Prizes, Patents and the Search for Longitude M. Diane Burton Tom Nicholas Working Paper 16-046 Prizes, Patents and the Search for Longitude M. Diane Burton Cornell University Tom Nicholas Harvard Business School Working Paper 16-046 Copyright © 2015, 2016 by M. Diane Burton and Tom Nicholas Working papers are in draft form. This working paper is distributed for purposes of comment and discussion only. It may not be reproduced without permission of the copyright holder. Copies of working papers are available from the author. Prizes, Patents and the Search for Longitude M. Diane Burton† Cornell Tom Nicholas* Harvard Business School March, 2016 Abstract The 1714 Longitude Act created the Board of Longitude to administer a large monetary prize and progress payments for the precise determination of a ship’s longitude. It is frequently cited to justify the use of prize-based incentives over patents. We use new data on marine chronometer inventors from 1714 to 1939 to examine long run technological development. We show that while the initial prize spurred entry by key inventors and progress payments helped to finance interim R&D, patent usage was also high. We highlight a complex interplay between prizes and patents over the life cycle of the industry. Keywords: Prizes, Patents, Innovation † ILR School, Cornell University 170 Ives Hall Ithaca, NY 14853, USA. Email: burton@cornell.edu * Soldiers Field Road, Boston, MA 02163, USA. Email: tnicholas@hbs.edu. We are very grateful to Steve Broadberry, Zorina Khan, Naomi Lamoreaux, Ramana Nanda and Joachim Voth for comments and to Richard Dunn and Rory McEvoy from the Royal Observatory Greenwich for sharing their expertise on chronometers and for invaluable help with data sources. The Division of Research and Faculty Development at Harvard Business School provided funding. I. INTRODUCTION The race for global trade and maritime supremacy led the Spanish monarchy to offer a prize for the discovery of longitude at sea during the late 1590s, to be followed in the early 1600s by the Dutch Republic’s sequence of prizes for finding “the East and West” (Davids, 2011).1 In response to a prominent navigation disaster and growing demands for a solution to the longitude problem, a 1714 British Act of Parliament created an even larger award.2 Using a prize of up to £20,000 (around £2.5 million today) a commission of adjudicating experts (known as the Board of Longitude) and resources for inventors to engage in experimentation, the government aimed to encourage knowledge accumulation in an area of high social value but relatively low private investment. By the early 1770s following a long and acrimonious dispute with the Board of Longitude, John Harrison (1693-1776) an English clockmaker, was awarded monetary values approximately equivalent to the prize for his marine chronometer innovations.3 The longitude prize is frequently cited in the innovation literature as the most prominent example of a non-patent based mechanism designed to spur technological development (Wright, 1983; Kremer, 1998; Kalil, 2006; Kremer and Williams, 2010; Williams, 2012; Brunt et al., 2012; Moser and Nicholas, 2013; Murray et al., 2014). It has motivated a range of modern prize competitions. For example, the recent X-Prize contests for space innovation, developments in super-efficient vehicles or cost-effective gene sequencing revolve around a substantial monetary award. The America COMPETES Act passed by Congress in 2010 provides Federal agencies with the necessary authority to conduct prize competitions. In the spirit of the 1714 Act, the 2014 Longitude Prize supported by the British government consists of a £10 million prize fund in an 1 Phillip II initiated the prize offer in 1597 which was formalized by Phillip III in 1598 as a prize of 6,000 ducats plus an annual annuity of 2,000 ducats and a gratuity of 1,000 more. In 1600 the States General of the United Provinces of the Dutch Republic offered a prize of 5,000 guilders plus an annual annuity of 1,000 guilders. The Dutch raised the prize amount to as much as 50,000 guilders by 1738, although there is some uncertainty in the historical record concerning the exact amount of the prize award (Gould, 2013, p.12). Assuming this latter amount is accurate, it would be equivalent to about £450,000 today. 2 In 1707 during the War of the Spanish Succession, Admiral Sir Cloudesley Shovell led a fleet of British naval ships back to England from Gibraltar but the fleet lost its position in fog around the Isles of Scilly off the Cornish peninsula of Britain, leading to the loss of four ships and almost 2,000 lives. Also, in July 1713 two mathematicians William Whiston and Humphrey Ditton published an idea in The Guardian newspaper whereby ships in set locations in sea trade channels would explode a mortar at a set height and time to allow location by other ships to be determined by calculating the time elapsing between the explosion flash and the corresponding sound. They also engineered a petition submitted to Parliament seeking to establish an award for a method to establish longitude. 3 It is important to note that the longitude prize was not actually awarded. The monetary amounts given to Harrison represented only a tacit admission that the navigational problem had been solved. 2 effort to solve the problem of global antibiotic resistance. This is an area with substantial social value that has not been addressed through patent-based incentives. Several studies have analyzed the search for longitude in the eighteenth century from an historical or a legal perspective (e.g., Sobel, 1996; Siegel, 2009). Harrison’s efforts are especially well-documented (e.g., Andrewes, 1996). There is considerable debate about the Board of Longitude’s decision to refuse payment to Harrison given that a key member, the Astronomer Royal Nevil Maskelyne (1732-1811) favored “high-science” lunar observation methods relative to Harrison’s “low-science” mechanical solution. On the other hand, we know very little about the process of technological development that led to the navigation challenge being solved. No empirical analysis has been conducted on the inventors who developed marine chronometers or on the relationship between the prize and the patent system. Hence, the longitude prize is commonly referenced in the innovation literature in the absence of hard evidence to support the hypothesis that it is the exemplar case for the superiority of prize-based incentives. Using a new dataset on chronometer inventors this paper examines the effect of the longitude prize focusing on three main areas: the extent to which the Board of Longitude influenced entry and patenting; the propensity of inventors to patent chronometer inventions; and relative changes in the level of chronometer patenting over time. Results from each of these areas underscore a complex interplay between the prize and the patent system over time. Though we cannot pinpoint causality in our empirical analysis, we use a mix of qualitative and quantitative data to provide suggestive evidence for our argument that the development of the marine chronometer over the life cycle of the industry reflected the contribution of multiple inducement mechanisms. In particular we pay close attention to the set of prize and patent-based mechanisms that jointly created an environment which spurred entry and competition by key inventors, provided financing for experimentation and interim R&D, and facilitated the diffusion of ideas. The period we consider from 1714 to 1939 covers the duration of the prize competition under the Board of Longitude, the rise of the industry after technical challenges were overcome as “the British turned the marine chronometer into an object of industrial manufacture and commercial use” (Landes, 1998, p. 171), and its interwar decline when radio signals displaced navigation by chronometers. In other words, we are able to take a long run perspective on the process of technological development. Data were assembled from Chronometer Makers of the World (CMW) compiled by Tony Mercer (1919-2012), the grandson of the founder of Thomas Mercer 3 Ltd., a prominent English watch and chronometer manufacturer established in London in 1858. CMW includes information on individuals, firms and governments active in the marine chronometer industry. CMW entries were hand-matched against a data base containing all British patents granted from 1714 to 1939 to determine the propensity to patent. Our analysis begins by focusing on the Board of Longitude era. The monetary prize offered by the British government spurred entry and led to intense competition by a small group of key inventors, including John Harrison. But the Board could not easily manipulate the direction (lunar versus mechanical solutions) or the timing of technological change. We show this using the Board’s interim progress payments (totaling £52,535 or around £6.6 million today) paid out to inventors in certain years for successful developments, which do not predict entry or patenting. The arrival rate of new inventions was highly uncertain due to the level of technological complexity and the time it took to design, test and manufacture an accurate marine chronometer. We argue instead that the progress payments