition to Chile, El Salvador and the Kyrgyz Republic have tariff structureswith very small dispersion,and Hong Kong, Singaporeand Estonia have a uniformtariff of zero. Uniformitydoes not implythat that there can be no exemptionsfor productsthat are deemed to be of great social importancesuch as essentialmedicinesor mosquitonets (Bannister and Thugge, 2001). However,care should be taken that such exceptions targetonly productsthat are criticalto attain socialand publichealthobjectives. 3.3 Emergency Protection, Antidumping and Other Trade Remedies Liberalizationof trade will give rise to adjustment pressures as import competition intensifies.For this reasonreform programsoften reducetariffs and other trade barriers gradually and are ideally complemented by measures to facilitate adjustment (complementaryreforms-see below).However,in some instancesimportsmay expand so rapidly that governmentsmay want to be able to interveneby raising trade barriers. Import surges that create serious difficultiesfor a domestic industry may also occur independentof liberalization.In such cases trade interventionmay be the most effective instrumentavailable to governments.If so, the appropriateaction to take is a so-called safeguardmeasure-the impositionof a temporaryduty againstall importsof the product concerned.A necessaryconditionfor interventionshould be that the domesticindustryis seriouslyinjuredby importcompetition,and a determinationby economicdecisionmakers that protectionis in the nationalinterest(i.e., the associatedcosts to consumersare less than the benefits that would accrue to producers). Safeguard actions should be temporary,lasting no more than 2 or 3 years, as the objectiveis not to raise protection permanentlybut to facilitateadjustmentby the industryto increasedcompetition.It is also importantthat tariffs be used,not quotas,for transparencyand politicaleconomyreasons. 7 Many countriestend to use antidumpingas a safeguard instrument.This is ill advised. Antidumpingis a trade policy instrumentthat allows duties to be imposed on imports that are sold for less than what is chargedin the exportershome market.That is, it can be invoked to offset price discriminationacross markets.Such differentialpricing usuallyreflectseconomicconditions,and is not detrimentalto welfare.As antidumpingis an instrument that is easily captured by industriesto raise the price of imports, and requires the use of scarce administrativeresources,it is counterproductiveto economic developmentand povertyreduction.If there is a needto raise protectionbecauseimports injure domesticindustry,it is preferableto useWTO consistentsafeguardactions, as they allow the country to consider the impact of taking action on the economyas a whole, 8 includingthe poor, as opposedto simply the industrythat confrontsimport competition. Antidumpingprocedurestypically replace considerationsof the national interest or the impact on the poor with an assessmentof pricing practicesof foreignfirms. That is, the question of whether it is in the nation's interestto offer protectionto the industry under considerationfor a duty is neverasked. The best policy optionfrom a developmentperspectivein this area is to have no antidumpinginstrument.If antidumpingproceduresare adopted,efforts should be made to establishproceduresthat allow for the nationalinterestand the impact on the poor to be taken into accountpriorto the impositionof an antidumpingduty. *-I. ___- . Tariffs on imports hurt exports in various ways. Tariffs reduce the demand for foreign exchange, and that tends to appreciatethe real exchange rate. The appreciatedreal exchange rate hurts exportersand competitivenessof nationalfirms as they must pay higher pricesfor their importedintermediates.Prices of labor and capital are also bid up by importcompetingsectorsthat are favoredby the tariff. Programslike duty drawbackand temporaryadmission,if properlyadministered, allow exporters duty-free access to imported intermediates. Although the exchange rate 9 provisionof tariff-freeaccessto bias againstexportsthat resultsfrom protectionremains, imported intermediatesfor exportersis crucial. This is also the case for countries with uniformtariffs,althoughthe needfor duty-freeaccessdeclinesas the averagelevelof the tariff falls. The principalproblem with duty drawbackschemes (involvingthe repaymentof duties paid on imported inputs that are embodiedin subsequentexports) is that their administrationcan be very costly, and leadto cumbersomeproceduresand delays when tariffs are high. Exporterscomplainof delays and lack of re-paymentin many countries. When tariffs are high there is also the risk of fraudulentclaims. The empiricalevidence suggeststhat in countrieswithout well-functioningpublic administrations,duty drawback becomesineffective.They are very difficultto administerat tariff rates in excess of 15 or 20 percent becauseof leakage,delays in paymentand fraudulentclaims (Mitra, 1992). UndertheWTO,safeguards alsorequirecompensation to be offeredto exportingcountriesif the actionlastsmorethan3 years.Thisis a usefulmechanism to ensurethatprotectionis temporary. SeeHoekman andKostecki(2001)for moredetaileddiscussion. 8 In addition,to avoid anti-exportbias, dutydrawbackschemeswouldhaveto be extendedto indirect exportersas well(i.e.,firmswhichdo not exportthemselves but whichsell to exporters). Administration of suchmechanisms arequitecomplicated in practice formostdeveloping countries.. 9 8 Delays are particularlydetrimentalto small and medium enterprisesand small farmer organizations. Temporary admission may be more effective at allowing tariff free access to intermediateinputs for exporters in these situationsas they do not involve payment of duties on importedinputs,but rathera requirementthat firmsdocumentex postthat these inputs have been used in the productionof exports.The major potentialproblemwith this approachin low-incomecountrieswith weak administrativecapacityis so-calledleakage of goods into the economy (that is, the goods are not used for export production).A frequentlyused option to control such leakageis the bondedwarehouse,or on a greater scale, an export processingzone. These are specificterritories that are controlled by customsand where imports are not taxed on entry, but goods are taxed if sold into the domesticmarket.Exportprocessingzonesare discussedfurtherbelow. 3.5 Export Subsidies Export subsidiesmay be appropriateto offset marketfailures, for example,information problems associated with breaking into new markets by individualfirms. In practice, to promoteexports and to offset the anticountrieshave often used them indiscriminately export bias createdby other policies.While theycan stimulateexports,they maydo so at a huge cost to the budget.From a poverty perspectivetheir impact on the poor may be detrimentalas they may result mostlyin rentsto relativelyrich exporters.Using subsidies to offset the negative effect of other policies (such as protection) on exports is inappropriate.Such situations call for the removal of protection and the adoption of instrumentssuch as drawbackor EPZs. DevelopingcountryWTO membershavebecomemore constrainedin the use of export subsidies,but least developedcountriesand countrieswith per capita incomes below $1000 are permittedto use them. This provideslegal coverto pursuepoliciesthat aim to offset informationalasymmetriesand relatedmarketfailures. To be effectiveand not distortincentives,such policiesshouldbe 'horizontal'in nature,not sector-specific. The main problemwith export subsidiesis their use by high-incomecountriesfor agriculturalcommodities.This has a destabilizingeffect on world prices and is highly detrimentalto producersin developingcountriesof the productsconcerned(see below). 3.6 Export Taxes Developingcountriesoften imposeexport taxes on primarycommodityexports.In some casesthese are imposedinsteadof royaltiesfor the extractionof minerals;in others they are used in an attemptto exercisemarketpoweror to supportlocalprocessingindustries. In such casesthere is oftenan adverseeffect on the poor (Box2). Export taxes result in a lower price for the farmers than the prevailing price in world markets for their commodities.Eliminationof the tax will raise the incomes of farmers, the majority of whom tend to be poor, and reduce the profitability of the establishedprocessing facilities. The latter may employ poor urban labor. Examples includecocoaand coffee processorsin West Africathat obtaincocoa and coffeebeansat prices belowthe export price;textile firms in Pakistan,Indiaand FrancophoneWest Africa that obtaindomesticcotton at favorablepricesfrom parastatalexport monopoliesor as a result of export taxes or restrictions;leather processingfirms in India that buy local and 9 partly processedhides at low prices as a result of cascadingexport taxes; cashewnut processors in Mozambiquethat benefit from export taxes on raw cashew nuts; and cashmerewool processorsin Mongoliathat benefitfrom the price reducingeffect of an export tax on raw cashmere. In all these cases the export taxes and restrictionsare economically inefficient because they reduce the incentive to produce the primary agriculturalproductrelativeto the incentiveto processit. In most cases,the net effect on povertyof removingexport taxes and restrictions will be stronglypositive.Thereare manymore poorfarmersthat wouldbenefitfrom export tax removalthan there are industrialworkerswho might lose,and the highestincidenceof the most severepovertyis usuallyfound in rural areas.For example,the cashmereexport tax in Mongoliareducesthe incomesof about250,000goat-herdingfamilies,the majority of which are poor, with the poorest heavily dependenton incomefrom cashmere. In contrast, there are only about 2,000 workers employed in cashmere processing. Moreover,part of the incomethe export tax transfersfrom the goat herdersgoes to the owners of the processingfirms (Filmer,2001; and Takacs, 1994).1iAs is generallythe case, safety net policiesfor those adverselyimpactedby exporttax eliminationshould be carefullyconsidered,especiallywhenthe impacton processorsis severe. Box 2: Madagascar's Marketing Board for Vanilla Exports:Taxing the poor In 1960the internationalmarketfor naturalvanillawas dominatedby Madagascar, the World's lowest cost-producerof high-quality bourbon vanilla. From its dominant position of 60 percent of world exports of natural vanilla, Madagascarorganized the bourbon vanilla cartel with Comoros and Reunion, sefting high export prices and restrictingsupplyby regulatingits domesticmarketthrougha MarketingBoardwhichfixed low producerpricesand requiredlicensesto grow, prepareand exportvanilla. If the MarketingBoardwas to be assessedby the effect it had on export prices of vanilla from Madagascar,it was a clear success.The export price of vanilla increased from US$10in the late 60s to more than US$ 65 per kilo in the early 90s. However,the share of Madagascarin world marketsdeclinedto 30 percent as Indonesia(outsidethe cartel)took advantageof highworld pricesto developa highexport capacity.The entry of Indonesia into world markets left the total value of Madagascar'sexports constant throughoutthe 1970sand 80s. The Board's interventionsin the domesticmarket had a similareffect on producerprices,whichfluctuatedaroundUS$5per kilo duringthe 1980s. Who benefitedfrom the bourbonvanillacartel and the marketingboard'sdomestic policies? Indonesianproducers were the winners, Madagascar'sproducersthe losers. These were small producers (60,000),with an average productionof 130 kilos and an average incomeof US$650per plantation.Estimatesof producerprices that would have prevailed in Madagascarhad the marketingboard been abolishedare close to US$26, well above the US$5 price fixed by the board. Taking into account the increase in production that such a change in prices would have generated, abolitionwould have increasedvanillaproducersurpluseight-fold. '° Muchof cashmereis smuggledout of thecountry.Whilethis avoidsthe tax, herdersstill lose capturemuchof thedifferencebetween worldanddomesticprices. incomeasmiddlemen 10 An alternative to free-trade would have been to eliminate interventionin the domesticmarket,but to continueto exploitmarketpowerin internationalmarketsthrough an export tax. Estimatessuggestthat the optimalexport tax would have been close to US$25per kilo insteadof the US$61implicittax that was imposedon producers. Why where these policiesnot adopted?A possibleexplanationis that taxation of small producersgeneratedan importantincomeredistributionfrom the rural poor to the urbanelite. Source:De Melo,Olarreagaand Takacs(2000). 3.7 Export Processing Zones (EPZs) EPZs are "enclaves"for export production,especiallynon-traditionalexports, that are often used in contextswhereeconomy-widetrade reformis impededor infrastructureand regulatoryrequirementscannotbe met on a nationalbasis. EffectiveEPZs combineclear private property rights and investmentregulations,no restrictionson foreign exchange, tariff free imports for export production, moderate levels of taxation, streamlined administrativeproceduresand privatesectormanagement.Some of the most successful EPZs are in Mauritius where, in 1994, EPZs generated 71% of gross exports and employed 16.6%of the work force. Mexico has also had successfulEPZs. Such zones can not only expand exports, but may also have a significanteffect in raising female employment.Bangladeshzones employ a majorityof women (70% of ChittagongEPZ employeesare women,a much higher ratio than the nationalaverage).In the Dominican Republic,EPZ employmentwas an importantfactor in decreasingthe share of female poorfrom 22.6 percentto 15.8 percentover the 1986-93period(Madani,1999). Experience has shown that development of EPZs, including provision of infrastructureand management,should be privately handled. Publicly developed and managed EPZs have typically been unsuccessful.Attractinginvestmentinto EPZs is a functionof many factors, includingsome that are national-such as politicalstabilityand sound macroeconomicmanagement.An overvaluedexchange rate will discourage exporting from EPZs just as much as from the rest of the economy. In general, the conditionsthat make EPZs successfulinvolvethe same complementarypoliciesthat are required to make a trade reform successful(see below). Consequently,EPZs are best regardedas transitionalmechanismsin the pursuitof an overallliberaltrade regime. 3.8 Other Trade Related Institutions In additionto the commercialpolicy instrumentsdiscussedabove,there are a numberof other trade-relatedinstitutionsthat can have importantimplicationsfor the impactof trade reforms.These includecustomsclearance,exportfinance,productstandardsand access to informationon marketopportunities. Customs Clearanceefficiencyand transparencyis an important determinantof the costs associatedwith trade. Burdensomeand redundantprocedures-red tape-can give rise to substantial uncertaintyand are often associated with rent seeking and corruption. Minimizing discretion by simplifying as much as possible the clearance process,includingthrough adoptionof internationalstandardsfor classificationof goods, elimination of most exemptions (see below) and providing officials with training and appropriateinformationtechnologyare importantdimensionsof trade reform. 11 Export finance is one of the major constraintsinhibiting exports in many low income developingcountries.Inadequaciesmay result from the overall weaknessof the financial sector or may reflect difficultiesin assessing creditworthinessof traders or becausetradersdo not havesufficientassetsto be judgedcreditworthy.To the extentthat the poor are involvedin trading activities,they may face special difficultiesin obtaining accessto the trade credit they need-just as they face such difficultiesin accessingother parts of the financial sector. While ensuringavailabilityof trade finance is a matterthat needs to be left to the private sector, any effort to expand exports and to promote increasedopportunitiesfor the poor in the export sector needs to investigatewhether credit is a problem. Remediesshould be sought as part of overall efforts to increase accessto financefor low-incomeproducers.These are discussedelsewherein the PRSP sourcebook Product standards based on international norms are important to poverty reduction.When standardsare used appropriatelyin internationaltrade (as well as in domestictransactions),they facilitateinterconnectionof goodsand informationexchange, and guaranteesafety, health,qualityor the environment.As the poor have less accessto informationand do not have the resourcesto buy higherqualitygoods and services,they are more dependenton efficientstandardizationand consumerprotectionregimes. In the area of trade,developingcountriesface a dual challenge:on the one hand they need to reformregulationsand establishefficienttesting, certification,and laboratory accreditationrequirementsto minimizethe impact on trade while still attaining sanitary, phytosanitary,and product standards. Low-income developing countries need both technicaland financial assistanceto meetthis objective.Institutionalarrangementsneed to be developedto ensurethat poorfirms (such as farmers,smallproducersand artisans) have access to standards organizations-through co-operativesand similar collective organizations-and are not unduly penalized by the use of labor-intensiveproduction technologies. Marketing of exports internationallyis a challenging task for all low-income countries.They have to overcomeproblemsof lack of information,product and country recognition,and concerns about quality. Foreign partners and FDI can be helpful in providingthe necessarycontactsand advice;but frequentlyit is necessaryto organizea local association of exporters or producers.When the producers tend to be a large numberof small poor farmers, co-operativesand similarventures can be very helpful in ensuringthat the potentialbenefitsfrom exports are realizedby the poor. But competition in these institutionsis importantor poorfarmersmayreceivelower pricesfor their outputs Most developing countries have formed or are members of regional integration agreements(RIAs). From an efficiencyof resource allocationviewpoint, RIAs between developing countries (so-called South-Southagreements) are likely to hurt member countries(WorldBank,2000b).The reasonis that the trade preferencestypicallydisplace efficiently produced low-priced imports from non-partner countries with inefficiently 1 A solutionto this problem is for producedhigh-pricedproductsfrom partnercountries." member countriesto lower their externaltrade barriers,thereby reducingthe inefficient 11 The impactof North-Southor North-Northagreementstends to also involvemoreefficientlypricedimports frompartnercountriesand thus maybe beneficial. 12 displacementof non-partnercountry imports.In fact, a harmfulRIA can be turned into a beneficialone by loweringexternaltrade barrierssufficiently. From the viewpoint of poverty, the effects of an agreement among developing countries are likely to be asymmetric, with the poorer member countries losing significantlyand the higher incomememberslikelyto gain (World Bank,2000b).This is, in part, due to the fact that the relatively developed country produces protected manufacturesthat are importedon balanceby the less developedcountry.With a RIA, the more advancedcountry sells its protectedmanufacturesat a higherprice since its exports are no longer subject to a tariff in the poorercountry'smarkets.This entails a terms-oftrade loss for the poorer country, since it pays a higher price to its partner country for imports it could buy more cheaplyfrom the rest of the world. This problemof asymmetric distributionof gains and losses emerged in the 1960sin the East African Community-where Kenya gained and Tanzania and Uganda lost--and in the Central American CommonMarket-where El Salvadorgained and Honduraslost. In both cases,the more advancedcountry resistedextemal tariff reduction,which led to resentmentin the less developedmembercountriesand a breakdownin implementationof the agreements. Loweringexternaltrade barriersis beneficialboth from the viewpointof efficiency and from the viewpointof minimizingthe losses for the poorermembercountry. In fact, the losses from regionalism,both in overall efficiency and in adverse distributional consequences, can be reduced by lowering external trade barriers. In terms of implementation,in the case of a free trade agreement(such as the plannedFree Trade Agreement of the Americas or the ASEAN Free Trade Agreement),each country can lowerits tariffs independently,and can thus protectitselffrom adverseconsequences.For a customs union (such as the West African Economic and Monetary Union or MERCOSUR),the member countriesmust agreeto jointly lower the common extemal tariff. Thus, customs unions among developingcountries should be approached very cautiously,since tariff policyis taken out of the handsof nationalpolicy-makers. Space constraints prohibit a detailed discussionof the WTO, which has many provisions that constrain the use of trade-related policies by members, including and www.wto.orgfor more developingcountries (Box 3). See www.worldbank.org/trade informationand referencesto the literature.A major dimensionof the WTO that makes it relevant from a poverty perspective is that it provides a potent mechanism for the reciprocal liberalizationof trade barriers. Although most major industrializedmarkets provide preferential access for exports from developing countries, especially least developednations,trade restrictionsremainprevalentespeciallyfor agriculturalproducts, appareland other labor-intensiveproducts. Box3. WTO and PovertyAlleviation The WTO agreementsinvolvelegal commitmentsby governmentsregardingthe rules and policiesthey follow in the conduct of internationaltrade in goods and services. As such, the Agreementscontain no explicit referencesor direct links to policiesaffecting poverty. Their impact derivesfrom the trade policiesthat governmentshave committedto pursue based on their WTO commitments.More than 100 of the 140 WTO members are developingcountries(althoughthe WTO does not define what constitutesa developing nation-this is largelyleft to self-selection).Almostall the 30+ countriesseekingto accede are also developingcountriesor economiesin transition. 13 Within the WTO agreements, developing countries are supposed to receive special and more favorable treatment(usually referredto as "Special and Differential" Treatment)aimed at addressingtheir particularcircumstancesin internationaltrade. The poorest of the developingcountries-the 49 countrieson the UN list of least developed countries (LDCs) are provided with further additional more favorable treatment. The Specialand DifferentialTreatmentprovisionsinvolvefive sets of measures:(a) developing countriesare given moreflexibilityin termsof their own trade policies-e.g. they have not had to reducetheir tariffs significantlyin previousmultilateraltrade negotiationsand they do not have to 'bind' all their tariffs; (b) their exports can be charged lower preferential tariff rates in developedor other developingcountry markets; (c) they are given longer 'transition' periods to implement provisionscontained in some WTO Agreements; (d) developedcountriesare supposedto providethemwith technicalassistanceto help them implement the commitmentsthey have assumed; and (e) developed countries are to implement their WTO commitments in a manner 'favorable' to developing country interests. WTO provisions in general, and those which apply to developing countries in particular,tend to be quite permissivein terms of the trade policies an individualcountry can pursue-and hencedo not tend to constrainthese policiesin ways that would harm the poor. On the contrary,they are on the whole supportiveof trade and foreign direct investment policies that would tend to promote poverty alleviation. Moreover, the availabilityin the WTO of an effectivedisputesettlementmechanismand the guaranteeof MFN treatmentfor all its memberscan be of specialimportanceto developingcountriesin their dealingswith more powerfuldevelopedcountrytradingpartners.Thus, it is important for all developingcountriesto be membersof the WTO. At the same time, the permissivenessof the WTO Special and Differential Treatment provisions has been a problem for LDCs. This has enabled developing countriesto maintain higher levels of domesticprotection,which has harmedtheir own economies.And, export subsidies--often used to offset the disincentivesof protectionare a drain to the budget, and hence are not affordable,and can not be relied upon to provide sustainable,laborintensiveexportgrowththat helpsalleviatepoverty. Source: For more on the WTO, see http://www.wto.org/.Hoekmanand Kostecki (2001) provide a general introduction; McCulloch,Winters and Cirera (2001) focus on the poverty-relateddimensionsof manyWTO agreements. 00. IEIIKO 0=- .0 M 0" Trade liberalizationinvolves reducing discriminationagainst foreign suppliers of goods and services. This is achieved not simply by eliminatingquotas and reducing average tariffs and dispersionacross tariffs, but also by strengtheningtrade-relatedinstitutions,in particularcustomsand standardsbodies.In addition,complementarypoliciesare needed to supporttrade reform. - 09 0 0 -. 1* -R To be sustainedand contributeto an efficientallocationof resources,trade liberalization must be supported by a stable macroeconomicenvironment and a competitive real exchangerate. Trade reform works throughthe transmissionof price signals.These are 14 concealed in a regime of high and variable inflation. Thus, macro-stabilityis a key complementarypolicy.12 A competitivereal exchangerate is also crucialto create conditionsfor continued support of liberal trade policies. With an overvaluedexchangerate, import competing industriesare at a competitivedisadvantage,and this generatespolitical pressuresfor protectionthat are difficult to withstandin the face of rising trade deficits and declining foreignexchangereserves(ShatzandTarr, 2001providea moregeneraltreatment). Initially,trade liberalizationis likely to lead to a trade deficit because the rise in importstends to occur faster than the export supplyresponse.A depreciationof the real exchangerate will help to restorea balancebetweenexports and importssince it makes imports more expensiveand exports are more profitablein domesticcurrency. Under a flexible exchangerate regime,the real exchangerate will adjust throughmarketforces. Undera fixed exchangerate regime,significanttrade reformshouldbe accompaniedby a devaluationof the domesticcurrency.The requireddepreciationis largerthe greater the extent of trade liberalizationand the greater the lags in the supply response (see Appendix). Without recommendingany particulartype of exchangerate regime,we note that some developingcountriesare participantsin a currencyzone, which limitstheir capacity to devalue-an example is providedby the countriesin West and CentralAfrica who are membersof the CFA zone. Due primarilyto currencyovervaluation,in the CFA zone between1986and 1994there was no economicgrowth,whenother Sub-SaharanAfrican countrieswere growingat 2.5 percentannually(Clement,1994).In fact, for some of the CFA countries (e.g., Cameroon, Cote d'lvoire) the overvaluationinduced an output contractionbetween 1986 and 1994comparableto the Great Depressionin the United States(Shatzand Tarr, 2001).A numberof CFAcountriesalsosufferedlargeincreasesin poverty (Devarajanand Hinkle, 1994).After the devaluationof 1994, growth strongly resumed. Some countries seek to maintain a fixed exchange rate through the establishmentof a currency board or some other arrangement(e.g., Argentina and Estonia). In such countries, to contain output losses, trade liberalizationmay have to proceedat a paceconsistentwith the feasiblerate of real exchangeratedepreciation. 4.2 Fiscal Revenueand the Design of Tariff Reform In 1990, collectedtrade taxes as a percentof GDP averaged0.6 percentamong OECD 13 Policy makers in low-income countries and 4.4 percent among non-OECDcountries. countriesmay be concernedthat reformmight substantiallyreducegovernmentrevenue, yieldinglargerfiscal deficits and inducinginflation.While these concernshavesome merit, trade reform need not entail diminished revenues.Many countries have implemented successfultrade reformprogramswithoutsignificantloss of revenue.For example,in the 12 The relativepriceof tradable to non-tradable (or home)goods,Pt/Ph,is typicallyreferredto as the real exchangerate(RER)and is usedas a measureof the competitiveness of the tradable sector.Thereasonis thatseveralof thedeterminants of Ph (suchaswages)affecttheproduction costsof tradables.Oversimplifying for purposes of illustration, supposea govemment runsa fiscal deficitandfinancesit by printingmoney.Theresultinginflationraisespricesin the non-tradable sector.If tradablepricesdo notincreasebythesameamount,inflationlowersPt/Phandthusthe realexchangerate,therebyreducing thecompetitiveness of thetradablesector.SeetheAnnex. 13 Trade taxes as a percent of GDP were: 5.3 percentin Africa,4.4 percentin Asia, and 3.5 percentin the MiddleEast.Ebrillet al. (1999). 15 1990s, Ghana, Kenya, Senegal and Malawi implementedtrade reforms without a significantloss in revenueas a percentof GDP(Ebrillet al., 1999). Perhapsthe foremostreasonwhy trade reformneednot lead to a loss of revenue is that developingcountrieshave traditionallyrelied heavilyon quantitativerestrictionsof imports.Governmentrevenueincreaseswhen quantitativerestrictionsare convertedinto tariffs. Reductionof tariffs should start with the highestones. Also, where tariff rates are very high initially,they will generatelittle or no revenue.Reductionsof the tariffs to more moderatelevels will increaseimports and thus revenues,as the incentiveto smuggle is reduced.Moreover,exemptionsoften are a significantsourceof revenue loss and their reductionincreasestariff collections.Finally,an exchangeratedepreciation,whichshould accompanysignificanttariff reduction,will raise the local currencyvalue of imports and thus tariff revenue. Box4. Summaryof RevenueImpactsof TradeLiberalization ExpectedRevenueImpact TradeReform ReplaceNTBswith tariffs Eliminatetariff exemptions Eliminatetrade-relatedsubsidies Reducetariff dispersion Eliminatestatetradingmonopolies Positive Positive Positive Ambiguous/Positive Ambiguous/Positive Reducehigh averagetariffs Lowermaximumtariff Reducemoderateor low averagetariffs Eliminateexport taxes Ambiguous Ambiguous Negative Ambiguous/Negative Source: Shareret al. (1998). When tariffs rates are already uniform and in the moderateto low range, then further tariff reduction is likely to result in revenue loss. Only in this latter case does revenue representa genuine problemfor trade liberalization.Alternate broad-basedand nondiscriminatoryrevenue sources should be sought, and trade reform sequencedto coincidewith the availabilityof these alternaterevenuesources. Such altemative,broad based tax instrumentswill be more efficient (much less distorting)than trade taxes. For many products,such as alcohol,tobacco and petroleum,collectionof taxes on domestic productionas well as imports will have very low additionaladministrativecosts, and will reduce the incentives to develop inefficient import-substitutingfirms. Even very poor countriessuch as Cambodiahave beenableto introducebroad-basedconsumptiontaxes that reduce dependence on customs duties, and raise much-needed revenues for developmentexpenditures. 