performed a more valuable function by providing research investment for improvement and experimentation. Harrison’s first marine chronometer (called H1) was completed in 1735 but his final H4 chronometer was not completed until 1759. More generally, we show that the number of active chronometer makers and craftsmen did not peak until the 1870s and 1880s, more than 150 years after the Longitude Act had been passed. This highlights that key aspects in the development of the industry depended on innovation incentives that extended beyond the impetus created by the 1714 prize. The Longitude Act did not prohibit inventors from acquiring patents. In fact, a primary objective of the Board was to ensure the diffusion of knowledge across innovators, which was difficult to achieve if inventors opted to protect their inventions through secrecy. Harrison did not patent his inventions because he was concerned about reverse engineering and the Board expended considerable efforts on encouraging him to disclose the details of his chronometers. Another early entrant, John Arnold (1736-1799), used the patent system, which required disclosure. We find a high propensity to patent among marine chronometer inventors relative to benchmarks in the literature. Although patents can block innovation, an alternative interpretation is that they provide an important basis for the market for inventions to function. Recent research on the British patenting system indicates that patents were privately beneficial by helping inventors to appropriate on the basis of their ideas while at the same time being socially 4 beneficial by promoting the disclosure of useful knowledge (Bottomley, 2014). In line with this perspective we find a high demand for patenting despite the presence of the prize. We also examine the determinants of patenting in the cross section of inventors during, and after, the Board of Longitude era. We confirm econometrically that the prize did not preclude patenting and show that the probability of using the patent system increased with the quality of invention. Finally, we compare marine chronometer patenting to patenting in other technology areas. Time varying estimates show that patent usage spiked during the 1820s, 1830s and 1840s relative to patenting in a control group of scientific instrument patents, before attenuating later in the life cycle of the industry. We link the relative spike in patenting to prize competitions conducted by the British Admiralty at the Royal Observatory in Greenwich, London to promote cumulative improvements to Harrison’s marine chronometer design. This evidence reinforces our argument that the development of the industry from its nascent eighteenth century stage revolved around a complex link between prizes and patents. Overall our findings suggest that the development of the marine chronometer reflected an environment in which multiple innovation incentives were available and adopted by inventors. This heterogeneity is overlooked when the development of the marine chronometer is contextualized as a simple contrast between prizes and patents. We maintain that the prize provided the catalyst for skilled inventors to direct their efforts towards solving the longitude problem because patents alone could not generate sufficient incentives for private investment. As the prize provided a boost to innovation, inventors used patents to secure private returns. Because the patent system mandated inventors to disclose, it simultaneously corrected for a defect in the design of the longitude prize where a lack of disclosure created a barrier to incremental invention. Patenting became even more important as the industry focused on cumulative refinements to chronometers and the design of marketable products. A simple account of award-driven innovation cannot explain our results. Rather, a more complex set of prize and patent incentives influenced the behavior of inventors developing what Mokyr (2010, p.42) describes as “one of the epochal innovations of the eighteenth century”. The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. In the next section we outline in detail the main aspects of the longitude prize and the functioning of the Board of Longitude. Section three describes the dataset and section four presents the results. Section five concludes with an assessment of the broader implications of our results and caveats to our analysis. 5 II. INSTITUTIONAL DETAILS AND ASPECTS OF THE LONGITUDE PRIZE To determine location at sea it is necessary to know both latitude and longitude accurately. However, while the measurement of latitude at the time of the Longitude Act involved using a simple scientific instrument (a sextant) to observe the angle between the horizon and a known celestial object such as the Sun or the North Star, finding longitude was far more complex.4 Although the theory was well-known (every 24 hours the earth turns through 360 degrees, so each 15 degrees of longitude corresponds to a time-difference of one hour) without highly accurate sea-based timekeeping it was impossible to compare the local time with the time at a particular reference point. Longitude could potentially be identified by a variety of celestial methods, such as eclipses of Jupiter’s satellites, but with considerable measurement error. For example, in 1713 Sir Isaac Newton pointed out that the lunar approach of measuring the distance between the moon and a fixed star would establish the location of a ship only to within two or three degrees – about 138 to 207 miles at the equator. This level of error was not much better than navigating by the rudimentary method of dead-reckoning (Gould, 2013).5 In his comments to the committee established by the British government to determine the feasibility of a prize for longitude, Newton suggested that an accurate time keeper was the most promising potential solution.6 Because he also suggested it was unlikely that a watch overcoming formidable technological challenges (coping with variable temperature, pressure and humidity) would ever be constructed, the government created a substantial award for a practicable solution. The Longitude Act of 1714 authorized the following payments to be made to anyone regardless of nationality: £10,000 for a method that could determine longitude within one degree, £15,000 if it was determined within two-thirds of one degree and £20,000 for positioning within half a degree.7 Although it is not known how the government arrived at these “shadow prices” for innovation, the Act created a premier targeted (i.e., ex ante) prize. 4 A sextant measures the angle between two objects. At night, with clear skies, a navigator could determine a ship’s latitude by the angle between the horizon and the North Star. The North Star is directly overhead the North Pole at an angle of 90 degrees north latitude whereas at the Equator it is at zero degrees latitude. During daytime the angle of the Sun above the horizon at noon could be used along with nautical almanacs to correct for the Sun’s declination. 5 Dead-reckoning involves using calculations about direction and distance traveled to pinpoint location, but is complicated by the effects of factors such as wind drift and tide. 6 Newton stated: “[F]or determining the Longitude at Sea, there have been several Projects, true in the Theory but difficult to execute[.] One is by a Watch to keep time exactly[,] But by reason of the Motion of a Ship, the variation of Heat and Cold, Wet and Dry, and the Difference of Gravity in different Latitudes, such a Watch hath not yet been made” (Gould, 2013, p. 13). 7 At the equator each degree of longitude is approximately 69 miles converging to zero miles at the poles. 6 The longitude prize had three key design elements of importance to our analysis. First, the Act created the Board of Longitude, a 23 person body of elites like the President of the Royal Society and the Speaker of the House of Commons, who ultimately met about three or four times a year, typically at the Admiralty Building in London. At the Board’s discretion awards could be made or withheld according to the criteria stipulated in the Act. With majority agreement one half of an award could be paid out, with the remainder held back until the method had been scientifically assessed on a voyage from a British port to a port in the West Indies. Further Acts were passed between 1714 and 1828 to promote additional areas in need of navigational improvement, clarify the powers of the Board and the conditions of the longitude award. Second, the Board of Longitude provided progress payments. The 1714 Act stipulated a sum not exceeding £2,000 could be sanctioned by a quorum of five Board members for inventors making significant breakthroughs or interim research and development, but larger amounts were also paid out. For example, Leonhard Euler (1707-1783) received £300 in 1765 for his contribution to Tobias Mayer’s (1723-1762) lunar tables. Mayer’s widow received £3,000 the same year as a posthumous award for her husband’s work. Importantly, the amounts paid by the Board were counted against the value of the 1714 prize. In Harrison’s case he received £23,050 in a sequence of installments over more than three decades, which included the amount provided to him to construct his chronometers (Gould, 2013, p. 67).8 During its 114 year existence the Board of Longitude spent about £157,000 on items such as salaries for administrators and expeditions. About one-third can be attributed to progress payments and prizes (Howse, 1998). Third, the prize did not substitute for patenting, but rather created an additional layer of incentives on top of the patent system. Notwithstanding the concept of intellectual property was still rudimentary at the time, a means of establishing proprietary rights over invention did exist in Britain (MacLeod, 1988). The 1624 Statute of Monopolies provided the basis of British patent law until the 1852 Patent Law Amendment Act was passed (Alpin and Davis, 2013). Although the 1624 Statute did not require detailed disclosure for a 14 year patent term, by the 1720s comprehensive written descriptions had become the norm and they were widely diffused.9 8 There is some disagreement about the precise amount. Howse (1998, pp. 407-8) documents that Harrison received a total of £22,000 from the Board of Longitude: one payment of £250 in 1737, six payments of £500 each between 1741 and 1760, £1500 in 1762, £1,000 in 1764, £7,500 in 1765 and a final payment of £8,750 in 1773. 9 The famous 1778 Liardet v. Johnson case established that the specification should include disclosures to allow anyone skilled in the art to be able to replicate the invention. 7 Bottomley (2014, p. 28) describes patent specifications as being “diligently prepared, at least from the 1770s” and reflecting “a uniquely reliable corpus of cutting edge technology.” Records of the Board of Longitude reveal the interaction between prizes and patents. Thomas Mudge (1715-1794), who patented the “lever” escapement in 1766, was awarded £3,000 by the Board for design ingenuity and workmanship.10 Thomas Earnshaw (1749-1829) patented his original invention of a “spring detent” escapement through a sponsor, while John Arnold patented a variant of this technology in 1782 (Betts, 1996). Although the origins of the discovery were contentious, both were awarded £3,000 by the Board of Longitude in 1805, the joint highest amount for a mechanical solution, along with the sum paid out to Mudge.11 Generally, the Board was concerned with incentivizing inventors while also ensuring that knowledge was diffused. In that sense allowing inventors to patent had benefits in terms of opening technical ideas up to the public. This is perhaps one of the reasons why the Board declined an offer made by Arnold in 1782 to “buy-out” his patents (Gould, 2013, pp. 113-114). As Harrison opted for secrecy to protect his ideas, the Board was forced to take additional measures to promote disclosure. Following a partially successful trail of Harrison’s H4 to Jamaica and back in 1761-62, a 1763 Act was passed to encourage Harrison to reveal information to make his chronometers fully replicable by British watchmakers.12 Because placing this information in the public domain would disadvantage Harrison, the Act stipulated that no other watchmaker could win the Longitude Prize within a four year time period. In the decades after the 1763 Act was passed, refinements to Harrison’s H4 pocket watch design focused on overcoming obstacles to accurate timekeeping at sea due to variable factors such as heat, cold and lubrication. Manufacturers like Larcum Kendall (1721-1795), who was tasked by the Board of Longitude with replicating Harrison’s design, aimed to produce at a price that was practicable for widespread usage, while Mudge, Earnshaw and Arnold continued with technical improvements to achieve greater accuracy. Earnshaw and Arnold in particular were responsible for more cost-efficient production of pocket and box chronometers in what became “the elite branch of the British watchmaking industry” (Davies, 1978, p. 524). Harrison’s chronometer, or more specifically Kendall’s replica (called K1), was tested between 1771 and 10 An escapement stalls or creates mechanical movement in a chronometer according to a set rhythm. John Roger Arnold received the award since his father died in 1799. 12 The 1763 Act was titled: “An Act for the Encouragement of John Harrison, to publish and make known his Invention of a Machine or Watch, for the Discovery of the Longitude at Sea.” 11 8 1775 on James Cook’s second voyage of discovery and according to Cook’s assessment it had “exceeded expectations” by the end of the expedition (O’Sullivan, 2008, p. 210).13 Logbooks of the East India Company show the use of chronometers for navigation was systematized by the 1790s (Sobel, 1996, p. 162). By contrast, the Royal Navy was a late adopter as lunar distance continued to be the preferred method. Less than 20 naval voyages per year used chronometers before 1815, at a time when the Navy had almost 1,000 ships (Ishibashi, 2013, p. 56) In 1774 Harrison successfully petitioned Parliament and received a final monetary award of £8,750 to supplement the amounts he had already received from the Board of Longitude, yet this represented only a tacit acknowledgement that the longitude problem had been solved. In fact, the same year a new schedule of awards was established under an Act of Parliament that repealed all preceding Acts. A prize of £5,000 was set for a method that could determine longitude within one degree, £7,500 for within two-thirds of one degree and £10,000 for within half a degree.14 That is, the new legislation maintained exactly the same location parameters as the original 1714 Act, but with prize levels set at half the original amounts. Several decades later, in 1818 the Board of Longitude was reorganized. More scientific members from the Royal Society were added and new positions were created including a Superintendent of Chronometers with the responsibility for administering trials at the Royal Observatory in Greenwich. These took place as “premium trials” between 1823 and 1835 with monetary awards for first, second and third place in an attempt to encourage cumulative improvements in chronometer design and accuracy. The trials extended the stringent tests according to scientific standards that the Board of Longitude had first initiated. Nevertheless, and in spite of advances that it had made, critics of the Board argued it was institutionally inept. Most notable among the critics was Member of Parliament John Croker, who was also the First Secretary of the Admiralty, who argued in 1828 that the Board of Longitude “was of no use whatever” (Howse, 1998, p. 405). The Board was dissolved by an Act of Parliament in 1828. III. DATA CONSTRUCTION AND SUMMARY STATISTICS Our empirical analysis is based on a dataset of chronometer inventors compiled from CMW. Pioneers in the lunar approach to discovering longitude are not included in this source, though 13 H1 had been on a short sea trial to Lisbon. The new Act also stipulated that if longitude was determined within given tolerances using solar and lunar methods, the prize award would be £5,000. It also shifted the emphasis from longitude to navigation more generally. 14 9 we do observe progress payments made by the Board of Longitude to those working in this area, which we do utilize in our empircs.15 Variables in CMW CMW represents “a comprehensive list of makers and craftsmen... who worked in the industry, their places of work and dates and serial numbers of their instruments.” Mercer compiled the data using Thomas Mercer Ltd records and a series of supplementary sources including extensive firm archives, records of the British Admiralty and the British Horological Institute, and drawing also on a number of experts in marine history. His data include government end users and public institutions like the British Ministry of Munitions established in 1915, which we exclude in our analysis. This exclusion, plus further data cleaning produced 1,336 observations from the original 1,701 entries in CMW. Table 1 provides descriptive statistics for entry years during the Board of Longitude era (1714 to 1828), the post Board era from 1829 to 1939 and the life cycle of the chronometer industry from 1714 to 1939. Entry and exit are defined in CMW by “dates of occupation” – when activity in the industry first started and then ceased. Although the list includes entry years up to 2006, we truncate the data on the entry side to be between 1714 and 1939 because this is the period for which we have patent data. Moreover, Mercer himself acknowledges a drop in data quality around 1939 as records were lost during the Second World War. Entry and exit are provided in the majority of cases but to maximize use of the data, we linearly interpolated when one of the dates was missing. An active career was around 26 years for individual inventors. By comparison Khan (2015) finds an average career length of 18 years for a pre-1820 cohort of famous British inventors. For firms (just over one third of the data), an active period was about 44 years. Figures 1 and 2 reveal the distributional characteristics of the data over the full non-truncated range of observations in CMW. Prior to the longitude prize being established very few inventors were engaged in this area of technical development. Pre-1714 entrants include Christiaan Huygens (1629-1695), a famous Dutch scientist, mathematician and horologist, who attempted to patent his discoveries in France. He built a marine chronometer in 1660 which used a pendulum and a coiled spring to moderate mechanical movement. This timepiece, however, proved to be 15 Lunar methods were un-patentable but the prize had an important effect on knowledge diffusion through the publication of ideas. Maskelyne argued that improvements in calculations by lunar distance should be made more accessible by including them in a publication, which became the Nautical Almanac. It was first published in 1766 and widely diffused thereafter. 