1111 -M. "I. .0 Where labor market flexibility is low, reformsto improvethe operationof labor markets shouldaccompanytrade reformsin orderto enhancelabor mobility.For instance,in Peru in the 1980s, a trade reform failed to generateany supply responsebecause of severe labor market rigidities. Labor legislationprohibitedfirms to shed labor, close plants or even change activities.This led to many bankruptcies,contributedto foreign exchange and financialcrises and a failureof the reform(Nogues,1991). 16 The poor are often concentratedin the informalsector and reformswhichincrease labor mobility in the formal sector can have a powerfuleffect on reducingpovertywhen combinedwith trade liberalizationby openingup additionaljobs in the formal sectorfor workerspreviouslyin the informalsector.This was the case in Panama,for example,see World Bank (1999). The mutuallysupportiverelations between trade, macroeconomic, labor market and other policiesmay then serve to increasethe credibilityand payoffsof each. Property rights for land (and water) are also important in coping with needed adjustmentsor taking advantageof export opportunitiesthat may be beneficialto the poor. For example,Egyptcould producelabor-intensivecrops (fruits and vegetables)for export to the EU, as is done in other Mediterraneancountries,and the rural poor could gain significantly(Barresand Valdes,2000).But becauseof the lack of existenceof land (and water) markets,Egypthas not taken advantageof this opportunityand continuesto grow traditionalcrops. 4.4 Competition Policies In manufacturing,pricespaidby poor consumersare affectedby competitiveconditionsin the country. It is possibleto increasethe competitivenessof marketsfor manufactured goods in developingcountries,that is, reducethe markupover the cost of productionby loweringexternalbarriersto internationalcompetitionas well as by reducinggovernment imposedbarriersto entryagainstdomestic firms, Both are importantin providinggoodsto poor consumerswith low monopolymarkups. In small countriesan open trade regimeis especiallycrucial, since there are fewer domesticfirms contestingthe market. In large countries, administrativeand legal barriers againstdomestic entry are relatively more important than in small countries since there are more potential entrants blocked by domesticbarriersto entry(Hoekman,Kee and Olarreaga,2001). Box5. RuralPoverty,Cottonand Parastatalsin WestAfrica In most of FrancophoneAfrica, the nationalparastatalcompanyis the sole authorized purchaserand processorof the farmers' seed cotton, and the sole seller of the joint productsof ginning: cotton lint and cottonseed. It also suppliesinputs to the farmers, owns and operatesall the cottongins, and providesthe transportneededto supplythe inputsto the farms, the seed cottonfromthe farmsto the gins, the lint to the portsor to local textile firms, and the seed to local oil mills or to other markets. It is also responsiblefor the sale of the lint, nearlyall of whichis exported. Cotton has provedto be an economicallyvery efficientcrop and has made major contributionsto the developmentof rural areas,exports,povertyalleviationand growth. The share of cottonlint exports increasedfrom about4 percentof world trade in cotton in the mid-1970sto about 15 percentin 1997.However,the absenceof any competition in the purchaseof seed cotton from farmers has impliedthat farmers have been paid pricesfor their seed cottonthat tend to be far below competitivelevels. In terms of lint equivalent,seed cotton prices in the FrancophoneAfrican countries have generally been withina range of 40 to 50 percentof the export price of cottonlint, comparedto ratios averagingalmost90 percentin Indiaand around80 percentin Zimbabwe. Detailedcomparativeanalysesof costs show that only a small part of the low Francophoneseed cotton prices can be explainedby higher transport and operating costs. More importantare high governmenttaxes (includingspecialtaxes on parastatal profits and export taxes on cotton lint), and implicittaxes from sale of lint to domestic textile firms at low prices and periodic costly managementmistakes and corrupt 17 practices. Simulations suggest that removing this taxation would generate large percentageincreases in seed cotton prices for farmers, varying from 45 percent in Cameroon to 87 percent in Burkina Faso, expand output, and increase real farm incomes.Another problemwith parastatalsis that they typically impose pan-territorial prices wherebythey pay the same price for all locations(and times of the crop year). These subsidiesfor transportand storageeliminatedany incentivefor privateprovision of these services, and resulted in production in socially inefficient locations. The parastatalmonopolyalso preventedthe developmentof privatecredit services. Allowing private firms to provide the services of the parastataland permitting farmersto contractwith privatefirms can be expectedto greatly improveefficiencyand have distributionaladvantagesfor poor farmersin the long run. However,it is important to pay attentionto supportingservicesand markets(such as credit and transportation) duringthe transitionto a marketbasedsystem.It is also possiblethat the eliminationof pan-territorialpricing will have a negativeeffect on poor farmers that are located in isolated regions.As is frequentlythe case, not all will necessarilygain, pointingto the needfor a socialsafety net. Source: Pursell(1998). An important sector in the context of trade reform is distribution. If there are barriers to entry into distribution,those who control this sector may be the primary beneficiariesof trade liberalization,pocketingmuch of what used to be collectedas tariff revenue and not passing the tariff cut on to consumers. In agriculture, parastatal marketingboardsoften stronglyrestrict competitionfor the productsof poor farmers and restrain their incomes (Box 5). Eliminationof the these boards, while paying attention during the transitionthat key ancillaryservices like transportationand credit that these parastatals may be providing continue to be supplied, should benefit the poor. But competitionamongprivatefirms is also important.Thus, exclusivegovernmentlicensesto the private sector should also be avoided so that poor farmers do not have to pay excessiveprices for their inputs or receive monopsonisticallydepressedprices for their outputs. The prescription applies to import monopolies and exclusive distribution arrangements. FDI is an important channel of technology transfer across national boundaries. Multinational corporations account for a large share of the world's research and development,and more than 80 percentof royaltypaymentsfor technologytransfersflow from subsidiariesof foreign companiesto their parentfirms (UNCTAD1997). Econometric evidencetends to supportthe view that developingcountriesreceivingFDI perform better in terms of productivitythan their counterpartsthat are not FDI recipients. What mattersfrom a poverty reductionperspectiveis whether and to what extent FDI has a positiveeffect on the incomes(employment)of the poor and on the prices of what they consume.As far as employmentis concerned,it is importantfrom a short run viewpointthat FDI involve labor-intensiveproductionand result in the transfer of skills throughtraining. Improvementsin communications, transport and informationtechnology, togetherwith globaltrade policyreforms,have madeit much moreattractiveto companies to engage in so-calledoutsourcingand processingtrade, wherethe labor-intensiveparts of production are located in developingcountries. In the 1970s such FDI focused in particular on textiles, more recently it has also includedthe electronicsand auto parts 18 sectors. Such investmentcan be an importantcatalyst for the creation of low skilled employment-as exemplifiedby Mexicoand South-EastAsianeconomies. Given the importanceof low trade costsfor suchactivity,policymakersshouldavoid offering trade protectionto foreign investors,since this will attract the 'wrong' type of investmentfrom an employmentcreationperspectiveby deprivingthe host countryof the benefitsfrom participationin internationalproductionand distributionnetworks.Protection may also result in lossesto the hosteconomyby providingrentsto foreigninvestorsat the expense of domestic consumers.Lall and Streeten (1977:172-174)studied some 90 foreign investments,using a cost-benefitmethodology,and found that more than 33% reduced nationalincome;this was mainlydue to excessivetariff protectionthat allowed high cost firms to producefor the local marketat very highprices,even thoughthey could have been imported much more cheaply. Encarnationand Wells (1986) found that between25-45% of 50 projects studied(dependingon analyticalassumptions)reduced nationalincome;againthe mainculpritwas highprotection. Intellectualpropertyright protectioncan be importantin attractingFDI in sectorsthat rely extensivelyon patent protection,helpingto tilt the focusof investmentprojectstoward manufacturingand away from distribution (Smarzynska,2000). Intellectual property protection is of direct importance to the poor in developing countries, especially for products and sectors that rely heavily on traditional knowledgeand culture, including ethno-botanicals,as well as activitiessuch as writingand performingmusic.The absence of effectiveprotectionof intangibleassetsand intellectualpropertycan havevery adverse consequencesfor the poorthat are either producers(e.g., handicrafts)or the beneficiaries of assetsthat have been built up over time (e.g.,traditionaldesigns,plant varieties).The costs of intellectualproperty rights include the price.increasingeffect of protection.This can have harmfuleffectson the poor by preventingaccessto drugsand keepingpricesfar above the cost of production. As discussed at greater length by Maskus (2001), intellectual property right protectionmust be complementedby trade and competition policyinstrumentsthat serve to offsetthe marketpowergrantedto right holders. 5 Sector Issues In many developingcountries the manufacturingsector has been most protectedas a means of promotingindustrializationand longer term development.A great deal of the analysis regardingtrade reform in earlier sectionsfocuses implicitly on reforms in that sector.However,trade reformsin agricultureand servicesprovidesignificantopportunities for employmentand incomes of the poor as well as reductionsin the costs of their consumption. 5.1 The importance of agriculture Becausethe poor in developingcountriesare oftenlocatedin ruralareas and employedin agriculture,how trade reform affects agriculturewill criticallyaffect its overall impact on poverty alleviation.Agriculturalimportables(mainlystaples)are typicallyprotected,while agriculturalexportablesare often subject to export taxes. Agriculture as a whole has tendedto be taxed indirectlythroughprotectionof the manufacturingsector,overvaluation of the real exchangerate (Schiffand Valdes, 1992,2000),and the operationof marketing boards or similar parastatals (see above). Trade reform, which should cover both agricultureand manufacturing,will thereforetypicallyraiseagriculture'sdomesticterms of trade and help the rural poor. The same is true for improvedmacroeconomicand fiscal 19 policiesthat result in a real exchangerate that is closer to a sustainableequilibrium.In other words, the rural poor will generallybenefitfrom trade reform,evenwhen it includes agriculture. Some of the rural poor,however,maylose. Foremostamongthese to considerare those who are employedor producein sectorsthat are highly protected,low-productivity sectors. Examples include maize in Mexico, wheat in Morocco, and various importcompetingcrops in manydevelopingcountries.If the mobilityof these rural pooris limited, then a reductionin the tariffs in that sectoris likelyto hurtthat sub-group,especiallyin the short term, as prices of their output fall. Over time these losses can be minimizedas farmerschangetheir outputmix and producemore of the crops whosepricesdid not fall. In a study on the Northeastof Brazil,one of the world's poorerregions,switchingto more profitable crops after trade liberalizationand devaluationgreatly reduced negative real income effects for small farmers (Lopez and Romano,2000). Thus, trade liberalization accompaniedby devaluation(seesub-section4.1) can help dampenthe short-termeffect on incomesof the rural poor. The abilityto shift to the productionof new products(possiblyexportableswhose price has risen) may depend importantlyon necessarycomplementaryreforms.Shifting crops may require restructuredlandarrangements,additionalcapitalor accessto water. If marketsfor these factors are poorlydeveloped,farmersmay be unableto take advantage of new opportunities.Thus, complementaryreformsthat focus on these marketsmay be necessaryto help poor farmers. Given that poor farmers may be hurt in the short run, compensationpoliciessuch as improvingrural infrastructure,researchand development, and creating educational opportunitiesfor children are important. These options will almost alwaysbe betterthan protection,as only if farmer'sreturns outsideagricultureare increased will poverty be reduced in the longer term. As far as trade reform itself is concerned, one option to consider is to phase down tariffs in the vulnerable sector graduallyfollowing a pre-announcedschedule.This is what was agreed for the maize sector in the NAFTA negotiationsbetweenthe US and Mexico. Experienceshows that unlessa scheduleof tariff reductionsis pre-announcedand actuallyimplementedfrom the start, reforms with long transition periods (typicallyover five years) lack credibilityand providelobbyistswith time to defeatreform. Fluctuatingworld prices.The liberalizationof a country'sagriculturaltrade policies meansnot only adjustingto loweror highergeneralprice levelsprevailingin international markets,but alsoto the fluctuationsin worldpricesof agriculturalcommodities.In many countries,the impactof these fluctuationson the domesticeconomyis a major motivation for interventionsthat de-linkdomesticandinternationalmarkets.Exportand import controls,governmentcontrolledparastatalsor marketingboards,and variabletariffs all reducethe size of the internationalmarketin whichthe commodityis freely tradedand thus increasethe sensitivityof internationalpricesto exogenousshockssuch as bumper harvestsand crop failures.For example,internationaltrade in rice is equivalentto only 5 percentof world production.Moreimportant,the extentto whichsome of the largest producingand consumingcountries(e.g.China,India, Indonesia,and Brazil)importor export is subjectto discretionarygovernmentcontrols.Policiesby these countriesaimed at stabilizingdomesticpricescan havea very largeimpacton prices in the narrow internationalmarket,in turn leadingto pressuresto maintainor increaseborder interventionselsewhere.For this reason,all countrieshave a commoninterestin reducing the instabilityof world pricesby openingtheir domesticmarketsand removingpolicies whichde-linkdomesticfrom worldmarkets. 