10 erratic in anything but calm seas. It was unable to correct for measurement errors caused by temperature variations and gravity changes at different latitudes (Gould, 2013, pp. 27-30). Even after the Longitude Act was passed entry into the industry was quite protracted. Figure 1 shows that peak activity for the individuals in the data occurred more than a century and a half after 1714. The time scale associated with chronometers is quite distinct. In historical cases like U.S. automobiles or tires, entry and exit dynamics played out over a much shorter interval of a few decades with industry evolution typically characterized by a period of limited and then general entry. In tire manufacturing, for example, Klepper and Simons (2001) document that a peak in the distribution was reached in 1922 by which time 274 firms had entered. At this point the industry was only about 25 years old. The kind of industry evolution shown in Figure 1 indicates that technological development in marine chronometers was a function of long run dynamics that extended well beyond prize-based incentives created in 1714. The reason for this timing was technological complexity. Although Harrison’s dominant design was largely perfected by the 1770s, it took decades of incremental advance to make the chronometer fully accurate, cost effective and commercially practicable. Chronometers consisted of numerous complex parts including a movement, drawn by a weight or spring and an escapement, all of which required significant breakthroughs to be made. Following the growth of the industry during the Board of Longitude era and beyond, the interwar “shakeout” and decline illustrated in Figure 2 were reasonably rapid. This was driven by a fundamental technology shift away from navigation using marine chronometers and towards radio time signals. The longitude prize was a “public reward” that was open to inventors of any nationality. CMWs coverage is global, including chronometer makers like Pierre Le Roy (1717-1785) and Ferdinand Berthoud (1727-1807), two prominent innovators and rivals residing in Paris. Outside of Britain, 23 countries are represented, with the largest concentrations in France, Switzerland the U.S. and Germany. Figure 3 shows the location of the makers and craftsmen within Europe broadly defined. Britain was a significant location accounting for at least 70 percent of the entries with clustering in London, the county of Lancashire, and in cities along the south and northeast coast. These clusters reflected a division of labor in watch making. In 1800 70,000 workers were employed in the industry, mostly in Clerkenwell, London where final assembly took place (New Scientist, 1957). Specialist craftsmen in Lancashire produced tools and partly finished watch movements for the London market. Harrison’s early experiments culminating in 11 H1 were conducted in Barton-upon-Humber, in North Lincolnshire, but fewer than 3 percent of CMW entries were located within 50 miles of there. Harrison moved to London in 1730. Chronometers varied by the quality of craftsmanship. We were able to parse the data based on a quality indicator of the individual or firm listed. According to Mercer (1991, p. ix) “a marine chronometer was of no value whatsoever until it had passed the exacting tests laid down by the British Admiralty.” In 1805 the Admiralty instigated a formal plan requiring that chronometers could only be sold to the public when they had been officially tested. Moreover, the best chronometer makers were permitted to use the prestigious title of “Maker to the Admiralty” which was used in catalogues and advertisements to aid appropriability (Ishibashi, 2013). During the Board of Longitude era, 35 percent of CMW entries supplied the Admiralty with chronometers falling slightly to 27 percent in the post Board of Longitude era. Board of Longitude Awards and other Prize Competitions We matched the names in CMW to individuals who received a Board of Longitude award using the list in Howse (1998). Although the longitude prize was never technically awarded, interim disbursements made by the Board can be thought of as progress payments or awards for exceptional developments. 3 percent of the CMW entries for the period 1714 to 1828 received a Board of Longitude award, with the largest cumulative amount being paid to Harrison. Finally, we coded a dummy variable for whether an inventor received an award at other prize competitions. The Board of Longitude was not the only source of public approbation for innovation. Prize competitions were commonplace during the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries, with a multitude of European, American and Asian industrial exhibitions. Mercer includes biographical details on entries which we augmented with our own literature searches. Table 1 shows 7 to 9 percent of CMW cohorts received a prize for chronometer innovation. For example, Jean Adrien Philippe (1815-1894), a French horologist who co-founded Patek Philippe & Co., received a gold medal at the 1844 French Industrial Exposition. Matching to Patent Data We identified patent usage by hand matching CMW names to a comprehensive dataset of British patents, including those granted in Scotland, which had its own separate registration system for patents prior to 1853.16 We matched by the title of the invention and by name in order 16 Ireland also had its own separate registration system prior to 1853, but most of the records no longer survive. 12 to get as close a correspondence as possible between the invention and inventor. Because the cost of obtaining a patent was high (by the middle of the nineteenth century a patent could cost £120 in England and as much as £350 in Scotland and Ireland) liquidity constrained inventors had the option to patent through a sponsor or an agent, who would sometimes have their own name on the patent.17 Although we made every effort to correct for such instances, our method will lead to a downward biased estimate of the propensity to patent because of this practice. We find that 15.9 percent of inventors patented their technical discoveries during the Board of Longitude era (Table 1) rising to 18.9 percent if we exclude all foreign domiciled inventors. In the post-Board of Longitude era for entry cohorts after 1828, the figures are 18.1 percent and 20.3 percent respectively. Either way, these shares are much larger than the 9.6 percent patenting rate observed for all inventors exhibiting scientific instruments at the Crystal Palace Exhibition in 1851 (Moser, 2012, p.55), a category that would include chronometers. Furthermore, the propensity to patent was even higher among the best inventors. 63 percent of inventors who received a Board of Longitude progress payment patented. This can be compared to 15.8 percent of award winning inventors exhibiting scientific instruments at Crystal Palace who patented. At a time when it was common for inventors not to patent, chronometer inventors appear to have disproportionately protected their technical developments using formal measures. Clearly, the longitude prize did not preclude patenting and in the rest of the paper we explore this aspect of the competition and its implications in more detail. IV. EMPIRICAL STRATEGY AND RESULTS The Effect of the Board of Longitude on Entry and Patenting We first examine entry and patenting in relation to incentives for innovation created by the Board of Longitude. A key requirement of a prize competition is that it stimulates competitive entry. It is reasonable to assume that the 1714 longitude prize met this objective. Harrison was motivated by the prospect of winning and the most prominent horologists of the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries were incentivized to discover a solution to the longitude problem. Moreover, the contest was not restricted to experts, so it was associated with a specific type of entry dynamics. Its design was analogous to the modern crowd sourcing tournaments examined by 17 Thomas Earnshaw could not afford to patent given that fees were so high. He received financial assistance from a watchmaker, Thomas Wright, who used his own name to patent Earnshaw’s escapement invention. Even by the middle of the nineteenth century patent fees were about four times larger than per capita income (Khan, 2005, p. 31). 13 Boudreau et al., (2011). They show that if the problem to be solved is particularly difficult, opening up to a broad array of entrants can elicit the production of high-value long-tail ideas beyond what could be achieved by restricting the tournament to domain experts alone. Widespread entry meant that the longitude prize attracted practically-oriented inventors like Harrison, not just experts in celestial methods. Qualitative accounts indicate that the announcement of the longitude prize encouraged entry and competition. An important additional issue is the extent to which prize administrators can influence the timing of entry through the certification of particular areas of innovation (Kalil, 2006). Given the richness of the data available from the Board of Longitude era, we can implement a test. We use the monetary amounts paid out by the Board to inventors for successful experimentation as a proxy for “certification” of particular approaches. The first payment of £250 was made to Harrison in 1737 for his H1 and H2 chronometers. We consider awards in aggregate and we also distinguish between awards for “mechanical” and “lunar” methods. While it is often argued that the Board was against mechanical solutions, Figure 4 shows that by around the 1770s it was vested in this area of development. If these awards created incentives, we might expect to see a response in the data through an effect on entry rates and patenting. To gain a better understanding of how the progress payments functioned, we exploit time series variation in awards to determine if these predict changes in entrants and chronometer patents. We use variants of the following specification where t indexes time and AWARD is the logarithm of monetary awards. We allow awards to influence our outcome measures with a one period lag, though all of our results are robust to including longer lag structures as well. We also use a one period lag of the outcome variable as an additional control, which helps to mitigate omitted variable bias under the assumption that unobserved factors that would influence entry (such as common trends) will be correlated with the prior year outcome. OUTCOMEt 1 AWARDt 1 2OUTCOMEt 1 t Results in Table 2A are from negative binomial regressions given the count distribution of the outcome measures. Baseline estimates suggests a positive relationship between awards in the prior year and entry in the current year. Column 1 shows a statistically significant relationship between progress payments and entrants, implying that a 10 percent increase in awards at time t1 is associated with a 1.1 percent increase in entry at time t. The coefficient on awards in column 14 2 is also statistically significant when controlling for lagged entry. That is, the Board of Longitude progress payments have explanatory power even in the presence of natural dynamics where the previous level of entry activity is a strong positive predictor of current entry. However, when we disaggregate the award payments into “mechanical” and “lunar” components the regressions produce counter intuitive results. We would expect entrants into the chronometer industry to respond positively to changes in mechanical awards if there was any Board of Longitude certification effect, but the relationship is actually negative in columns 3 and 4. By contrast, in columns 5 and 6 we find positive and statistically significant coefficients on variables measuring lunar awards. When conditioning on both award types in the same specification in columns 7 and controlling for dynamics in column 8, the pattern in the coefficients remains the same. In column 9 we take the additional step of restricting the entry count to only CMW entries domiciled in Britain and include covariates controlling for British real GDP and population using the data provided by Broadberry et al., (2015). Yet we still find no systematic evidence of a link between entry and the Board of Longitude payments. Figure 5A shows that there is no observable relationship present in the raw data. Neither do we detect any economically meaningful associations when we use chronometer patents as an outcome variable in Table 2B. We find no evidence of a statistically significant effect of awards on patents in columns 1 or 2. And when using mechanical and lunar awards as predictors (columns 3 to 8) the coefficients are also imprecisely estimated. In a similar way to the entrant specifications, we find the most important determinant of current period patents in these regressions to be prior period patents. In fact it is only the autoregressive terms in the specifications that have any statistical power. Column 9 uses real GDP and population controls and the coefficients remain imprecisely estimated. Even a parsimonious model does not generate a statistically significant coefficient on mechanical awards. Figure 5B plots the raw relationship between patents and mechanical awards, again showing no evidence of a systematic pattern. There are two potential explanations for these null results. First, the level of technological complexity associated with chronometer innovation meant the arrival rate of entry and patents was highly uncertain. This is consistent with the protracted pattern of entry shown in Figure 1, where over a century and a half elapsed from 1714 to the industry reaching its peak. Entry and patenting may have been subject to some degree of path dependency set in motion by the announcement of the 1714 prize, but the Board of Longitude did not determine the direction of 15 innovation or the timing of entry and patents beyond this point in time. Second, we are generating null results because the confidence intervals are wide and not because of a precisely estimated zero effect. The spread in the confidence interval is plausibly driven by idiosyncrasies in individual behavior. Some inventors may have been strongly impacted by these progress payments, whereas for others the entry and patenting decision was probably more stochastic. We suspect that the results are at least partly a reflection of this underlying heterogeneity. This is not to say that the progress payments were irrelevant. To the contrary, they performed a central role by providing financing for intermediate research and development efforts and for experimentation. As Macleod (1988, p. 193) points out, “without the grants made him by the Board… it is most unlikely that Harrison could have perfected his chronometer.” The effect was not confined to Harrison. The Board awarded the horologist Thomas Mudge £500 in 1777 for further experiments associated with precision watchmaking. In that sense the payouts functioned more like modern government procurement contracts with progress payments, or “advance market commitments” where R&D funding is often allocated in step-by-step increments (Kremer and Williams, 2010). These types of stimulus may be more likely to affect the intensive margin of technological development. This would help to explain why our regression specifications reveal no effect of progress awards on the extensive margin of entry and patenting. Inventor-level Correlations with Patenting Next, we turn to the cross-sectional analysis of patenting at the inventor-level for the Board of Longitude and the post-Board eras. For each of the CNW entries we constructed an indicator for patent usage. Although we do not exploit the timing of patenting with respect to awards given the limited number of observations we have, Figure 6 shows that pre- and post-award patenting were both possible. While around two-thirds of patenting occurred roughly contemporaneously with an award, patenting either side can also be observed in the data. For example, Arnold first patented in 1775, four years after he received a Board of Longitude award, whereas Earnshaw patented in 1783, 17 years prior to his first award. These observations indicate that there was not a simple sequential relationship between prizes and patents. Indeed, insofar as the progress payment awards were made by the Board for intermediate innovation and R&D, it may have been optimal for inventors to patent ideas at these different stages of the technology cycle. Beyond this basic descriptive evidence, we can enhance our understanding of the factors that were correlated with the discrete decision to patent. We use variants of the probit specification 16 below where i indexes inventors. We measure awards using both the logarithm of monetary values received and an indicator variable coded 1 for an award and 0 otherwise. PRIZE is an indicator for awards received in other prize competitions, which provides us with a benchmark for comparing the propensity to patent for longitude award winners. BL is coded 1 for inventors entering the chronometer industry in the post-Board of Longitude era (i.e., after 1828) to control for any changes in the propensity to patent by specific cohorts of inventors. We use a vector of control indicators (X) to identify the geography of inventors (Britain is coded 1), firms versus individual inventors and whether or not an inventor was a “Maker to the Admiralty.” Pr(Patent 1) 1 AWARDi 2 PRIZEi 3 BLi X i i Table 3 presents estimates of marginal probability effects. The use of patents by chronometer inventors during the Board of longitude era was increasing in the monetary value awarded. The estimates in column 1 show that a doubling in the award value is associated with an increase in the probability of patenting of 4.7 percent. The economic magnitude of this estimate remains approximately the same when controlling for other covariates in column 4. A discrete change