20 Althoughpoliciesto open domesticmarkets,especiallyin large countries-both 14 --havethe potentialto substantiallyreducethe amplitudeof developedand developing fluctuationsin worldcommodityprices,these pricesare inherentlyless stablethan the 5 In any case, most world pricesof manufacturedgoodsand the pricesof services." individualsmall countriescannoton their own have any perceptibleeffect on the levelor volatilityof world commodityprices,and needto find the bestway to live with the price swingsthat they mustby and largetake as a given.Consequently,trade liberalizationin any individualcountry,if fully implemented,will often(but by no meansalways)mean that domesticcommodityprices,includingpricesat farm level,will becomemore unstable.16 Farmersin many countrieshave repeatedlyshownthat they can adjustrapidlyand efficientlyto relativeprice changes.For thereto be an overallwelfareimprovementfrom shelteringfarmersfrom pricefluctuations,the extraincomeof the groupsthat benefitfrom interventionsmust outweighthe net economiclossesconsequenton distortedconsumer pricesand changesin the government'sfiscal position.If all changesin income,including governmentincome,are weightedequallyin the decision-makingprocess,the costs of interveningwill alwaysexceedthe benefits.It is generallybetterto targetthe low income groupsthat are hurt with actionsthat increasethe abilityof farmersand workersto switch betweencrops,complementedwith welfareand workfareprogramsuntil a reasonable degree of flexibilityand responsivenessis achieved. In consideringpricestabilizingpolicies,it importantto recognizethat once such policiesare introduced,it is very difficultif notimpossibleto stopthe politicallypowerful from usingthem to shift the averageprice.The commoditymarketingboardsand parastatalmonopoliesin developingcountriesdiscussedpreviouslyoftenstabilizedprices at very low levelsrelativeto worldprices,implyingheavytaxationof smallfarmersand resourcetransfersto governmentsand local processinginterests.This may seriously retardthe growthof economicallyefficientruralindustriesand slow downthe contribution that their expansioncouldmaketo the alleviationof rural poverty.For importsubstitutes, the politicaleconomyforcesgenerallypointin the oppositedirection,and intervention originallyjustifiedin the nameof price stabilization(e.g. price bandschemesintroducedin LatinAmericaduring the 1990s)very oftenbecomede facto price supportschemesthat developa momentumof their own. OECDintervention. Exportsubsidieson productssuch as meat, dairy products and grains, depressprices on world markets,and thus also on the domestic marketsof developingcountries.Some countriessuch as Japan maintainvery high barriersagainst imports of wheat, rice and other agriculturalcommodities.As mentioned,such policies if the marketsfor rice,wheat,sugar,milkproducts,sugarandcottonwereopenin "4 Forexample, Chinaand India,that wouldgreatlyexpandthe sizeof the worldmarketfor theseproductsand shocks(TyersandAnderson,1992). reducetheimpactof variousexogenous from fragmentedworld markets,commodityprice instabilityis associatedwith 15 Abstracting etc. weatherconditions dueto seasonalproduction, inelasticdemand,lagsin supplyadjustments markets(e.g.for sorghumandmaizein inlandareasof Africaand commodity 16 Pricesin domestic of high domesticand from worldmarketsby a combination SouthAsia) that are disconnected marketingcostsand/orrestrictivetradepolicies,mayfluctuatemorethanworldpricesbothwithin and acrossseasons.Linkingthemto world marketsby openingimportscould increaseprice stability,e.g.,bycuttingoff pricepeaksresultingfromcropfailures.Theuseof measuresto control mayalsolead marketconditions importsandexportsin waysthatdo notadjustflexiblyto domestic to higherdomesticpriceinstabilitythan in worldmarkets,or worsestill, to costlyand wasteful A significantportion marketingorganizations. of excessstocksheldbygovernment accumulations of suchstocksoftenarelostto pestsandweather. 21 contribute to world market price instability, constrain exports and increase import competition.While most of the poorest developingcountries produce temperatezoneproductssuch as fruits, nuts and vegetablesthat do not competewith subsidizedand protectedmeat, milk and grains,for some low-incomecountries(e.g., meat productionin Mali or Burkina Faso), and, of course,for middle incomedevelopingcountriessuch as Argentina or Brazil, EU export subsidies are a major factor constrainingagricultural exports. What is the appropriateresponseto such foreign policies? Insofaras prices are forced downward, consumerstend to gain. The impact of the policies on producers dependson whetherfarmerscompetewith subsidizedimports,whetherthe subsidiesvary significantlyover time, whetherfarmers are on average net buyers or net sellers of the commoditiesconcemed,the relativeimportanceof subsistencefarming, and the relative sizes of the rural and urban poor population.If there is no domestic productionof the agriculturalproductsconcerned,there is no needfor intervention,as subsidizedpricesare beneficialto consumers.Mattersare more complexin instanceswherethere is domestic productionof the commoditiesconcerned.It is importantto note that householdsthat are net buyers of the products will gain from subsidies,while subsistencefarmers will be unaffected.The urbanpoor will generallygain insofaras the subsidieslowerprices. Thus, what matters from a policy point of view is whetherthe gains to the non-ruralpoor are largerthan the losses incurred by rural householdsthat are net sellers. To answerthis questionrequirescollectinginformationon the numberof householdsthat are engagedin subsistenceproduction,those that are net buyers,and those that are net sellers.Another importantfactor concernsthe distributionof the laborforce engagedin productionin farms that are net sellers.Those that ownthe landmay lose from lowerprices, but the extent of such losses are bounded(as they may shift to subsistencefarming).While this can imply a severe reductionin real incomes,landlesslaborersworking for net sellers confrontthe most severe potential loss in that they may lose their source of incomewithout having subsistencefarmingto fall back on. In cases of agriculturalsectorswith significantnumbersof householdsthat are net sellersof commoditiesthat are subsidizedby OECDcountries,it is sometimesarguedthat higher tariffs on agriculturalimports are appropriate.This increasesthe domestic price, thus helping to offset the effect of the subsidy and allowing domestic producers to compete.This is akin to 'countervailing'the effect of foreign policies. From the viewpoint of efficiency,whensubsidiesare permanent,such a policyis not desirableas it movesthe structureof protectionawayfrom uniformity,and distortsproducerand consumerchoices. Given the long-lastingnature of interventionby high-incomecountries, countriesshould regardthis as part of the externalenvironment.The implicationis that importingcountry governments should not impose countervailingtariffs.17 However, with the Uruguay Round, multilateral disciplines were strengthened, and it is clear that there will be significant pressureon the EU and other high-incomecountriesto substantiallyreduce protectionand graduallyeliminateexport subsidiesin the comingdecade.Thus, over time 17 A key issueis whetherthe exportsubsidies are permanentor transitory.If the subsidiesare permanent, it willbe in thecountry'sinterestto ignorethe subsidyfor policypurposesbecausethe economiccostsof protectionto the economyoutweighthe benefitsto domesticproducers.If the foreignsubsidyis permanent,thenthe nationalinterestis unaffected by whetherthe priceis low becauseof foreigncomparative advantage or exportsubsidies.If thesubsidiesaretransitory(and thereare capitalmarketor otherimperfections), thereis a casefor temporary protectionfor those tariff lines subjectto competitionfrom subsidizedexportsso that adjustmentcosts can be minimized-see below. 22 the external environment is likely to become less distorted. Insofar as developing countries currently maintain above averagetariffs on the relevant agriculturalimports, there is then a potentialcase not to reducethese as muchor as rapidlyas tariffs on other 8 The reason is that liberalizationcould productsas part of an overalltrade policyreform." give rise to inefficientreallocationof resourcesif there are adjustmentcosts associated with the downsizingof agriculturalproductionfollowingliberalizationand the subsequent expansionas the exportsubsidiesand OECDprotectionare reduced. In practice, however,OECD liberalizationcan be expectedto take a long time, witnesseffortsto do so over the past30 years.Moreover,it will be impossibleto precisely countervailthe impactof foreignpolicieson worldprices;the informationrequirementsfor such a policyare substantial.Accountshould also be taken of the risk that protectionmay become permanent even if the foreign protectionand export subsidiescome off, and, more fundamentally,that trade interventionis a secondbest approachto dealingwith the problem. The best policy is to push for the phase-outof export subsidies and OECD protectionof agriculturein the WTO context,and ensurethat any assistanceprovidedto domestic farmers is designed primarily to target domestic poverty concerns. More generally,whetheror not foreigncountriesintervenein agriculturalmarketsshould not be the focus of policy. Instead, the focus should be on determining how large is the populationthat may lose from trade liberalizationin the short run, that is, net sellers of protectedcommodities. While trade policy is not the appropriatelong-terminstrumentthroughwhich to pursuerural povertyreductionobjectives,it can play a role in three situations.The first is to deal with temporary import surges that have a significant negative impact on the livelihood of poor farmers. In such cases a special safeguard mechanism can be considered, under which temporary protection can be sought if domestic prices of productsthat are of importanceto the poor in terms of productionand employmentfall significantlyin a short period of time due to imports.Whetherthese are subsidizeddoes not matter;what mattersis that there is a seriousdetrimentalimpacton poorfarmers.The generaldesign of any such safeguardmechanismshould conformto the principlesset out in section 3.3 above. The second situationis if the overall policy regime discriminates against agriculture,i.e., policy favors industrialproductionand/or urban consumersof food.While this can be used as an argumentin favor of higher protectionfor poor farmers in low-incomecountries,-theappropriatepolicy is insteadloweringprotectionfor industry and offsetting any prevailingpolicy bias against the rural poor. In contextswhere this cannotbe achieved,or whereit is pursuedgradually,there may be a casefor maintaining higher rates of protectionon agriculturalcommoditieson second-bestgrounds.Third, in situationswhere complementarypolicies(safety nets) are inadequateand a significant numberof the poor are engagedin productionof commoditiesthat are sold domestically, agriculturaltrade policy reformshould be gradual,involvinga pre-announcedscheduleof tariff reductions. Potentialnegativeimpactsof reformin this sectoron net sellerscan be attenuated by accompanyingthe trade reform with a devaluationand implementingcomplementary reformsin marketsfor land, credit and water to enable farmersto take advantageof the new opportunities,adjustto changedincentivesand benefitfrom the reform.Govemment has an important role to play in fostering agriculturaland rural development,including thereis no rationale 18 If agriculture importbarrierscurrentlyare nothigherthanfor manufactures, for raisingthemgiventhatadjustment willalreadyhavetakenplace. 23 through encouraging absorption of new technologies, education and providing infrastructure.Such complementarypolicies are crucial in that they can be critical in addressingthe needsof the rural poor. In all casesthere is a needfor carefulanalysisof the prevailingsituationbefore reformsare pursued.This should focus on identifyingthe balance betweenrural net buyers, rural net sellers,and the urban poor, as well as the importanceof subsistencefarming. A final remark.For the least developedcountries,a key challengeis meetingthe standards and rule of origin requirementsimposed under preferential arrangements granting duty-freeaccess.By allowinggoodsproducedin these countriesto receivehigh prices in major export markets,but goodsto be importedat world prices,they allow the poorest countriesa double benefit. Preferentialaccess providesa positiveincentiveto produce these productsfor sale in the highly protectedmarketsof the OECD countries that grant such access. In effect, the preferentialaccess provides protection to LDC producers in the developed country markets that offer preferentialaccess. As these markets are both vastly larger than their own, and offer very inflated prices due to protection,this mayallowfarmersin LDCsto increasetheir incornesby producingmore of 19 these productsfor export. IMa 17-; 0S Services-which include activities such as transport of goods and people, financial services (banking, insurance) telecommunications,distribution, tourism (hotels and restaurants),construction,as well as educationand health care, account for a rising portion of GDP, in even in the lowest-incomecountries.The importanceof an efficient servicesectorgoes beyondthe contributionof the servicessector itself to the balanceof payments,because the efficiencyof many service sectors is a key determinantof the competitivenessof firms. Key sectors that influencethe ability of firms to participatein world trade are telecommunications, transportation,financialservicesand other business servicessuch as accountingand legal services. The gainsfrom eliminatingbarriersto competitionin the variousbusinessservices can be very large and fundamentallyeffect the country's comparativeadvantage and pattern of trade (Markusen,Rutherfordand Tarr, 2000). As nations reduce barriers to trade in goods, it has become apparent that in many countries, inefficient business services sectors have become the principal barrier to effective integration in world markets. Inefficient provision of trade-supportservices acts as a tax on exporters of merchandisegoods and ultimatelyon growthand poverty reduction.Establishingpolicies that encouragecompetitiveand efficient services sectors,such as allowing entry where possibleand encouragingforeign direct investmentshouldtherefore be a major element of global integrationand povertyreductionstrategies.In particular,projectsthat address restructuringand reform of service sectors should take into accountthe importance of establishinga regulatoryenvironmentthat is contestable. Liberalizationof servicessectorsmeansreductionor eliminationof barriers,where barriers tend to take the form of prohibitions,quantitativerestrictions and regulations (UNCTADand World Bank, 1994). For example,such restrictionsmay prohibit foreign Farmersin middleincomecountriesmayfacedifferentincentives,as theywill suffera decline in demandfor their productsin the EUbecauseof preferentialaccessprovidedonly to the LDCs. t9 24 direct investmentin certainsectors,limit the share of ownershipof foreign firms in these sectors, limit the numberof expatriatesthat can be employed,or restrict the amount of imports of a particular service. Frequentlythe restrictionsapply to both domestic and foreignsuppliersand result in publicsectormonopoliesin the provisionof services,e.g. in air and maritime transport (inclusive port services), telecommunications,or financial services. In many such cases, eliminationof public sector monopoliesmay need to be accompaniedwith openingup of servicemarketsto foreigndirect investment(e.g.through relaxing of provisionsregardingthe right of establishmentof foreign firms) becauseit is the foreign providersthat may be able to provide significantimprovementsin efficiency and cost reductions. There is evidenceof a positiverelationshipbetweenprivate competitiveprovision of telecommunicationservicesand the availabilityof telephonelines at affordable rates. This is especiallytrue in countrieswhere initial conditionsare characterizedby a low teledensityor servicerationing(longwaitinglistsfor obtainingconnections).Simply letting the marketwork can substantiallyimproveaccessin an environmentwhere serviceshave beentraditionallyprovidedby inefficientpublicmonopolies-even in the poorestcountries and amonglow incomeconsumers. For many intemationallytraded goods, the cost of internationaltransportationis higher than the applicabletariff on imports.For a small economyconfrontinggiven world pricesof traded goods, highertransportcosts reduceexport prices and increasesprices of delivered imports. Hence, exporting industrieswith higher transport costs must pay lower wagesor accept lower returnson capital.Amjadiand Yeats (1995)find that freight rates for Sub-SaharanAfrican countriesoften are considerablyhigher than on similar goods originatingin other countriesand thus have contributedto the region'spoor trade performanceover the last decades.High transportationcosts are due in part to anticompetitivepolicies,such as cargo reservationschemesmaintainedby a large numberof African countriesand internationalshippingcartels and legislatedmonopolyprovidersin both industrializedand developing countries (Francois and Wooton, 2001; Fink and Mattoo,2001). Box6. LiberalizingTradein TransportServices Shipping deregulationin Chile started in 1979 and aimed at dismantlinga system basedon cargo reservationprotectionfor the nationalfleet. The core of the reformwas eliminatingrestrictionson foreignshippingcompaniesto supply internationaltransport services. In addition,monopolyrights in cargo loadingoperationsin Chileanseaports were eliminated,allowingthe entry of new privateoperatorsand the developmentof a competitivemarketfor cargo handlingservices.Moreover,the governmenttripledport capacityby obtaininglaborflexibility.It did this by payingthe unionfor the right to use workers not under union contractwhich allowedit to move from a union-constrained eight hour day to 24 hour cargo handling.This led to a significantcost reductionand an increase in exports, particularly the time-sensitiveagricultural exports that are intensive in rural labor. Demand increased especiallyfor female labor involved in picking,sorting,selectingand packingof fruits and vegetables The new status quo provedbeneficialduring the 1981-82economiccrisis, as Chile's exportershad "untrammeledaccessto the internationalshippingmarkets"and were able to supply more price-competitiveproducts.Chileanfruit exportersentered into long-term contracts with international shipping enterprises to ensure regular service, guaranteeing rapid transit and certain timing of delivery, essential requirementson the highlycompetitiveexportfruit market. 25 Denial of access to foreign-ownedtransport companiesto domestic inland routes can also be important in cutting off a region to internationaltrade. China provides an example: exportersfrom inner China typically send goods to ports in a break-bulkform by truck or railway,where the goods are containerizedand shipped. Multinationalcompanies,however,requireaccessto containertransportfrom door-todoor. This multimodal transport requirement cannot be met given low inland penetrationof containers,so that most export industrieslocateon the coast and often import raw materialsand intermediatesfrom abroadrather than sourcefrom mainland China. Lack of competitionwas a major factor: two state-ownedcompanies(SOEs) had around 80% of the marketfor freight forwardingand shippingagencies.Although the governmentallowsmajorforeignshippinglinesto establishfreightforwardingarms in China, they may only handle parent companies'products.Restrictionson shipping agenciesare even more sweeping:governmentrules bar foreignor joint venturefrom enteringthe shippingmarket,limitingit solelyto SOEs. Source: Bennathan(1989)andWorld Bank (1996). The case of Zimbabwe'svegetableexports illustratesthe enormouspossibilities when transport and related services are efficient. In the early 1990s, farmers near the capital have been supplying fresh vegetablesto the London market by picking them, immediatelytruckingthem to the airport, andflying them ovemightto Londonwhere they are on the shelves ready for sale in the morning.This requires cheap and reliable air transport and moderntelecommunications becausethe shipmentsare deliveredto order (Krugman, 1998). In the Maghreb,Amiot and Salama(1996) estimate that eliminating restrictions on ship registry in Morocco could lead to 25% savings on the maritime transport costs for clothingand footwear.All Algerianand Moroccanports, as well as the main ports in Tunisia, are operated by inefficient government-ownedcargo-handling companies,which charge 30% in excess of the rates that would be quoted by a private independentoperator. Licenses required by exporters and importersto charter vessels also create barriersto internationaltrade,since permissionto charteris grantedonly if the national shipping line withdraws.This is estimatedto cost an additional 20% over the usualinternationalfreight rates. Services reformand the poor.Althoughthe poor spend less of their incomeon services than the non-poor, significantbenefits can accrue to the poor from increased efficiency of services markets. Services such as transport, education, and access to communicationsand finance are vital determinantsof the ability of the poor to find employment and market their production.The incomes of the rural poor are strongly dependenton marketingand transportationcosts, and on the efficiencyof transportation networks.Hightransportor marketingcostslowerthe pricesreceivedby poor farmersand raise the prices of food to poor consumers.Competitionin these sectorsis very important to poverty reduction, as are resources devoted to "trade facilitation" to improve the efficiencyof servicenetworksand reducecorruptionand relatedtransactionscosts. Recent research based on household surveys found that farmers' access to a public telephoneis positivelyrelatedto the price they receivein district marketsfor their farm output. Decreasingthe distanceto a telephoneby 10 percentwould lead to a 1.6 percent increase in local prices (Larson, 2000). In Bangladesh villages, women entrepreneursprovide pay phone services at a profit, using mobile cellular technology. Even though rural villagers cannot afford a phone individually,they can afford one collectively(Lawson and Meyenn,2000).A key aspect of servicesliberalizationis that it 26 often involves the movementof factors of productionbecausethe services concerned cannotbe traded.Giventhe structureof factor pricesin poor countries,an inflowof capital through FDI would tend to be to the advantage of the unskilled poor-increasing employmentopportunitiesand wages. Liberalizationof servicesand the resultantcompetitionare likely to lead to lower prices, greater availabilityand improvedquality of services. In so far as the poor are consumersof theseservices,they are likelyto benefit.Butthere is a twist. Frequently,the prices pre-liberalization are not determinedby the marketbut set administratively,and are kept artificiallylowfor low incomeend-users.Thus, rural borrowersmay pay lowerinterest rates than urbanborrowers,and prices of localtelephonecalls and public transport may be keptlowerthan the cost of provision.Thisstructureof pricesis often sustainedthrough cross-subsidizationwithin public monopoliesor through governmentfinancial support. New entrants may focus on the most profitable market segments("cream-skimming"), such as urban areas, where the cost or service provision may be lower and incomes higher. Privatizationcould mean the end of governmentsupport.The result is that even though the sector becomesmore efficientand averagepricesdecline, the pricesfor low 20 incomehouseholdsmayactuallyincreaseand/oravailabilitydecline. Universal service or access goals are not contradictorywith liberalizationof service markets.The handicapof providingservicesto low income householdscan in principlealso be imposedon new entrantsin a non-discriminatory way. Thus, universal service obligations can be part of the license conditionsfor new entrants into fixed network telephony and transport. But recourseto fiscal instrumentshas proved more successful than direct regulation-for example, through universal service funds or subsidiesfor providingservicesin ruralareas.Anothereffectivemechanismis to fund the consumerratherthan the providerthroughvouchers,as has been the case for education and energyservicesin a numberof countries(Mattoo,2001). Assessingservices policy and performance.A careful evaluationof services trade policy requires analysis of the conditionsof competition in a particular sector, notably restrictionson entry; ownershiplimitations,private and foreign; and regulation, especially elements designed to achieve pro-poor outcomes in competitivemarkets. Relevantquestionsfor policy-makersinclude:Howmuch greaterwould the benefitsbe if privatization were accompanied by the introductionof competition?Are there good reasonsto limit entry by policy?What institutionalfeaturespromotethe effectivenessof a sector regulator?What shouldthe regulatorregulate?What are the costs and benefitsof restrictionson foreignownership? In many countries, an assessment of policy and performance in services is frustrated by a dearth of data. Main performanceindicators include price and quality variables and measures of access and availabilityof services to the poor. Detailed templatesfor an assessmentof policyand performancein servicesin a particularcountry 2" These have recentlybeendevelopedby the World Bank for three key servicessectors. can be usedto benchmarkcountriesagainstinternationalexperience. 20 In the caseof agriculturalexportables, increaseddomestictransportefficiencyto the portwill typicallyraise inlandfarmgate prices.This could worsenthe welfare of low incomeconsumersof that productin inlandareas. . air and maritimetransport,andfinancialservicesand are availableat 21 Theycovertelecommunications, http:./wwwl .worldbank.org/wbiep/trade/services.html. 27 * -aIn 0O-reSI One of the most importantcomplementarypoliciesfor the pooris an efficientsocialsafety net. It is highly recommendedthat a programto establisha social safety net be in place independentof the needs relatedto trade liberalization.The best outcomesfor the poor can be expectedwhen as a result of the overall reformprocess,of whichtrade is a part, growthacceleratesin the economyas a whole.Especiallyin the short run, however,there are boundto be some effectson somegroupsof poor who maybe incapableof sustaining even short periods with adverse adjustmentcosts. One needs to be especiallycareful regarding the effects of any reform on the poor, as they are least able to bear risks becausethey do not havethe savings. An important issue that confronts all trade policy reforms then relates to the hardshipfaced by poor workersin import competingactivitieswho lose incomefollowing import liberalization.The policychoicesbroadlydefinedare: employgeneralsocialsafety nets; establish safety nets targetedto those who are harmedby the trade reform; and selectivelimitationof the reformsor interventionin marketsfor the purposeof limitingthe impactof marketreformson the poor. One type of market interventionis based on the view that opening up to world marketswill increase risk becauseworld marketsare typicallyunstable.However,poor countriesare also subjectto largedomesticshocksand it is unclearwhetheropennessto trade increasesrisk. Governmentattemptsto reducethe risk of trade opennessthrough marketingboardsand similarinstitutionsaimedto cushionthe impact of internationalprice fluctuations on producers,especiallythe poor, have often been counterproductive.As discussedabove, many of these agencieshave imposedsignificanttaxes on the poor. Experiencewith these institutionsrevealsthe risksfor the poor of efforts by governments to limit the scope of market reforms,even when these limitationsare intendedfor their benefit. A fundamental problem in using government interventionsthat limit market reforms ostensiblyfor the benefit of the poor is that these interventionsare subject to political lobbying.The poor typicallylack political power, so that political interventionin market processeswill typically result in outcomesthat are even worse for the poor (see above). A variety of efforts are underwayin many countriesto replace parastatalsand 2 2 In low-incomecountries such similar bodies with more efficient, privatesector entities. alternativesmay not be a viable option,however.As notedearlier,complementaryactions may be called,such as improvingand reducingthe cost of educationto poor households. Specializedsafety nets linked to trade reform have a spotty history. In practice difficult to distinguishworkers who are harmeddue to trade reformfrom those who are harmed due to normal turnoveror displacementin an economy.The United States has been providingtrade adjustmentassistance(TAA) to workers displacedby international trade since 1962 (not linked to poverty). The US program provides both monetary compensation(called Trade ReadjustmentAllowances,TRA) and retraining.In the early years of the program,it was found that incomesupportwas typicallyprovidedto workers who were not permanentlyseparatedfrom their employers,i.e., the programwas not well targeted (Corsonand Nicholson,1981).However,changesin the design and monitoring For example,the InternationalTask Force on CommodityRisk Managementseeks to establish marketbased price insurance schemesthat would reduce the price risk farmers (especiallythe poor) have to shoulderin exportingcashcrops. 22 28 of the programin 1982and 1988have resultedin bettertargeting(Deckerand Corson, 1995). The resultsof retrainingprogramsappearto be mixed.When retrainingis required, as in the U.S., it may be ineffective. More generally,the effectivenessof retraining programstends to increase if they are demand driven, so, for example, subsidized apprenticeshipsin the privatesectormay work better than governmentprovidedtraining 23 programs. An alternateapproachto requiringretrainingis to requirethe participationin a job search program.This appearsto increasethe likelihoodof employmentand reduce unemploymentbenefits among recipients (Johnsonand Klepinger, 1991; Decker and Corson,1995). Fundamentally,it is difficult to morallyjustify safety net programsto poor people who are harmeddue to trade reformand denyassistanceto other poor peoplewho suffer equivalentharm from fluctuationssuch as technologicaldisplacementor price changes due to domesticdemandshifts. Consequently,it is bestto employgeneral,country-wide, safety nets to deal with problemslinked to trade reform, rather than establish special safety net programsfor trade relatedproblems.As the main need for the poor during a difficult transitionperiod is likelyto be food, one approachis a time limitedfood subsidy and distributionprogram.Targetinga food subsidy,however,is difficult and where it has been done, it has been subjectto abuse.24 An alternativeis an untargetedsubsidyon inferiorgoods, as has been pursuedin Egypt(Adams,2000), althoughEgypt's program has beenpermanent,not temporary. Direct income support tends to be the most efficient type of social safety net, providedit can be administrativelyarranged.A problemis that it is very hard to identify who actuallyneeds the money and even harderto get it to all those who need it. One approach,whichwas employedsuccessfullyin Jordan,is to providea moneypaymentto all households initially. The programwas subsequentlynarrowedto middle and lowincomefamiliesand finally,to only low-incomefamilies.Becausedistinguishingthe poor from the non-poormay be difficult,workfareprogramsmay be more generallyapplicable, and have been proven effective under certain circumstances(Ravallion, 1999), as individualscan self-identifyfor these programs.The chapterin this Sourcebookon social protectionprovidesmore guidanceon safetynets. In general, as trade reforms are undertaken,the groups of poor which may be adverselyaffectedneedto be identifiedas accuratelyas possibleand provisionsshould be madefor their enrollmentin whateversafetynet programsare availablefor as long as necessary.Clearlysafetynetsare neededto supportthe poorduring a periodof transition which may vary in durationand severitydependingon their age, skills, mobilityand other similarfactors. If there are no general safety netsavailable,they should be installed,not because trade reform demands them, but because they should be an essential componentof a sustainablepoverty reductionstrategy.A practicalproblemis that some poor countriesmay not be able to afford a full-fledgedsafetynet. For the design of trade policyreformthis strengthensthe need both for up front analysis of wherethe poor are locatedin termsof production(income)and consumption,assessingwhichgroupsmay be O'Leary(1995)discussesthe measurementof the effectivenessof labormarket programsin Hungaryand Poland. 