had a much larger effect. Column 2 shows that wining an award is associated with an increase in the probability of patenting of 49 percent, which is robust to including controls in column 5. A sense of the economic magnitude of the discrete change estimates can be gained by a comparison to the coefficients for prize winners at other competitions. The longitude award effect in columns 2 and 4 is much larger than the other prize winner effect in columns 3 and 5 – it is about 4 times larger in column 7 when the effects are jointly estimated. Furthermore, in column 7 the longitude award coefficient is statistically larger than the prize coefficient under a Wald test (χ²=4.08, p=0.044). A plausible explanation is that the Board of Longitude effectively screened for quality. Evidence from industrial exhibitions shows that high quality inventors tend to win prestigious prizes and have a higher probability of patenting (Moser, 2012). Perhaps surprisingly we do not find a statistically significant effect on patenting for inventors located in Britain, under the assumption that it was easier to manage complex patent filing procedures domestically as opposed to from abroad (Khan, 2005). On the other hand, given that patent agents could facilitate transactions from overseas and London was the main center of the watch making industry during this time period, even foreign inventors would have had incentives to protect their intellectual property rights against expropriation in this geographic area. 17 We do not detect any differences between individuals and firms in terms of patenting probabilities, but we do find that inventors designated as a “Maker to the Admiralty” were more likely to patent. During the late eighteenth and early nineteenth centuries the Admiralty’s demand for chronometers increased and it put in place an institutional framework (including using the Royal Observatory at Greenwich as a store of government-owned time pieces) to ensure the supply of marine chronometers to Navy captains (Ishibashi, 2013). To the extent that being a “Maker to the Admiralty” reflected a coveted standard of excellence, the estimates suggest that patents were positively associated with the quality of technological discovery. Finally, we find limited evidence of a change in the probability of patenting conditional on entry cohort. In column 8 we do not find any statistically significant interactions on variables measuring inventors entering the chronometer industry in the post-Board era. Although, the main effect of the Board of Longitude variable across the specifications is positive and sometimes statistically significant, it is always economically small. This is consistent with the statistics shown in Table 1 where the share of inventors patenting only marginally increases over time. Changes in the Chronometer Patents Relative to other Technology Areas The last component of our analysis examines the changing role of patents over the life cycle of the chronometer industry. Although we have shown that the propensity to patent was high among inventors engaged in this technology area, this does not mean that the level of patenting was also high. The propensity to patent is an intensive measure whereas we are also interested in changes along the extensive margin. Figure 7 illustrates a striking pattern. A small number of chronometer patents (an average of 0.13 per year) were granted during the Board of Longitude era, but the use of patents increased substantially to an average of 2.30 patents per year in the period from the Board’s dissolution in 1828 to 1939. Towards the end of the time period the number of patents granted began to fall. One explanation is that patents became more important in the post-Board era due to commercialization efforts and cumulative improvements to the chronometer’s design. As the industry faced relative decline, patents became less important. Of course, the changes in patents shown in Figure 7 may also be driven by contemporaneous demand shocks or patent policy reforms. An average of 46.5 British patents were granted per year during the Board of Longitude era compared to an average of over 8,100 per year between 1828 and 1939. In an attempt to explore drivers of the trends in Figure 7 in a more robust framework, we construct a panel to compare changes in chronometer patents to patents in two 18 technology areas. First, we benchmark chronometer patents against all British patents and second (because variation in demand conditions or the rate of technological development may fundamentally differ across industries) we construct a more closely comparable technology area consisting of only scientific instrument patents. In the absence of an official concordance of individual patents to technology categories for our time period, we follow the procedure outlined in Brunt et al., (2012) and use keywords to identify these inventions from patent titles.18 We use negative binomial difference-in-differences specifications to measure relative changes in the level of patents. This allows us to account for different baseline rates over time and to control for the general upward trend in patenting. Due to the length of the timespans being considered in Figure 7, we do not use a single post-period setup but rather allow for flexible time-varying estimates. Given that we observe a small number of yearly patents in the data for some of the time period, we collapsed the observations into a dataset of decade-level means.19 In the specification below j indexes technology categories and t indexes time. CHR is an indicator coded 1 for chronometer patents and 0 for patents in the comparison category and TD represents time period decade dummies. The technology area fixed effect ϕj captures any systematic time-invariant differences in patenting across technology areas, while the time fixed effect γt controls for unobservable factors such as variation in the cost of accessing a patent that may have caused changes in patenting across all technology areas. PATENTSjt 1CHRj TDt j t jt Figure 8 plots point estimates and 95 percent confidence intervals for δ1 from the 1800s to the 1930s relative to a baseline from the 1710s to the 1790s. Compared to all British patents in Figure 7A we find no evidence of a change in chronometer patents until the 1870s when the coefficients turn strongly negative. Relative to scientific instrument patents (Figure 7B) we also observe negative effects from the 1890s, but the estimates are positive and precisely estimated 18 We derived list keywords from publications such as Gerard L’Estrange Turner’s, Scientific Instruments 15001900. These are: accelerometer, ammeter, amperage, anemometer, armillary, astrolabe, barometer, caliper, calorimeter, catheter, chartometer, circumferentor, clinometer, dental, dipleidoscope, dynamometer, eidograph, electrometer, electroscope, ellipsometer, graphometer, gravimeter, hodometer, hygrometer, inclinometer, interferometer, kaleidoscope, lithotomy, magnetograph, magnetometer, manometer, micrometer, microscope, nocturnal, ohmmeter, opisometer, optical, oscilloscope, pantograph, pedometer, planetarium, planimeter, reflector, refractor, sand glass, scale, seismometer, sextant, spectrogram, spectrometer, spectrometer, stereoscope, sundial, telescope, theodolite, thermocouple, thermometer, voltmeter, zograscope. 19 Convergence failures meant that we could not consistently estimate the models with annual data. 19 for the 1820s to the 1840s. Coefficients across these decades imply approximately a seven-fold relative increase in patents. We do not detect any change in chronometer patents compared to scientific instrument patents based on the estimated coefficients for the 1800s and the 1810s. Because the patenting trends are close for these decades, this provides another baseline comparison. A Wald test shows that coefficients from the 1820s to the 1840s are jointly statistically different from the coefficients for 1800s and the 1810s (χ²=115.14, p=0.000). Interestingly this spike in patenting coincides with intense competition associated with the refinement of chronometers. Specifically, the Admiralty conducted trials at Greenwich to improve the quality of chronometers being supplied to the Navy. The Board of Longitude had initially sent Harrison’s chronometers there to be subjected to scientific scrutiny, and the Admiralty’s “premium trials” from 1823 to 1835 reflected a continuation of this effort. Although the trials did not solve the problem that chronometers tended to lose time during extreme temperature fluctuations, the best chronometers achieved high standards of precision. For example, according to the formula that was used to measure accuracy, a+2b, a chronometer developed by a respected London-based maker Robert Molyneux (d. 1876) was awarded a £200 prize at the “premium trials” in 1832 (a+2b=12.3 comprising of 6.7 for a and 2.8 for b).20 Molyneux patented in 1840. We find a significant boost to patents during the premium trial era, implying that these incremental prizes may have intersected with the patent system to provide a mixture of incentives to promote further technological development. Equally, by around the 1840s chronometers were sufficiently well made and durable that they rarely needed to be replaced. Although the cost of accessing a British patent fell substantially with the modifications to patent law over time, patents became increasingly redundant in an industry that focused more on manufacturing cost efficiency. Kendall’s replica of Harrison’s chronometer cost £450 to construct in 1769 (approximately £55,000 today). By 1840 a chronometer could be produced for £40 (Davis, 2006, p. 515). As the chronometer industry reached technological maturity, patenting inevitably began to attenuate. Private returns, imitation and expropriation risk would have diminished as the technology approached obsolescence. 