24 Subsidiesto consumptionof essentialcommoditieswill often result in a transferof income to the middle and upperclassessincethewealthybuy morein absoluteamountsof essentialcommodities. 23 29 seriously detrimentallyaffected,and determiningwhat types of complementaryreforms would best offsetthese potentiallosses. 1-| *I - Bi - l - *1 - l As discussed above and in the Appendix, in tracing through the impact of trade liberalizationon the poor, it is importantto considerboth the pattern of expendituresand sourcesof incomesof the poor. However,what mattersmost in the shortrun is the impact on incomes.The effectof trade reformon povertyin the longerterm hingesvery much on the growth process-which in turn will dependon a varietyof complementarypoliciesand institutions.In low incomecountries,the key complementarypolicies/institutions that need to be analyzedfall into the following major areas: (a) macro-economic,and especially exchangerate policy; (b) the operationof the marketfor labor, since the poor are often concentratedin the informalsector;(c) the operationof the marketsfor agriculture-which is both a major source of income and accountsfor a large portion of the household expendituresof the poor; (d) access of the poor to trade relatedservices-for example, credit,marketing,transportation;and (e) accessto safety nets. There are of course other issues, such as governance,which are importanthere as well as in other reformefforts. Tools are being developedby the World Bankthat can assist policymakersin identifying 26 What follows provides a "checklist" of the impact of trade liberalizationon the poor. questionsand issuesthat shouldbe consideredin the designand pursuitof trade reform. The basicelementsof a goodtrade policyregimeinvolvepredictability,transparency,and uniformity.The following bullets describe in a nutshell what constitutes a liberal trade policy regime. These provide a benchmarkagainstwhich to judge the prevailingtrade regimeand provideguidancefor the directionof reforms. * No licensing,or other approvals,exceptfor health,safetyand environmentalreasons, and automaticlicensingusedfor statisticalpurposes;no otherQRs. * Low and uniformtariffs. If the tariff is not uniform,it should have little dispersion,with onlya smallnumberof bands.A few sectorswith very high tariffs shouldbe especially avoided. * If tariffs are importantfor revenuegeneration,uniformityimpliesthat the overall level of the tariff should be such as to generatethe revenue required. However,some products-such as alcohol and tobaccoproducts-may be subjectedto high dutiesto raise revenue, as long as equivalent excise taxes are imposed on domestic production. * An efficient customs clearance process with little red tape, that ensurestariff-free accessto intermediateimportsfor exporters. * Only one instrument of contingent protection-a safeguard provision. No antidumping. A moredetailedpresentationof theseguidelinesmaybe foundin Michalopoulos(2001). For a synthesisof availablemethodssee the proceedingsfrom a October2000 conference"Povertyand the IntemationalEconomy",availableat: http:I/wwwl.worldbank.orglwbiep/trade/povertyconf.html. Tools will be postedon this site as they becomeavailable. 25 26 30 * Contestableservice markets-measures to ensure competitionprevails,there is no discriminationagainst foreign suppliers that seek to establish a presence in the market,andthat appropriateregulationis in place. 7.3 Is Trade Reform Needed? A number of questionsare relevantin determiningwhether trade reform should be a priorityand whetherthis will benefitthe majorityof the poor: * * i * * * What is the impactof status quo trade policieson the poor? It is importantto determinethe effect on the poor of the existing pattern of protection/subsidization. Such effects may be positiveor negative,and affectparticularproductsconsumedby the poor or the incomesof a significantnumberof the poor, whethercountry-wideor in a particular region. Taxes or supports for important food staples or inputs to agriculture,in particular,should be identifiedand their incidenceexamined.In those cases wherethe structureof protectionis not beneficialto the poor there is a prima facie case for reform.In those caseswheresome of the poor benefit,an assessment should be made of the relativemagnitudeof the potential lossesand the economywide gainsfrom reform. Are there non-tariff barriersfor reasons other than for health, safety and the environment?To the extentthat significantnon- tariff barriersare present,there is again a primafacie case of a needfor reform-starting with conversionto tariffs.This reform is likely to benefit the poor more than the non-poorsince license recipients typicallycollectrents, are unlikelyto be poor (almostby definition)andthe competition for licenseswastesresourcesthat can be usedproductively. What is the average tariff and how dispersedis it? The more dispersion,the greaterthe differencein treatmentof differentsectorsand segmentsof societyis likely to be, and the greater the urgency for reform. Dispersion often generated by exemptionsand tariff escalationwill lead to high effectiverates of protectionand is likelyto entailsignificantinefficiencies. Is there discriminationagainst agriculture? The overall policy stance affecting agricultureshouldbe determined,startingwith an assessmentof the 'effective'rate of protectionfor this sector comparedto manufacturing-see Schiff and Valdes (1992) for a descriptionof a methodologyto do this. The importanceof agriculturelies in the fact that the rural poor are likelyto accountfor a largeshareof the poor. How well do critical service markets function? Do the poor have access to importantancillaryservicessuch astransport?Do policiesdiscriminateagainstforeign suppliersand leadto highcost, low qualitydomesticsupply?Is entrypossiblein laborintensivesectorssuch as tourism or back-officeservices?Doescompetitionprevail in key 'backbone'sectorssuchas transport,financeand communications? Is appropriate pro-competitiveregulationin place? How efficientis customs?How long does it take to clear a containeror air freight shipment?How doesthis compareto neighboringcountriesandto best practice?How large are 'unofficial'trade facilitationpayments?Is there a functioningdrawbackand temporaryadmissionmechanism? 7.4 Getting There The overall analysis of the trade regime should yield a preliminaryjudgment on the desirabilityof trade reform.Analysisof both the impactof the statusquo policyset and the likelyeffect of alternativereformson the pooris important.The tools to undertakesuch an 31 analysiscan be constructedfor mosteconomies;the basicrequirementsincludedetailed data on imports and exports,the trade barriersthat apply to those goods, household survey information on the consumptionpattem of the poor and the sources of their income,and data on the basic structureof the economy(ideallyan input-outputtable or social accountingmatrix). The basic elementsof a frameworkfor the analysis that is requiredis laid out in the Appendix-practicaltools to undertakesuch analysesare being as they developedby the World Bank and will be posed on www.worldbank.ora/trade 27 becomeavailable. Thisjudgmentshouldbe then reviewedin the lightof the potentialshort-termeffects of trade reformon the poor. If there are possiblenegativeeffects,it is importantto identify the relevant products and sectors early on, in order to help design arrangementsfor dealing with adverse impacts of the reform and develop strategies for developing consensusin their support. Strong government commitmentto the reform is critical. The govemmentshould attemptto explainthe desirabilityfor reformand obtainthe supportfrom some parts of civil society. Obtaining a broad consensusmay be a difficult task. The benefits from reform are likely to be dispersed,uncertainand spreadover time; whereas the private costs of sectorsthat will be facing increasedcompetitionfrom imports will be obvious, nearterm and likelyto be concentratedin powerfulpoliticalgroups. It might appeartemptingto design a pro-poortrade reformby identifyingsectorsthat are importantto the poor-either on the consumptionside or the income side-and singlingout these sectorsfor differentiatedcuts in protection.If, for instance,many poor peopleproducemaize,as in Mexico,it mightseem sensibleto excludethis productfrom a tariff reduction.There are at least two problemswith this approach.One is fundamental and the other relatesto politicaleconomy. Thefundamentalproblemis that trade policyis a single instrument,and a fundamentalprincipleof economicpolicyformulationis that a single instrumentcan not be expectedto addressmultipletargets.The politicaleconomy problem is that, once a highly differentiatedtrade regime is adopted, it is essentially impossibleto stop special interests building a case that their sector deserves special treatmentfor one reasonor another.Returningto the exampleof maize, if we decideto maintainor raise protection,we are likelyto find that there is anotherimportantgroup of poorpeoplefor whom maizeis an importantexpenditureitem. A better approachis to focus on developingtwo different sets of instruments-one, trade policy, focused on providingthe incentivesappropriatefor efficient productionand use of goods and services, and another, distributionalpolicy, focused on alleviating poverty. With this assignmentof instruments,trade policy can be designed using the simple, comprehensible,guidelines for trade policy formulation.A set of distributional instruments will necessarily have a much wider range of dimensions, including investmentsin expandingaccessto education,the provisionof safetynets, and a rangeof infrastructureinvestmentsneededto allow peoplein poorerregionsaccessto the markets and other amenitiesenjoyedby relativelyadvantagedpeople. 27 On this websitethe reader may find the initial efforts whichincludeHarrison,Rutherfordand Tarr (2001) andother papersfromthe Stockholmconferenceon Povertyandthe InternationalEconomy. 32 7.5 Complementary Policies Trade policyreformand institutionalstrengtheningmust be implementedin the contextof a varietyof complementarypolicies.Someof these are generaland some are focusedon makingthe trade policyreformmore likelyto benefitthe poor. Macro-economicstabilizationand a competitiveexchange rate are essential to support greater integrationinto the world markets. Exchange rate depreciationin the beginningof major trade reform programswill facilitateadjustment.Great care must be taken to avoid real exchangerate appreciationat a time of import liberalization.As this is largely determinedby macroeconomicand fiscal policies, it is importantthat these are managedto be consistentwith the trade reform. Markets.If marketsare not competitiveor are missing,trade reformsmay not benefit the poor. Critical obstacles to the operation of market signals must be identified. Questionsthat shouldbe posedinclude: * In agriculture,are prices passed on to farmers,or are there governmentor private intermediarieswhich makelargeprofitsin the sale of farm productsor farm inputs? * More generally,is the reformlikely to destroyexistingmarketsthat are significantfor the poor? Will it allow poor consumerto obtainnew goods? (For further discussion, seeWinters,2000,2001). * Are there seriousimpedimentsof variouskinds(legal,cultural,transportation)to labor mobility? Labor market restrictions,such as prohibitionson firing of workers, often result in an informal labor market sector,with the poor concentratedin the informal sector.Reductionin the restraintsin the labormarket,especiallycombinedwith trade reform,can result in an expansionof the formal sector.This can have a strongimpact on poverty reductionsince the poor will move from the informalto the formal sector with the expansionof demandin the formalsector. - Are there serious financing obstaclesto participationin trade? In the long run, developingan effective financialsystem is a key to development.In the short run, trade-focusedinstrumentssuch as the use of back-to-backlettersof credit may allow some of the most pressingobstaclesto tradeto be alleviated. - Are there serious obstaclesin setting up a business?Competitionmay be impeded because it is difficult to obtain a license to start a new business or to make an investment.Or foreigninvestmentmaybe impeded.The reductionin barriersto entry, especially those imposed by governmentsat various levels, can be expected to improvecompetitionand allow entrepreneursto sell new cheaperimportsto the poor or to provideservices necessaryto bring goods to market. The latter is particularly importantin cases where reformaffects entitiesthat provideancillaryservicesto the poor and may ceaseto do so after reformoccurs.An examplewould be the provision of transport,storageand distributionservicesto farmersby a marketingboard.If there are barriersto entry into such service activities,or entry is unlikelyto occur because the market cannot sustain operations,continuedgovernmentinvolvementmay be necessary. * Are there transportobstaclesto trade? Hightransportcosts make it difficultto engage in trade. Landlockedeconomiesthat are far away from marketsmay have little that they can influence,both becauseof the absenceof direct links and the difficultiesof establishingtransit arrangementsbut sometimesthere are governmentpolicies or institutionsthat can be modifiedwhich would lowertransportcosts. Here again a key test shouldbe whetherentryis feasible. 33 * * In those instanceswhere analysissuggeststhat the marketwill not supplythe needs of the poor or those locatedin outlying regions,there may be a need for universal service regulation. Experience suggests that explicit subsidies to achieve such objectivescan be efficient. Are there serioustrade obstaclesin enteringmajorexternalmarketsor in competition from abroad? Most low income developingcountriesface relatively low traditional trade barriers in external markets,given a variety of preferenceschemes; but there are specificproblemsrelatedto sanitaryand phytosanitarycontrolsin many markets, the threat of contingentprotectionand competitionfrom subsidizedexports in third markets. Trade Related Institutions.Success of trade policy reforms involves a variety of institutionsboth public and private.On the governmentside, an effectiveand non-corrupt Customs Authority is critical to the success of reforms. Other institutions to which particularattentionneedsto be paid in orderto ensurethat trade reformsbenefitthe poor include marketingand export finance.Both are necessaryfor export expansion.In order for the poor to benefit,it maybe usefulto establishorganizationssuch as a co-operatives which can put together large enough shipmentsfrom individualproducers to supply foreign markets; and to be able to obtain financing linked to their exports-which individualpoor farmerscan not. There is a lot of internationalexperienceon these issues, including through the InternationalTrade Centre and UNCTAD in Geneva. Bilateral donorsand multilateraldevelopmentbanks can provide assistancein the design of such programs,as well as financing. Agricultureand the Rural Poor. Key issues where complementaryactions may be required for poor farmers include the availability and cost of education for children; researchand development;and infrastructure,especiallytransport and communications. Unless the opportunitycosts of farm residentscan be raised, they will stay trapped in poverty. 11 1"* . -"11 Existing interest groups, often entrenchedelites benefitingfrom the status quo, may opposereform.And if it is agreed,there will be pressuresto postponeadjustmentas long as possible. Recognizingthat this is the likely environmentin which trade reforms are usually proposed, it is nonetheless,extremelyimportant to investigate in advance the impactof reformson specificgroupsof the poor and to design programsto addressthem. In such a case, the timing of the implementationof trade reformsneeds to be closely linkedto the establishmentof the programsthat dealwith their impacton the poor. Some pointsworth notingaboutsequencingare the following: * If a reformis preannouncedto be implementedover a few years and it is a credible reform, then normal market adjustmentand attrition can be used to eliminate or greatly reduceadjustmentcosts. However,this may come at the cost of the threat of reversalof the trade reforms,as entrenchedinterestswill be grantedtimeto mobilize opposition.A stagedreformthat is scheduledto take morethan five years is not likely to be credible unless it is anchoredin WTO commitmentsor a far-reachingregional trade agreement. * It is important, as noted earlier, to address non-tariff barriersand high tariff peaks earlier ratherthan later. * It is also importantto reducetariffs across the boardduring each stage of a gradual reform.If insteada target is set basedon the tariff average,the tendencywill be to cut 34 * * tariffs only where they cause no immediatedifficultyand leaveall the adjustmentto last. Broadtrade reformsfrequentlymeet with much less politicalresistancethan cuts in protectionto individualsectors.Broadreformshelpthe winnersfrom reformrecognize their potential gains, and tend to reduce the costs even for industries that lose protectionon their output. Waiting for some importantinfrastructureproject to be completed,such as a port facilityor a road, is not usuallya goodreasonto delayreforms. Summingup, not everythingwill be perfectat the start,but some minimum,especially macro-economicstabilityand a competitiveexchangerate, should be in place.The best outcomesfor the poor can be expectedwhen,as a resultof the overallreformprocess,of which trade reformis a part, growthacceleratesin the economyas a whole.That said, it must be recognizedthat the poor are least able to bear risks, and that In the short run there will be lossesfor some groups.Analysisof the status quo and the likely impact of reform on the poor is thereforevery important.Generalsafety nets may not exist or be inadequate in many low-incomecountries. In such situations reforms should not be postponed, but rather should be implementedgradually, following a pre-announced schedule, and complementedby actions to minimize adverse consequencesto the poorestin society.In many casesthis can be doneby directlytargetingtrade policiesthat are currentlyclearlydetrimentalto the interestsof the poor, and ensuringthat the reform processalso considersthe needfor actionin ancillaryareassuchas servicemarkets. 35 * MA.g[ , M. 0r* - A- - S In order to providea schematicoverviewof the variouspossibleeffects of a trade policy reform on the poor, it is useful to distinguishbetween three types of sectors: those producing importable or import-substitutegoods (M), exportablegoods (X) and nontradableor home goods (H), as well as two factorsof production,labor and capital.We assumehere that the only assetof the poor consistsof labor,while the asset owned by the non-poor is capital. The effects of trade policy reform on the poor depend on the consumptionand productionof the poor in these three sectors.The effects also differ in the short and long run. In the short run we assumethat the factors of productionare immobile,while they are mobilein the longrun. ^jlA uj -- - We assumethat the countryconcernedis small--ithas no powerto affect worldprices of tradedgoods-and that labormarketsfunctionwell in the sensethat that nominaland real wagesare flexible.Domesticpricesof M (Pm) andX (Px) dependon their worldprice and on policy variablessuch as the exchangerate and importtariffs. On the other hand, the price of H (Ph) is determinedfundamentallyby domesticsupplyand demand.Allocationof resourcesdependson these three prices.In the long run, resourceallocationdependson 28 relativepricesonly, such as Px/Pmand PxIPh. Trade liberalization(a reductionin tariffs) raises Px/Pm,and laborand capitalhave an incentiveto move from M to X. Whether Pm falls or Px rises makes an enormous differencein the short run and is likely to determinethe successof the reform.This is wherecomplementarypoliciesplaya crucialrole, includingexchangeratepolicy. Suppose the nominal exchangerate (ER) remains unchangedfollowing a tariff reduction.Then Pm falls while Px remainsunchanged,and labor and capital in sector M are hurt in the short run. The groupsthat are hurt are likelyto lobbyfor a policyreversal. Also, though in the long run both imports and exports increasewith a tariff reduction, importstend to increasefaster thanexports,with a likelydeficitin the balanceof trade that may be unsustainable.Boththe pressurefrom short-termlosers and the balanceof trade problemmay result in a failure of the reform.This outcomecan be avoidedor its effects are mitigated by depreciation of the domestic currency. This raises the price of importablesrelative to non-tradables,and helps dampen both the increase in import demand and the decline of labor and capital's nominalincomein sectorM. On the other 29 hand,laborand capitalin sectorX benefitfrom the devaluationsince Px increases. Thus, a policypackageof tariff reductionand currencydepreciationshould make it easier for the factorsof productionin sectorM in the short run and during the transition period, and should dampen the resistanceto the reform. In countrieswith a flexible or floating exchangerate policy, the lower tariff will raise the demand for imports and for foreignexchange.This will raise the priceof foreign exchangeor lowerthe value of the domestic currency. In other words, the exchange rate will depreciate (more units of Withthreenominalprices,thereareonlytwoindependent relativeprices.Forinstance, choosing Px/PmandPx/Ph,thethirdrelativeprice(Pm/Ph) is obtained bydividingPxlPhbyPxlPm. 29 A devaluation has no impacton the relativepricePx/Pmbecausebothpricesincreasein the sameproportion. 28 domesticcurrencyper unit of foreigncurrency).Thisis similarto a devaluationexceptthat it is determinedby the marketand not by the monetaryauthorities.30 The effect of trade reformon the poor also dependson the second relative price PxlPh.That relativepricedependsnot only on policybut also on consumerreactionto the policy since it is determinedby supply and demand. PxlPh also rises following a tariff reduction,thoughless than Px/Pm. When the value of the nominalexchangerate cannotbe changed,a tariff reduction has no impacton Px but lowersPm. This leadsto a shift in consumptionfrom H and X to M, and thus to a reductionin Ph (thoughless than the reductionin Pm). This implies an increase in PxIPh. With a full devaluationequivalentto the tariff reduction,Pm remains unchangedand Px rises by the magnitudeof the depreciation,shiftingconsumptionfrom X to M and H, raising Ph. Px/Ph rises by the exact same amount as in the absence of devaluation. Finally, with flexible exchange rates, the depreciationis less than the reductionin the tariff, so Pm falls, while Px rises.Consumptionshiftsfrom X to H and M, and from H to M, so the net effect on the demandfor H is ambiguous,as is the effect on Ph. Note,however,that Px/Phrisesexactlyas in the othertwo cases. A.2 Effects on real income in the short run The impact of trade reform on the poor in the short run will critically depend on their location in terms of consumptionand production(income),in particularwhetherthey are employed in tradable or nontradableactivities. There are three cases to consider that indicatethetypes of effectsthat may arise: i) Poor employedin the exportablesector.The relativeprice of sectorX increases. Thus, in the short run, as factors are not mobile acrosssectors, the wage rate of labor employedin X increases.On the consumptionside, labor (andthe poor, by assumption) would gain as long as they consumeeither someM or some H or both (sincetheir prices fall). Thus, labor's real income must improve; and the higher the proportionthe poor spend on H and M, the largerthe gains.Thus,the real incomeof labor in X must rise, or remainunchangedin the unlikelycircumstancethat the poor spendtheir entire incomeon the exportableX. ii) Poor employedin the importablesector.If, on the other hand,the poor produce in the importablesector, a tariff reductionwould leadto a declinein the wage of the poor (labor)employedin the importablesector.Howmuch they would lose then would depend on the consumptioneffect:if they spendall their incomeon importables,the incomeand consumptioneffectswould cancelout andthe net effect of trade liberalizationon their real income is zero. However,if they also consumeX and H, they will lose. The expected result is that the poor lose in the shortrun, but their loss is smallerthan the declinein their wages, becauseof the gainsfrom the effect of trade liberalizationon the pricesof things they consume. iii) Poor produceonly in the non-tradablesector.With the declinein the price of H, the wage rate in that sector also declinesby about the same percentage.On the other Thissectionemploysa stylizedandsimpleframework thatabstractsfromthecomplexities which, in practice,are often important.For example,the existenceof unemployment, the presenceof intermediates products etc. 30 37 hand, labor in H also benefitsfrom the lowercost of consumingM and H. It is possible that the impact on the real incomeof the poorrises becausethe cost of the consumption bundlefalls more than their wages. In general,the impacton the real incomeof laborin H is ambiguousand dependson the sharesof M, X and H in the consumptionbasket,and on the responseof the price of H to trade liberalization.The largerthe share of M in the consumptionbasketof the poor, the greaterthe likelihoodthat they will gain. They must gain if they only consume M, they must lose if they only consume X, and they are unaffectedif theyonly consumeH. These results are summarized in the matrix below. Each cell in the matrix representsthe "location"of the poor in termsof productionand consumption.The first sign representsthe effect of trade liberalizationon the incomeof the poor, i.e. the return to their assets (labor).The second sign representsthe effect on their real income due to changesin the cost of their consumptionbasket.Thus a "+" after the "I' sign meansthat the cost of their consumptionbasket has fallenfollowingtrade liberalization.The sign in parenthesisgives the net effect of changes in their nominal income and cost of their consumptionbasketson their real-incomein different"locations".To summarize,the best outcomeis when the poor are employedprimarilyin the exportablesectorX and consume importablegoods M. And the worst outcomeoccurs if the poor are primarilyemployedin sector M and consumeprimarilyexportablegoodsX. Table 1: Locationof the poorand effectsof trade liberalizationin the short-run M Production M X H TotaP -/+(0) Consumption X H -I() -I+(-) Totala -/+(-) +/+(+) +/-(O) +/+(+) +/+(+ -I+(+) ?/+(+) -I-(?/-(-) -I+ (°) ?/+(?) -+? a Thiscolumngivesthe effectsfor the poorthatreceivetheirincomefrom production in onlyone fromthethreesectors. sector,buttheirconsumption basketincludesproducts t Thisrow givesthe effectsfor the poorthatconsumeproductsfromonlyonesector,butreceive theirincomefromthethreesectors. Although the discussionhas focused on trade reform involvingtariffs, in practice reforms often involve the abolition of quantitativerestrictions (QRs) such as import licenses. As discussed above, due to rent-seeking,shifting from QRs to tariffs could significantlyhelpthe poor. In the long run, labor and capital are mobile across sectors. Then, trade liberalization results in a contractionof sector M and an expansionof sectorX. If, as is likely for most low incomedevelopingcountries,M is on average capital intensivewhile X is relatively labor intensive,then, in the new output configurationresults in an increaseddemandfor labor and a higher nominalwage rate. As the prices of M and H fall, labor's real income rises as well. Consequently,while in the short run some labor employedin M loses from trade liberalizationand the impact on labor in H is ambiguous,when factors are mobile, labor in both sectorsgain. Of course,for this to applyto all the poor, labor marketsneed to be integrated.If they are segmented,then some poor could lose, especiallyif they are 38 employedin the import competingsectorand are unableto move.In orderto ensurethat the poor are betteroff followingtrade liberalization,the conditionsaffectingthe functioning of the labormarketare thereforecritical. In the analysispresentedabove,it is assumedthat all factors are fully employed and changesin trade policyare reflectedin changesin relativefactor prices. In practice, and for many of the countriesfor whichPRSPsare being prepared,there may be a large supply of unskilledlabor in the subsistencesector that can be employedat a fixed real wage in the modernsector. Trade reform may have a positiveimpact in this case, not throughincreasein the wagesof the unskilledworkers but ratherby reducingthe amount of unemployedor underemployedin the subsistencesectorand inducingan expansionof the output of the modern sector. Indeed, following the Indian trade reform in 1991, manufacturingemploymentincreasedfaster while wages increasedslower than before the reform(Winters,2000). In mostcases,one can expect a lastingtrade policyreformto have a mixtureof quantityand price effectson the labormarkets.But no matterwhat the situation, labor mobility is essential in order ensure movementof workers from the contracting and expandingsectors. A.4 Sector-specific issues The aboveframeworkis highlystylizedand abstractsfrom manyfactorsthat are important in determiningthe impact of reform on the poor. Such factors include the existenceof imperfect competition and inter-sectoral dependencies.For example, although the agriculturalsectoris generallymadeup of smalland competitivefarms,this is typicallynot the case for marketing and distributionservices. In a number of LDCs, marketing is organizedby public agencies or parastatals,who usually fix producerprices at levels belowworldpricesand do not alwayschangethemin responseto changesin world prices or in exchangerates. For instance,in some of the countrieswhere the devaluationfrom 50 to 100 CFA Francsto the FrenchFranctook place,farm pricesdid not at first increase by the full amountof the devaluation,while the prices of their importedinputs often did, and some of the productsfarmers consumedid as well. This may have had a negative impact on the real income of farmers in the short run. Thus, though the framework developed above is useful in order to understandthe likelyfirst-orderimpacts of trade reform on the real income of the poor, the specificsof each case needto be taken into account. To continue with the agriculturalexample, an issue to take into account is the degree to which farmers consume their own output. The greater the share of own consumption,the smallerthe impact of the reformon the real income of the farmers. If farmers consumeexactly what they produce,then the real incomeeffect of trade reform on them is nil. If farmersare net buyers,it is often arguedthat in that case farmers lose from an increasein the price of the productthey produce.This maywell be the case, but one must also consider that in order to be net buyers, they need to obtain additional income. If this additionalincome is obtainedby working on other farms, real incomeof these farmersneed not decline giventhat nominalrural wageswill tend to increasewith the price of farm products(or increasewith trade reformin the long run). 