20 Daily measurements were taken against a synchronized clock with a being the difference in seconds between the greatest and the least weekly sums of the daily rates and b being the greatest difference between two consecutive weekly sums of the daily rate rates. The metric had a scientific and a practical rationale: a would reflect week-toweek precision, a key factor on short voyages and b would reflect long-term precision, a key factor on distant voyages. A smaller value of a+2b was better. Measurement occurred over 29 weeks under variable simulated temperature conditions. See further, Gould (2013, pp. 257, 267-272). 20 V. CONCLUSION The longitude prize is the archetypal example of a government sponsored attempt to promote technological development. It is oft-cited in the literature on the economics of innovation and by policy makers considering the design, or administration of intellectual property rights regimes. Typical accounts assert that the longitude prize led to a major technological breakthrough and so it is frequently used in policy discussions to suggest that prizes can successfully substitute for patents. Yet, such strong normative inferences are not justified by the available evidence. There are still major gaps in our understanding of how the longitude prize actually functioned, and also in the development of the marine chronometer industry more generally. We have combined qualitative and quantitative information with a view to providing a more comprehensive analysis of how innovation incentives influenced the way the navigational challenge was solved. Our results suggest that the search for longitude did not reflect a contrast between prize and patent-based incentives; rather the prize did not preclude patenting and patenting was not precluded by the prize. While patents had not created sufficient incentives to generate private investment in this area of navigational science, the initial 1714 prize led to entry by a group of inventors many of whom still relied on patents. Patenting was advantageous from a government policy perspective because it led to the disclosure of proprietary ideas. Furthermore, the industry developed for reasons beyond the initial spur to entry created by the longitude prize. Although our empirical analysis shows that the Board was unable to precisely control the direction of innovation over time, its progress payments for experimentation facilitated research and development and incremental invention. Notably, most of those awarded payouts also used patents. As the industry progressed during industrial maturity and a dominant design was established, premium award trials were used by the Admiralty to support cumulative innovation, which also coincided with patent usage. Our analysis underscores the presence of a multifaceted system of prize and patent-based innovation incentives affecting the behavior of inventors over the life cycle of the marine chronometer industry. What we cannot do in this paper is to establish causal relationships or make hard inferences concerning welfare. Over the duration of the Board of Longitude, the government did not insist on a transfer of patent rights, nor did it engage in a buyout of inventors who did patent influential inventions. The literature on the theory of optimal innovation incentives has long debated the type of incentives that maximize social welfare (e.g., Wright, 1983; Kremer, 1998; Shavell and 21 Ypersele, 2001; Chari et al., 2012; Spulber, 2014). Even the most optimistic proponents of prizes from a theory perspective note the potential for downside risk. While Polanvyi (1944) argued that government sponsored prizes would create a welfare-efficient solution to incentivizing innovation, he also indicated the potential for “corruption and arbitrary oppression”. Khan (2014) finds imperfect administration in several cases of historical prize competitions. Our analysis should be interpreted more as providing suggestive observational evidence that the longitude prize and patents had jointly beneficial attributes in this historical context. The intersection of prize and patent-based incentives helped to create an inducement effect to spur entry, financed interim R&D and promoted disclosure, thereby helping to facilitate a major technological breakthrough in an area of high social value. It is also important to clarify the circumstances surrounding the use of the longitude prize given its preeminence in policy discussions where the development of welfare beneficial innovations is often thought to be constrained under market mechanisms and patents. 22 References Aplin, Tanya and Jennifer Davis. 2013. Intellectual Property Law. Oxford, Oxford University Press. Betts, Jonathan. 1996 “Arnold & Earnshaw: The Practicable Solution” in William J. H. Andrewes, ed. The Quest for Longitude: The Proceedings of the Longitude Symposium Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press., pp. 311-330. Bottomley, Sean. 2014. The British Patent System during the Industrial Revolution 1700-1852. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press. Boudreau, Kevin J., Nicola Lacetera, and Karim R. Lakhani. 2011. “Incentives and Problem Uncertainty in Innovation Contests: An Empirical Analysis.” Management Science 57(50: 843-863. Broadberry, Stephen, Bruce Campbell, Alexander Klein, Mark Overton and Bas van Leeuwen. 2015. British Economic Growth, 1270-1870. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press. Brunt, Liam, Josh Lerner and Tom Nicholas. 2012. “Inducement Prizes and Innovation”, Journal of Industrial Economics 60(4): 657-696. Chari, V.V., Michael Golosov, and Aleh Tsyvinski. 2012. “Prizes and Patents: Using Market Signals to Provide Incentives for Innovations.” 147(2): 781-801. Davids, Karel, 2009. “Dutch and Spanish Global Networks of Knowledge in the Early Modern Period: Structures, Changes and Limitations,” VU University Amsterdam Working Paper. Davies, Alun C. 1978. “The Life and Death of a Scientific Instrument: The Marine Chronometer, 1770-1920,” Annals of Science 35(5): 509-525. Gould, Rupert T. 2013. The Marine Chronometer, Its History and Development. Woodbridge, Suffolk, England. Howse, Derek. 1998. “Britain’s Board of Longitude: the Finances, 1714-1828,” The Mariner's Mirror 84(4): 400-417. Kalil, Thomas. 2006. “Prizes for Technological Innovation.” Brookings Institution Working Paper no.8. Khan, B. Zorina. 2005. The Democratization of Invention: Patents and Copyrights in American Economic Development, 1790-1920. Cambridge, Mass.: Cambridge University Press. Khan, B. Zorina. 2014. “Inventing in the Shadow of the Patent System: Evidence from 19thCentury Patents and Prizes for Technological Innovations” NBER Working Paper. Khan, B. Zorina. 2015. “Knowledge, Human Capital and Economic Development: Evidence from the British Industrial Revolution, 1750-1930” NBER Working Paper. Klepper, Steven and Kenneth L. Simons, 2000. “The Making of an Oligopoly: Firm Survival and Technological Change in the Evolution of the U.S. Tire Industry,” Journal of Political Economy 108(4): 728-760. Kremer, Michael. 1998. “Patent Buyouts: A Mechanism for Encouraging Innovation,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 113(4): 1137-1167. Kremer, Michael and Heidi Williams. 2010. “Incentivizing Innovation: Adding to the Tool Kit”, Innovation Policy and the Economy 10: 1-17. Landes, David S.1983. Revolution in Time. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press. MacLeod, Christine. 1988. Inventing the Industrial Revolution. The English Patent System, 1660-1800 Cambridge. Cambridge University Press. Mercer, Tony. 1991. Chronometer Makers of the World. London, N.A.G. Press. 23 Mokyr, Joel. 2010. “The Contribution of Economic History to the Study of Innovation and Technical Change: 1750-1914,” in Bronwyn H. Hall, and Nathan Rosenberg, Handbook of the Economics of Innovation, Volume 1. North Holland, Elsevier, pp., 11-50. Moser, Petra. 2012. “Innovation without Patents: Evidence from World’s Fairs,” Journal of Law and Economics, 55(1): 43-74. Moser, Petra and Tom Nicholas. 2013. “Prizes, Publicity and Patents: Non-monetary Awards as a Mechanism to Encourage Innovation,” Journal of Industrial Economics 6(3): 763-788. Murray, Fiona, Scott Stern, Georgina Campbell and Alan MacCormack, 2012. “Grand Innovation Prizes: A Theoretical, Normative and Empirical Evaluation.” Research Policy, 41(10): 1779-1792. Nicholas, Tom. 2013. “Hybrid Innovation in Meiji Japan,” International Economic Review 54(2): 575-600. Officer, Lawrence H. and Samuel H. Williamson. 2014. “Six Ways to Compute the Relative Value of a U.K. Dollar Amount, 1270 to present,” MeasuringWorth, 2014 Polanvyi, Michael. 