39 Note:a numberof these papersas well as many othersdealingwith trade policyissues can be downloadedfromwww.worldbank.org/trade. Adams,R. (2000), "Self-targetedsubsidies:the politicaland distributionalimpact of the Egyptianfood subsidy system,"EconomicDevelopmentand Cultural Change, 49(1):115-36(October). Amiot, F. and 0. Salama (1996),"LogisticalConstraintson IntemationalTrade in the Maghreb,"PolicyResearchWorkingPaper1598(May),TheWorld Bank. Bannister,G. and K. Thugge(2001),"InternationalTrade and PovertyAlleviation,"IMF WorkingPaper01/54(www.imf.org). Barres,J.F. and A. Valdes (2000),"Egypt:AgriculturalExport-OrientedStrategy,"World Bank (MNSRE). Ben David, D. (1993), "Equalizing Exchange: Trade Liberalization and Income Convergence,"QuarterlyJournalof Economics,108(3). Bennathan,E. (1989),"Deregulationof Shipping:What is to Be Learnedfrom Chile," WorldBank DiscussionPapersNo. 67, (Washington,DC:TheWorld Bank). and Development:Are Bhagwati,J. and T.N. Srinivasan(1999), "Outward-Orientation RevisionistsRight," Yale UniversityEconomicGrowthCenter DiscussionPaper No. 806. Cadot, O., J. de Melo and M. Olarreaga (2000), "Can Duty Drawbacks Have a ProtectionistBias,"The World Bank,mimeo. Clarette,R. (1989), "The EconomicEffectsof Trade Liberalizationon Philippine Agriculture,"PhilippineReviewof Economicsand Business,vol. 26 (2), 208-235. Coe, D. and E. Helpman (1995), "InternationalR&D Spillovers,"European Economic Review,39, 859-887. Coe, D. E. Helpman and E. Hoffmaister(1997), "North-SouthR&D Spillovers," The EconomicJournal,107,134-149. Corson,W. andW. Nicholson(1981),"TradeAdjustmentAssistancefor Workers:Results of a Survey of Recipientsunder the Trade AdjustmentAssistanceAct of 1974," Researchin LaborEconomics,4:417-469. De Melo, J., M. Olarreagaand W. Takacs (2000),"Pricing Policy Under Double Market Power:Madagascarand the InternationalVanilla Market,"Reviewof Development Economics. Decker, P. and W. Corson (1995), InternationalTrade and Worker Displacement: Evaluationof the Trade AdjustmentAssistanceProgram," Industrial and Labor RelationsReview,48(4):758-774. Devarajan,S. (1997),"Real ExchangeRateMisalignmentin the CFA Zone,"Journal of AfricanEconomies,Vol. 6, No. 1, March,pp. 35-53. Devarajan,S. and L. Hinkle (1994), "The CFA Franc Parity Change: an opportunityto restoregrowthand reducepoverty," Africa Spectrum,29(2), 131-151. Dollar, D. (1992), "Outward-OrientedDeveloping Economies Really Do Grow More Rapidly: Evidence from 95 LDCs, 1976-1985," Economic Development and CulturalChange,40(3),April, 523-544. Dollar, D. and A. Kraay (2001). "Growth Is Good for the Poor," World Bank Policy ResearchWorkingPaperNo. 2587. Ebrill, L., J. Strotskyand R. Gropp (1999),"RevenueImplicationsof Trade Liberalization," InternationalMonetaryFundOccasionalPaperNo. 180. Edwards,S. (1989), "ExchangeRate Misalignmentin DevelopingCountries," The World BankResearchObserver,Vol. 4, No. 1, January,pp. 3-21. 40 Edwards, S. (1993), "Openness, Trade Liberalization,and Growth in Developing Countries,"Journalof EconomicLiterature,31(3),September,1358-1393. Edwards,S. (1998), "Openness,Productivityand Growth:What Do We Really Know?," Economic Journal, 108(March),383-398. Edwards, S. and D. Lederman (1998), "The Political Economy of Unilateral Trade Liberalization:The Caseof Chile",NBERWorkingPaper, no.6510,April 1998. Elbadawi,I. and N, Majd(1996),"Adjustmentand EconomicPerformanceUndera Fixed ExchangeRate: A ComparativeAnalysisof the CFA Zone,"WorldDevelopment, Vol. 24, No. 5, May,pp. 939-951. Encarnation,D. and L. Wells (1986), In TheodoreMoran(ed.),Investingin Development; NewRolesfor PrivateCapital?WashingtonDC:OverseasDevelopmentCouncil. Filmer,R. (2001), TheMongolianCashmereIndustry.Consultantreportpreparedfor the World Bank,mimeo(March). Finger, J.M. and P. Schuler(2000), "Implementationof Uruguay Round Commitments: The DevelopmentChallenge,"WorldEconomy,April. Frankel, J. and D. Romer (1999), "Does Trade Cause Growth?"American Economic Review,89(3), 379-399. Ghura,D. and T. Grennes(1993),"The RealExchangeRate and Macroeconomic Performancein Sub-SaharanAfrica," Joumalof DevelopmentEconomics,Vol.42, No. 1, October,pp. 155-174. Harrison,A. and A. Revenga(1995),"FactorMarketsand Trade Policy Reform,"World Bank manuscript. Harrison,G., T. Rutherfordand D. Tarr (2001),"TradeLiberalization,Povertyand Efficient Equity."Availableat: http:l/wwwl.worldbank.org/wbiep/trade/povertyconf.html. Hinkle,L. and P. Montiel(eds.)(1999), ExchangeRate Misalignment:Conceptsand Measurementfor DevelopingCountries,NewYork: OxfordUniversityPress. Hoekman,B. and M. Kostecki(2001),ThePoliticalEconomyof the WorldTrading System.Oxford:OxfordUniversityPress. Hoekman,B., H.L. Kee and M. Olarreaga(2001),"Markups,Entry Regulationand Trade: DoesCountrySize Matter?,"TheWorld Bank,mimeo. lanchovichina,E., A. Mattoo and M. Olarreaga(2001), "UnrestrictedMarketAccessfor Sub-SaharanAfrica: How much is it worth and who pays?,"World Bank Policy ResearchWorkingPaperNo. 2595, Washington,DC (April). lanchovichina,E., A. Nicita and 1.Soloaga(2000), "Implicationsof Trade Reformon the Distributionof Incomein Mexico,"World Bank,mimeo. Johnson, T. and D. Klepinger (1991), "Evaluationof the Impacts of the Washington AlternativeWork SearchExperiment,"UnemploymentInsuranceOccasionalPaper No. 91-4,WashingtonD.C.: U.S. Departmentof Labor, Employmentand Training Administration. Krueger, A. (1974), "The Political Economy of the Rent-SeekingSociety," American EconomicReview,64(3):291-303(June). Krueger,A. (1983), Trade and Employmentin Developing Countries: Synthesisand Conclusions,Chicago:NationalBureauof EconomicResearchand The University of ChicagoPress. Krueger,A. (1998),"WhyTrade Liberalizationis Goodfor Growth,"EconomicJoumal, 108 (September),1513-1522. Krugman,P. (1998), TheAccidentalTheorist, Norton:NewYork. Lall, S. and P. Streeten(1977),ForeignInvestment,Transnationalsand Developing Countries. Larson,D. (2000),"Crop Marketsand HouseholdParticipation,"World Bank,mimeo. 41 Lawson, C. and N. Meyenn (2000), "BringingCellularPhone Service to Rural Areas," Viewpoint,Note204, TheWorld Bank. Liedholm,C. and D Mead (1995),"The DynamicRole of Micro and Small Enterprisesin the DevelopmentProcess,"GEMINIActionResearchProgramI: Final Report. Lopez, R., Nash, J. and Stanton, J. (1995), "Adjustmentand Poverty in Mexican Agriculture: How Farmers'Wealth Affects Supply Response",Policy Research Workingpaper,no. 1494.TheWorld Bank,Washington,D.C. factor Lopez, R. and C. Romano (2000), "The determinantsof farm revenuesand returns of poorfarmersin Brazil,"mimeo,Universityof Maryland,CollegePark. Lopez,R. and M. Schiff(1998),"Migrationand the Skill Compositionof the Labor Force: The Impact of Trade Liberalizationin LDCs," CanadianJoumal of Economics (May). Madani,D. (1999)," A Reviewof the Roleand Impactof ExportProcessingZones",World Bank,mimeo. Matusz,S. and D. Tarr (2000),"Adjustingto Trade Liberalization,"in Anne Krueger(ed.) EconomicPolicyReform,Chicago:Universityof ChicagoPress,forthcoming. Markusen, J. (1983), "Factor Movementsand CommodityTrade as Complements," Journalof InternationalEconomics14:341-356. Markusen,J, T. Rutherfordand D. Tarr (2000),"ForeignDirect Investmentin Servicesand the DomesticMarketfor Expertise,"NBERWorkingPaperNo. 7700, (May);Policy and ResearchWorkingPaperNo.2413,TheWorld Bank (August). Maskus,K. (2001),IntellectualPropertyin the GlobalEconomy.WashingtonDC: Institute for InternationalEconomics. McCulloch,N., L.A. Winters and XavierCirera (2001),Handbookon Trade Liberalization and Poverty.London:CEPR,forthcoming. Michalopoulos,C. (1999), "'Trade Policy and Market Access Issues for Developing Countries,"PolicyResearchWorkingPaperNo. 2214,World Bank. Michalopoulos,C. (2001),"Rules of Thumbfor Trade Policy," in B. HoekmanP. English and A. Mattoo (eds.), Trade Policy, Economic Developmentand M,ultilateral Negotiations:A Sourcebook,Washington:World Bank,forthcoming. Mitra, P. (1992), "The CoordinatedReform of Tariffs and Indirect Taxes," World Bank ResearchObserver,7:195-218. Moran, T. (1998). Foreign Direct Investment and Development,Washington, D.C., Institutefor InternationalEconomics. Nogues,J. (1991), "Trade,Employment,and Growthin Peru SinceWWII" in Liberalizing Foreign Trade,DemetrisPapageorgiou,Michael Michaely,and Armeane Choski (eds.),Basil Blackwell. O'Leary, C. (1995), "PerformanceIndicators:A ManagementTool for Active Labour Programmesin Hungaryand Poland,"InternationalLabourReview,134: 729-751. Panagariya,A and D. Rodrik(1993),"Political-Economy Argumentsfor a UniformTariff," InternationalEconomicReview. Papageorgiou,D., A. Choksi, and M. Michaely (1990), LiberalizingForeign Trade in DevelopingCountries: TheLessonsof Experience,The WorldBank. Parker, R., R. Riopelle, and W.F. Steel (1995), "Small Enterprises Adjusting to Liberalizationin FiveAfrican Countries,"WorldBank DiscussionPapersNo. 271. Pursell,G. (1998),CottonPoliciesin FranconphoneAfrica,World Bank,mimeo. Ravallion,M. (1999),"Protectingthe Poorin Crisis" PREMNote no. 12. The World Bank, WashingtonD.C. Ravallion,M. and D. Van de Walle, (1991), "The Impact on Poverty of Food Pricing Reforms:WelfareAnalysisfor Indonesia",Journalof PolicyModeling,13:281-99.. 42 Rhee, Y., B. Ross-Larson,and G. Pursell(1984),Korea's CompetitiveEdge: Managing Entryinto WorldMarket.Washington,D.C.:WorldBank. Rodriguez,F. and D. Rodrik (1999), "Trade Policy and EconomicGrowth: A Skeptic's Guide to the Cross-NationalEvidence,"Centre for Economic Policy Research WorkingPaperNo. 2143,London. Rodrik, D. (1998), "Why is Trade Reform So Difficult in Africa," Joumal of African Economies,7,10-36. Rodrik, D. (2000), "Trade Policy Reform as InstitutionalReform," in B. Hoekman, P. English and A. Mattoo (eds.), Trade Policy, Economic Development and MultilateralNegotiations:A Sourcebook.Washington:World Bank,forthcoming. Romer,P. (1994),"NewGoods,Old Theoryand the WelfareCostsof TradeRestrictions," Journal of Development Economics," 43(1): 5-38 (February). Sachs, J. and A. Warner (1995), "Economic Reforms and the Process of Global Integration,"BrookingsPaperson EconomicActivity, 1-118. Schiff, M. and A. Valdes (1992), The PoliticalEconomyof AgriculturalPricingPolicy. Volume 4. A Synthesis of the Economicsin DevelopingCountries, Johns HopkinsUniversityPress. Sen, A. (1981), Poverty and Famines: An Essay on Entitlementand Deprivation, OxfordUniversityPress,Oxford. Sharer,R. and others.(1998),"TradeLiberalizationin IMF-SupportedPrograms,"IMF, World Economicand FinancialSurveys,WashingtonDC. Schatz,H. and D. Tarr (2001),"ExchangeRate Managementand Trade Protection,"in B. Hoekman,P. Englishand A. Mattoo(eds.), TradePolicy, EconomicDevelopment and Multilateral Negotiations: A Sourcebook, Washington: World Bank, forthcoming. Smarzynska,B. (2000), "Compositionof ForeignDirect Investmentand Protectionof IntellectualPropertyRightsin TransitionEconomies,"TheWorld Bank,mimeo. Srinivasan,T.N. (2000), Eight lectures on India's economicreforms, Oxford University Press. Tarr, D. (2001), "On the Design of Tariff Policy: Argumentsfor and Against Uniform Tariffs,"in B. Hoekman,P. EnglishandA. Mattoo(eds.), TradePolicyReformand MultilateralNegotiations:A Sourcebook,Washington:WorldBank,forthcoming. Takacs, W.E. (1994), The Economic Impact of Export Controls:An Application to Mongolian Cashmere and Romanian Wood Products. World Bank, Policy ResearchWorkingPaperNo. 1280(March). Tyers,R. andAnderson,K. (1992),Disarrayin WorldFood Markets:A Quantitative Assessment.CambridgeUniversityPress. UNCTAD(1997),World InvestmentReport:TransnationalCorporations,MarketStructure, and CompetitionPolicy,UnitedNations:NewYork. UNCTC (1992), The Determinants of Foreign Direct Investment. A Survey of the Evidence,UnitedNations:NewYork. Watson,P.. 2000.'ExportProcessingZones:HasAfricaMissedthe Boat? Notyet!,'World Bank,mimeo. Westphal,L.E. (1990), "IndustrialPolicyin an Export-propelledEconomy: Lessonsfrom South Korea'sExperience,"Joumalof EconomicPerspectives,4: 41-60. Westphal,L.E. and K. S. Kim (1977),IndustrialPolicyand Developmentin Korea.World Bank StaffWorkingPaper No 263. Condensedversionsubsequentlypublishedin Bela Balassa and others; (1982), DevelopmentStrategies in Semi-Industrial Economies.JohnsHopkinsUniversityPress. Winters, L. A. (2000), "Trade and Poverty:is there a connection?,"in WTO: Special Studies# 5: Trade,incomedisparityand poverty,Geneva. 43 Winters, L. A. (2001)."Trade Policiesfor PovertyAlleviationin DevelopingCountries,"in B. Hoekman, P. English and A. Mattoo (eds.), Trade Policy, Economic Developmentand MultilateralNegotiations:A Sourcebook,Washington:World Bank,forthcoming. World Bank.(1996)."ContainerTransportServicesand Trade:Frameworkfor an Efficient ContainerTransportSystem."ReportNo. 15303-CHA.(TheWorld Bank). World Bank (1999), PanamaPovertyAssessment:Prioritiesand Strategiesfor Poverty Reduction,Human DevelopmentDepartment,Latin Americanand the Caribbean Region,Washington,DC. World Bank (2000a),World DevelopmentReport:Attacking poverty, Washington,DC. World Bank (2000b),Trade Blocs. A PolicyResearchReport,Washington,DC (June). World Bank (2000c), GlobalEconomicProspects,Washington,DC. 44 Policy Research Working Paper Series Title Author Date Contact for paper WPS2717Bridgingthe EconomicDividewithin RajaShankar Nations:A Scorecardon the AnwarShah Performanceof RegionalDevelopment Policiesin ReducingRegionalIncome Disparities November2001 A. Santos 31675 WPS2718 LiberalizingBasic Telecommunications: The Asian Experience CarstenFink AadityaMattoo RandeepRathindran November2001 R. Simms 37156 WPS2719Is There a PositiveIncentiveEffect from PrivatizingSocialSecurity? EvidencefromLatin America TrumanG. Packard November2001 T. Packard 89078 WPS2720InternationalMigrationand the Global AndresSolimano EconomicOrder:An Overview November2001 A. Bonfield 31248 WPS2721Implicationsfor SouthAsianCountriesSanjayKathuria of Abolishingthe Multifibre WillMartin Arrangement AnjaliBhardwaj November2001 M. Kasilag 39081 WPS2722Japan'sOfficialDevelopment Assistance:Recent Issuesand FutureDirections November2001 J. Mendrofa 81885 WPS2723UsingDevelopment-Orineted Equity HeloMeigas Investmentas a Tool for Restructuring TransitionBankingSectors November2001 S. Torres 39012 WPS2724TropicalBubbles:Asset pricesin LatinAmerica,1980-2001 SantiagoHerrera GuillermoPerry November2001 R. lzquierdo 84161 WPS2725BankRegulationand Supervision: WhatWorks Best? James R. Barth GerardCaprioJr. RossLevine November2001 A. Yaptenco 38526 WPS2726Applyingthe DecisionRights Approachto a Caseof Hospital InstitutionalDesign FlorenceEid November2001 A. Santos 31675 WPS2727HospitalGovernanceand Incentive Design:TheCase of Corporatized PublicHospitalsin Lebanon FlorenceEid November2001 A. Santos 31675 WPS2728EvaluatingEmergencyPrograms WilliamF. Maloney December2001 A. Pillay 88046 December2001 R. Vo 33722 MasahiroKawai ShinjiTakagi WPS2729InternationalEvidenceon the Value Luc Laeven of Productand GeographicDiversity Policy Research Working Paper Series Title Contact for paper Author Date J. MichaelFinger FrancisNg SonamWangchuk December2001 R.Simms 37156 WPS2731An AlternativeTechnicalEducation GladysLopez-Acevedo Systemin Mexico:A Reassessment of CONALEP December2001 M. Geller 85155 WPS2732The UnbalancedUruguayRound Outcome:The NewAreasin Future WTO Negotiations December2001 R. Simms 37156 WPS2730Antidumpingas SafeguardPolicy J. MichaelFinger Julio J. Nogues