1944. “Patent Reform,” Review of Economic Studies 11(2): 61-76. Shavell, Steven and Tanguy van Ypersele. 2001. “Rewards versus Intellectual Property Rights,” Journal of Law and Economics 44(4): 525-547. Siegel, Jonathan R. 2009. “Law and Longitude,” Tulane Law Review 84(1): 1-19. Sobel, Dava. 1996. Longitude: The True Story of a Lone Genius Who Solved the Greatest Scientific Problem of His Time. New York: Penguin Press. Spulber, Daniel. 2014. “Prices versus Prizes: Patents, Public Policy, and the Market for Inventions,” Northwestern University Working Paper. Wright, Brian. 1983. “The Economics of Invention Incentives: Patents, Prizes, and Research Contracts,” American Economic Review 73(4): 691-707. Williams, Heidi. 2012. “Innovation Inducement Prizes: Connecting Research to Policy,” Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 31(3): 752-776. 24 Table 1. Descriptive Statistics Board of Post Board Full Time Longitude of Longitude Period 1714-1828 1829-1939 1714-1939 Observations Entry Year Exit Year Patented Longitude Award (progress payment) Prize Winner (other competitions) Britain Firm Maker to Admiralty 271 1802 [23.9] 1841 [33.7] 15.9% 3.0% 6.3% 74.0% 36.5% 35.1% 1,065 1875 [23.9] 1906 [29.1] 18.1% 1,336 1860 [39.6] 1893 [39.7] 17.7% 7.1% 69.7% 35.0% 26.9% 7.0% 70.6% 35.3% 28.6% Notes: Means and standard deviations in parentheses. Data compiled from information in Mercer (1991). Statistics on the percentage who patented are constructed by hand matching observations with a dataset on British patents described in Bunt et al., (2012). Table 2. The Effect of Longitude Awards on Entry and Patents A. Entry Longitude Awardt-1 (1) (2) 0.106** [0.048] 0.085* [0.048] Longitude Awardt-1 (Mechanical) (3) (4) -0.029 [0.046] -0.026 [0.046] Longitude Awardt-1 (Lunar) Entrants t-1 0.154*** [0.059] (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) -0.029 [0.051] 0.140** [0.056] -0.028 [0.048] 0.116** [0.059] 0.149** [0.060] -0.037 [0.043] 0.092 [0.058] -0.035 [0.029] -0.001 [0.017] 0.027 [0.027] 0.140** [0.058] 0.115* [0.060] 0.151** [0.059] 114 -227.35 114 -220.84 114 -227.18 114 -220.66 114 -159.31 (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) 0.074 [0.071] 0.098 [0.078] 0.101 [0.076] 0.057 [0.076] 0.346** [0.157] 0.095 [0.075] 0.088 [0.085] 0.172 [0.193] 0.038 [0.030] -0.042 [0.051] 114 -80.62 114 -79.70 114 -72.05 0.163** [0.064] GDPt-1 Populationt-1 Observations Log pseudolikelihood 114 -228.40 114 -221.61 114 -230.88 114 -223.26 B. Patents Longitude Awardt-1 (1) (2) 0.112 [0.078] 0.102 [0.080] Longitude Awardt-1 (Mechanical) (3) (4) 0.101 [0.073] 0.001 [0.078] Longitude Awardt-1 (Lunar) 0.317** [0.147] Patents t-1 0.120 [0.080] 0.093 [0.079] 0.282** [0.135] 114 -80.97 114 -80.34 0.394** [0.177] GDPt-1 Populationt-1 Observations Log pseudolikelihood 114 -80.86 114 -80.01 114 -81.17 114 -79.87 Notes: The dependent variable in the top panel is an annual count of entrants into the chronometer industry, with entry years determined by Mercer (1991). Columns 1 to 8 include all entrants, while column 9 includes only entrants located in Britain. Indexes of real GDP and population in Britain are from Broadberry et. al., (2015). The dependent variable in bottom panel is an annual count of chronometer patents. Award amounts reflect progress payments made by the Board of Longitude and are compiled from Howes (1998). These were then categorized into mechanical (i.e., chronometer-based) and lunar awards and then converted to constant 1800 values using the retail price index of Officer and Williamson (2014). Award amounts are specified in logarithms with one added to rescale zero values. Coefficients are from negative binomial specifications with robust standard errors. Significance at the *** 1 percent ** 5 percent and * 10 percent levels. Table 3. The Determinants of Patenting (1) (2) (3) Longitude Award (£ amount) 0.047** [0.020] Longitude Award (indicator) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) 0.046** [0.019] 0.488*** [0.166] Prize Winner 0.484*** [0.166] 0.141*** [0.050] 0.493*** [0.164] 0.118** 0.121** [0.049] [0.049] 0.021 [0.109] Great Britain -0.013 [0.028] -0.013 [0.028] 0.000 [0.028] -0.004 [0.028] 0.066 [0.059] Firm 0.020 [0.025] 0.019 [0.025] 0.014 [0.025] 0.017 [0.025] 0.050 [0.057] Maker to the Admiralty Post-Board Era (BL) 0.095*** 0.095*** 0.083*** 0.081*** 0.043 [0.030] [0.030] [0.030] [0.030] [0.062] 0.044 [0.027] 0.046* [0.027] 0.027 [0.027] 0.051* 0.052** [0.027] [0.027] 0.035 [0.027] 0.050* [0.027] 0.084 [0.052] BL×Prize Winner 0.113 [0.141] BL×Great Britain -0.085 [0.074] BL×Firm -0.039 [0.058] BL×Maker to the Admiralty 0.044 [0.072] Observations Log pseudolikelihood 1,163 1,163 1,163 1,163 1,163 1,163 1,163 1,163 -564.25 -563.44 -562.99 -557.60 -556.81 -557.64 -553.26 -556.11 Notes: The dependent variable is an indicator coded 1 for patent usage and 0 otherwise. Award amounts are specified in logarithms with one added to rescale zero values. The full dataset includes 1,336 observations, but data are missing for some of the variables included. Hence, we use 1,163 observations for which we have complete data across the specifications. Coefficients are marginal effects from probit specifications with robust standard errors. Significance at the *** 1 percent ** 5 percent and * 10 percent levels. Observations 200 300 400 500 Figure 1. The Number of Active Chronometer Makers and Craftsmen Post Board of Longitude Era, 1829-1939 0 100 Board of Longitude Era, 1714-1828 1500 1600 1700 1800 1900 2000 Notes: See the text. 300 Figure 2. The Distribution of Entry and Exit Post Board of Longitude Era, 1829-1939 0 Observations 100 200 Board of Longitude Era, 1714-1828 1500 1600 1700 Entry Notes: See the text. 1800 1900 Exit 2000 Figure 3. Geographic Location of Observations ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! !! ! ! !! !!! ! ! ! ! !! ! ! ! ! ! ! !!! ! ! ! ! ! !! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! !! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! !! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! !! ! !! !! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! !!! ! ! !! !!!! ! ! ! !! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! !! ! ! !! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! !!! ! ! ! !! !! !!! ! ! ! !!! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! !! !!! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! !! ! ! ! !! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! !! ! ! ! !! ! !! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! ! !! Notes: Constructed using geocoding of the addresses given in Mercer (1991). 0 10000 British Pounds 20000 30000 40000 Figure 4. Cumulative Board of Longitude Award Payments 1720 1740 1760 Mechanical 1780 1800 1820 Lunar Notes: Award amounts reflect progress payments made by the Board of Longitude and are compiled from Howes (1998). These were categorized into mechanical (i.e., chronometer-based) and lunar awards and then converted to constant 1800 values using the retail price index of Officer and Williamson (2014). Figure 5. Mechanical Area Longitude Awards, Entry and Patents 0 0 5 Number of Entrants 10 15 2000 4000 Mechanical Awards 20 25 6000 A. Entry 1710 1720 1730 1740 1750 1760 1770 1780 1790 1800 1810 1820 1830 0 0 1 Number of Patents 2 2000 4000 Mechanical Awards 3 4 6000 B. Patents 1710 1720 1730 1740 1750 1760 1770 1780 1790 1800 1810 1820 1830 Notes: Award amounts in solid red circles reflect mechanical (i.e., chronometer-based) progress payments made by the Board of Longitude compiled from Howes (1998) converted to constant 1800 values using the retail price index of Officer and Williamson (2014). Bars reflect an annual count of entry in the top figure and an annual count of patents in the bottom figure. 0 20 Percent 40 60 Figure 6. The Timing of Inventor Patents and Awards -20 -10 0 10 Patent Lag Relative to Award Date 20 Notes: The timing of awards reflects the year a progress payment was made by the Board of Longitude from Howes (1998). The timing of patents reflects when a patent was issued. Negative values on the x-axis indicate patenting prior to an award and positive values reflect post-award patenting. Patents 10 12 14 16 18 20 Figure 7. Chronometer Patents 1717 to 1939 Post Board of Longitude Era, 1829-1939 0 2 4 6 8 Board of Longitude Era, 1714-1828 1700 1750 1800 Moving Average 1850 1900 1950 Raw Data Notes: Raw plot of chronometer patents per year overlaid using a 10 year moving average of the series. Figure 8. Time Varying Effects of Changes in Chronometer Patenting -6 Relative to Base Period = 1710s to 1790s -5 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 A. Relative to All British Patents 1800 1810 1820 1830 1840 1850 1860 1870 1880 1890 1900 1910 1920 1930 Decade -6 Relative to Base Period = 1710s to 1790s -4 -2 0 2 4 B. Relative to Scientific Instrument Patents 1800 1810 1820 1830 1840 1850 1860 1870 1880 1890 1900 1910 1920 1930 Decade Notes: Coefficients derived from a negative binomial difference-in-differences specification where the indicator for chronometer patents was interacted with a decade indicator to obtain time varying estimates. The Board of Longitude was dissolved by an Act of Parliament in the 1820s (1828).